INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE

HOUSING
CO-OPERATIVES

.;->'.;..,;.

GENEVA
G
ENEVA

V, '

, > •

l

•s

5"

1964

•••••4.:.^J-'-:''::"

STUDIES AND REPORTS
New Series, No. 66

PRINTED BY "LA TRIBUNE DE GENÈVE", GENEVA (SWITZERLAND)

CONTENTS
Page
INTRODUCTION

1

PART I
GENERAL DESCRIPTION
CHAPTER I : Characteristics and Advantages of Housing Co-operatives . . . .
The Co-operative Housing Sector
Building Workers' Co-operatives
Co-operatives Conferring Individual Ownership
Collective Ownership Co-operatives
Tenants' Co-operatives
Mutual Self-Help Co-operatives
Management Co-operatives
Building Credit Co-operatives
Scandinavian System
Developing Countries
Advantages of the Co-operative System
The Main Positive Factors Needed

7
7
8
8
8
9
9
10
10
10
10
11
12

PART n
THE SCANDINAVIAN COUNTRIES
CHAPTER II: Sweden

Historical Background
Organisation
Structure of the H.S.B
" Daughter " Co-operatives
" Mother " Co-operatives
The National H.S.B
Membership of H.S.B. Co-operatives
Allocation of Housing
Repair Fund
Relationship between the Co-operative and Its Members
Transfer of the Right of Co-operative Ownership
Dissolution
System of Financing of the H.S.B
Internal Financing
Financing of Co-operative Building
The Role of Public Authorities
Inter-Co-operative Financing
The H.S.B. and the Building Industry
Swedish National Building Society
Social Significance

15

15
16
19
19
19
21
22
22
23
23
24
25
25
26
26
29
32
32
33
34

IV

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
Page

CHAPTER III: Denmark

Historical Background
Organisation
General Federation of Danish Housing Associations
The Arbejderbo
Financing
Mortgage Credit Co-operatives
Building Workers' Co-operatives
The Role of Public Authorities
Building Fund
Social Significance
CHAPTER TV: Norway

36

36
36
37
38
40
40
41
41
42
43
45

Historical Background
Organisation
Membership
Transfer of Co-operative Property
Youth Co-operative Movement
Financing
Co-operative Finance
The Role of Public Authorities
Social Significance

45
46
47
48
48
50
51
51
53

PART in
OTHER EUROPEAN COUNTRIES
CHAPTER V: France

Historical Background
Organisation of the H.L.M. Co-operative Movement
Types of Co-operative Housing Schemes
Co-operatives of Future Owners
Privileged Users' Co-operatives
Tenants' Co-operatives
Financing of H.L.M. Co-operatives
Homes for Ownership
Homes for Rent
Comprehensive Loans
Savings
Membership of H.L.M. Co-operatives
Limited Means
Nationality
Protection of Members' Interests
Social Significance
CHAPTER VI: Federal Republic of Germany
Historical Background
Present Situation
Organisation
Regional Audit Unions
National Union
Building Workers' Co-operative Movement
Some Characteristics of German Housing Co-operatives

57

57
58
59
59
59
61
62
62
62
63
63
64
64
65
65
65
67
67
67
68
70
70
71
73

CONTENTS

V
Page

Financing
Members' Contributions
Private Credit Institutions
The Role of Public Authorities
Social Significance
CHAPTER VII: Poland

75
75
76
76
78
80

Historical Background
Organisation
Financing
Social Significance

80
81
82
82

CHAPTER VIII: Spain
Historical Background
Social Housing Policy
Organisation
Financing
Social Significance

85
85
85
86
88
90

PART IV
NORTH AMERICA
CHAPTER IX: Canada

95

Historical Background
Organisation
Nova Scotia
Quebec
Ontario
New Trends
Financing
Social Significance

95
98
98
98
100
102
102
105

CHAPTER X: United States
Historical Background
Organisation
Financing
Social Significance

107
107
110
112
116

PART V
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
CHAPTER XI: Colombia

Historical Background
Organisation
General Characteristics
Characteristic Type of Housing Co-operative
Mutual-Help Co-operatives
Colombian Federation of Housing Co-operatives
Financing
Social Significance

121

121
121
121
122
123
123
124
125

VI

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
Page

CHAPTER XII: India

127

Historical Background
Organisation
Financing
Subsidised Industrial Housing Scheme
Low Income Group Housing Scheme
Middle Income Group Housing Scheme
Village Housing Projects Scheme
Social Significance

CHAPTER XIII: United Arab Republic
Historical Background
Organisation
Financing
Social Significance

127
127
129
130
130
130
131
132

133
133
133
134
136

PART VI
CO-OPERATION AND THE HOUSING PROBLEM IN THE
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
CHAPTER XIV: Suggestions for Adaptation of the Co-operative Formula in
Developing Countries
139
Organisation
139
The Three Basic Forms
139
Selection of the Type of Co-operative
140
Comprehensive Housing Co-operatives
141
Personal Mutual-Help Co-operatives
142
Co-operatives of Future Owners
142
Management Co-operatives
143
Tenants' Co-operatives
144
Building Workers' Co-operatives
144
Certain Essential Requirements
145
Co-operative Education and Training
145
Federation of Societies
146
Relations between Co-operatives
146
Economic Organisation
147
Normal Market Prices
147
National Housing Policy
147
Special Legislation
148
Housing Agency
148
Building Sites
149
Credit Facilities
149
Stable Interest Rates
149
Subsidies
149
Agents of Social Policy
150
Financing
150
Housing Co-operatives and the Building Industry
152
Model Urban and Rural Neighbourhood Communities
153

CONTENTS

VII
Page

LIST OF TABLES
I.

France: Maximum Loans Granted by the State for the Construction of
Low-Cost Family Housing

63

II. Germany: Housing Construction, 1927-35

68

III. Federal Republic of Germany: Homes Built by and on Behalf of Cooperatives, 1950-61

69

IV. Federal Republic of Germany: Co-operative Share Capital, 1950-60 . . .

77

V. India: Development of Housing Co-operatives, 1957-60

128

INTRODUCTION
Housing is one of the basic needs of man, and a shortage of housing
constitutes a grave problem from two points of view: the one social, and
the other economic. Social, because a shortage of accommodation compels many families to dwell in unhygienic conditions, with harmful
consequences for their health; because the home environment in which
a child grows up has a very important bearing on the forming of his
character as an adult and on the part he will come to play in society;
and because a worker who Uves in wretched conditions is usually unable
to engender a consciousness of true human dignity either in himself or
in his children. Economic, because the bad social conditions in which
the worker lives cause his standard of output to fall; so much so that the
success of economic planning may be said to depend in some respects
upon the housing facilities available to the people.
This explains why the International Labour Organisation has always
shown such active interest in seeking a solution to the housing problem,
in line with the principles embodied in the Constitution of the Organisation and reaffirmed in 1944 in the Declaration of Philadelphia, which
recognises the solemn obligation of the I.L.O. to further among the
nations of the world programmes which will provide adequate housing.
The problem of housing—and workers' housing in particular—has
therefore been debated at a great many meetings organised by the I.L.O.,
and significant conclusions and resolutions have been adopted on the
major aspects of this problem. In 1960 and 1961 the subject was discussed at the General Conference of the I.L.O., culminating in the
adoption in 1961 of a Recommendation concerning workers' housing
which sets forth a series of provisions on the objectives of national
housing policy, the responsibility of public authorities, housing provided
by employers, financing, housing standards, measures to promote
efficiency in the building industry, house building and employment
stabilisation, and town, country and regional planning, and suggests a
series of practical measures regarding these matters. 1 At the same session
in 1961 the International Labour Conference adopted a resolution
concerning international action in the field of workers' housing, in which
it requested the Governing Body of the International Labour Office to
1

Official Bulletin (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. XLIV, 1961, No. 1, pp. 4 ff.

2

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

find ways and means of increasing, in collaboration with the organisations concerned, both international and national, practical assistance in
particular to developing countries in solving their housing problems with
respect to thosefieldsin which the I.L.O. has a special competence under
the United Nations Long-Range Programme of Concerted Action in the
Field of Housing and Related Community Facilities and, in particular,
vocational training of building workers, productivity in the building
industry and co-operative housing.1
The problem of housing is in no way new, but it continues to be of
pressing and profound concern, despite the achievements realised in some
countries since the Second World War. The problem is a complex
one, since the causes of a housing shortage are many-sided. Aggravating
factors include the growth in the world's population, the increasing
concentration of workers in the industrial urban centres and the general
failure to develop available resources of building materials. From the
point of view of the workers, and of low-income families in general, the
real problem amounts to this : is it possible for the mass of the workers,
alone and unaided, to acquire decent homes of their own if they set aside
a reasonable proportion of their incomes for that purpose? A series of
surveys shows that in the majority of cases the reply is in the negative.
In view of the gravity of the problem, the need is daily becoming more
apparent for investigation of the principal methods which might be
encouraged in an endeavour to help find a satisfactory solution to the
distressing problem resulting from a shortage of housing. One such
method is the co-operative system. This is a field of activity in which the
International Labour Organisation has special competence2 and with
which it has concerned itself ever since its foundation immediately after
the end of the First World War, as a means of helping to raise the
standard of living of the working classes.
The author of this study is Mr. Samuel Ruiz LUJAN, a member of
the Co-operation and Small-Scale Industries Division of the I.L.O. Its
purpose is to describe how some of the principal co-operative housing
schemes came into being and are operated in certain countries, as
revealed by the documentation available when the report was prepared.
The most interesting achievements in the field of housing are noted, and
attention is drawn to the factors which have led to success or failure,
in the hope that this will be of help in particular to developing countries
by providing information on the great advantages and savings to be
1

Official Bulletin, Vol. XLIV, 1961, No. I, p. 26.
See, for example, UNITED NATIONS: Twentieth Report of the Administrative
Committee on Co-ordination to the Economic and Social Council, document E/2931,
18 Oct. 1956, paras. 14 and 15.
2

INTRODUCTION

3

derived from the successful use of co-operative techniques. Further
studies which may be produced later in this field may deal with other
aspects of the housing problem or describe the co-operative achievements of other groups of countries in the different continents.
The I.L.O. wishes to express its appreciation to the Swedish H.S.B.
(Hyresgästernas Sparkasse- och Byggnadsföreningars Riksförbund),
and in particular to Mr. Sven Kypengren and Mr. Âke Johnsson,
for the most valuable information on which the section concerning the
Scandinavian countries is based.

PART I
GENERAL DESCRIPTION

CHAPTER I
CHARACTERISTICS AND ADVANTAGES OF
HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
There are various forms of co-operatives to meet the need for
accommodation: some deal only with specific phases in the provision of
housing, such as financing or building, while others cover all the phases
from the selection and purchase of the land to the administration of the
completed project and the establishment of complementary community
services.
THE CO-OPERATIVE HOUSING SECTOR

It has been debated in the past whether co-operative housing should
be classified as a consumers' movement or a producers' movement. In
actual fact, this type of co-operation aimed at satisfying the need for
housing in the wide sense in which it is considered in this study has
always had a twofold character, embracing both consumption and
production, depending on whether people join together with a view to
becoming occupants, in which case they look upon the accommodation
not as a production article but as a consumer commodity, or whether
teams of workers in the building industry band together on a co-operative
basis and operate undertakings to produce dwellings for others. A
typical example of a large-scale co-operative housing scheme which is
predominantly a consumers' movement is the Swedish Tenants' Savings
Bank and Building Society, or H.S.B., whereas the Swedish National
Building Society, or S.R., the other big housing co-operative in Sweden,
is a classic example of co-operative housing in which production is the
keynote. The way in which both societies operate will be discussed fully
in the section dealing with achievements in the field of co-operative
housing in that country.
There also exists a third form of co-operative housing which has been
particularly successful in Canada, whereby both objectives are combined
in a single organisation. Societies organised as teams of workers produce
a given number of dwellings, not for third parties but to be occupied by
the members who have built them and who will then be using them as
consumer goods.

8

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

The truth is that every day it is becoming clearer that co-operative
housing forms a well-defined sector on its own, having its special features
and problems, and having developed its own specialised methods and
activities in this sphere. In its widest sense it embraces the organisations
of both producers and occupiers of housing, and is a movement on its
own, although naturally bound by the generally accepted principles and
methods of international co-operation and linked with the other branches
of the same movement.
BUILDING WORKERS' CO-OPERATIVES

Co-operatives in which production is the dominant feature, and
which are organised in the main by building workers with the immediate
aim of creating employment for their members, generally cover all the
phases involved in the construction of a particular house or group of
houses. Sometimes they build for other co-operatives of future occupiers
or for other non-profit organisations concerned with housing; sometimes
for the employees of the consumers' co-operatives or of other private
undertakings; sometimes for municipal housing programmes; sometimes
for individual families; and sometimes they handle projects for other
residents' co-operatives organised under their auspices.
CO-OPERATIVES CONFERRING INDIVIDUAL OWNERSHIP

Among the co-operatives organised with the primary objective of
building houses to be lived in by the members themselves, some confer
individual ownership upon their members while others retain the ownership of the buildings and allocate the individual dwellings to their
members, giving them privileged occupancy rights which they may pass
on to their heirs.
Of the co-operatives which confer individual ownership on their
members, some do so as soon as building is completed, if each individual
member is directly liable for the financial obligations incurred; it is more
usual, however, for the deeds not to be made over until the mortgage has
been paid off. Such societies normally build single-family houses, and
are frequently wound up once the houses have been handed over.
COLLECTIVE OWNERSHIP CO-OPERATIVES

Co-operatives which retain the ownership of the property have confined themselves in the main to constructing buildings or groups of buildings, or even large residential estates, with particularly noteworthy
achievements in the Scandinavian countries and in New York City.

CHARACTERISTICS AND ADVANTAGES

9

These organisations are of a permanent nature, and are characterised by
the fact that they not only endeavour to satisfy the housing needs of their
members but also create additional amenities for the benefit of the community in the neighbourhood. In these co-operatives—as in the societies
conferring individual ownership—the member pays for his accommodation in accordance with the agreed financial arrangements, but instead of
becoming the individual owner he receives a stake as co-owner of the
building or group of buildings which make up the project, being allotted
a dwelling which he lives in and runs as if it were his own. He may sell
his stake in the property, but naturally only in accordance with the
stipulations laid down in the rules of each society, so as to preclude
profiteering contrary to the principles of co-operation.
A variant of this type of comprehensive housing co-operative has
emerged in the United States since the Second World War, based on
large-scale projects for buildings constructed mainly by the Government
as part of its war time programme, which has made it easier for many
families of modest means to acquire homes. The organisation, functioning and advantages of these mutual home ownership associations will be
studied in the chapter on the United States.
TENANTS' CO-OPERATIVES

Between the respective methods whereby ownership is either conferred
on members or retained by societies come the tenants' co-operatives. In
these, as the name indicates, the members are not individual owners nor
have they a privileged right of occupancy which may be transferred.
They are tenants, but as members they do not just pay a reasonable rent
but also have a voice and a vote in the administration of the actual
buildings they occupy, which are leased to them by the society. These
tenants' co-operatives have thrived in France in particular during the past
few years and, as examined below, they have special financing arrangements.
MUTUAL SELF-HELP CO-OPERATIVES

Another interesting type of housing co-operative has emerged in
Canada, in particular as part of the so-called Antigonish Movement,
which combines the two elements of production and consumption in a
single association, as discussed above. The principal characteristics of
these co-operatives are that they consist of small groups which first study
the different aspects of the housing problem and its possible solution for
their families and then organise themselves on a co-operative basis as
teams of workers to construct the houses needed.

10

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
MANAGEMENT CO-OPERATIVES

In some countries, once the job of building is completed and the
houses allocated, the co-operative is wound up or devotes itself entirely
to other projects, and the residents form a new society to manage the
dwellings and organise complementary services. These societies are
known as management co-operatives.
BUILDING CREDIT CO-OPERATIVES

Societies extending credit for building represent another of the ways
in which co-operation can help to solve the housing problem. The funds
of such co-operatives are derived from two main sources : either shares
taken out by members, or deposits made by the members or by other
persons or bodies. Each member of a society must subscribe and pay for
shares or deposit a sum equivalent to at least 7 or 8 per cent, of the cost
of the house he wishes to buy or construct. The society offers mortgage
loans, generally for 80 per cent, of the value of the building, to be paid
off in instalments over a specified number of years. This type of cooperative has made a noteworthy contribution to the house-building
industry in some countries, particularly in Great Britain.

SCANDINAVIAN SYSTEM

In Scandinavia, which is the most interesting group of countries as
far as co-operative housing is concerned, the three aspects of saving,
building and the subsequent administration of the projects, instead of
being handled by individual specialised societies, are combined in a single
organisation, with very satisfactory results. In the chapters which follow,
and in particular in connection with Sweden, it will be seen in detail how
this system works, and what is the structure of the so-called " mother "
and " daughter " societies which are characteristic of the co-operative
housing movement in the Scandinavian countries.
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Housing co-operatives certainly do not represent the only possible
answer to the grave problem of accommodation. Progress on these lines
is hindered by a variety of obstacles which may be financial or sociological,
administrative or of some other nature. Nevertheless, the results obtained
in countries where this form of co-operation has advanced to a notable
extent will be seen below to give grounds for the belief that in other parts

CHARACTERISTICS AND ADVANTAGES

11

of the world, and in developing countries in particular, similar achievements can be realised through the adoption of the co-operative outlook
and techniques as an integral part of the social housing programme of the
various state and municipal authorities. Part VI is devoted to examination
of the possibility of adapting such techniques to the developing countries.
ADVANTAGES OF THE CO-OPERATIVE SYSTEM

Among the advantages offered by the co-operatives as a way of helping to solve the housing problem, mention may be made of the following:
Financial:
They encourage people to save, and channel such money into the financing
of house building.
They reduce and stabilise prices by eliminating a series of speculators at
all stages from sale and development of land to actual building.
They facilitate credit on favourable terms.
They can practise mass-production methods.
They purchase building materials at wholesale prices.
They are directly engaged in production, establishing their own factories.
They produce and use best quality materials, since they are non-profit
bodies.
Technical:
They organise their own technical services.
They engage highly qualified technical staff.
They carry out their own surveys in respect of all the problems relating to
building.
They set quality standards.
They introduce new techniques into the construction and running of
homes.
Social:
They offer many low-income families the only means within their reach
of acquiring a decent home.
They encourage people to turn their spirit of initiative and mutual aid
towards solving their own housing problem by inviting them to participate in a joint programme rather than depend entirely on outside help.
They relieve the state and municipal authorities of a large part of their
administrative and economic responsibilities in the field of housing.

12

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

They establish additionalfinancial,cultural and recreational amenities as
part of their housing programmes.
They help to create new communities where neighbours who come to
know and appreciate one another better through engaging in the same
co-operative activities are likely to maintain closer ties.
They constitute a satisfactory method for public authorities in their social
housing programmes for the modernisation of large cities, replacing
old districts full of unhygienic dwellings with well-planned cooperative projects equipped with the best amenities for the people.
THE MAIN POSITIVE FACTORS NEEDED

It goes without saying that if co-operation is to play an important
role in solving a country's housing problem it is necessary first of all, as
shown in the chapters which follow, to create a favourable climate in
which co-operatives can flourish. What must be done in the first place,
for instance, is to awaken the interest of the people who are to form the
foundation of the co-operative system, in order that they may realise the
strength which comes from self-help and mutual aid, and may thus be
ready to play an active part in the co-operative programme to solve their
housing problem. A well-thought-out national housing policy is needed,
giving co-operatives favourable conditions in which to operate and
providing the necessary financing institutions to extend credit on terms
that will enable low-income families to participate in the programmes
also. Well-organised co-operatives are needed which will co-ordinate
their housing activities so as to make use of all available resources in
their programmes, set up their own subsidiary companies for the production of materials and derive the greatest benefit from modern building
techniques.

PART II
THE SCANDINAVIAN COUNTRIES

CHAPTER II
SWEDEN
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

Sweden is in the vanguard of the countries where co-operatives play
a role of great importance in the solution of the housing problem.1
Although a society for the construction of housing was founded in
Gothenburg as long ago as 1872—setting an example which was quickly
imitated by a number of other societies of the same type which were
founded in Stockholm from 1874 onwards—the co-operative housing
movement as such is of more recent date, having originated in the period

between the two world wars. The building societies which were founded
at the end of the last century and in the period before the First World
War were isolated enterprises with a very limited field of action, from
which the profit motive was not always excluded. Nevertheless, despite
the fact that these societies were not really co-operatives, it must be
acknowledged that they were of service to the community, not only
because they contributed towards relieving the housing shortage but
because they introduced a certain spirit of co-operation with the organisation of groups, thus preparing the ground for the formation of the housing
co-operatives of today.
In 1916 the Central Union of Social Labour, a workers' organisation
representing a powerful force in the political and economic life of the
country, founded an important co-operative housing society which may
be looked upon as the forerunner of the modern movement which was
to make its appearance a few years later. This Co-operative Housing
Society of Stockholm, anxious to eliminate the profit-making basis which
had been a feature of the earlier societies, established the principle whereby the co-operatives as such retained ownership of their dwelling units,
allocating accommodation to their members for occupancy for an
indefinite period. This first co-operative housing society, which was
founded with the assistance of the Stockholm City Council, was a success;
by 1951 it was administering over 2,800 apartments for its members.
1
Sweden is therefore the first country to be considered in this document. In
view of its achievements in the field of co-operative housing it is examined more
thoroughly, and often serves as a point of reference for the study of other countries.

16

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Organisation of the co-operative housing movement on a national
scale did not begin, however, until 1924. The immediate cause lay in the
distressing social conditions following the First World War owing to the
shortage of housing, and the consequent soaring of rents which characterised that period, laying a heavy burden on families of modest means.
Furthermore, the overcrowding and unhygienic conditions of accommodation available on the market were both a constant menace to health,
especially of children, and an obstacle to creating a pleasant home
environment.
As a result of this situation, even before the end of the First World
War, tenants' associations sprang up in the working-class districts of
Stockholm to protect the interests of their members and seek a satisfactory means of solving their housing problem. In an endeavour to
create a stronger force to achieve their objectives the associations in the
different districts set up a central body which they called the Tenants'
Union of Stockholm, and this society came to the conclusion that if any
radical improvement was to be made in the housing situation the best
thing to do was to seek ways of constructing and administering their
own dwellings. This led to the founding in 1923 of the Tenants' Savings
and Building Society, commonly known by the initials of its name in
Swedish, H.S.B. (Hyresgästernas Sparkasse- och Byggnadsförening).
The example set by this co-operative society in Stockholm was
imitated in other Swedish cities. But there still remained one great
hurdle to be overcome before an adequate housing programme could be
brought under way: as a result of the war, building costs had risen
considerably. So it was that the independent societies formed by tenants
in the different cities united to form a central national association with its
headquarters in Stockholm which, by pooling all resources and operating
on a vast scale, was able to cut down costs. This happened in 1924, a
year which will therefore go down in history as the year when the modern
co-operative housing movement in this country was born.
ORGANISATION

Although the various forms of housing co-operative in Sweden are,
of course, part of the national co-operative movement, from a structural
point of view housing co-operatives have their own special characteristics, and their internal structure within the country is completely
independent of that of the other branches of the Swedish co-operative
movement.
The H.S.B. is the most powerful organisation and the one which
best typifies the co-operative housing movement in Sweden. The

SWEDEN

17

most striking characteristic it reveals regarding this type of Swedish
co-operation is the way in which the three elements of savings, construction and administration of housing projects are combined in a single
organisation.
The basis for the structure of the H.S.B. lies in the so-called " mother "
co-operatives which have been formed all over the country, and which
cover specific areas. These societies are joined by all residents of the area
interested in obtaining a co-operative dwelling. The strength of the
Swedish co-operative housing system lies in these " mother " co-operatives, which are continually planning new building operations for the
benefit of their members in the light of the needs of their area of competence. The " mother " co-operatives encourage their members to save,
they collect such savings, they acquire the necessary sites and they run
the whole building project.
Once building is completed and the lucky members installed in their
respective homes, the " mother " society organises them into a " daughter "
co-operative whose function is the administration and maintenance of the
building or group of buildings in which they live. Each " daughter "
co-operative is an independent economic and social unit, but the members
of the " daughter " association continue at the same time to be members of the " mother " society, with all the rights and privileges deriving
therefrom. What is more, the task of the " mother " co-operatives
does not finish when building ends, as they continue to look after the
interests of their " daughters " by seeing to their bookkeeping, collecting
payments due and arranging for administrative, economic or social
services.
The " daughter " society owns the building or group of buildings, as
the case may be. The occupants are in reality neither tenants nor
individual owners. Each member who has been allotted a home is
entitled to indefinite " use " of that dwelling so long as he keeps up the
appropriate payments and obeys the rules of the society.
At the national level there is a central H.S.B. body whose members
are the " mother " co-operatives. In 1959 it had 188 affiliated " mother "
co-operatives which were operating in different parts of the country and
had a total membership of 150,000.
Under the constitution of the H.S.B. the functions of the national
society include the following :
to lend assistance in the establishment of new co-operatives of the H.S.B.
type, or in the formation of any subsidiary societies that may be
necessary;

18

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

to facilitate the exchange of ideas and experience among the various
" mother " societies ;
to offer legal assistance to its members;
to give technical help to building projects initiated;
to purchase building materials at wholesale prices;
to make direct arrangements, where advisable, for the production of
building materials needed ;
to organise and stimulate savings among the members of the H.S.B.
movement;
to provide loans to " mother " societies which need them.
In order to be able to carry out its functions the national H.S.B. has
set up its own bank and a number of specialised departments responsible
for top-level handling of both the administrative and the technical aspects
of the different projects.
The national H.S.B. plays a role of great importance in the Swedish
co-operative housing movement, not only because it channels and
distributes personal savings through its own bank in order to finance an
appreciable part of construction costs, and because it represents the
individual co-operatives and establishes direct contact with other sources
of credit, but also because its position enables it to engage the services of
the most highly qualified experts in fields such as economics, town
planning, architecture and design to make the necessary surveys and put
into effect the building projects called for under its national housing
programme.
Another very important function of the national H.S.B. is research.
In nearly 40 years of activity the national H.S.B. has acquired valuable
experience in the construction and administration of buildings, and this
experience is studied, analysed and then brought to the notice of the
member co-operatives in order that use may be made of it in planning the
construction and administration of new housing. This explains why the
housing co-operatives were the first to introduce more advanced and
efficient building methods in Sweden, as well as initiating significant
achievements in making co-operative dwellings more pleasant and comfortable, as will be seen below.
Of no less importance is the service performed by the national H.S.B.
in testing different construction materials and laying down standards
of quality to be observed by its member co-operatives. Moreover,
this information is gradually made available to private building firms
as well.

19

SWEDEN
STRUCTURE OF THE

H.S.B.

Like every true co-operative, the H.S.B. is a democratic organisation,
whether viewed from the national angle or at its base level—i.e. the
" mother " society or the " daughter " administering a specific housing
project.
" Daughter " Co-operatives
The supreme authority of the " daughter " association is the members'
meeting, which elects four members to the board of the association.
Under the rules which govern relations between a " mother " society and
its " daughters " the former reserves the right to appoint the fifth member
of the board of each " daughter ", as well as an auditor.
" Mother " Co-operatives
Meeting.
In the " mother " society too the general meeting of members is the
supreme administrative authority. In the case of co-operatives whose
numerical strength is relatively small, representation is direct; otherwise
it is through delegates. Thus in the " mother " co-operative for Stockholm, for example, which in 1959 had some 35,000 members, representation is indirect, and the method followed for the election of delegates is as
follows : each " daughter " co-operative has the right to elect two delegates, plus an additional delegate for every 100 members after the first
100. Members who have not yet obtained their co-operative dwellings—
in 1960 the " mother " society for Stockholm had nearly 20,000 members
in this category—elect one delegate for each 75 members.
Board.
Often the " mother " societies of the H.S.B. elect an advisory board
to deal with administrative matters. Such a board is composed of six
members, two of whom are elected directly by the tenants' associations,
the bodies which founded the H.S.B. shortly after the First World War,
and the remaining four by the members' meeting. The rules do not
require the members of this advisory body to be members of any of the
co-operatives in the H.S.B. movement; it is even expressly stipulated that
half of them must be chosen from among outstanding local personalities
with an interest in or special knowledge of housing questions, and must
not be members of the co-operative.
The following are some of the principal matters about which the
members of this body have to be consulted in advance :
general policy in respect of property administration;

20

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

acceptance of loans ;
consideration of the most important building problems ;
long-term investment of available funds;
the agenda for meetings of the management committee;
the budget;
matters to be submitted for consideration to the annual meeting.
Another function of this advisory body is to propose to the annual
meeting candidates for election either to the management committee or as
auditors.
Management Committee.
The members' meeting, which is normally held only once a year,
delegates a considerable part of its administrative functions to a management committee, generally consisting of five members elected for a twoyear term. Elections are staggered, so that the situation never arises
where the committee consists entirely of new members who are unfamiliar
with the administrative problems in hand. The functions of this committee vary according to the terms of reference laid down for them by
the by-laws and by the decisions of meetings in the various societies.

Broadly speaking, it may be said that the management committee of an
H.S.B. " mother " co-operative is empowered to sell, demolish or rebuild
the property of the society. In addition it administers the savings of
members, since each " mother " society acts as a branch of the bank
belonging to the national H.S.B. The committee is also responsible for
organising the educational programme to provide training in co-operative
methods for members, especially as regards the problems involved. On
the administrative side, it is the task of the committee to admit or expel
members or employees, in conformity with the principles established in
the by-laws or in the internal rules, as the case may be.
The management committee engages the administrative and technical
staff needed to cope with the volume of work in each society. At their
head, directing the work of every employee of the co-operative, is the
manager, who is also chosen by the committee. Generally speaking,
managers attend meetings of the committees of their respective societies,
and are allowed to speak, but not to vote, in the discussions.
Auditing.
Regular examination of the books of each society is an item of great
importance in the co-operative housing movement of the H.S.B.
For the " mother " societies of the H.S.B. there are generally two

SWEDEN

21

auditors, one elected directly by the general meeting of the society
concerned and the other appointed by the competent department
of the national H.S.B. In cases where the State is helping to finance
co-operative housing projects, the municipal authorities also have the
right, if they so desire, to designate a third auditor. As a general rule
auditors are elected for one year, and may be re-elected an indefinite
number of times.

The National H.S.B.
Congress.
The supreme authority of the national H.S.B. movement is the congress, attended by delegates from the " mother " societies, which elect
their representatives in accordance with their own internal rules. Each
" mother " society is entitled to elect one delegate. As the maximum
number of congress delegates is fixed at 300, any vacant seats are distributed among the " mother " societies in proportion to the number of
their members. As a general rule each delegate is entitled to one vote,
except in the case of revision of the by-laws, the election of members of
the national board or matters connected with financial contributions, in
which specific cases each " mother " society has only one vote, irrespective of the number of delegates representing it at the congress. When
other types of ordinary business are being discussed, on the other
hand, each individual delegate may exercise his right to vote independently,
and it frequently happens that representatives of the same " mother "
society express different opinions.
Board.
The congress of the H.S.B. delegates the authority vested in it under
the law and the by-laws to a board, also elected by the congress for a
three-year term of office. This board consists of 25 members, two of
whom are nominated by the central offices of the H.S.B. and the remainder chosen directly by the congress, which endeavours at all times to
ensure representation of all the geographical areas into which the
country is divided.
The functions of the board include the over-all direction of the
executive activities of the national H.S.B.; the examination of reports;
the approval of balance sheets; the distribution of any profits which may
accrue from the operations of subsidiary industrial undertakings; and
the election of members both of the executive committee and of the
auditing committee.

22

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Executive Committee.
The seven-man executive committee is responsible for the day-to-day
administration of the national H.S.B. Under the by-laws it may, without
prior authorisation from the board, sell or mortgage properties belonging
to the national association. But for matters such as the investment of
capital to open up new sectors of activity the committee needs the express
approval of the board. The committee must also consult the board when
the question arises either of widening the scope of activities by the construction of new buildings or of making substantial changes in the quality
standards set for building materials, or in similar matters.

Membership of H.S.B. Co-operatives
In principle anybody who has a housing problem to solve may join
the " mother " co-operative in the district where he lives. In order to
become a member of the H.S.B. movement he must contribute to the
co-operative's capital by taking out one membership share, and must pay
an admission fee. In addition the H.S.B. societies insist that prospective
members should first join a tenants' association, if one exists in their
district. In imposing this condition they remind members of the movement's origins and ideals.
Membership of " daughter " co-operatives is naturally limited to
those living in the dwelling units which make up the building or group of
houses covered by a given project.

Allocation of Housing
It is not general practice in Sweden for ownership rights to be granted
to members who move into newly completed dwellings. The usual
procedure—and the same can be said, broadly speaking, of the other
Scandinavian countries—is for members to be entitled to " use " of the
homes allotted to them. In Sweden the societies of the H.S.B., and
following their example the other housing co-operatives which have been
set up in the country, grant this right of occupancy for an indefinite
period.
It frequently happens, however, that the H.S.B., in view of the
efficiency it has shown in its efforts to provide housing on favourable
terms, is asked to furnish technical help for private house building. In
such cases, once construction is completed the houses are handed over as
private property.

SWEDEN

23

Repair Fund
The H.S.B. co-operatives set up a special fund to cover the cost of any
repairs which may be needed. The members of the " daughter " cooperatives are required to make monthly payments into this fund until it
reaches a specified level, 5 per cent, of the value of the apartment they
occupy. Repairs are made with money from this fund; when it drops
below a safe level the member resumes his monthly payments. In this
way the co-operatives encourage their members to keep their homes in
the best condition so that their monthly payments to the fund are kept at
a minimum.1
It should be noted that while repair costs are met out of the balance
credited to each resident in the fund established for this purpose, members
may not order repairs to be carried out without prior authorisation from
the management of their " daughter " co-operative. On the other hand,
if a member does not take the trouble to keep his accommodation in good
repair, then the management of the co-operative will itself order the
necessary repairs to be carried out, drawing for the purpose on the funds
credited to the offending member. In the case of extensive repair work or
modernisation, the co-operative draws on its emergency fund.

Relationship between the Co-operative and Its Members
As in any good co-operative organisation, within the H.S.B. movement there is a clearly established policy of maintaining the best possible
human relations between management and members, in order that the
latter may be kept informed of progress and encouraged to take an active
part in programmes and activities. In the " mother " co-operatives in the
cities of Sweden the number of members varies, as a rule, between 300
and 400; in the " daughter " societies in the towns the number of members is generally from 70 to 80, while in the villages the largest have
about 30, and the smallest six.
The city of Stockholm, however, is a case apart, since the " mother "
co-operative had 35,000 members in 1959, and some of its " daughters "
had up to 1,000 members each. This growth in the societies which has
taken place particularly in recent years stems from a desire to increase
the administrative efficiency of the various projects by basing them on
larger units, but it has made it more difficult to maintain close relations
between the societies and their members. The societies have consequently
1
UNITED NATIONS, Department of Economic and Social Affairs : Housing through
Non-Profit Organizations, Housing, Building and Planning, No. 10 (New York, 1956;
Sales No.: 1956. IV.T), p. 99.

24

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

multiplied their efforts to keep alive the interest and participation of
members through a suitable educational and publicity campaign and by
forming small study groups. These methods aim at reminding members
that they really are the co-owners of the innumerable enterprises of the
H.S.B., so that they will look upon their co-operative dwellings as their
own homes and realise that the administration and progress of the H.S.B.
co-operative movement depends on them, on their interest and on their
active participation through the democratic bodies established for the
purpose.
Transfer of the Right of Co-operative Ownership
In the H.S.B. movement a deceased member's rights and obligations
vis-à-vis his society may be passed on to his widow or children. Furthermore, since members are registered according to the district in which
they live, privileges and obligations deriving from membership may be
transferred from one district to another in certain specified circumstances.
If a member wishes to leave the organisation, it is acknowledged in
principle that he has the right to do so, but in practice he may only do so
if he complies with the relevant clauses of the by-laws. Generally a
member's resignation will be accepted if he has t o move to another

district or if he has belonged to the society for at least two years before
asking to withdraw. In no case, however, will a member be allowed to
withdraw with less than six months' notice to the management.
When a member withdraws from the H.S.B. his society does not return
the money he has put in, but it does authorise him to sell his right of
co-operative ownership. The member is then free to sell to anybody he
wishes, provided, of course, that the buyer satisfies the conditions of
membership of the co-operative. In addition, in order to avoid any risk
of speculation, which would be alien to the principles of co-operation,
the transaction is examined by the board of the " mother " society. The
by-laws of the co-operatives of the H.S.B. provide that in such cases the
sale price may not exceed the initial payment plus instalments already
paid. It is also stipulated in the internal rules that the outgoing member
must leave his dwelling in good condition. The cost of any repairs which
may be necessary will be charged to his account in the special fund
established for that purpose. If his credit under that fund is not sufficient
to cover the cost, the sale price must be reduced by the amount needed to
pay for the balance of the repairs.
Even though in a continually expanding economy such as Sweden's
it is not difficult to find a buyer, the H.S.B. has evolved a system to prevent members who wish to sell their co-operative dwellings from getting

25

SWEDEN

into difficulties, by setting up a special fund to buy dwellings which the
members themselves have not been able to sell. This fund is financed out
of revenue from shares taken out by the members of the " daughter "
co-operatives. The dwellings acquired in this way by the H.S.B. are
leased on the open market until a suitable buyer is found. Only on very
rare occasions has it been necessary to draw on this fund, however, and
then only for a limited period. In other cases, this same fund has been
used to give partial assistance to members in solving personal financial
problems in special circumstances.
In the same way as members are free to leave the co-operatives, provided that they observe the relevant provisions of the by-laws, so the
H.S.B. in its turn can expel members who dishonour the ideals of the
movement. The decision to expel a member is taken by the management
committee of the " mother " co-operative, but it must be ratified by the
board of the society.
Dissolution
In the event that a society has to be wound up, it is laid down that
everything possible must first be done to safeguard the interests of the
members. Thus, if the society to be wound up is a " mother " co-operative,
the first thing that must be done is to return to the members all the money
that has been deposited with the society, and any balance then outstanding

is distributed among other bodies whose aims are similar to those of the
association in dissolution.
In the case of a " daughter " co-operative, here also the first thing is
to pay back all the money contributed by the members, any sum left over
being handed to the appropriate " mother " society. But if the " daughter "
co-operative is one of those financed by the State, once members' contributions have been repaid to them in full any balance remaining is
returned to the body which has given financial help. That body, subject
to consultation with the H.S.B., may make use of these funds for purposes
approved by the central authorities in charge of financial assistance. It is
worth recording that as yet there has not been a single case of bankruptcy
within the H.S.B. co-operative movement.

SYSTEM OF FINANCING OF THE

H.S.B.

In studying the H.S.B.'s financial arrangements a distinction has to be
made between the procedure established for the internal financing of the
societies and the system adopted for the financing of the various housing
projects.

26

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Internal Financing
The national H.S.B., which is a co-operative of co-operatives and
whose members are the " mother " societies established in different parts
of the country, draws its working capital from the following resources :
(i) membership fees from its affiliated co-operatives;
(ii) wholesale business profits ;
(iii) profits from subsidiary industrial enterprises ;
(iv) fees for technical work done by its own team of professionals for
the " mother " co-operatives or for other bodies which ask for
help, such as local authorities;
(v) interest from banking operations.
The funds of the " mother " societies are derived from the following
sources of income :
(i) administrative charges for work in connection with the building of
new projects;
(ii) commission on building materials sold to the " daughter " societies;
(iii) fees payable by the " daughter " co-operatives in respect of the
administration of completed houses.
The " daughter " co-operatives derive their income directly from
their members' regular payments in respect of the dwellings they occupy.
Financing of Co-operative Building
As a general rule members of co-operative housing projects are
required to contribute funds to finance the building of their homes, since
a co-operative cannot begin work unless it has at least some capital to
serve as a starting-point, as the costs of house building are generally high.
Savings.
When the tenants' associations were formed during and after the
First World War in order to solve their housing problem on a cooperative basis, they knew very well that they would need considerable
funds to achieve their objectives. Realising besides that members' contributions alone would not suffice to finance their projects, they profited
from earlier experience to introduce a new form of organisation which
combined both savings and building in a single society. Since then this
form of organisation has become one of the key factors in the success
achieved by this co-operative housing movement, the principle being
clearly established that savings must precede construction.

SWEDEN

27

Hence not only is the H.S.B. an organised movement of tenants, but
it stimulates saving as the first step in the construction of housing by
joint effort. The national H.S.B. states in its by-laws that its objective is
to raise the economic level of its members through savings within the
co-operative so as to enable them to acquire their own homes.
The savings system within the H.S.B. works in the same way as in any
commercial bank. In the different areas of the country the " mother "
co-operatives collect savings from their members and act as branches of
the central bank, which is an agency of the national H.S.B. To encourage
saving with a view to solving the housing problem the H.S.B. pays its
members interest on their savings at a higher rate than that normally
paid by commercial banking institutions. Members who have already
acquired co-operative dwellings also take part in this special scheme,
saving to modernise their homes or to obtain larger homes for their
families.
Although not all the savers availing themselves of the services of the
H.S.B. do so in order to facilitate the building of a home, the savings of
all are used without distinction to help finance the movement's housing
projects as a whole. By way of an example, of the 76,000 people who
deposited savings with the H.S.B. in 1959, only about 20,000 were
members saving under the special scheme as a contribution towards the
financing of their own homes. On the other hand, in the same year the
total savings deposited in the H.S.B. bank reached a figure of 76 million
kronor, which the H.S.B. could use either for the purchase of sites or to
finance actual building work. Naturally, as with any other bank, savings
may be withdrawn at any time and for any purpose that the saver may
have in mind.
In this way the H.S.B., through its own organised savings scheme,
makes it possible for its member co-operatives to obtain on favourable
terms some at least of the short-term loans they need to finance their
housing projects. Once a development is completed, the temporary
loans extended by the H.S.B. are replaced by long-term credit in the
form of mortgages. The national society in its turn uses the money paid
back to help finance new projects.
Members' Direct Contribution.
In the first place the members of the H.S.B. must co-operate in
furnishing the organisation's capital by taking out at least one membership share. In addition they must make a down payment on their
co-operative homes.
The H.S.B. offers four types of housing: a member who applies for
a dwelling of type A, in addition to taking out a membership share,

28

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

must make a down payment equal to 10 per cent, of the value of the
dwelling unit. Type B likewise requires a membership share, but in
this case, which is the most common, the initial deposit is only 5 per cent.
Types C and D are intended for tenants who cannot afford to pay any
deposit. Only the first two of these are irue co-operative projects, of
course. In the case of types C and D the H.S.B. is lending its technical
services and collaborating in the social programme of the municipal
authorities, who are responsible for the financing of these projects. The
municipal authority reserves the right to exercise a certain control over
the selection of tenants, endeavouring in the main to help families with
children.
Funds constituted by members' payments are treated by the cooperative in the same way as capital from other sources. Thus, at the end
of each year the H.S.B. pays its members interest, usually at 4 per cent.,
both on membership shares and on deposits.
The yearly payment made by members in the form of rent includes
interest and instalments on loans, fund contributions and payments for
services. In an annual rent equivalent to $200, the percentage breakdown
would be as follows :
Interest on loans
Loan instalments
Administrative services
Hot water and heating
Repair fund
Reserve fund

60.00
17.50
10.50
8.00
3.25
0.75
100.00

As the societies retain the ownership of the buildings, after 20 years
the H.S.B. returns the original deposit the member made to help finance
the project. From then on a resident member is only required to make
a modest payment each year to cover administrative charges or to restore
the special fund which is drawn on for any repairs which may have to be
made to his home.
There is also a special internal insurance scheme, the annual premium
for which is equivalent to 1 per cent, of the funds deposited and may be
deducted from the 4 per cent, annual interest payable by the society. This
provides that if an insured member dies before the first 20 years of cooperative tenancy are up the deposit is returned in full to his family,
which may continue to live in the dwelling indefinitely with the obligation
to pay only the yearly administrative charges and the cost of any repairs.
In order to assist their salaried and wage-earning employees to obtain
accommodation, private bodies such as the Co-operative Union and
Wholesale Society of Sweden have their own financial programmes,

SWEDEN

29

designed to enable payment of the 5 per cent, deposit required from
members wishing to take part in co-operative housing schemes.
The present financial arrangements whereby a prospective co-operative
co-owner is required to pay a deposit equivalent to 5 per cent, of the cost
of the dwelling have only been in existence since 1946. During the period
between the two world wars the H.S.B. was obliged to ask its members to
pay a deposit equivalent to 10 or even 13 per cent, of building costs.
Even at that time, however, in its efforts to bring down the cost of
construction, thanks to efficiency of operation, elimination of middlemen, planning on a nation-wide scale and the establishment of subsidiary industrial enterprises, the H.S.B. was able to provide accommodation where occupants were offered savings of up to 20 per cent, on general
costs and better facilities than those afforded by comparable private
projects in Stockholm.
Mortgages.
The final loans for the financing of housing projects are granted under

the triple-mortgage system instituted in the country for the purpose.
The first and second mortgages, which generally cover 60 and 10 per cent.
respectively of production costs, are arranged by banking houses,
insurance companies or other credit institutions. The third mortgage,
offered by the Government as part of its national housing policy, covers
up to 25 per cent, of total building costs in the case of co-operatives.
This explains why members are normally required to provide only the
remaining 5 per cent.
The Role of Public Authorities
After the Second World War the Swedish Government embarked
upon an advanced national housing policy which has helped to make
money available to co-operatives by classifying them among the most
important of the non-profit institutions which are in a position to make a
positive contribution towards attaining the stated objectives.
The Swedish housing plan has included long-term measures, such as
the third mortgage referred to above, and transitional or temporary
measures, such as supplementary loans, family allowances or protection
against rising interest on mortgage loans granted by private institutions.
Some of these measures have been of direct assistance to co-operatives in
financing their housing projects; others have aided indirectly by helping
members to find the funds for their personal contribution.
The supplementary loan is a kind of capital subsidy which originated
in the following circumstances. Although the members of the H.S.B.

30

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

co-operatives do not, correctly speaking, pay rent for the dwellings
they occupy, since they are not tenants but co-owners of the building or
group of buildings which make up a project, the annual payments they
must make to their own society are none the less subject to the statutory
provisions governing rents in Sweden. In order both to maintain a curb
on inflation and to stimulate the construction of housing the Government introduced these supplementary loans after the Second World War.
They are not granted exclusively to co-operatives, and they are designed
to make up the difference between the capitalised value of the statutory
rent and the real value of the building, construction costs having risen
considerably. These loans are made for ten years, and to begin with no
interest was payable; since July 1961, however, under the Government's
new financial policy, interest has been charged at 4 per cent. Another
difference under the former policy was that, if on expiry of the ten-year
period the society could show that its income was insufficient to enable it
to pay back the loan, the State and the competent municipal authority
would share this " overcost " of construction, contributing 90 per cent.
and 10 per cent, respectively. Today, following a decision taken by the
Swedish Parliament in July 1959, these loans must be paid back in the
normal way.
The Government also helps indirectly to finance co-operative housing
projects by assisting families to participate through the so-called rent
subsidy. This subsidy, which is distinct from the family subsidy payable
in respect of each child, is paid to all families with two or more children
under 16 years of age provided that the annual income does not exceed
6,000 kronor. For each child after the second the income ceiling is raised
by 1,000 kronor a year. The purpose of this subsidy is to facilitate the
removal of families with children to homes offering better facilities.1
Another of the measures which indirectly facilitate the financing of
co-operatives is the protection guaranteed to borrowers by the Government in the event of any rise in the interest rate of 3 per cent, on the first
mortgage loan or 3.5 per cent, on the second. The difference between
those rates and the guaranteed interest rate can be deducted from the
payment made to the State on the third mortgage.2
For the construction of individual one- or two-family houses, rather
than of large projects, the H.S.B. may also negotiate on behalf of its
members the loans offered by the Government in such cases, which
represent from 50 to 90 per cent, of the cost of construction, depending
on the security offered. In this way the cash contribution which has to
be made by the member in such cases may be reduced to 10 per cent.
1
2

UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 95.
Ibid., p. 96.

SWEDEN

31

Furthermore, since houses built for a single family are generally prefabricated, it is common for the member's contribution to take the form
not of cash, but of personal labour. It is natural that the Government,
offering as it does such generous financial help as part of its national
housing policy, should logically require individuals and building contractors to observe a minimum of administrative, technical and sanitary
standards. The societies of the H.S.B. have therefore agreed that the
municipal authorities should elect a representative to sit as an observer
on the board of each " mother " society receiving State aid for any
of its projects. By the same token the municipal authorities may elect
an auditor to work in collaboration with the auditors appointed by the
co-operatives concerned, as explained earlier.1 But it should be borne
in mind that the task of these Government representatives is limited to
ensuring that official financial aid is put to the proper use, without
interfering in any way with the internal management of the co-operative.
As regards the provisions stipulating the type of facilities and services
which should be made available by housing projects in order to qualify
for financial aid from the State, this has never been a problem for the
societies of the H.S.B., since these co-operatives have been in advance
of the official regulations in introducing the most modern amenities.
It is worth noting that in Sweden there is no speculation in land
suitable for building, because the municipal authorities, foreseeing the
development of their cities, have bought up large areas of land surrounding built-up areas which they make available to co-operatives and other
non-profit building associations for new developments in line with the
national housing policy.
The policy adopted by the municipalities with respect to this land has
tended to be in favour of leasing it, usually for a period of 60 years
renewable at the end of that time. This policy is important for the
official point of view, since the municipal authorities retain the ownership
of the land, thus facilitating matters in the event of a future change in
town development plans. In practice it has made it difficult for housing
co-operatives to obtain mortgage loans from private credit institutions.
Faced with this situation a number of Swedish cities, following the
example of Stockholm, have founded special credit institutions in which
the local authorities are the principal shareholders. These credit agencies
are authorised to issue bonds guaranteed by their respective municipalities,
and in this way facilitate the financing of housing projects, there being
very little difference between the interest they charge and that paid by
building firms with their own sites to private credit institutions.
^ e e above, p. 21.

32

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Although the national housing policy provides for considerable
assistance in the financing of housing projects, nevertheless the societies
of the H.S.B.—and the same applies to the other housing co-operatives
which exist in the country—enjoy no special tax exemptions, paying the
same municipal rates as any other property owner, in accordance with
the assessed value of the property. Co-operatives are also subject to
the national Government tax of 32 per cent, of net profit.
Inter-Co-operative Financing
Another factor that facilitates the financing of housing projects
consists in relations between co-operatives. Thus, for instance, the
H.S.B. movement and the co-operative insurance movement offer each
other mutual services. The housing societies insure their properties with
the insurance co-operatives, which in turn provide loans to the housing
co-operatives to help them in their construction work.
THE

H.S.B.

AND THE BUILDING INDUSTRY

The H.S.B. plays a very important role in the country's building
industry. It does not, however, build through direct labour; it prefers
to get the work done for it by contracting it out in free competition to the
firm offering the lowest tender with equal conditions as to quality,
workmanship and materials. One of the main factors behind the genuine
impact that the H.S.B. has made on the building industry is that it is a
national housing movement organised in such a way as to enable it,
firstly, to centralise all its technical and financial resources and, secondly,
to channel them all over the country through a system of administrative
decentralisation based on its affiliated societies. This technical centralisation has made it possible to draw up construction plans on a vast scale,
with all the advantages of wholesale purchase of materials and mass
production of buildings. The H.S.B., which already has nearly 40 years
of experience behind it in the field of construction, is engaged in intensive
activity which has helped to bring about uniformity, standardisation and
mass production, thereby reducing building costs.
Furthermore, far from contenting itself with the purchase of materials,
the H.S.B. has also gone into production on its own account. It has set
up and financed a number of subsidiary industrial enterprises which
produce bricks, pipes, doors and windows to standard specifications for
mass-production programmes, as well as modern kitchen and diningroom fittings, sanitary installations, etc. With the same end in view the
H.S.B. has purchased the largest marble quarry in the country, which it
operates indirectly as a subsidiary enterprise.

SWEDEN

33

In addition, the H.S.B. has its own factories mass-producing prefabricated houses. As output far exceeds the demand within the affiliated
societies, they are also sold to non-co-operative associations and to
private individuals both at home and abroad, and the H.S.B. has therefore set up its own export service.
The H.S.B. also has its own research department, which collects and
analyses information and reports and has its own laboratories where it
tests materials and establishes prototypes which can then be reproduced
in large quantities.
Realising the H.S.B.'s great experience and the technical and administrative service it has rendered to the building industry, a considerable
number of local authorities in Sweden have sought its collaboration in
carrying out their own municipal housing programmes. Some have even
financed the first stage of their building work with loans from its savings
bank. It bears witness to the prestige enjoyed by the H.S.B. that on
quite a few occasions its technical services have been sought for the
planning of whole new towns or the modernisation of old ones.

SWEDISH NATIONAL BUILDING SOCIETY

Among the other co-operative housing organisations in Sweden,
special mention should be made of the Svenska Riksbyggen (S.R.), or
Swedish National Building Society, which was originally founded to
combat the large-scale unemployment which existed among the country's
building workers at the outbreak of the Second World War.
It is primarily a builders' movement, as distinct from the H.S.B.,
which is essentially a movement of users, namely of individuals who
join together for the express purpose of acquiring a co-operative home
in which they themselves will live. The founders of the S.R. were the
trade unions, and in particular the workers in the building industry.
As stated in its articles, the objectives of the S.R. are as follows :
to promote the building industry and seek a market for housing;
to build homes both for workers in the building industry and for trade
union members in general;
to construct housing for subsequent sale to families organised into
co-operative groups to administer such housing;
to construct houses for individuals, groups of buildings or even entire
districts for other organisations or local authorities which seek its
services.
The structure of the S.R. is, in broad terms, of the same type as that

34

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

of the H.S.B., with its three levels—national, regional and local—and its
representative bodies.
The methods employed by the S.R. to carry out its housing programme are also very similar to those of the H.S.B. as described above.
It should be noted, however, that the S.R. has no factories of its own,
although, since it is working in close collaboration with the building
unions, it makes use of their subsidiary industrial enterprises.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

The Swedish co-operative housing movement means something more
in the life of the country than bringing homes within the reach of families
seeking them. Both the H.S.B. and the S.R. have distinguished themselves not only by building houses for their members but by endowing
each project with the best social and financial amenities in order to make
life pleasant and easy for the families living there. The expansion of this
type of co-operative throughout the country and the influence which each
individual project has on the surrounding district have caused the co-operative housing movement to make a significant impact on national life.
To understand the anxiety of the Swedish housing co-operatives to
offer the best social conditions as part of their housing programmes it
must be borne in mind that, when the tenants' associations set up cooperative societies in an effort to solve their housing problem, one of the
primary considerations was the need to provide dwellings offering
healthy and pleasant surroundings for family life and proper places for
children to play in.
This explains why such stress is laid on the social objectives of this
type of co-operative in the societies' rules. One of these objectives is
centred on the house as a home, others on the general atmosphere
surrounding the various projects, while others go even further, indirectly
exercising a beneficial influence both on the community, town or city
in which the co-operative is situated and on national housing policy.
In its desire to play its part in raising the standard of living of the
middle and working classes, 40 years ago the H.S.B. became the first
housing society in the country to launch a policy of providing cooperative dwellings with modern facilities while at the same time cutting
building costs.
A social lead taken by the H.S.B. which has had much to do with the
success of housing co-operatives in Sweden was the establishment of day
nurseries where mothers could leave their children under the care of
trained staff. This idea has today become generalised throughout the
country and has been taken up by local authorities.

SWEDEN

35

Mention may also be made of other social achievements of cooperative housing in Sweden, such as the provision of playrooms and
sports grounds for young people, the formation of clubs and voluntary
study groups on each estate, the systematic organisation of adult discussion groups to debate problems of general interest to the community
or the country, social activities to enable families living on the same
co-operative housing estate to get to know one another, or competitions
to stimulate residents' artistic talents or occupational skills.
The housing co-operatives have also had a tremendous impact on the
national building industry. According to data for 1959 one-third of all
buildings constructed in Swedish cities were the work of one or the other
of the two great national organisations, the H.S.B. and the S.R. Not all
of these were co-operative projects, of course: the efficiency, both technical and administrative, of the housing co-operatives was held in such
esteem that many local authorities and other non-profit bodies frequently
called on the services of the H.S.B. and the S.R. in carrying out their own
housing programmes.
Up to the end of 1959 the H.S.B. had helped in the construction of
148,700 dwelling units, of which 96,300 were co-operative enterprises,
47,200 were built under municipal projects or for other non-profit
societies and 5,200 for individual families under the special scheme which
confers individual ownership and where the future occupiers themselves
work on the houses allocated to them. The value of the properties constructed by the H.S.B. up to the end of 1959 amounted to 4,500 million
kronor.
For its part the S.R., while pursuing the traditional co-operative
policy of putting quality before quantity, built more than 70,000 dwellings in its first 20 years of existence. Of these, 50,000 were co-operative
dwellings in 168 different localities, while the remaining 20,000 were
built under the scheme for collaboration in the housing projects of
municipalities which are short of funds, or other non-profit bodies. The
S.R. has organised some 700 co-operative housing societies in the
country and has 26 regional offices.1
Originally founded to solve the housing problem of limited groups
of citizens, the co-operatives have made such remarkable strides in
Sweden that they are capable, as was shown after the Second World War,
of constructing or reconstructing entire towns.

1
International Housing Bulletin (Copenhagen, International Federation of Building and Wood Workers and European Regional Office of the International Confederation of Free Trade Unions), Eighth year, No. 6, June 1961, p. 105.

CHAPTER ÏII
DENMARK
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

Danish national housing policy has not favoured allocating direct
responsibility for house building to the State, and the way has been left
open for co-operatives and other non-profit associations to tackle the
problem of providing accommodation at reasonable cost.
The initiative in forming co-operatives as one way of solving the
housing shortage came from the working class. The Workers' Housing
Co-operative Society, which is known by the initials A.A.B. (Arbejdernes
Andéis Boligforening), came into existence in 1912. The following year
the organisations of stone masons, cabinet makers and carpenters, which
had been formed on the co-operative model in Copenhagen in 1899 in
order to conduct a labour dispute, were merged to form a new association
with the title of Workers' Construction Co-operative Society.1
Nevertheless, despite these co-operative experiments, it is safe to say
that the co-operative housing movement in Denmark only became
nation-wide in character after the First World War.
ORGANISATION

In its organisation the Danish co-operative movement is broadly
similar to its Swedish counterpart, having " mother " and " daughter "
societies combined with a democratic internal structure in each society
in accordance with co-operative principles. Nevertheless, there are
certain differences in structure between the Danish and Swedish systems.
Co-operative housing, in the wider sense in which it is interpreted in
this survey, takes a number of forms in Denmark, chief among them
being the following:
(a)

housing co-operatives proper, the purpose of which is to build
houses for their members, ownership usually remaining vested in
the society. These co-operatives assume responsibility for building
the housing and for managing it afterwards;
1

Cf. UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 23.

DENMARK

37

(b)

house-building co-operatives. These societies, which are mainly
composed of building workers, are intended to construct homes
not primarily for their members but for the market in general or
for particular groups. They stipulate in their rules that their aim
must be to help the consuming public to raise its standard of living
by making production methods cheaper and more efficient;

(c)

co-operative organisations performing auxiliary functions in the
field of housing. These include mortgage co-operative associations,
which date from the last century, together with technical advisory
associations organised on co-operative lines.

Housing co-operatives which supply technical and financial services
to their members form federations or confederations which enable them
to co-operate on a nation-wide scale and thereby to raise building
standards and lower costs.
There are also a number of low-profit building associations with a
membership which mainly consists of trade unions, but also includes
local co-operatives which take out shares in them. These associations
build housing which they let to the general public at moderate rents, but
the tenants have no voice or vote in the management, which in each case
is in the hands of a board made up of representatives of the shareholding
members, the Ministry of Housing and the co-operative movement.
Legally speaking—and also from the standpoint of co-operative principles
—these associations are low-profit joint-stock companies.
One distinguishing feature of the Danish housing co-operative movement is the extent to which it works with other non-profit organisations.
By helping to co-ordinate programmes and provide financial resources, it
has promoted a nation-wide housing drive which plays a prominent part
in the country's life.
General Federation of Danish Housing Associations
The General Federation of Danish Housing Associations, which
comprises housing and building co-operatives and other non-profit
building associations, has been in existence since 1919. Its aims are to
safeguard the interests of member associations and to promote national
housing policy. Under its constitution the Federation is open to any
associations concerned with housing, provided they operate on a nonprofit basis.
The internal organisation is democratic. The highest body is the
congress, which meets every three years and to which each member
association can send at least one delegate. The organisation also has
a board and an executive committee.

38

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

For internal administration purposes the Federation divides the
country into areas, and the member associations in each area elect their
official representative on the board. Each area is entitled to elect an
additional delegate for every 1,000 homes completed or in process of
construction, although no area may send more than ten delegates.
The executive committee consists of a president, who is elected by the
congress and is at the same time chairman of the board, and the official
representatives of the areas.
This Federation has played a leading part in planning Danish housing
policy, and its representatives have regularly been invited to sit on
governmental or parliamentary committees appointed to examine
various aspects of the housing problem and ways and means of dealing
with them. In addition, it has organised educational campaigns on
topics connected with housing.
At the end of 1958 the General Federation of Danish Housing
Associations comprised 313 member bodies, which by that date had
built 106,000 homes in 1,659 separate housing estates. Most of the
member bodies are co-operative associations.
One major innovation introduced by this Federation was the establishment in 1947 of a special central agency for the bulk purchase of building
materials in order to lower production costs. This agency, the Bolind,
is also empowered to establish and operate its own production plants.
Another interesting step taken by the Federation has been the establishment of the Building Estimates Institute 1 , to investigate building methods
and costs and circulate the results among the member associations.
The Arbejderbo
In 1941 the A.A.B., together with the trade unions, founded the
Arbejderbo, which is an association set up to promote and advise public
utility housing associations; in addition to co-operatives, its membership
includes a number of non-profit organisations such as trade unions, as
well as various local authorities.
(i)

Under its rules the objects of the Arbejderbo are as follows:
to assist the formation of housing or building associations, together
with any other non-profit associations with similar aims, in places
where the housing shortage is most acute;

(ii)

to assume responsibility for the management of building projects
on behalf of co-operatives, local authorities or other member
associations ;
1

Cf. UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 32.

DENMARK

39

(iii) to supervise the building of cultural or other facilities on housing
estates constructed by member associations;
(iv)

to give technical and financial aid for the study of plans for new
building schemes.

In order to carry out these tasks the Arbejderbo has established
branches in each part of the country. These branches conduct surveys of
housing needs in their areas, call general meetings to discuss possible
ways of tackling the housing problem, explain the national housing policy
and foster the organisation of co-operatives or other non-profit associations. In cases where it is decided to form an association of this type, the
branch office makes arrangements for giving training to the future
managers of the new co-operative or association, and also helps to draft
the rules, enlist the support of the appropriate local authority and
complete the preliminaries needed to launch the new organisation.
When the co-operative or non-profit building association has been
legally established, the branch office helps by advising it on the choice
of the most suitable sites and by drawing up the initial development
plans.
Once this first stage has been completed, the head office of the
Arbejderbo comes into the picture by making its technical facilities
available, helping to secure finance for the scheme and assuming responsibility for awarding contracts, giving preference where possible to local
builders. The Arbejderbo is not a building association, but its services
are extremely valuable because of its long experience in the management
of building schemes, which enables it to select the best tenders from
contractors.
Like the H.S.B. in Sweden, the Arbejderbo has a highly qualified staff
of architects, economists and legal experts whose services are available
to member associations.
The educational work of the Arbejderbo is not confined to the
meetings held before a new association is formed with the help of one of
its branch offices. The organisation carries on a constant campaign to
pubhcise new ideas and methods, by publishing pamphlets and giving
advice on improvements in interior decoration, furnishing, domestic
services and other matters of interest to householders.
The Arbejderbo is based on democratic internal organisation. The
highest body in the society is the general meeting, which elects 25 delegates
to make up the board, of whom ten represent associations on whose
behalf the Arbejderbo is managing building projects, and 15 represent
organisations which are at the time engaged in building projects. This
board elects an executive committee consisting of nine members.

40

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

By the end of 1959 the Arbejderbo had played an important part in
organising the building of 29,000 homes in about 700 projects in various
parts of the country.
In 1948 the Arbejderbo set up another association solely for the
management of completed housing schemes, and by the end of 1959
this association was dealing with 8,450 homes coming under 86 estates
belonging to 16 member bodies.
FINANCING

Housing co-operatives always endeavour to finance their building
programmes from their own resources, partly by encouraging members to
contribute capital and partly by channelling their savings into housing
schemes. It has also been the policy of the Danish co-operative movement
that co-operatives of different types should help one another, and it is
by no means uncommon for consumer or insurance societies to invest
their funds in co-operative building programmes. However, the volume
of investment capital from these sources is not sufficient to finance the
whole national co-operative building programme, which has done
so much to speed up the tempo of house building since the war.
The Government, therefore, as part of its national housing policy,
also helps co-operatives by providing them (together with other nonprofit building associations) with the funds they need to achieve their
social aims.
Mortgage Credit Co-operatives
The first mortgage credit societies set up in Denmark over 100 years
ago only made loans against a first mortgage, but from 1895 onwards
other societies were formed specialising in loans against a second mortgage. These bodies are autonomous, but are subject to supervision by
the State, which in return allows them to issue tax-free bonds negotiable
on the market. The distinctive features of these co-operatives are: (a)
joint liability of borrowers; (b) loans based on the value of the property;
and (c) issue of bonds secured by the borrowers' mortgages.
The members of mortgage credit co-operatives are jointly liable, i.e.
any holder of a mortgage is not only answerable for his own borrowing
with the whole of his property, but also for the loans granted to other
members, although in such cases only up to two-thirds of the mortgage
on his own property.1
1

UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 45.

DENMARK

41

Usually mortgage credit co-operativesfloatloans at the lowest possible
rate of interest because they are soundly enough based to have the complete confidence of the general public, and savings institutions, commercial
banks, insurance companies and other concerns readily buy their bonds.
The interest rates charged by these co-operatives range from 3 to 5 per
cent., depending on the annual instalments the borrower chooses to
repay; these instalments must cover redemption of part of the capital
as well as payment of the interest.
In principle, these mortgage credit co-operatives can only make loans
on completed buildings, but sometimes they also lend while work is in
progress, the money then being advanced by instalments as building goes
ahead.
Building Workers' Co-operatives
The building workers' co-operatives were originally established in
Denmark as vertical associations, being made up of workers employed
in the same occupation, but in recent years they have tended towards a
horizontal form of organisation. They are financed to a large extent by
the trade union movement through the Workers' Co-operative Movement Investment Fund. This fund has a twofold function, because it
not only invests its own capital in these co-operatives but, by standing
surety for their borrowing, helps them to negotiate loans from banks and
other sources of finance.
The Role of Public Authorities
Danish housing policy, which after the First World War took the
form of large-scale financial aid for house-building programmes by
co-operatives and other non-profit associations, underwent a far-reaching
change in 1959. As in Sweden, housing policy in Denmark, especially
after the Second World War, was to supply finance in various ways to
housing projects undertaken by co-operatives and other non-profit
building associations. The new policy involved curtailment of State aid,
leaving the main responsibility for financing house building to the
societies themselves and to private investors. At the present time, State
financial aid is almost entirely confined to guaranteeing the third mortgage, and even then only in certain specified circumstances.1
This new policy of cutting down State aid to housing has led to higher
interest charges and building costs, with the result that the rents of houses
1
UNITED NATIONS, Economic Commission for Europe: European Housing Trends
and Policies in 1960 (Geneva, 1961; Sales No. 61.II.E/Mim.20), p. 32.

42

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

built from 1960 onwards have gone up, especially in Copenhagen and
other large towns, to a proportionately greater extent than the increase in
building costs. According to thefiguresfor the end of 1960, the rents for
new houses built without Government financial assistance were between
25 and 75 per cent, higher than those of housing built by co-operatives
or other non-profit agencies.1 This policy has also led to the establishment of a number óf new private building firms.
The restriction of State financial aid to co-operatives and other
non-profit building associations has upset the balance which existed until
recent years in Denmark between private building for profit and public
utility building by co-operatives and other bodies. In 1960 co-operatives
and other non-profit bodies built a total of 6,100 homes in urban areas,
which represented only 27 per cent, of the total number of homes completed in Danish urban areas in that year. Despite the marked effect
which this new housing policy has had on the number of new non-profit
building schemes, the Arbejderbo reported that it worked at full pressure
in 1960, but concentrated on the planning of new schemes rather than on
current building.
Building Fund
The rules of the co-operatives belonging to the Danish movement
stipulate that co-operative societies do not simply exist to build isolated
housing schemes, but that their ideal must be to try to solve the housing
problem throughout the country by helping the worst-off sections of the
community. The movement has therefore established a special building
fund in order to maintain the tempo of expansion. Under this scheme,
members of co-operatives forgo a large part of the dividends that would
normally be payable to them out of the savings in costs and repaid mortgages. This money is then used tofinancenew schemes. The building fund
is divided into two accounts, only thefirstof which yields interest. A third
of the fund's income is paid into the first account and two-thirds into the
second. The interest on thefirstaccount is distributed at least once every
five years to members who during that time have lived in co-operative
housing, in proportion to the rents they paid. On the death of a member,
his widow or children under the age of 21 draw this interest; if he leaves
no such dependants, the amount due to him is automatically paid into
the non-interest-bearing account. Undoubtedly, the most important
feature of this plan is that it marks a step towards achieving the Danish
movement's ambition to have its own source of finance for its building
and modernisation schemes.
1

UNITED NATIONS: European Housing Trends and Policies in I960, op. cit., p. 36.

DENMARK

43

SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

The movement has not only built thousands of homes for its members
on the best possible terms, but it has also discharged its responsibilities
under the country's general economic policy.
Being concerned with the well-being of the lower income groups, the
co-operative movement has given its enthusiastic backing to the Government's housing policy and has collaborated extensively with special
committees appointed to investigate such matters as building methods,
tendering systems and rent control and has also made its services available to the Government Research Institute.
Moreover, although the hundreds of Danish housing co-operatives
do not (as in Sweden) possess a central body at the head of a nation-wide
organisation, together with other non-profit organisations belonging to
the General Federation of Danish Housing Associations, which has its
own staff of economic, technical, legal, educational and social experts,
they help to relieve the State of a large part of its responsibilities in this
field.
When building on behalf of their members, Danish co-operatives have
not only adopted the principle of providing the highest standards at the
lowest possible price, but, believing that it is not enough just to give
families a roof over their heads, they also organise various communal
facilities on co-operative lines within each project (e.g. shops, laundries,
nurseries) and thereby stimulate a new type of community based on
neighbourliness and co-operation.
Care for the children of members living in co-operative housing has
always been a marked feature of the Danish movement, as it has in all
the Scandinavian countries. Co-operative housing estates contain kindergartens where specially trained staff look after children while their
mothers are working, together with such amenities as playing fields,
recreation rooms and cinemas for young people and adults. Special
mention should be made of the youth club movement started in Copenhagen in 1933 which by 1950 had over 1,000 member bodies. These
clubs organise sports of various kinds, study groups and various social
activities using the facilities of the co-operative housing projects. Financial support is usually provided by the Government and the local
authorities.
In Denmark, apart from large projects consisting of one or more
blocks of flats which are jointly owned by the residents through their
society, co-operatives also build single-family houses which on completion
become the property of their occupants. Several attractive middle-class
housing estates have been built using the co-operative system on the

44

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

outskirts of Copenhagen. In one scheme of this kind—the Grondalsvaenge
—a welfare fund has been set up to help new members with limited
means to meet the costs of their participation.
The organisational experience and the building and research programmes of the Danish housing co-operatives, in conjunction with the
State and other non-profit bodies, have a significance extending beyond
the confines of the country and contain features which could certainly be
adopted by developing countries.

CHAPTER IV
NORWAY
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The co-operative housing movement in Norway is more recent in
origin than in Sweden or Denmark. Broadly speaking, it can be said that
until shortly before the First World War the building industry was
entirely in private hands, although it would appear that at that time
housing was not a particularly profitable field for investment capital.
The years immediately before the First World War saw the emergence of
a number of building associations along co-operative lines through which
the middle classes endeavoured to solve their housing problem by pooling
their own capital. But these were short-lived associations which were
wound up as soon as the buildings were completed and in no way
claimed to constitute a genuine movement for solving the national
housing problem.
When the housing shortage became more acute during the First World
War, local authorities first of all tried to encourage private investment,
and when this policy failed they set up their own building departments
which catered mainly for the lower income groups.
After some years of trial, this formula of direct building by local
authorities was not found to be entirely satisfactory. This was not only
for financial reasons but particularly because the management of building operations and of completed homes imposed a new burden on local
administration. This led to a shift in policy, which began when the city
of Oslo decided to stop building municipal housing estates and to give
encouragement and aid to co-operative associations instead.
In 1934 the Oslo city authorities gave their financial support to the
Oslo Bolig og Sparelag (O.B.O.S.), the Oslo Building and Savings
Association. This co-operative was founded in 1929, but in 1934 was
reorganised by the city of Oslo on the model of the Swedish H.S.B. 1
Since that date, the O.B.O.S. has expanded its programme to such an
extent that it can now cater even for the lowest income groups.
1
See MINISTRY OF HOUSING, Copenhagen; STATE HOUSING BOARD, Helsinki;
HOUSING DIRECTORATE, Oslo; NATIONAL HOUSING BOARD, Stockholm: Housing in the

Northern Countries (Copenhagen, 1960), p . 102.

46

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

As members' savings were sometimes inadequate, the Oslo city
authorities agreed, in certain cases, to lend the money for the initial
contribution so that families were not excluded because they could not
afford to participate in co-operative housing schemes. These loans
were not made to the associations themselves, but to the members who
needed the money, and in return the latter had to undertake to pay off
their loans gradually on easy terms.
It was, however, only after the Second World War that co-operative
organisation became important in Norway as a way of tackling the
housing problem. There were two factors which gave special impetus to
the development of co-operative housing at that time : the large-scale
destruction of buildings during the Second World War and the new
emphasis in Government policy on encouraging the provision or
modernisation of housing for the lower income groups.
Taking advantage of this new shift in national housing policy, the
co-operatives reorganised themselves with a view to improving their
operating methods and lowering building costs. This reorganisation
led to the establishment of the National Federation of Housing Cooperatives.
By the end of 1959 this Federation consisted of 910 " daughter "
societies belonging to 88 " mother " co-operatives in various parts of the
country, with a total membership of 122,000 individuals. The biggest of
the " mother " co-operatives belonging to the Federation is the O.B.O.S.
in Oslo, which is one of the world's biggest housing co-operatives. This
association alone had 63,000 members by the end of 1959, and it is
estimated that the number increases by about 3,500 every year.
ORGANISATION

The Norwegian housing co-operatives have studied and benefited by
the organisational and building experience of the Swedish movement,
and in taking over its methods have adapted them to Norwegian needs.
For example, the O.B.O.S. in Oslo is now a large " mother " cooperative carrying out housing schemes for its members through a large
number of " daughter " societies. Taking Oslo as their model, all the
major towns and cities in Norway have also set up " mother " co-operatives, which in turn establish " daughter " societies in various parts of
their areas.
Norwegian co-operative housing has, however, one feature which
distinguishes it from its Swedish counterpart—its decentralisation. In
Norway the " mother " co-operatives are independent of each other,
which is not the case in Sweden, where " mother " and " daughter "

NORWAY

47

co-operatives all belong to the same national organisation. It is true that
in Norway housing co-operatives form a national federation, but each
" mother " society organises, finances and manages its own building
programme and is only associated with other co-operatives of the same
type through a central secretariat which looks after the interests of the
co-operative housing movement throughout the country and provides
it with technical, legal, economic and administrative assistance.
The " mother " co-operatives set up " daughter " societies consisting
of the residents or future residents of their housing estates. It is, however,
the usual practice for the " mother " society to acquire suitable sites, draw
up the plans, arrange finance, appoint the architects and contractors,
and supervise building operations on behalf of its "daughter" societies.
Nevertheless, if it is found necessary for technical reasons to make major
changes in the plans once they have been approved, the board of the
" mother " co-operative is bound to secure the consent of the general
meeting of the " daughter " co-operative on whose behalf the estate is
being built. On completion of the building or buildings, as the case may
be, the " mother " co-operative hands the homes over to its " daughter ".
It also supplies details of construction costs and submits proposals for
the gradual repayment of the loans needed to finance the scheme. In
Norway it is quite common for the " mother " co-operative to be asked
to manage the estate on its completion.
Membership
With the scrapping of the older type of " closed " co-operative which
was usual in the years immediately before and after the First World War,
modern co-operatives in Norway are open to anyone needing housing
who is willing to undertake certain obligations and abide by co-operative
rules.
Under Norwegian law members of co-operatives must contribute
towards their capital by buying a share certificate. However, bodies
corporate which join co-operatives, e.g. the city of Oslo, are allowed to
acquire more than one share certificate, provided their holding does not
exceed 10 per cent, of the total certificates subscribed by individual
members. Usually the latter are required to purchase a share certificate
in the " mother " co-operative as well as in its " daughter ". They are
also required to pay a moderate admission fee on joining together with
an annual charge to cover management costs. It should be noted that
although municipalities or other bodies corporate which care to join can
hold more than one share certificate, they may—in accordance with
co-operative principles—only have one vote like any other member.

48

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Once members have joined a co-operative in accordance with the
rules, they constitute the ultimate authority and exercise their powers
through the general meeting, irrespective of whether they are actually in
residence or are still waiting for their homes to be completed. The procedures for organising the general meeting and electing the board and
executive committee are broadly similar to those described earlier in the
case of Sweden.
It is common for local authorities to be represented and to vote in
these meetings and to have seats reserved for their representatives on the
management bodies. This is due to the fact that in Norway there are
cases—e.g. in Oslo, where the local authority is not only associated with
the co-operative (to which it gives support and financial aid) but uses
the co-operative organisation to carry out its social responsibility for
providing good, cheap housing for families in the lower income groups.
In order to give co-operatives an incentive to speed up their building
programmes, their rules entitle members who have not yet been allotted
co-operative housing to elect one or more representatives to the board
of each " mother " co-operative.
Transfer of Co-operative Property
Co-operative housing is not the individual property of members, nor
is it rented in the strict sense of the term. The co-operative retains
ownership of the property and allots housing to its members for occupation by their families in perpetuity.
A deceased member's widow or children can inherit his right to live
in co-operative housing in the same way as any other family asset.
Before transferring or bequeathing this right to any person who is not a
close relative, the rules require a member to secure the approval of the
co-operative management. If a member wishes to leave his co-operative
accommodation, the procedure is as follows. If the transfer is not made
to a close relative, preference must be given to another member of the
same " daughter " society or of the " mother " co-operative. If no other
member is interested, the accommodation can be transferred to any other
person who accepts the rules and undertakes to carry out the obligations
involved; this person must also be accepted by the management. In
order to avoid any speculation in the sale of rights to live in co-operative
housing, the terms of sale must first be approved by the management.
Youth Co-operative Movement
In 1948 a group of young Norwegians launched a housing movement
in Oslo based on spare-time work. This movement, the Ungdommens

NORWAY

49

Selvbyggelag (U.S.B.L.), began its first housing scheme in 1950 and forms
an interesting example of a type of co-operative in which the members'
own labour plays an important part.
Under its rules the U.S.B.L. has the following aims:
(i) to unite in one nation-wide organisation young people who wish
to acquire a home through their own exertions and are willing to
take part in all the activities needed to build housing for young
people ;
(ii) to take the initiative in establishing subsidiary building enterprises
and to offer personal participation in carrying out building schemes;
(iii) to encourage, handle and manage savings by members to finance
their future homes;
(iv) to build homes for young people who have not yet founded their
own families;
(v) to give generous assistance to members who already own building
sites within approved housing schemes ;
(vi) to establish youth clubs, kindergartens, recreation rooms, playing
fields and other community welfare facilities on new housing
estates;
(vii) to give publicity to the shortage of adequate housing, especially for
young people, and to ways and means of overcoming it.
When joining this movement, members undertake to save regularly
to help to meet the cost of their homes. Members' savings are used to
buy land or building materials.
Apart from any special need for new accommodation on the part of
individual members, the decisive factor governing the allocation of
homes is the personal contribution of each in the form of labour. For
this purpose each member has a special book in which he is credited with
as many " housing points " as the number of hours he has worked on
the project.
The first scheme to be completed by the U.S.B.L. consisted of 16
buildings of which one was for two families and the remainder for four
families each. Of the 498 members of the movement at that time, 259 took
part in the building of this initial scheme and in all the members contributed 53,000 hours' work. The member who contributed most worked
for 1,413 hours, obtaining an equal number of points, and the lowest
contribution was 445 hours. Three years later the total contribution by
members amounted to 730,000 hours' work, equivalent to about 2 million
kroner in value.

50

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Nevertheless, by the end of 1953 the increasing complexity of modern
building techniques compelled the U.S.B.L. to change its policy. The
original idea had been that wherever possible the members themselves
should perform the work, such as the purchase of land, planning, buying
materials, obtaining loans and organising the actual building work.
When the U.S.B.L. launched its housing programme, therefore, it at
first concentrated solely on building simple houses, mainly of wood, for
occupation by two or four families. Since changing its policy, the association has tended to concentrate on building blocks of flats. Despite this
switch, the early idea of personal participation by members in the work
of building has still been retained, especially in the construction of singlefamily houses. The present rules of the movement stipulate that members
who have no special skills in any branch of the building industry may be
given an opportunity of working only on those jobs which require no
skill and in so far as it does not involve any unnecessary delay in the
project.
By changing its policy in this way, the association considerably
extended its scope and by the autumn of 1958 had completed 2,000 homes.
In order to increase its efficiency, while at the same time reducing
building costs, the association has set up its own technical departments
at headquarters and has also established contracting firms specialising
in various branches of the building industry. Since 1957 the U.S.B.L. has
taken a further step forward by opening its own factories for the mass
production of building components. For legal purposes these contracting and manufacturing concerns are organised as joint-stock companies,
but the bulk of their shares are held by the U.S.B.L.
FINANCING

The first experiments in co-operative house building in Norway were
mainly financed out of personal contributions by members and loans
obtained from private sources of finance. This was particularly true in
the years immediately before and after the First World War. But after
the Second World War, when the housing shortage worsened to such an
extent that it became one of the most serious problems facing the country
and building costs rose sharply, the Government intervened by supplying
low-cost credit to co-operatives to enable them to expand their programmes. The Government thereby became the main source of finance
for the modern co-operative housing movement. For their part, the cooperatives justified the confidence placed in them, backing up the public
authorities by making their organisation and facilities available for
carrying out official housing programmes.

NORWAY

51

Co-operative Finance
It is always the " mother " co-operative which bears responsibility for
arranging finance for a project, although the members themselves must
take the initial step by contributing towards the cost of their future
homes.
The practice in recent years has been to require members to contribute between 15 and 20 per cent, of the estimated cost of the accommodation they require. In order to encourage participation, the largest
Norwegian co-operatives insist that, once members' applications have
been approved, they should open special deposit accounts with their
society and regularly pay in their savings until they can make the down
payment. It is not uncommon in Norway for local authorities or private
firms to make loans on easy terms to enable certain classes of citizens or
employees, as the case may be, to make the necessary down payment and
thereby join the co-operative housing programme.
In accordance with common practice in co-operative organisations,
the Norwegian societies allocate 20 per cent, of the savings obtained by
large-scale production or bulk purchase to a reserve fund to cover any
losses they may incur.
After housing has been allotted to members, the Oslo O.B.O.S.,
together with a number of big co-operatives throughout the country,
opens another special account to cover the cost of maintenance and
decoration. This account, which is based on the example of the Swedish
co-operative movement, is constituted and operated in much the same
way as described in the account of co-operation in that country.
The Role of Public Authorities
The key measure in the Norwegian Government's housing policy was
taken in 1946 when it established a special bank to assist the building
industry by helping to finance new housing schemes. In accordance with
the social purposes for which it had been set up, this bank (called the
Housing Bank) launched a programme of easy credit involving low
interest rates and long repayment periods. Under its new housing policy,
the Government accepted the principle that residents should also be
allowed a share in the ownership of the dwellings they inhabited, and
co-operatives were given preferential treatment for official assistance
through the Housing Bank.1
The first loans needed to begin building are usually obtained from
savings funds and private banks, after the Housing Bank has given its
1

See Housing in the Northern Countries, op. cit., p. 94.

52

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

approval to the plans. Once building is completed, the Housing Bank
grants the final loans against mortgages on the homes. These loans are
first mortgages, but are usually sufficient to cover the whole cost of the
building or buildings in the scheme. The Housing Bank makes its loans
in one instalment.
Since 1948 another banking institution, the Smallholders' Bank,
which formerly used to operate in rural areas and financed other farming
activities as well as house building, has been reorganised by the Government and now works in close collaboration with the Housing Bank and
along the same lines, although concentrating on rural housing.
Loans by these banks are not calculated on the market price of the
housing, but are based on the banks' own estimates which, in turn, make
allowance for the social aims of the country's housing policy.
The procedure for paying off loans granted by the Housing Bank is
as follows. If a house is built of non-flammable material such as brick or
concrete, the annual repayment is 1 per cent, of the loan, which means
that the process takes a hundred years. In the case of wooden houses, the
annual repayment is 11¡3 per cent., i.e. it takes 75 years. No repayments
are made on loans by the Smallholders' Bank during the first two years,
and thereafter annual repayments must be made for 47 years. The annual
amount may, however, be changed by the Housing Bank if circumstances
make it necessary, but only after ten years.1
When these banks began operations, their loans bore interest of only
21/2 per cent., but 3y2 per cent, is charged on all loans granted since
1 January 1957. (The average interest charged by mortgage banks
before the Second World War was 5 per cent.) The rate of interest
charged by the Housing Bank remains unchanged for five years, as
opposed to 15 years until 1 January 1957.
In addition to this special aid from the Government, co-operatives
derive indirect financial benefit from direct State assistance to large
families in the lower income groups, the elderly and the disabled to
enable them to acquire homes in co-operative housing projects.
For its part, the Housing Bank requires co-operatives and other nonprofit bodies which benefit by its credit facilities to abide by certain
technical standards in their building programmes. This is, in any case,
in accordance with the principles and practice of the co-operative movement. In addition, co-operatives financed by the Housing Bank cannot
be wound up or change their rules without prior approval by the Housing
Directorate 2, which is the official body in charge of national housing
policy.
1
2

See Housing in the Northern Countries, op. cit., p. 95.
See UNITED NATIONS : Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 102.

NORWAY

53

SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

The Government's strong appreciation of the economic and social
programme of the Norwegian co-operatives and the confidence it has
shown in them by largely relying on them to carry out the national
housing programme are eloquent evidence of the important part played
by this type of co-operative in Norwegian social and economic life,
especially since the Second World War.
In 1946 there was an acute shortage of housing in Norway, especially
in the towns. It was estimated that, because of the complete standstill in
the building industry, between 60 and 70 thousand homes were needed
to meet the needs of normal population growth. A further 22,000 homes
had been completely destroyed by military action.1
According to figures for the year 1959 published by the International
Co-operative Alliance, the housing co-operatives affiliated to it had by
that date helped to solve this acute shortage by building 47,000 homes.
They were continuing to build at a steady rate of 6,000 homes a year
with an approximate value of 276 million kroner.
In Norway, as in the other Scandinavian countries, the co-operatives
have shown by their achievements that housing should consist of something more than a roof and four walls for each family. They have also

tried to carry out official social policy by taking care not to create
separate neighbourhoods for workers, for the elderly or the disabled, or
for large families in the lower income groups. They have done this by
making membership open without discrimination to anyone in need of
housing (making special arrangements with the local authorities to deal
with needy cases), with the aim of creating a new form of community
living in accordance with the requirements of modern industrial democracy.

1

See Housing in the Northern Countries, op. cit., p. 90.

PART III
OTHER EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

CHAPTER V
FRANCE
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The first attempts in France to solve the housing shortage by means
of co-operative organisation date back to the end of the last century.
These were spontaneous working-class experiments supported by a
handful of middle-class philanthropists, with the State playing a completely passive part.
In order to have a legal existence, these early associations based
themselves on the Companies Act of 1867, but later the authorities came
to realise what could be done by this type of organisation towards
improving housing conditions for the working classes, and a series of
legislative measures were passed from 1894 onwards.
At the outbreak of the First World War there were still no organised
co-operative housing movements in France, but the seed had been
planted by such recent experiments as the promising " Terre et Famille "
society formed by a group of office workers, manual workers and
craftsmen in Paris in 1908.
Between the two world wars the existing housing co-operatives
expanded their activities and concentrated on building houses which
became members' individual property after repayments had been made
for some years.
But it was only after 1945 that the co-operative housing movement,
with its past experience to draw on, began to play a leading part in
national construction. With the large-scale destruction of property, the
problem of housing the population assumed alarming proportions. In
view of the emergency the Government recast the housing policy which
had been followed since the end of the First World War and devised a
series of measures to encourage house building. It decided to make use of
the savings, provident and low-cost housing societies normally known as
H.L.M. co-operatives (habitations à loyer modéré), and gave encouragement to those wishing to form new associations of this type in order to
speed up the drive to provide adequate homes for the lower income
groups. This marked the real beginning of the modern French co-operative housing movement.

58

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
ORGANISATION OF THE

H.L.M.

CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT

In the French co-operative housing movement there is no system of
" mother " and " daughter " societies of the kind found in the Scandinavian movement. In France the co-operatives are more decentralised
in structure and have more in common with the German system of local,
regional and national bodies.
But although local co-operatives do not have " daughter " societies
as in the Scandinavian movement, their practice follows much the same
lines, because the members living in a block of flats or group of homes on
an estate constitute a separate unit within the co-operative and hold
their own meetings to deal with matters affecting the homes they occupy.
They can then submit their problems to the general meeting, which
decides any issues affecting the society as a whole.
The local co-operatives in turn combine to form regional unions,
whose chief purposes are as follows :
(i) to maintain contact between the housing co-operatives in the area
and to facilitate examination of problems occurring at the regional
level in relations with the local authorities ;
(ii) to help smaller or new co-operatives by providing them with
information obtained from larger societies participating in meetings
of the National Federation.
According to information published in ihe Annuaire de la coopération
H.L.M.1 for 1961, there were 15 area unions in operation in France on
1 January of that year. These unions in turn belong to the National
Federation of H.L.M. Co-operative Societies.
The Federation is the central body which officially represents the
H.L.M. co-operative movement and, as such, has an influence on
national housing policy. It has its own representatives on the main
national and international bodies in its particular field and is responsible
for safeguarding the interests of its member societies.
In addition, the Federation provides technical services through the
area unions and also, by means of short-term exchanges of staff between
societies, helps to train competent managers and administrators for
co-operatives with limited means or of recent origin.
In 1960 the National Federation of H.L.M. Co-operative Societies
joined the National Union of Federations of Low-Cost Housing Agencies,
and H.L.M. co-operatives now benefit by that Union's efforts to promote
a national policy for the building and management of low-cost housing.
1

Published in Paris by the National Federation of H.L.M. Co-operative Societies.

FRANCE

59

The main activities of the Union are as follows :
(i) compiling information concerning improved family and popular
housing, with special reference to the low-cost housing movement;
(ii) publishing literature to inform public opinion about the working of
the H.L.M. movement and the practical operation of its family and
popular housing policy;
(iii) maintaining permanent links with public authorities and other
national bodies, and representing the H.L.M. movement both
nationally and internationally;
(iv) co-ordinating the programmes of its member bodies, reconciling
differing viewpoints, and working out a single course of action for
submission to national authorities.1
Although it has joined the National Union, the National Federation
of H.L.M. Co-operative Societies has retained some degree of freedom:
for example, it still has its own national secretariat and issues specialised
literature. In addition, under an agreement approved by both bodies in
1960, the National Federation of H.L.M. Co-operative Societies is
represented by three delegates on the board of the National Union and
by a permanent delegate on the executive committee.
TYPES OF CO-OPERATIVE HOUSING SCHEMES

Co-operatives of Future Owners
The traditional French housing co-operative up to the end of the
Second World War was a society formed to provide a means for workers
to acquire their own homes. Under this system, a member was required
to purchase a number of share certificates equal in value to the cost of
his future home. The State nowadays provides assistance by granting
a loan, which is usually equal to 70 or 75 per cent, of the total cost,
while the member is required to make a down payment of only the
remaining 25 or 30 per cent. The State loan, which is paid off over a
period normally ranging from 25 to 30 years, also comprises life insurance
guaranteeing payment of the remainder in the event of the member's
death. Once the price of the share certificates has been fully paid off, the
member becomes the individual owner of his home.
Privileged Users' Co-operatives
A second type of housing co-operative, which was introduced in
1947, aroused fresh interest among the public by easing the financial
1

Annuaire de la coopération H.L.M., 1961, op. cit., pp. 67 ff.

60

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

burden on co-operative members and has undoubtedly given new
impetus to the French co-operative housing movement. This scheme is
much the same as the method widely used in Sweden and the other
Scandinavian countries, namely an intermediate formula between
individual ownership and tenancy.
When this new scheme was first launched a member also had to
purchase a number of share certificates equal to the cost of his future
home, and a State loan was granted to cover the difference between the
cost and the down payment. The main difference, as compared with the
traditional type of co-operative housing which had hitherto been known
in France, was that under the new scheme a member, even after paying
off the whole of the State loan, still did not become the individual owner
of his home. Ownership remained vested in the co-operative, which
therefore continued to manage the property.
The terms on which this new scheme was launched were not, in fact,
very attractive from the standpoint of the individual member and led
to confusion and disputes. However, the French co-operators learned
from their initial experience and the Government also took an interest
in the new scheme. In 1956 it restricted the amount of share certificates
that had to be purchased by members, who now only buy them to the
value of their down payments, i.e. the difference between the State loan
and the total cost of the dwelling. Moreover, under French law cooperatives can obtain bigger loans in respect of such tenancy contracts.
The initial number of share certificates which a member is required to
buy depends (under the latest legislation) on the type of dwelling to be
built, but generally does not exceed 15 per cent, of the total building cost.
It is also quite common for members to receive individual assistance in
financing their purchase, either from such bodies as the family allowance
funds, or the auxiliary loan funds, or else from their employers or the
welfare funds of the co-operatives themselves. Sometimes members'
contributions only amount to about 6 per cent, of the total building cost.
At the Sixth Congress of the H.L.M. Co-operative Movement in February
1962 it was pointed out that participation involving a purchase of less
than 6 per cent, of the cost in the form of share certificates was undesirable if members were to be induced to take an interest in co-operative
building and management.
Under arrangements laid down in an order dated 8 February 1954
(which is still in force for contracts of this type), H.L.M. co-operatives
charge their members 1 per cent, interest on their loans, which are
repayable over 45 years. During the first three years all interest charges
are waived and capital repayments are deferred.
This second scheme is fully in accordance with the true co-operative

FRANCE

61

spirit. While a member is never granted individual ownership of his
home, he is covered by a special contract which he signs with the cooperative entitling him to use his home as if it were his own property.
This entitlement derives from his initial purchase of share certificates
and, as long as he retains ownership of them, he cannot be deprived of his
right to live there. He may sell his certificates and thereby transfer his
right to the property to the purchaser, but naturally the new member
must first be approved by the board of the co-operative, and in no
circumstances may the sale of the certificates become a speculative
transaction. On a member's death his lawful heirs inherit his rights
unless he transferred them earlier.
Thus, by acquiring a home under this scheme a member enjoys all the
rights which normally go with traditional individual ownership, while at the
same time remaining free of the obligations and burdens involved. Moreover, as the co-operative remains the owner of the property and each
resident in his capacity as a member is entitled to speak and to vote, he has
an opportunity of taking part in the general management of the project.

In short, this type of housing co-operative can be described as a
co-operative of privileged users.
Tenants' Co-operatives
In its effort to provide housing on reasonable terms for families in
the lower income groups who cannot make the down payment needed to
qualify under the individual ownership or privileged users' schemes, the
French co-operative movement, with Government backing, has successfully tried out a new formula. The H.L.M. co-operatives have made
considerable efforts to obtain additional sources of finance to enable
them to meet the cost of this scheme, under which members' down
payments are reduced to a minimum. The scheme is based on a cooperative tenancy arrangement.
It involves a lease with the following distinctive features :
(i) the scheme is designed as a social service and not as a profit-making
enterprise;
(ii) each tenant is a member of the society which leases the homes;
(iii) a resident of one of these co-operatives differs from a tenant in that
he is not only entitled to live in the housing as long as he pays the
agreed rent but, in his capacity as a member, he shares to the full
in the life and management of the co-operative ;
(iv) a member must also make an initial down payment by purchasing
share certificates, but the amount is very small ;

62

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

(v) as opposed to other schemes, a member has no privileged residence
rights, either for himself or for his heirs ;
(vi) the monthly amount payable by member-tenants is regulated by the
decree of 8 April 1960.
Until a short time ago the H.L.M. co-operatives freely used all three
plans, but nowadays the tendency—in accordance with Government
policy—is towards specialisation. In other words, each H.L.M. cooperative is asked to specialise by organising societies for either owners,
privileged users or tenants.
It should be noted that even in the H.L.M. co-operatives which have
made simultaneous use of all three systems there have never been any
classes with greater or lesser rights. All members enjoy the same right to
share in the management of their society in the established democratic
way and with the same opportunities for taking advantage of co-operative
facilities.
FINANCING OF

H.L.M.

CO-OPERATIVES

In carrying out their policy of building homes for families with
limited means, the H.L.M. co-operatives have been forced to rely mainly
on Government loans. The main State agency providing finance for
housing is the National Deposit Fund, which is authorised by law to
grant loans at low rates of interest. The terms on which these loans are
made vary in accordance with the form of co-operation selected.
Homes for Ownership
It is possible, in principle, to obtain a loan equal to 70 per cent.
of the cost of buildings for future ownership, and when there is a guarantee
by the département or commune the loan may be as much as 85 per cent.
In practice, however, under an order dated 25 April 1959, loans depend
on the type of dwelling required and the location. As of 1 January 1954
loans for new building of this type or the enlargement or modernisation
of existing buildings which meet the statutory requirements of the lowcost housing programme bear 2 per cent, interest and are repayable over a
period not exceeding 30 years. A discount of 1 per cent, on the capital
to be repaid is allowed during the first ten years (order dated 8 February
1954).
Homes for Rent
When homes are not being built for individual ownership by members,
co-operatives, together with other non-profit bodies and institutions

63

FRANCE

participating in the low-cost housing programme, are granted easier
financial terms (as was explained before in describing the work of the
privileged users' co-operatives).
The following table gives details of the amounts up to which State
loans may be granted for the building of low-cost family housing for
rent, as laid down in an order dated 11 January 1960:
TABLE I. FRANCE: MAXIMUM LOANS GRANTED BY THE STATE FOR
THE CONSTRUCTION OF LOW-COST FAMILY HOUSING
(In francs)
Geographical area *
Type of home

F.l

l

. . . .

FAbis . .
F.2 . . .
F.3 . . .
F.4 . . .
F.5 . . .
F.6 . . .
F.7 . . .

.
.
.
.
.
.
.

P

A

B

c

D

7,800
15,300
19,100
22,800
26,600
30,300
34,200
37,500

7,200
13,800
17,200
20,700
24,200
27,700
31,300
35,000

7,000
13,600
16,900
20,300
23,700
27,100
30.7C0
34,000

6,600
12,900
16,100
19,400
22,700
26,000
29,500
32,700

6,300
12,300
15,400
18,500
21,600
24,700
28,000
31,200

Source: Sixth Congress of the H.L.M. Co-operative Movement; 5-7 February 1962; II: Financement
(nouveau régime), logements économiques et familiaux, H.L.M. à usage locatif.
1
Classified according to the number of main rooms, excluding sanitary facilities. 8 P represents the
Paris area. The other areas comprise the other départements classified according to local building costs.

The amounts quoted in the table may be increased by 350 francs for
each room in a dwelling with a central-heating installation which meets
the technical and administrative standards laid down by the authorities.
In the case of a block of flats more than five storeys high, an additional
900 francs may be granted per flat to cover the cost of installing a lift.
These figures are based on surveys and statutory provisions regarding
maximum building costs for each type of dwelling and area.

Comprehensive Loans
Under the legislation implementing the national housing policy,
H.L.M. co-operatives are able to obtain comprehensive loans to finance
building schemes consisting of estates for future owners or blocks of
flats for rent, without having to apply for a loan to cover the cost of each
housing unit.
Savings
Apart from this principal system of obtaining finance and any loans
which can be secured from other public or private sources, the French

64

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

co-operative movement also has its own savings programme, which
receives special Government guarantees against the danger of inflation
and is used to finance the purchase of land, to cover part of the building
costs or to repair or modernise existing buildings.
MEMBERSHIP OF

H.L.M.

CO-OPERATIVES

As is the normal practice in any genuine co-operative, membership
of the French co-operative housing movement is open, in principle, to
any persons who are willing to co-operate and abide by the rules of the
society they wish to join. However, in order to take part in the building
programme and benefit by the financial facilities made available by the
Government as part of its low-cost housing policy, members are subject
to certain restrictions which are imposed, not by the co-operatives
themselves, but by law.
The decree of 27 March 1954 lays down the principle that the legislation to promote house building only applies to natural persons of limited
means and, first and foremost, to workers living mainly on their earnings.
In practice, there are two conditions imposed on members wishing to
benefit by the Government-sponsored low-cost housing programme:
they must be of limited means and of French nationality.
Limited Means
Members wishing to qualify for the financial benefits available under
the low-cost housing scheme must not have incomes in excess of a certain
level (without counting family allowances). In the case of housing for
ownership, the upper limit is higher than in the case of homes for rent.
The calculation is based on the net monthly income, having regard to the
number of dependants and the rules laid down in the order of 29
September 1960. Usually no application is entertained from persons who
already own their homes.
Although the programme caters mainly for workers who live on their
own earnings, applications from members of the professions are not
rejected if they can show that their incomes are not higher than the
ceilings laid down in the regulations. Applications are also considered
from the social angle and from the standpoint of the convenience of
having a member of a particular profession on the estate who can serve
all the residents.
In the case of professional workers and craftsmen, co-operatives
usually add on an extra room which can be used, for example, as a
surgery by a doctor or a workshop by a craftsman.

FRANCE

65

Nationality
Government assistance to housing co-operatives in building homes
for ownership is only given in respect of French citizens, although it can
be extended to nationals of countries which have concluded reciprocity
treaties or conventions with France, e.g. Belgium, Italy and Poland.
As regards the financing of house building for rent, there is at present
nothing to stop foreign members from benefiting by the privileged use or
tenancy schemes of the H.L.M. co-operatives.
Protection of Members' Interests
In order to protect members' interests, the Government reserves the
right (through the appropriate agencies) to supervise co-operative
societies' handling of the public funds entrusted to them on behalf of
their members. Apart from this officiai supervision, however, cooperatives control their own affairs effectively by delegation from the
general meetings of their members.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

The H.L.M. co-operatives have been one of the principal elements in
the Government's nation-wide low-cost housing programme. But they
are not alone, for other non-profit bodies and institutions are also
recognised to be playing an effective part in tackling the French housing
shortage. Nor are the H.L.M. co-operatives the only form of co-operative
organisation in France to participate in the drive to make adequate
housing available for the lower income groups. Since the end of the
Second World War the French trade unions have launched a number of
schemes to secure social progress through adequate housing. They have,
for example, encouraged building workers to form labour co-operatives,
which are carrying out their own programmes as part of the national
policy of encouraging non-profit house building. There are also building
loan societies which do not themselves engage in building but help to
overcome the housing shortage by granting loans for schemes carried
out by other bodies. Mention should also be made of the self-help and
mutual-aid movement known as the " coopératives de Castors " launched
in 1948.
Figures taken from the Annuaire de la coopération H.L.M. for 1961
show the scale of the contribution made by H.L.M. co-operatives towards
solving the housing shortage in France. Between September 1947 and
31 December 1960 they completed 88,575 dwellings, and at the latter
date a further 78,090 dwellings were under construction.

66

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

But the French co-operative housing movement has done more than
perform an outstanding social service through its three-pronged housing
programme. The co-operative formula has also helped to create a community atmosphere of good neighbourliness among members living in the
same housing projects. In many cases, when building is for ownership and
also in schemes for rent where the society building the project is not
responsible for its subsequent management, a special type of co-operative
is set up to manage the completed scheme. In addition to the normal
functions of estate management, such societies do much to improve the
amenities, e.g. by planting trees and gardens, installing cultural facilities,
providing various services for members, organising sports groups and
fostering the co-operative spirit among members.
The " Castors " movement has put up a number of large estates in
various parts of the country for its worker-members. This is an interesting experiment which suggests yet another approach which could be
tried and developed as part of the national drive to supply adequate
housing on reasonable terms for the lower income groups.
The French housing co-operative movement has not stopped there.
In its determination to improve its systems and methods by drawing on
the experience of other countries, the National Federation of H.L.M.
Co-operative Societies, under the auspices of the Ministry of Building,
called an international conference in Paris in October 1960, which was
attended by representatives of housing co-operatives in 16 European,
Asian and African countries. This meeting and the survey it made of
common problems and possible ways and means of dealing with them
strengthened the leaders of the French co-operative movement in their
effort to adapt their methods to changes in the building industry and to
find additional sources of finance and new approaches to enable them to
discharge the social responsibilities falling to the co-operative movement
in a dynamic modern economy.

CHAPTER VI
FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

German housing co-operatives have a long history. The earliest
experiments in co-operative housing schemes were made in the midnineteenth century, but it was only from 1889 onwards that the movement acquired any momentum, because until that year German law only
allowed societies to operate on an unlimited liability basis, and many
people were deterred from joining through fear of losing their own
capital if the society were to show a deficit. However, the co-operative
housing movement only began to play an important part in the German
economy after the First World War.
Official policy was the decisive factor governing the development of
this type of co-operation. After the First World War the housing
situation in Germany was extremely serious, partly because hundreds of
thousands of families were in need of homes and partly because the
economy had been undermined by inflation and building costs had risen
sharply. In order to tackle this problem it was decided to grant largescale Government aid for house-building projects, and co-operatives and
other non-profit bodies, many of them co-operative in form, were given
priority for their building programmes, whether on behalf of their own
members or for other persons or groups.
Table II shows the steady contribution made by co-operatives and
other non-profit organisations towards solving the housing shortage.
This lasted until the 1930s, when the country was hit by the slump and,
in addition, the co-operatives found their scope considerably circumscribed as a result of the change in political régime.
PRESENT SITUATION

Although there was an acute housing shortage in Germany at the
end of the Second World War, and the co-operative movement immediately overhauled its own organisation, it was unable to do any largescale building until 1950, i.e. until members could begin to save some-

68

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

TABLE II. GERMANY: HOUSING CONSTRUCTION, 1927-35
(Numbers and percentages)
Year

1927
1928
1929
1930
1931
1932
1933
1934
1935

Private
builders

Co-operatives and other
non-profit societies

Public bodies
and authorities

Number

%

Number

%

Number

%

169,395
180,900
173,139
156,754
118,749
91,672
99,660
133,542
154,845

60.3
59.6
55.5
51.3
51.7
70.4
75.4
70.5
73.0

78,426
90,889
109,121
121,394
92,587
27,282
19,546
30,187
40,050

27.9
30.0
34.9
39.8
40.3
20.9
14.8
15.9
18.9

33,269
31,538
30,010
27,148
18,492
11,337
12,986
25,760
17,127

11.8
10.4
9.6
8.9
8.0
8.7
9.8
13.6
8.1

Source: H. UMRATH: European Labour Movement and Housing (Brussels, European Regional
Organisation of the International Confederation of Free Trade Unions, 1953), p. 35.

thing towards the cost of their homes following the currency reform of
1948. This did not apply to the co-operatives alone, for little of importance was accomplished by the German building industry during the
first inflationary post-war years.
Table III shows the part played since then by housing co-operatives
in national reconstruction.
The modern German co-operative housing movement which has
come into existence since the Second World War has little in common
with the co-operative experiments made at the end of the last century
and the beginning of this. Those experiments were undertaken by
idealists without much co-ordination between their schemes or any real
business sense, although they did at least reveal the difficulties and
opportunities in the co-operative method as applied to housing. The
modern societies are highly efficient organisations using up-to-date
methods and equipment, and administered by skilled managers. As a
result, the German co-operative housing movement has played a prominent part in the building industry and has helped to strengthen the
national economy by providing the lower income groups with adequate
housing at reasonable prices.
ORGANISATION

Unlike the Swedish co-operative housing movement, which is
characterised by a centralised national organisation, through the H.S.B.
movement, the German societies are usually local enterprises which
remain independent of each other and confine themselves to building

TABLE III. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: HOMES BUILT BY AND ON BEHALF OF CO-OPERATIVES, 1950-61

Total
number of
co-operatives

Number of
co-operatives
submitting
returns

Homes built by
co-operatives
on their own
account

Average
number of
homes built
by each
co-operative

Number of
homes built
by private
contractors
on behalf of
co-operatives

Average
number of
homes built
by private
contractors on
behalf of each
co-operative

Total number of
homes built by
and on behalf of
co-operatives

Average total
number of
homes built
by and on
behalf of each
co-operative

1950

1,750

1,591

60,028

38

2,800

2

62,828

40

1951

1,860

1,703

61,954

36

7,156

4

69,110

41

1952

1,855

1,771

59,496

34

6,022

3

65,518

37

¡«

Year

O
a
so
>
r

a

•tí

1953

1,840

1,718

65,977

38

7,101

4

73,078

43

G
ta

1954

1,835

1,686

58,633

35

7,980

5

66,613

40

n

1955

1,787

1,719

46,816

27

8,867

5

55,683

32

1956

1,762

1,698

47,459

28

9,432

6

56,891

34

1957

1,720

1,641

39,770

24

9,711

6

49,481

30

1958

1,689

1,632

35,053

21

8,485

5

43,538

27

1959

31

1,679

1,628

40,744

25

9,598

6

50,342

1960

1,651

1,586

35,787

23

9,046

6

44,833

28

1961

1,647

1,527

34,079

22

8,969

6

43,048

28

O
en
¡w
2
>
•z

Source: GESAMTVERBAND GEMEINNÜTZIGER WOHNUNGSUNTERNEHMEN: Empfehlungen zur Entfaltung gemeinnütziger Wohnungsbaugenossenschaften (Cologne, 1962), p. vin.
0\

VO

70

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

homes for particular groups of individuals in the town or rural district
in which they operate. There are, however, a number of co-operative
federations in Germany, at both the regional and national levels, which
do very useful work, especially as regards accounting and cost control.
Regional Audit Unions
At the regional level there is a network of audit unions, each dealing
with a particular area. At first these unions were solely concerned with
helping the co-operatives (and non-profit building associations in
general) within their areas, by auditing their books and helping them to
keep better accounts. As time went by, however, their functions were
enlarged to include technical help over management, planning and
layout, the legal aspects of contracting, financing, costing, purchasing
of material and equipment, negotiating contracts with technical staff,
standardisation, the management of completed housing owned by
societies, insurance schemes, etc.
National Union
At the national level the housing co-operatives, in conjunction with
other non-profit building associations, formed in 1949 a central organisation called the Gesamtverband gemeinnütziger Wohnungsunternehmen
(G.G.W.).
This Union of Non-Profit Housing Enterprises is a nation-wide
organisation with the following objectives:
(i) to promote the establishment of co-operatives and other non-profit
building associations;
(ii) to represent the interests of such bodies;
(iii) to supervise the work of the regional audit unions;
(iv) to conduct research into new building techniques which could be
used for the construction of low-cost housing;
(v) to maintain contact with the public authorities and to participate
in all aspects of national housing policy.
The democratic structure of the G.G.W. comprises three main
bodies : the congress, the board, and the executive committee.
Congress.
The congress (Gesamtverbandstag) is the highest authority within the
G.G.W., consisting of delegates representing the regional audit unions,
together with the co-operatives and other non-profit building associations

FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY

71

affiliated to the G.G.W. Its main responsibilities are to formulate a
social housing policy for member bodies and to elect the executive
committee and general secretary.
Board.
The board consists of 28 members, the chairman being elected
directly by the congress and the remainder by the audit unions. This
body settles any major issues arising out of the G.G.W.'s social and
economic policy and draws up programmes and projects for submission
to the congress.
Executive Committee.
The executive committee is elected by the congress for three years
and consists of five members, two of whom represent the audit unions
and two the local societies belonging to the G.G.W. ; the fifth member
is the general secretary, who is elected for a period of five years. This
committee, working through the audit unions and local member organisations, is responsible for carrying out the housing policy laid down
by the congress and any decisions approved by the board.
Building Workers' Co-operative Movement
The German trade union movement has also contributed towards
solving the housing shortage by sponsoring the formation of co-operatives. Not only have the unions promoted co-operatives to provide
adequate housing for their own members, but they have also encouraged
building workers to form co-operatives to put up homes for other
groups of workers or for the general housing market.
Building workers banded together to form co-operatives because
they were convinced that in this way they could demonstrate that it was
possible to build good housing at reasonable prices.
In 1919 members of the building trade unions organised themselves
as producers and set up their own co-operative societies in Berlin and
other German industrial cities.
The unions quickly realised, however, that, if these co-operatives were
to achieve their purpose and provide adequate housing at prices within
the reach of the working class, it was necessary to co-ordinate the
scattered efforts being made in various parts of the country. The nationwide Verband sozialer Baubetriebe (V.S.B.), or Federation of Non-Profit
Building Enterprises, was therefore founded in 1928.1
1
See H. UMRATH: European Labour Movement and Housing (Brussels, European
Regional Organisation of the International Confederation of Free Trade Unions,
1953) p. 37.

72

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

After the V.S.B. was established, its responsibilities were enlarged
and, in addition to co-ordinating and helping its member co-operatives
and other workers' non-profit building associations, it also organised
new enterprises with the same aims and in the same spirit.
Adhering to the distinctive feature of administrative decentralisation,
the V.S.B. set up regional unions in the most industrialised areas of the
country to act as co-ordinating and operating centres for member
organisations in their areas. Two years after its foundation, in 1922,
the V.S.B. had already formed 207 new local societies through its regional
unions.
In the early days, however, the efficiency of the V.S.B. left a good
deal to be desired. It was an organisation of workers which was also
managed by workers, but individuals who might be highly skilled in
their own trades were not necessarily qualified to become competent
managers, especially in the inflationary period through which Germany
passed in the early post-war years.
Nevertheless, the V.S.B. did not confine itself to co-ordinating and
helping its member societies, but also entered the building industry as a
contractor. To start with, it only acted as a contractor for co-operatives
and other non-profit associations belonging to it, but later it undertook
contracts on behalf of public and private bodies.
In the interests of efficiency the V.S.B. set up a technical department
in 1926 to advise member societies on building management. It also
standardised accounting systems so as to facilitate comparative analysis
of costs and thereby help to keep them in line with estimates.
In order to make homes available on reasonable terms to families of
moderate means in accordance with its fundamental principles, the
V.S.B. went a step further and decided to go in for production as well,
with the result that by 1929 it was making many of the materials for its
housing projects in its own factories.
By the end of 1929 the V.S.B. had become one of the biggest concerns
in the German building industry, making a contribution of outstanding
social value towards solving the housing shortage. This was not only
because of its own manufacturing activities and services to its member
organisations, but also because of its striking success in reducing building
costs.
Unfortunately, just when this type of co-operative house building
was forging ahead, the slump occurred in 1930 and the German economy
was badly hit. Nevertheless, it was not the slump but the political
regime that came to power shortly afterwards which destroyed the work
of the V.S.B. and its member societies.
One of the first steps taken by the German trade union movement in

FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY

73

reorganising itself after the Second World War was to demonstrate its
renewed interest in co-operative house building. First of all the unions
asked for the co-operative assets which had not been destroyed to be
returned to them so that they could be reorganised. Later, owing to
the sheer scale of the problem facing the country because of wartime
destruction, the new German trade union organisation decided that its
housing policy, instead of being confined to societies in which the
unions themselves had a stake, should be enlarged to include the many
families who had lost everything, especially refugees needing homes
near their new places of work.
By 1951 the co-operatives and other union-sponsored associations
on the co-operative model had already built about 10,000 homes with
the help of the consumer co-operatives, backed by the Wholesale
Society of the German Consumers' Co-operatives, which supplied them
with high-quality materials at reasonable prices.1
Since then, workers' building co-operatives, operating as autonomous
local bodies, have continued to carry out housing schemes while belonging to regional and national associations which ensure co-ordination and
enable them to take advantage of each other's experience or obtain the
benefits of standardisation and large-scale manufacturing or purchasing.
All these measures enable them to provide homes for families in the
lower income groups at reasonable prices.

Some Characteristics of German Housing Co-operatives
This survey does not set out to describe the democratic internal
structure of the German housing or building co-operatives, nor its
underlying principles, because basically they are the same as elsewhere
in the international co-operative movement and very similar in operation
to those described in detail earlier in connection with the Swedish
H.S.B.—apart from the fact that the German co-operatives are more
decentralised. It is, however, worth mentioning certain distinctive
features of the way in which the German co-operative housing movement
is organised.
Individual Ownership.
Some of the homes built by the co-operatives are intended for sale
to the families living in them. As there is no question of making a
profit, the sale price is calculated on the basis of the mortgage obtained
by the co-operative on the property. It should be noted that the pur1

See UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 111.

74

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

chasers remain members of the co-operative even after they become
the owners of their homes. According to figures published by the
Economic Commission for Europe, by the end of 1956 a total of 82,787
homes built by co-operatives had in this way become the individual
property of their occupiers.1 In such cases co-operatives take special
precautions (as permitted by German law) to ensure that purchasers do
not then resell their dwellings for speculative purposes. This is done by
inserting a clause in the contract of sale empowering the co-operative to
re-acquire the property in such cases as are allowed by the legislation on
public utility housing.
Collective Ownership.
Usually, however, housing co-operatives retain the ownership of the
dwellings they build, not only in the case of large blocks of flats, but also
in the case of housing estates consisting of small homes for one or two
families. It is often said that in such cases the co-operatives are building
houses for rent at moderate rates to their members, but in fact the latter
cannot be said to be tenants since, as members, they are co-owners and
co-managers of the properties in which they live. When a member is
allocated a co-operative dwelling, he becomes entitled to live in it for the
rest of his life provided he remains a member of the association and
carries out his obhgations. In allocating co-operative dwellings, priority
is given (other things being equal) to length of membership of the
co-operative.
Members' contributions to their co-operative's capital in the form of
share certificates are practical evidence of their collective ownership and
entitlement to occupy the dwellings respectively allocated to them.
In principle, a member can at any time transfer his share certificates
to another person by means of a written contract signed by both parties.
In such a case, however, he must first secure the approval of the society's
management committee for the sale, and the committee must register
the deed with a notary. If the share certificates are acquired by a person
who does not belong to the co-operative, the rules require him to apply
at once for permission to join.
A member can also withdraw from a co-operative, in which case the
normal procedure is for him to give two years' prior notice in writing.
The management committee is required to register his withdrawal with
a notary at least six weeks before the expiry of the financial year in which
the withdrawal actually occurs.
1
See UNITED NATIONS, Economic Commission for Europe: Financing of Housing
in Europe (Geneva, 1958; Sales N o . : 58.II.E.3), p. 81.

FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY

75

In the event of a member's death, his rights only expire on the expiry
of the financial year in which he died. Until then all his rights pass to
his heirs. If there is more than one heir they may only act collectively
in exercising the rights of the deceased member.
FINANCING

In accordance with the true spirit of co-operation, which is not to
rely entirely on outside assistance in financing building schemes, the
German co-operatives have tried to cover as much as possible of the
cost of their projects. But in the circumstances resulting from two world
wars, which largely shattered German society and, in fact, the whole
national economy, and with the extremely acute housing shortage caused
by the almost complete destruction of many cities and towns during the
last war, the German co-operatives, on resuming operations in 1945, had
to rely on external assistance in undertaking the large-scale reconstruction that was needed. The Government, for its part, realised the valuable
work that co-operatives could do as voluntary agents of its social policy
for coping with the emergency, and gave them generous assistance out of
public funds, while at the same time respecting their internal autonomy.
One of the advantages of co-operative organisation is that it generates
its own capital out of the savings secured by the bulk buying of materials,
production in co-operative factories and large-scale building operations,
and also by means of the nation-wide technical and financial services
provided by the co-operative federation. In addition to this capital of its
own, the main sources of finance for the housing co-operative movement
are members' contributions, private credit institutions and public funds.
Members'" Contributions
When combining to form a co-operative, members undertake to
contribute towards the capital of the association by purchasing one or
more share certificates. They also undertake to pay a prescribed deposit
in due course. The amount and conditions depend on circumstances
and are laid down in the society's rules.
Societies set up their own savings funds to encourage and facilitate
participation by members in this way.
In the rural areas of Western Germany it is also common for
members' contributions to their co-operative to be wholly or partly in
the form of their own labour instead of cash.
A special agency, the Lastenausgleichsfonds, was set up after the
war to help refugees and other sections of the population which had

76

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

suffered serious hardship in the war to join co-operative housing schemes.
This agency granted interest-free loans repayable at the rate of 2 per
cent, per year. The loans varied according to the type of home needed
by each family1 and enabled recipients to purchase share certificates
in the same way as other members. Table IV shows the contribution
of members to the formation of co-operative capital through share
certificates.
Private Credit Institutions
The main credit institutions providing funds for housing in the
Federal Republic of Germany are the insurance companies, mortgage
banks, savings funds and building societies. These bodies make loans
on the first mortgage up to 35 per cent, of the total building cost. Repayment periods vary between 30 and 40 years, and the interest rate is
usually 6 per cent.2
It is also by no means uncommon for private companies to advance
money to co-operatives to finance building schemes for their own
employees.
The Role of Public

Authorities

The key legislation governing house building in Germany after
the war was passed in 1950 and amended in 1953.
The 1950 Act laid down general principles governing the granting
of second mortgage loans and encouraged Land and local authorities
to give this policy their backing. It specified that the maximum interest
on such loans must be 4 per cent, and allowed interest charges to be
waived altogether if it could be proved to be necessary to enable a
building scheme to be financed. Between 60 and 65 years were allowed
for repayment. The Act also stipulated that housing built under this
programme would be subject to lower taxation for a specified number
of years.
The 1953 amendment marked a significant shift in national housing
policy by favouring home ownership. It encouraged the growth of
housing co-operatives and entitled them to preferential financial treatment from the Federal Government if they built flats for individual or
joint ownership (title of ownership in the latter case being vested in the
co-operative) so that members could become co-owners with indefinite
rights of possession.
1
See Herbert ASHWORTH: Housing Finance in Western Europe (London, International Co-operative Alliance), p. 38.
2
Ibid., p. 40.

TABLE IV. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: CO-OPERATIVE SHARE CAPITAL, 1950-60
Percentage
increase of
share capital
compared with
preceding year

Average share
capital per
co-operative
(in DM)

Percentage increase
of average share
capital compared
with previous year

Year

Total number of
co-operatives

Number of
co-operatives
submitting
returns

Total share capital
(in D M )

1950

1,750

1,591

186,819,000

—

117,422

—

1951

1,860

1,703

201,934,000

8.1

118,575

1.0

1952

1,855

1,771

236,296,000

17.0

133,425

12.5

1953

1,840

1,718

260,250,400

10.1

151,485

13.5

1954

1,835

1,686

294,389,700

13.1

174,608

15.3

1955

1,787

1,719

324,744,313

10.2

188,915

8.2

1956

1,762

1,698

355,895,265

9.6

209,597

10.9

1957

1,720

1,641

391,400,583

10.0

238,513

13.8

1958

1,689

1,632

430,981,147

10.1

264,082

10.7

1959

1,679

1,628

481,890,543

11.8

296,002

12.1

1960

1,651

1,586

530,581,077

10.1

334,540

13.0

m
O
ta
¡a

ta

ES
c
r
ts

o
it

O
m

!»

Source: GESAMTVERBAND GEMEINNÜTZIGER WOHNUNGSUNTERNEHMEN: Empfehlungen zur Entfaltung gemeinnütziger Wohnungsbaugenossenschaften (Cologne, 1962), p. vi.
-J

78

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

In addition to this Government aid over second mortgages in nonprofit housing schemes, the Federal Republic of Germany operates a
subsidy scheme to help families in the lower income groups pay their
contributions and thereby participate in co-operative housing schemes
and other associations with similar methods and aims. The amended
legislation passed by the Bundestag in 1961 enlarged the facilities
available for those wishing to take part in housing programmes sponsored
by the Federal Government and introduced a number of major changes
to help families of moderate means, the extent of the help depending on
the number of children. It also included former prisoners of war and
persons who had suffered from persecution under the previous political
régime.
This legislative reform in 1961 emphasised the trend to grant subsidies to house-building associations which encourage stability of residence by occupants of flats or houses and allow them to manage their
own affairs.1 All these features are characteristic of co-operative
housing.
However, the same trend has been noticeable in the Federal Republic
of Germany in recent years as in the other Western European countries,
whereby State aid for house building is being steadily curtailed in view
of the changed economic circumstances, and financial aid from public
funds is confined to special sections of the population.2
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

The great social significance of the German co-operative housing
movement is apparent from the major contribution made both by
genuine co-operatives and by other non-profit associations in rebuilding
the country, especially since the Second World War.
One example of this highly successful contribution is the Neue
Heimat in Hamburg. This society, which has now extended its operations
to other areas such as Bremen and Lübeck, has its own technical department with specially qualified staff and has devised a scheme based
on short-term loans financed out of the savings and monthly contributions
of the residents on its housing projects. Neue Heimat has not confined
itself to isolated projects but has also built large estates with up-to-date,
modern services, such as those at Hohnerkamp, Farmsen and Vedel,
with 1,520, 1,992 and 1,700 homes respectively. A noteworthy point
is that, by making full use of co-operative methods to increase efficiency
1

See International Housing Bulletin, loc. cit.

2

UNITED NATIONS: European Housing Trends and Policies in 1960, op. cit., p. 32.

FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY

79

and generate capital, this society has managed to build several hundred
dwellings without having to rely on the State for financial aid.1
From the social standpoint, however, the greatest contribution made
by the German co-operative movement towards housing reconstruction
has been its effort, in collaboration with the authorities and other nonprofit organisations, to tackle the problem of housing the refugees.
An example of this is the pilot project carried out in Schleswig-Holstein.
In 1946 the position in Schleswig-Holstein was extremely serious
because of the enormous increase in the population caused by the influx
of refugees in need of homes and work if they were to support themselves.
The German trade union organisation therefore decided to carry
out a joint scheme (to serve as a pilot project) involving the construction
of 10,000 homes for the refugees. The aim was to demonstrate the scope
for cutting costs through large-scale building, bulk purchase of materials
and use of modern techniques.
The co-operatives played a leading part in this scheme (in which the
Land of Schleswig-Holstein, the trade unions and various non-profit
organisations also took part) by managing it and contributing their own
special techniques and experience in the field of house building. Apart
from the building or housing co-operatives, the consumer co-operatives
also took part, e.g. the Wholesale Society of the German Consumers'
Co-operatives, which acted as a central purchasing agency and bore the
main responsibility for lowering building costs.1
To sum up, the gains from this pilot scheme were as follows: in
human terms, 35,000 displaced persons were accommodated in decent
housing close to their new places of work; as regards organisation and
administration, it demonstrated the advantages of co-operation between
public and private bodies concerned with the same subject; and from
the economic standpoint the Schleswig-Holstein experiment showed
that large-scale building and modern techniques could not only lower
construction costs but also raise productivity substantially. It also
greatly helped the Land of Schleswig-Holstein to overcome the acute
housing shortage and to derive some benefit from the absorption into
the local economy of thousands of refugees, once they had settled in
their new homes close to the manufacturing centres.

1

See UMRATH: op. cit., p. 46.

CHAPTER VII
POLAND
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The Polish co-operative housing movement has a tradition dating
back to the end of the nineteenth century, the first such society having
been founded in 1890. Between the two world wars there were 400
housing co-operatives in Poland.1 Some of these societies discharged a
valuable social function during these years. For example, the Warsaw
Housing Movement, which was founded in 1921 by wage and salary
earners of moderate means, had by 1932 built 14 blocks containing a total
of 1,200 flats for its members; ownership of the property remained
vested in the co-operative.
Nevertheless it was only after the Second World W a r that co-operative

organisation as a means of dealing with the housing problem began to
assume nation-wide importance under the Government's reconstruction
plan. It was agreed that, in order to rebuild the country after the virtually complete destruction of many towns and villages, it was essential
to encourage participation by the homeless themselves in acquiring
housing for their families. Co-operatives were considered to be the best
way of enlisting such participation.
For example a society was founded in Warsaw in 1945, consisting
entirely of homeless workers, which concentrated on repairing partly
damaged buildings in order to make them fit for occupation once more,
and by the following year there were 33 of these societies in existence,
which between them repaired 2,177 dwellings in a single year. By the end
of 1947 nearly 100 co-operatives of this type had been formed in the
capital alone. At that time the Government was not in a position to
give any substantial financial aid to the societies, but the Warsaw municipal authorities (which now owned the land) made sites available to
workers belonging to co-operatives.
Despite the existence of the societies and the Government's declared
desire to encourage this form of co-operation, house building or repair
1
See Bohdan TRAMPCZYNSKI: The Tasks and Activities of the Co-operative Movement in Urban Centres (Warsaw, Supreme Co-operative Council, 1962), pp. 28-31.

POLAND

81

by co-operative societies until 1957 was on a very small scale, and
barely accounted for 1 per cent, of the total number of dwellings available in the urban centres. But the Government's new housing policy
launched in 1956 gave fresh impetus to the co-operative movement, with
the result that, whereas in 1957 there were only 280 societies in the whole
country, three years later in 1960 the number of societies was over 1,000,
comprising 120,000 families.1
ORGANISATION

The main types of housing co-operative in Poland are as follows :
(i) collective ownership, which is the oldest form and traditional in
Poland. These societies finance and build homes which they then
assign to their members for an indefinite period while retaining
ownership themselves. Collectively all the members are owners of
the block or blocks of flats forming part of the project;
(ii) associations formed to help the construction of single-family homes
by co-operative methods; on completion the houses are allocated to
members, and the society itself is usually wound up;
(iii) management co-operatives which are set up solely for the purpose of
providing and organising communal services for a particular housing
scheme.
The traditional type of Polish housing co-operative, in which the
society retains ownership of the property, can take one of two forms.
In the first case the cash contribution by members towards the cost of
their homes is comparatively slight, and members are entitled to live in
the homes allocated to them for an indefinite period but cannot sell them
to a third party. Under the second system members make a somewhat
bigger financial contribution and are entitled not only to live in the
dwellings indefinitely with their families, but also to sell their acquired
rights in the society.
In principle housing co-operatives are open to any person supporting
himself by his own labour, but preference is given to workers employed
in socialised establishments or productive undertakings, especially if they
are saving out of their own earnings to acquire a new home. 2
As regards internal organisation, the chief authority in each cooperative is the general meeting of members. This meeting elects a
management committee which in turn appoints a manager.
1
See Witold KASPERSKI: "Housing Co-operation", in Polish Co-operative Review
(Warsaw, Supreme Co-operative Council), Sep. 1960, p. 25.
s

See TRAMPCZYNSKI: op. cit., p. 30.

82

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

At the national level all housing co-operatives belong to a central
federation, which, together with the other federations, belongs to the
Supreme Co-operative Council; this is the policy-making body of the
movement, which co-ordinates the programmes of its member organisations. At one time the Council consisted of Government nominees, but
now the delegates are chosen by the affiliated federations.
FINANCING

Although at one time building programmes were wholly financed by
the Government, the new national housing policy in operation since 1956
encourages those directly concerned to make a financial contribution as
well. Responsibility for implementing this policy has been given to the
co-operative movement, which has thereby achieved greater freedom of
action. Since 1957, therefore, there have been not one but two housebuilding programmes: State-built projects financed entirely out of
public funds, and co-operative schemes.
Under the current national housing policy, co-operative members are
required to make a down payment equal to 15 per cent, of the building
cost, which may be done at any time until their homes are actually
allocated. The undertaking in which the member is employed usually
advances two-thirds of this down payment.
The co-operative makes itself directly responsible for financing the
remaining 85 per cent., for which it obtains an interest-free bank loan
repayable over a period of 40 years. If a member undertakes (through
his co-operative) to pay off his loan in regular instalments, he need pay
back only two-thirds of the total, as the remaining third is automatically
cancelled.
In addition the Polish Government assists co-operatives during their
early months and provides them with suitable sites for their building
projects.
With this financial backing given to Polish co-operatives and the
favourable terms granted to members, it is not surprising that the cooperative housing movement should have expanded considerably from
1957 onwards, and now even families of moderate means are able to take
part in co-operative building schemes.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

By the end of 1961 there were 1,104 housing co-operatives in Poland
with 212,000 rooms in 74,500 flats and a membership of 175,000. In
other words, the co-operative housing movement, which played such

POLAND

83

an important part in the post-war reconstruction of the country, and
especially of Warsaw, is continuing to occupy a major role in the
country's housing drive.
As in other countries, such as Sweden, Norway, Denmark, the United
States and Canada, the co-operative housing movement in Poland has
sought to do more than build homes for its members—it has tried to create
an environment for genuine co-operative communities. One of the
methods used by the Polish co-operatives for this purpose is to call a
meeting of the future residents of a housing project some two months
before the dwellings are due to be allocated. At this meeting members can
get to know one another and are told how to make the best use of their
new homes, what are their rights and responsibilities and how they should
set about organising certain communal services in order to make life
pleasanter in their housing estate or block. This initial meeting between
the future residents, who are quite often of different educational standards
and of different backgrounds, creates a bond of common interest, and it
is not uncommon for teams of volunteers to be formed at the first
meeting—which is usually held on the building site itself—to do various
jobs in their spare time for the community as a whole. Each family is
responsible for maintaining the home allocated to it, but all are jointly
responsible for the upkeep of halls, corridors and stairways or the
gardens, playing fields or avenues which usually surround co-operative
housing projects.
A case in point is the Lublin Housing Co-operative which, although
only founded in 1957, is now one of the biggest in Poland. This cooperative, which includes professional as well as factory and railway
workers among its members, has built a number of co-operative housing
estates with every modern convenience and amenity and has managed
to turn them into genuine co-operative communities as well. Members
begin to work together from the time they come into contact with the
co-operative, long before they settle into their new homes. Some of
them look after the lawns or flower-beds, others plant trees or build
roads. It is the practice for the families in each building to take it in
turns to clean the stairways and other parts of the building used by all
the residents. This is done for two reasons: it cuts down the monthly
payment made by the residents, and it has been realised that, when the
residents themselves are personally responsible for the cleanliness and
upkeep of communal facilities, they take a greater interest in keeping
them neat and tidy.1
1
See "The Lublin Housing and Building Society", in Polish Co-operative Review,
Dec. 1961, pp. 41-44.

84

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Once members have settled in their homes they appoint a management committee which, apart from its administrative duties, undertakes
various educational functions so as to foster the co-operative spirit
among neighbours. For example it organises special programmes for
residents on certain traditional occasions such as the New Year, and
takes special care of the children.
In Poland co-operative societies do not build kindergartens, because
these are provided by the local authorities together with schools. In
planning their schemes, co-operatives try to make their members'
savings go as far as possible, but although the flats they build may be
fairly small they are so arranged as to provide the air and space needed
for healthy family life. They are also equipped with such services as
electricity, gas, running water, rubbish chutes and central heating.
All co-operatives try to provide shopping facilities for the benefit of their
residents in addition to the usual amenities. Many societies have their
own lecture halls and centres for the hire of equipment or machinery for
use in the home, and some have their own artistic clubs.
In short, the Polish co-operative housing movement has done much
to raise the living standards of a large section of the population. The
Polish Government has shown that it favours this type of co-operation,
which benefits the national housing programme by stimulating popular
interest and promoting members' participation in the construction of
their homes.

CHAPTER Vili
SPAIN
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The origins of the Spanish co-operative movement go back to the end
of the nineteenth century, a period which was marked by internal upheavals, economic instability and considerable social unrest, all of which
to a large extent reflected the initial impact of the industrial revolution.
However, the roots of the Spanish co-operative movement go deeper
than this, for they can be found in the fishermen's associations, communal barns, and other social and economic patterns of the Middle Ages.
Two different ideologies, the one social Catholic and the other
socialist, underlay the Spanish co-operative movement in its early days.
The former encouraged farm and rural credit co-operatives, while the
latter formed consumer co-operatives and to some extent paved the way
for the organisation of industrial co-operation.
This was the position of the Spanish co-operative movement at the
beginning of the present century, when the first housing co-operatives
were set up as specialised off-shoots of the consumer societies in a further
attempt to protect consumers in the most thickly populated areas where
the housing shortage was becoming steadily more acute. As a result,
by 1930 even before the law had recognised co-operatives as associations
with their own distinctive features, there were some 40 housing associations with 2,500 families living in the homes they had provided. On the
basis of this early experience in housing co-operatives, a number of new
societies were set up, such as La Propiedad Cooperativa, founded in 1912,
La Madrileña de Casas Baratas y Económicas, founded in 1925, and
El Viso, founded in 1930. These co-operatives alone built several hundred
single-family homes in Madrid for members and their families, who in
most cases are still living in them.
SOCIAL HOUSING POLICY

In order to appreciate the growth of this form of co-operation in
Spain and the great scope still open to it in the immediate future, it is

86

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

necessary to have some knowledge of the general trend of Government
social policy in Spain with regard to the housing problem.
The housing shortage in Spain is not entirely due to the destruction
caused by the Civil War or to the consequences of the Second World
War. It had been steadily worsening over the years because of a number
of other factors, such as the growth of the population and the influx into
the big industrial towns.
In order to overcome this shortage, which was particularly serious
among the lower income groups, the Government passed a Protected
Housing Act in 1939, which was followed by a Controlled Rents Act in
1954 and a Subsidised Housing Act in 1957.
In accordance with the policy laid down in these enactments, the
Government launched its first five-year housing programme in 1955.
The number of houses built under this programme (in which the cooperatives participated) with direct or indirect Government financial
assistance totalled 550,000, i.e. 110,000 per year.
Taking advantage of the experience acquired during this five-year
plan, a second national housing plan was launched in 1961 which will
continue until 1976 and has a target of 3,713,000 homes. Three different
types of dwelling are being built to cater for the varyingfinancialcircumstances of residents. Housing co-operatives play a leading part among
the organisations responsible for building homes for ownership by
salaried and manual workers, and are entitled to various forms of aid
under the State-sponsored programme.
According to estimates by the National Housing Directorate, the
demand for dwellings over the years 1961-76 will be as follows:
Estimated deficit on 1 January 1961 . . . .
Need caused by population growth
. . . .
Need caused by internal migration
Need caused by demolition of old housing .

1,000,000
1,550,828
252,000
911,072

The total number of homes needed thus corresponds to the target
mentioned earlier for the current national housing plan. It is calculated
that the plan will involve State investment of the order of 551,000 million
pesetas.
ORGANISATION

The new trend, which emerges very clearly from the conclusions of
the National Co-operative Assembly held in Madrid in November 1961
under official auspices, is for housing co-operatives (which were originally regarded simply as off-shoots of the consumer societies) to seek
recognition as a distinctive type of society which in addition to the general

SPAIN

87

principles and practices of any co-operative organisation has aims,
features, problems and methods which are peculiar to it and distinguish
it from other co-operatives.
But despite the fact that there are now about 800 housing co-operatives in Spain which have enabled some 50,000 families to obtain their
homes on exceptionally easy terms, it cannot be said as yet that the
Spanish housing co-operatives constitute a genuine national movement,
even though the trend in this direction is quickening. In the past, and
even in recent years, housing co-operatives have each acted independently
and have tackled their technical and financial problems entirely on their
own, without any national organisation to supply them with common
services, co-ordinate their work and resources or safeguard their interests.
It is true that there are associations of housing co-operatives which are
known as " area unions " and comprise the societies in each district or
province. These unions do supply them with certain common services,
but it would appear that, being formed compulsorily, they do not meet
the wishes of the co-operatives themselves and merely increase their
awareness of the need to belong to a national federated body.
In addition to these area co-operative organisations, there are a
number of bodies which have responsibilities under the Act of 2 January
1942 in thefieldof co-operation. In descending order, these bodies make
up what might be called the legal framework of the whole Spanish cooperative movement, viz. : the Ministry of Labour, the National Trade
Union Organisation, the Central Co-operative Council, and the Trade
Union Co-operative Department.
The functions assigned by the Act to these bodies as regards cooperatives are as follows. The Ministry of Labour supervises the cooperative movement through the registration and inspection of societies.
The National Trade Union Delegate is responsible for the guidance
and general policy of the Trade Union Co-operative Department and
for supervising its social welfare activities. The main task of the Central
Co-operative Council is to advise the Trade Union Co-operative Department on its function of giving encouragement, guidance and technical
aid to co-operatives, especially as regards the interpretation of the relevant legislation and relations between different types of co-operatives.
The Trade Union Co-operative Department supplies guidance and advice
to co-operatives, supervises their operation and safeguards the general
interests of the co-operative movement against third parties and even,
if necessary, against the State.
At the present time the Spanish Cortes has before it a new Bill on
co-operatives which relaxes controls over their internal organisation
and regional and national federations. The co-operative movement is

88

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

waiting for this measure to be passed in order to set up its own nationwide organisation.
To sum up, Spanish co-operatives have, by and large, followed the
traditional practice of confining themselves to building homes to meet
the needs of their members. Once built, ownership of the homes has
been transferred to the individual occupiers, and the societies have then
been wound up or have limited their activities to providing a few communal services for their members or simply managing the housing estates.
Nevertheless, the new Bill on co-operatives defines housing co-operatives
as bodies " established with the aim of providing housing and ancillary
buildings for their members under any legal system of construction,
acquisition or method of use " and adds that " such co-operatives may
include among their activities the maintenance and management of
communal facilities and the provision of services for the purpose of
community development and may be established solely for that purpose ".1
This approach was welcomed by the National Co-operative Assembly
and suggests that the Spanish co-operatives are now interested in expanding the scope of their housing movement by introducing systems other
than the traditional practice of building homes exclusively for individual
ownership by their members.
It should also be noted that the Spanish co-operative movement has
assisted the Government in tackling the housing shortage not only
through societies formed to enable their members to acquire homes, but
also through another type of co-operative undertaking, the industrial
building co-operative, consisting of workers from various building trades.
Some are labour co-operatives which concentrate on building houses,
especially for other co-operatives or non-profit housing associations,
while others are societies made up of workers with special skills in the
production of particular types of building materials. According to figures
supplied by the Spanish Trade Union Organisation, 65 industrial cooperatives were in operation in Spain in July 1962.
There are also other specialised types of co-operatives, such as consumer and credit societies which help to alleviate the housing shortage
by carrying out their own building programmes for their members.
FINANCING

Usually co-operative housing schemes in Spain are financed out of
contributions by the co-operative and the State, supplemented by loans
1
See José Luis del ARCO ALVAREZ: Bases del futuro ordenamiento jurídico y régimen fiscal de las cooperativas (Madrid, Asamblea Nacional de Cooperativas, 1961),
p. 24.

SPAIN

89

from other institutions. To start with, the co-operative carrying out the
project contributes a cash sum of not less than 10 per cent, of the total
cost of the scheme. Thereupon the National Housing Institute (subject
to the Ministry of Housing) grants an interest-free loan based on the
area of the site; this loan usually covers between 33 and 75 per cent, of
the total cost. Additional loans are then secured from bodies such as the
National Credit Institute for National Reconstruction, the Marine
Welfare Institute, the Mortgage Bank, the workers' mutual benefit
societies, and the savings funds. These institutions grant loans which are
repayable over a period of anything from 10 to 50 years and cover the
remainder of the cost of the scheme. In the case of subsidised housing,
the Government also makes a grant of 30,000 pesetas per dwelling over
and above the foregoing loans based on the site area.
Each member is required to make a down payment in respect of his
own home, and a monthly repayment (usually very low) of the supplementary loans. This charge also covers allocations to the reserve
fund, the contingency charge, common administrative costs and welfare
expenses. In theory this down payment should be made out of members'
own savings, but almost all the co-operatives—which, as was explained
earlier, are independent of one another—have special arrangements to
help their members to find the money for this initial outlay.
The practical and convenient way in which the financial plans of the
Spanish co-operatives work can best be appreciated from a few actual
cases of housing co-operatives in different parts of the country:
" Virgen del Carmen " Co-operative at Sanlúcar de Barrameda, Cadiz
The " Virgen del Carmen " Co-operative was founded in October 1960
and began to build in August 1961. Its first scheme comprises 322 homes
forming part of a subsidised housing programme and containing three types
of dwelling as follows:
First Type.
Three bedrooms, living-dining room, kitchen, toilet and drying room.
The buildings consist of four-storey blocks of flats with shops on the ground
floor and balconies in front. Behind, a large area amounting to 4,000 m2 has
been set aside for schools, gardens and other communal facilities. The flats
include a few with four bedrooms for large families.
Second Type.
These have a floor space of 47 m2, together with a courtyard at the back.
They consist of three bedrooms, living-dining room, kitchen and toilet.
Third Type.
Basically these flats also consist of three bedrooms, living-dining room,
kitchen and toilet. They are built, however, in groups of four, with two on the
ground floor and two above, but each with its own independent entrance and
private garden in front.

90

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

The contributions (in pesetas) required of members for these three types
are as follows:
Down payment

First type

Monthly contribution

4,000

100

Second type

. . . .

21,500

300

Third type

. . . .

45,000

375

" Viviendas para Todos " Co-operative, Murcia
The system of financing applied by the " Viviendas para Todos " Cooperative serves as a good example of the methods used in rural areas.
Out of a total building cost of 52,000 pesetas, members pay 22,000 pesetas
in three contributions (3,000, 4,000 and 15,000 pesetas respectively) and the
Ministry of Housing provides a subsidy of 30,000 pesetas.
Cooperativa Central del Ahorro Popular
The Cooperativa Central del Ahorro Popular is a loan society in Madrid
which decided to finance a house-building programme for its members. It
contracted out the building of the estate (4,500 homes) to a non-profit concern.
As a result of a poll among future residents, three types of homes were built—
two with two bedrooms and one with three. All have living-dining rooms,
kitchens, bathrooms and terraces.
The homes are financed as follows:
First type

Second type

(two bedrooms)

Third type
(three bedrooms)

Pesetas

16,480.00

19,480.00

20,720.00

784.09

841.07

969.74

101.23
30,000.00

102.05
30.000.00

117.66
30,000.00

Monthly contribution by
member during first five
Monthly contribution for
next 25 years
Government subsidy . .

The sources of members' initial contributions included the following:
28 per cent, from their own savings; 34 per cent, from ten-year 3 percent, loans
from a workers' mutual benefit society; 9 percent, advanced by their employers
for varying periods without interest; 23 per cent, in the form of loans from the
co-operative society for periods ranging from one to five years (depending on
members' financial circumstances) and bearing a rate of interest of 5 per cent.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

Although Spanish housing co-operatives do not as yet constitute a
genuine national movement with common technical services and the
financial resources to open its own components factories so as to cut

SPAIN

91

costs through standardisation and greater volume, the movement is
nevertheless playing a leading part in the national drive to build cheaper
housing for the lower income groups. This is all the more important
because of the rapid rate of population growth in Spain and the generally
low level of workers' wages, which means that they could not otherwise
hope to afford adequate accommodation for their families.
Naturally the overriding task of the housing co-operatives has been
to help the middle and working classes to acquire properly designed
homes of their own, and the achievements of the co-operative housing
movement have been in those parts of the country that are most thickly
populated and heavily industrialised. But they have gone further. Not
only are they laying out estates, building schools and parks for the children of members and setting up consumer co-operatives for residents,
but they are also fostering a new type of community in which neighbours
can get to know one another better by working together as members of
the same society.

e

PART IV
NORTH AMERICA

CHAPTER IX
CANADA
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The co-operative housing movement in Canada is a recent development, the first attempts dating from the end of 1936. Since that first
experiment co-operative house-building groups have increased considerably in numbers, particularly in certain provinces, but it could
not be said that this form of co-operation has so far played a really
outstanding role. Nevertheless, the successful experiments which have

been made in various parts of the country, and in particular the special
characteristics which mark co-operative housing in Canada, merit
careful study, since they have worth-while and positive features which
could be turned to advantage by developing countries in their efforts to
solve their housing problems.
The provinces in which this type of co-operative has thrived and has
played a significant part in the national campaign to provide people
with their own homes are Nova Scotia, Quebec, Ontario and Newfoundland.
It is interesting to note that the co-operative housing movement was
initiated by manual workers in the most unfavourable financial circumstances, with the encouragement and help of Catholic priests who
gave them spiritual guidance.
It all began in a small mining town, Reserve Mines, in Nova Scotia, a
province which has gained international renown in the co-operative
world for its great achievements in the field of co-operation, backed by
the St. Francis Xavier University in Antigonish. The idea was born in the
autumn of 1936, when ten miners in Reserve Mines formed a study club
to see what could be done to provide decent housing for their families
within their limited resources. This initiative led to the foundation
of a co-operative which built a new community, completed early in
1939, which was given the name of Tompkinsville in honour of the
Rev. J. J. Tompkins of the Extension Department of St. Francis
Xavier University, who was the guiding spirit of the project. Following the success of this first attempt at co-operative housing the idea

96

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

spread rapidly throughout the area. By 1959 there were already 86
co-operatives of this type in normal operation and obtaining very
satisfactory results.1
Independently of these achievements in Nova Scotia, a new co-operative movement of the same type was founded in the province of Quebec
in 1942. This also had its beginnings in a small mining town, Asbestos,
and spread rapidly throughout the province. The table below, which is
based on the 50 replies to a questionnaire sent to the 90 co-operatives
existing in 1950, illustrates the expansion of housing co-operatives in the
province of Quebec during the seven years immediately following the
foundation of the first co-operative in Asbestos.

Year

Number of
co-operatives founded

Membership

1943
1944
1945
1946
1947
1948
1949

2
6
4
2
4
20
12

131
508
267
238
590
1,813
475

Total . . .

50

4,022

Source : Ensemble (Quebec, Central Council for Co-operation and Canadian Council for Co-operation), June-July 1950, pp. 14-15.

According to the inquiry carried out by Ensemble, of the 50 cooperatives which replied 39 were actually engaged in construction during
this period. The table on the following page shows the considerable
increase in the number of societies engaged in building operations and
the number of houses built. To appreciate these figures it should be borne
in mind that in Canada, as a general rule, housing co-operatives do not
begin building immediately they are founded, but only after a period of
study and accumulation of funds which may last as long as two years.
Particularly in the early days of the movement a co-operative founded to
build houses for a specific group of families would suspend building
activities after completing that task.
In Ontario the original inspiration, co-ordination of activities and
technical assistance which brought co-operative housing into existence
came from the Institute of Social Action of St. Patrick's College in
Ottawa.
1

CO-OPERATIVE UNION OF CANADA: Co-operative Housing in Canada (Ottawa,

Nov. 1959; mimeographed), p. 2.

97

CANADA

Year

Co-operatives engaged in
building during the year

1943
1944
1945
1946
1947
1948
1949

0
5
9
8
9
14
37

Total . . .

Houses
constructed

0
34
65
45
65
288
704
1,201

Source : See previous table.

A team of experts from the Institute investigated the housing problem
and came to the conclusion that the co-operative system should be tried
as one possible solution. Not wishing to confine itself to mere theorising,
the Institute sponsored a pilot project in which a co-operative was
founded and, after nine months' study and saving, began to build homes
for its members in June 1953, in the western suburbs of Ottawa, under
the name of the Marrocco Home Building Co-operative Society. This
name was chosen in honour of Father Marrocco, who was the prime
mover behind the Institute's efforts to find a solution to the housing
problem. The satisfactory results achieved in this first experiment led to
the foundation of similar associations in different parts of the province
in the next few years. By 1960, in a matter of seven years, the number had
already reached 45.1
In Newfoundland the first step was the founding of the Humber
Housing Co-operative Society in 1944, which began to construct houses
for its members the next year. But this type of co-operation, which has
made a profound impact on the housing campaign of this province, did
not really begin to boom until 1950. The main factor to which the
expansion of housing co-operatives in this part of the country can be
attributed seems to have been Newfoundland's union with Canada
in 1949 2, which enabled it to take advantage of the financial facilities
offered under national legislation for the construction of new homes.
Profiting from the experience of the Humber Housing Co-operative
Society, up to 31 July 1960 a total of 36 new housing co-operatives had
been established in Newfoundland, and had already built several hundred
comfortable and up-to-date houses.
1

See INSTITUTE OF SOCIAL ACTION (St. Patrick's College): Guide to

Co-operative

Housing, edited by Gerald E. CLARKE (Ottawa, second edition, 1960), p. 95.
2
GOVERNMENT OF NEWFOUNDLAND : Co-operative Housing ; Origin and Outline of
Present Plan (1961; mimeographed), p. 1.

98

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
ORGANISATION

The organisation of Canadian co-operative housing does not follow a
uniform pattern; it has entirely distinct methods and features in Nova
Scotia, Quebec and Ontario, for example.
Nova Scotia
The pattern of co-operation in Nova Scotia continues to stem from
discussion in the study groups organised by the Extension Department
of St. Francis Xavier University. Each co-operative thus set up by
such a group is a small unit which constructs houses for its members,
generally numbering between 10 and 14. All members are required to
work personally on the project for at least four hours a day. The group
of members is really a team of workers under the leadership of a foreman
chosen by the members from among themselves. In each co-operative
project construction of all the houses goes at the same pace. For certain
specialised jobs skilled workers are hired if they are not to be found
within the group. As a general rule, the time taken by these co-operatives
to complete their houses varies from 14 to 18 months. Each co-operative
handles the entire financing of the project through the Nova Scotia
Housing Commission, and retains collective ownership of the homes
until the mortgage loan has been paid off in full. Each member is allowed
shares in the co-operative worth $1,500 in return for his labour on the
project. Additional shares are usually issued for improvements made by a
member to his home. If a member wishes to withdraw from his association he must give notice to this effect, whereupon the co-operative
will select a new member in accordance with its by-laws. It is generally
recommended by the co-operatives that each member should have an
insurance policy in an amount sufficient to cover his mortgage so as to
safeguard his family in the event of his death before the loan is paid off
in full.1
Quebec
The beginnings of co-operative housing in Quebec were very similar
to those of the movement in Nova Scotia, though without the guidance,
co-ordination and assistance of a body such as St. Francis Xavier University in Antigonish. Small groups were formed which, after studying
the problems of construction for some time, set to work to build their
houses, limiting the project to satisfying the needs of the members of
1
See Joe LABEN: Co-operative Housing Manual (Antigonish, Extension Department, St. Francis Xavier University, 1958), p. 37.

CANADA

99

the association. In this way small co-operative units of 20, 30 or 40
members mushroomed all over the province, particularly between 1946
and 1950. This meant that there were often four, six or seven different
co-operatives in one town. During this period various methods of construction were tried out and there is no doubt that the results, on the
whole, were satisfactory, although quite a number of these groups had
to suspend their activities after building only a few houses. These
attempts at co-operation, independent and scattered, brought home the
fact that if the co-operative system was to make a really significant contribution towards solving the housing problem in Quebec the societies
would have to use new methods and adopt some of the operational processes employed by the large building firms. That was how the Drummondville co-operative was born.
The purpose of the Drummondville co-operative was not exclusively
to satisfy the housing needs of the restricted group of its founder members
but to open its doors to all families who wanted a home of their own and
preferred the co-operative system, and its foundation marked the
beginning of a new era in the history of co-operative housing in Quebec.
Following in the footsteps of the Drummondville co-operative there
was founded shortly afterwards the Coopérative d'Habitation de Montréal, which started off by tackling the task of building 400 homes and
equipping its own workshops.
The city of Quebec did not lag behind, and the scattered co-operative
groups operating in the metropolitan area were amalgamated into the
Coopérative d'Habitation du Québec Métropolitain, which set up its
own subsidiary construction enterprises and began to build at the rate
of 100 to 125 homes a year.
The example set by the big cities was followed elsewhere, although
the smaller towns and villages could not profit from the concentration
of effort and resources which was producing such good results in the
large centres. So a step forward was taken in the organisation of cooperative housing in the province with the founding of the Fédération de
Coopératives d'Habitation, which was able to co-ordinate the activities
of the small co-operatives and give them any technical assistance they
needed, as well as the benefit of the experience acquired by the societies
operating in the large centres.1
According to its by-laws, the general aim of the Fédération des
Coopératives d'Habitation is to make known the great social advantage
that a family can derive from persuading its members to co-operate
1

Albert CÔTÉ : " Les coopératives d'habitation dans les grandes et moyennes villes ",
in Ensemble (Quebec, Central Council for Co-operation and Canadian Council for
Co-operation), No. 16, 21 Oct. 1959.

100

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

in the campaign for the safeguarding of family financial and social
interests, and, most important of all, to make it easier for the members of
its affiliated co-operatives to acquire homes of their own with decent
standards of comfort and hygiene.
The main functions of this federation, the headquarters of which are
in Montreal, are as follows :
(a) to study and propagate co-operative principles and methods, particularly as concerns housing;
(b) to advise its affiliated societies on legal and technical as well as
co-operative matters;
(c) to supervise, through its inspectors, all the activities of its member
co-operatives and approve their construction programmes and their
accounts ;
(d) to present a united front in defence of their interests against third
parties, including the public authorities, where this proves to be
necessary;
(e) to buy, sell, hire, store or manufacture such building materials or
equipment as are needed, and provide rechnical services requested by
affiliated co-operatives.

Ontario
Co-operative housing in Ontario is based on the " St. Patrick's
Plan ", being guided, co-ordinated and assisted by the Institute of Social
Action of St. Patrick's College.
The St. Patrick's Plan, like the Antigonish movement, maintains that
in co-operatives—particularly housing co-operatives—the education of
the members should come before construction. Hence in this province,
as in Nova Scotia, the study club is the nucleus of the housing co-operative. In Ontario, however, these study clubs are generally larger than
those in Nova Scotia, each group consisting of from 20 to 40 families.
Furthermore, each study group does not necessarily form a co-operative
of its own, since it frequently happens that all the families interested in
solving their housing problem by co-operative means in a given town
organise themselves into separate study groups and later link up into one
single co-operative enterprise in order to make the most of the concentration of effort and resources.
The programme for the housing co-operatives following the St.
Patrick's Plan consists of three phases: education, organisation, and
construction.

CANADA

101

Education.
The first step is to endeavour to instil the true co-operative spirit
into the future members, acquainting them with co-operative principles,
methods and practices. Then they must study in broad outline relevant
legislation and the various aspects of the venture on which they are
preparing to embark, such as sites, finance, house plans, materials and
labour. To carry out these studies more efficiently and give people a
chance to specialise, the members of each group are divided up into
special committees each dealing specifically with one of the major aspects
of the housing problem mentioned above. Finally, the future members
have an opportunity in these study clubs to familiarise themselves with
building terminology and acquire the rudiments of the trade in order
to equip themselves for the work they must do later.
Organisation.
This is the time for decisions. The group, already well informed as
to the problems it will have to cope with and the best methods to adopt,
applies for legal incorporation as a co-operative and takes its decisions
as to the most suitable sites on which to build, the type of housing to be
erected, the kind of materials to be employed, the financial plan to be
followed, the personal contribution to be made by members and the date
on which construction is to begin.
Construction.
Here, as in Nova Scotia, it is the custom in the co-operatives following
the St. Patrick's Plan for each member to contribute his own labour to
the building work. In each group members can generally be found with
different skills or trades, so that each can be given work adapted to his
capabilities. Every member is required, however, to work a minimum number of hours. In view of the need to divide up the work, some are given responsibility for the direction and administration of the project while others
work as labourers, but of course all enjoy equal membership rights and
privileges. The individual tasks to be performed are allocated in advance,
each member being generally called upon to spend from 20 to 25 hours a
week working on the project. A member who is unable to work the minimum number of hours required of him must pay cash compensation for
the hours he has not worked in accordance with the internal rules.
As regards the technical supervision of the project, if there is nobody
within the group sufficiently competent and familiar with all the aspects
and problems of the building industry a fully qualified building superintendent must be hired. Skilled workers are also taken on as and when
needed to supplement members' personal labour.

102

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

New Trends
At the present time the following trends are noted in co-operative
housing in Canada, with particular reference to the province of Quebec.
Desire for Continuity.
One great step forward as compared with the past, when nearly all
co-operatives were wound up on completion of the building project for
which they had been created, is the new trend in recent years towards
maintaining the co-operative in existence after construction is completed
and the mortgages paid off. The effect of this trend is that co-operatives
can continue to function by providing specific services for the communities they have created, and this, in addition, opens up possibilities of
attracting new members and embarking on new building projects.
Preference for

Amalgamation.

The tendency now is to found societies larger than the early associations, or to merge existing small scattered groups into medium-sized
units, the reason being that these co-operative enterprises are then in a
position to compete in the building industry at least on equal terms, thus
ensuring the best facilities for their members.
Introduction of Collective Ownership.
In an attempt to make a fresh contribution towards solving the
housing problem, co-operatives have begun to try out the system of
collective ownership, whereby the society retains the ownership of the
buildings it constructs, allocating dwellings to its members for indefinite
occupancy so long as they comply with the rules. The introduction of this
system, which is a common feature of co-operative housing in Europe,
particularly in the Scandinavian countries, was fully debated at the Cooperative Housing Congress held in Quebec in May 1959. It was stressed
on that occasion that the mass construction of groups of large blocks for
these co-operative communities could be helpful in cutting down production costs, as well as bringing decent homes of their own within the
reach of the mass of the people.
FINANCING

Generally speaking, the Canadian co-operative movement has grown
and prospered without having to seek special financial assistance from
the public authorities. The housing co-operatives have also endeavoured,
as far as possible, to find the funds for their own programmes within the

CANADA

103

movement itself without seeking credit from outside. An example of their
efforts is the project successfully completed in 1959 by a housing cooperative in the township of South Nelson, New Brunswick. This cooperative financed and constructed a group of ten houses of modern
style and standards of comfort, at a cost 27 per cent, below the average
for the area, without seeking help from any body or agency outside the
co-operative movement. The initial loan came from the local credit
union, the mortgage was arranged by a life assurance co-operative, and
the purchase of materials at wholesale prices was made through the
regional consumer co-operatives' federation.1 But this experiment was
only possible because the project was a small one. If the Canadian cooperatives were to decide to build only such houses as it was possible for
them to finance out of the still limited resources of the national co-operative system, the pace of construction could not be other than very slow,
and their contribution towards the solution of so important a problem
would be insignificant. Therefore, Canadian housing co-operatives, in
addition to drawing on funds available in other co-operative bodies, have
not hesitated to apply for assistance from the authorities under both
national and provincial schemes, and particularly on a long-term basis,
in order to provide the finance for projects whose cost goes far beyond
members' modest resources.
In Nova Scotia co-operatives have always been able to finance their
building operations under arrangements laid down in the province's
legislation on the subject. These make it possible for the Nova Scotia
Housing Commission, the agency responsible for implementing the
province's housing policy, to grant loans equivalent to 75 per cent, of
the estimated value of the houses, repayable over a 25-year period at an
interest rate of 3]/2 per cent, of the balance outstanding.2 Having
obtained such a loan, the member is then left to provide the remaining
25 per cent., which can take the form either of land on which to build
or of personal labour during construction. In this way, with the help of
an additional loan from the local credit co-operative, members have been
able to buy the sites for their homes and take part in the co-operative
programme.
From data covering the first ten years of co-operative building
activity in this province it can be seen that, thanks to the purchase of
materials at wholesale prices and effective team work, it was possible to
build houses worth $6,000 on the commercial market for between $3,500
and $4,000. The monthly payments which members had to make in order
to pay off the mortgage averaged $30, inclusive of interest and taxes.
1

CO-OPERATIVE UNION OF CANADA: Co-operative Housing in Canada, op. cit., p . 3.

2

LABEN: op. cit., p. 8.

104

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

In 1954 the Canadian Parliament approved a new national housing
policy, making it possible to finance building operations with a single
mortgage. To encourage finance houses to grant such mortgages the
State guarantees repayment of the loan through a special form of
insurance. Under this new policy members of co-operatives are required
to put down only 5 per cent, of the cost of their houses, in the form
of either cash or land. 1
Under the 1954 legislation advances may be made on a mortgage
loan while construction is in progress, but 20 per cent, is always held in
reserve to provide against any liens registered by third parties and is not
paid over until approximately one month after construction is completed.
The result of this lien holdback is thai co-operatives must arrange
additional interim financing for the equivalent of this 20 per cent. By
furnishing short-term credit for this purpose the Canadian co-operative
credit unions have played a very significant role in bringing homes to
the masses.
With perhaps the sole exception of the people's funds in Quebec,
co-operative credit unions in Canada do not yet appear to be sufficiently
strong to take on long-term mortgage lending, but as far as short-term
loans are concerned they have furnished and are continuing to furnish
valuable collaboration in the financing of co-operative housing programmes. Co-operative insurance companies have also begun to collaborate in these financial arrangements.
To help members to collect the down payment, and at the same time
stimulate their interest in the project, co-operatives generally organise
their own savings scheme right from the time a study group is formed. In
the province of Newfoundland, for example, each member is required from
the beginning to deposit monthly savings of $20. This savings programme
is carried through until the homes have been completed or until each
member has saved approximately $500. This amount together with the
labour contributed by a member represents the required down payment.2
Furthermore, the accumulated savings of members enable a co-operative to take the first steps towards the realisation of the project and can be
drawn on to meet expenses which cannot properly be classified as building
costs but are rather indirect costs which have to be met, as for instance in
respect of building permits, incorporation as a co-operative, other legal
matters, fire insurance, mortgage applications, plans, the purchase of
equipment or interest on short-term loans.
'INSTITUTE OF SOCIAL ACTION (St. Patrick's College): Guide to Co-operative

Housing, op. cit., pp. 26 ff.
2
GOVERNMENT OF NEWFOUNDLAND: Co-operative Housing ; Origin and Outline of
Present Plan, op. cit., p. 6.

CANADA

105

In 1955 the Co-operative Housing Federation of the province of
Quebec launched a workers' housing programme which usefully illustrates how Canadian co-operatives have encouraged the participation of
workers with slender financial resources by making it easier for them to
provide their financial contribution. In order to carry out this programme the workers were grouped into sections of 300 members, each
member being asked to make an initial deposit of $100 and a weekly
contribution of $2 until he took possession of his new home. He would
then have to pay only $48 monthly for 20 years to cover mortgage
repayments, insurance and taxes. The Federation obtained the necessary
funds through a million-dollar loan extended by the Société des Artisans
de Montréal. The type of house selected for this project contains three
bedrooms, living room, kitchen-dining room and bathroom, the floor
space measuring 50 by 84 feet.

SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

Although great progress has been made, especially in the last 14 y ears
towards solving the housing problem, there is no doubt that the problem
still exists and gives cause for concern to the public authorities and to
national opinion. At the end of the Second World War it was estimated

that at least 700,000 homes would have to be built if the housing needs
of the population were to be adequately met. This situation has been
aggravated not only by immigration but also by a considerable rise in the
population and by the high proportion of rural dwellers who have gone
into the towns, so that the industrial centres become more and more
overcrowded and decent housing for workers and their families becomes
increasingly scarce.
Faced with this problem the co-operative movement, which has made
use of its own organisational structure to satisfy the country's needs in
other fields such as agriculture, credit or consumption, has once again
tried to play its part by promoting the construction of housing for the
people. However, co-operative housing in Canada has not yet reached
the same stage of development as other sectors of the national co-operative movement. Taking not just three or four particular provinces but
the country as a whole, bearing in mind the extent of the housing problem
in the entire national territory and noting the size of the Canadian
building industry, it must be agreed that the contribution made by
co-operative housing on a national scale is still very modest.
On the other hand, what has been done, mainly in the provinces of
Nova Scotia, Quebec, Ontario and Newfoundland, means that co-operative housing is to be recommended as a method of assisting low-income

106

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

families to acquire decent accommodation. The various successful
experiments show that co-operatives have been able to help their members
to buy land on better terms ; to eliminate a whole series of middlemen
in the purchase of building materials; to obtain the necessary financial
backing more easily; to create a spirit of collaboration and mutual aid
among future neighbours; and considerably to reduce building costs
through the mass production of materials, through working on a number
of buildings at the same time, and through the personal effort put in by
the prospective home owners. Even the partial setbacks met with in the
early days by small co-operative groups in some parts of the country have
helped subsequent co-operative enterprises to profit from such experience,
and to organise on sounder lines.
Other provinces have shown great interest in the co-operative system
as a means of solving the housing problem, and, in response to this
interest, literature has been published and courses, seminars and conferences organised. There is also another important factor which has to
be borne in mind when reviewing the prospects of co-operative housing
in Canada : as the Co-operative Union of Canada noted in a document
on the subject in 1959, it is the rural population which is the most familiar
with co-operative principles, methods and practices and whose societies
are well organised in the agricultural areas, and hence the hundreds of
thousands who in the past few years have migrated and continue to
migrate to the cities give evidence of being anxious to continue to enjoy
the benefits of co-operation as a means of satisfying their needs, one of
the most important of which is accommodation in which they can settle
in decent conditions near the industrial centres where they have chosen
to work.1
In this way the social impact of Canadian co-operative housing is
growing every day, since today it no longer consists solely of scattered
societies but is an organised movement; nor does it confine itself to
small undertakings, but tackles large projects such as the one initiated
in 1961 in the suburbs of Winnipeg, in the province of Manitoba, to
provide housing for 4,300 families. With regard to this endeavour the
Urban Renewal Board told Winnipeg City Council that the project
provided the cheapest method by private enterprise to give low-cost
housing on a major scale in that city.2

1

CO-OPERATIVE UNION OF CANADA: Co-operative Housing in Canada, op. cit.,

pp. 4-5.
2
" Co-op Housing Project Set Up for Winnipeg ", in The Manitoba Co-operator
(Winnipeg, Manitoba Pool Elevators), 2 Feb. 1961.

CHAPTER X

UNITED STATES
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

In so highly industrialised an economy as the United States, the
co-operative movement might well appear to be of minor importance
as compared with other sectors. None the less, the co-operatives are a
lively and powerful force, and, though overshadowed by other branches
of the American economy, their achievements have placed them in the
forefront of the co-operative movements of the world.
Co-operative housing does not date back very far in the United
States. Without detracting from the merits of some earlier more or less
sporadic experiments, its modern co-operative housing has evolved in
three distinct phases, beginning in 1926, 1950 and 1960 respectively.
As in other countries, the fathers of the movement were trade unionists. In the years immediately following the First World War, although
the country had not suffered any destruction, the virtual standstill of
activities in the building industry during the war years had considerably
aggravated the shortage of accommodation, particularly in the large
cities, and rents had steadily risen. A group of workers belonging to a
New York trade union, the Amalgamated Clothing Workers, decided
to turn to co-operative methods. At first it seemed as though their
venture was an unattainable dream, since they were simple labourers who
belonged to a credit union operating within their trade union but had
no resources of their own other than their wages to cover their needs
and those of their families. Moreover, the economic situation during
those early post-war years did not make it any easier to tackle such a
mammoth task without personal capital. However, having complied
with the legal requirements, and after three years of struggle, a housing
co-operative was founded as the result of this initiative. Backed in the
main by the direct or indirect financial assistance of the trade union,
it began to build in November 1926, and only a year later 303 families
were already occupying new homes built under this first co-operative
project.

108

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

The success of this enterprise caught the attention of the public. Not
only had homes been provided for several hundred families, but the results
achieved by this first co-operative project showed that it had been possible to reduce building costs appreciably, while ensuring that each
dwelling was comfortable, modern and equipped with full sanitary
facilities. Furthermore, this co-operative estate in the centre of New
York signified the creation of a new non-profit community with its
own shops, day nurseries, recreation rooms and assembly hall, library
and transport facilities. As the papers said at the time, this experiment
was the starting point of a new era in the solution of the housing problem.
This first experiment in co-operative housing was followed by a
number of others, particularly in New York. It was not, however, until
after the Second World War that the co-operative system became really
widespread, particularly in New York City, as a method of dealing with
the housing problem.
The second phase—expansion on a nation-wide scale—began in 1950
when Congress amplified and amended federal housing policy, laying
the legal foundations which have since then facilitated thefinancingof
co-operative building all over the country.
Not all the societies which were founded at that time, however, were
true co-operatives from either the economic or the social point of view.
In some cases families needing accommodation readily allowed themse ves to be organised into so-called co-operatives on the initiative of
builders who saw the co-operative structure purely as a means of obtaining the benefit of the legislative amendments favouring this type of society.
Thus a number of co-operatives were born whose members had not been
trained in the true spirit of co-operation and did not know what their
obligations and responsibilities as co-operative owners entailed.1 Even
those societies, however, accomplished a social mission by at least
enabling many families to acquire decent accommodation.
The pace at which co-operative housing spread during this second
phase may be assessed from the fact that 45,000 new co-operative
dwellings were constructed in the eight years following the legislative
reform of 1950 under the federal programme of financial aid to nonprofit housing alone.3
| | | T h e development of co-operative housing during this period brought
the need for a national co-operative body to unite the movement, coordinate its activities, give technical assistance to existing co-operatives
and encourage the setting up of new ones.
1

Jerry VOORHIS : American Cooperatives (New York, Harper & Brothers, 1961 ), p. 49.

2

INTERNATIONAL HOUSING SERVICE, Housing and Home Finance Agency: Co-

operative Housing in the United States (Washington, D.C., 1958), p. 8.

UNITED STATES

109

However, although all the societies were in agreement on the need
to get together to form a central body, divergences of opinion among the
existing co-operatives led during this second phase to the forming, not
of one, but of three groups.
The first group, which grew out of the co-operative founded in 1926
by the workers of the Amalgamated Clothing Workers' Union and the
societies established shortly afterwards as a result of this experiment in
various districts of New York, formed a body known as the United
Housing Foundation. A feature of this group was its burning desire to
preserve the purity of the co-operative principles and methods tried and
tested with satisfactory results in its own projects. Other powerful trade
unions such as the International Ladies' Garment Workers supported
this group.
The second group was formed not only with the backing of a number
of religious and educational institutions but with the financial assistance
of the credit unions in the city and state of New York. It founded a new
agency under the name of the Middle Income Housing Corporation.
A third group, sponsored primarily by insurance companies with
a co-operative outlook, set up the Foundation for Cooperative
Housing. This body also established its headquarters in New York City,
but devoted itself in particular to promoting the formation of housing
co-operatives throughout the country. Although the Foundation for
Cooperative Housing did a most worth-while job assisting co-operative
projects in a vast sphere of action, it has been reproached for not
placing enough emphasis on the true co-operative spirit among member
families.1
Faced with this situation where the co-operative housing movement
had great possibilities opening up before it but was divided into three
independent groups, the Cooperative League, which is a national
organisation whose activities are primarily directed towards welfare
and education, and may be said, broadly speaking, to represent the
country's co-operative movement as a whole, endeavoured to unite the
housing co-operatives in a single plan of action. With this aim in view it
convened the first national conference on co-operative housing in Washington in 1958.
The Cooperative League finally succeeded in reconciling the divergent views and created a new superstructure, the National Association
of Housing Cooperatives. The founding of this body in May 1960
marked the beginning of the third phase in the development of cooperative housing in the United States.
1

See VOORHIS: op. cit., p.

48.

110

HOUSING COOPERATIVES
ORGANISATION

As regards the legal framework within which co-operatives operate
in the United States, there is no uniformity. Generally speaking, in the
absence of any federal legislation on the subject, the early co-operatives
adopted the legal forms most in keeping with their own individual
characteristics according to the legislation of the different states. In
some states housing co-operatives were organised along the Unes laid
down by legislation governing consumer co-operatives if such provisions
were broad enough to cover co-operative enterprises for the construction
and administration of dwellings. In other states co-operatives have
operated under laws concerning the construction of low-rent housing or
slum clearance in the large cities.
As regards the actual way in which they are formed, while some cooperatives have been founded as the outcome of discussions among the
people with a housing problem to solve, it is far more frequent for the
first move to come from some public or private institution which is
interested in this field and decides either directly or indirectly to sponsor
a project. The creation of Rochdale Village on Long Island, New York
provides a typical illustration.1 Early in 1960 the United Housing
Foundation decided to embark upon a new co-operative housing project,
to be named Rochdale Village in honour of the fathers of the co-operative
movement, and designed for families in need of homes who were ready
to join a new community in a particular part of New York City. The
scheme was announced by the Governor of the state, who gave an
approximate idea of the plans for financing it, and hence of the initial
payment which members would be expected to make. Within 24 hours
of his announcement 2,000 applications for membership had already
been received. A programme was then started for the education of the
future residents in co-operative principles, and work began on what was
intended to be a new self-sufficient neighbourhood with a highly developed community spirit, made up of families who a short while before
had not even known one another.
There are two main types of housing co-operative in the United
States: (a) those acting as co-operatives only for one or two of the
phases involved in the process, such as the purchase and development of
land,financing,or the building of the houses; and (b) those which assume
full responsibility, where it is necessary to do so, for the purchase and
development of land, financing, construction, administration, and provision of additional amenities for the new community. As a general rule
societies of the first type allow members to become owners in their own
1

See VOORHIS: op. cit., p . 42.

UNITED STATES

111

right, while those of the second type retain ownership of the property
and grant their members privileged rights of tenure of the dwellings
allocated to them. It follows that co-operatives of the first type are
generally wound up on completion of the phase or phases for which the
form of a co-operative was adopted; co-operatives of the second type,
on the contrary, do not go into liquidation, and hence, after construction
is completed and the homes allocated, the members continue to be bound
together in a co-operative community with joint administration, services
and facilities.
In New York, which has been the nerve centre for this type of cooperation in the United States, the most noteworthy housing projects
undertaken have been groups of large blocks for the modernisation of
the older parts of the town. Following the demolition of slums, apartments with modern facilities are put up, and the new occupants form
co-operative communities. These projects fall into the second category
described above.
In addition a third type of co-operative has come into being. Buildings
financed and constructed by the Government, especially during the
Second World War, were then offered for sale to the occupants. Seizing
this opportunity, co-operative associations were set up which have come
to be known as mutual housing associations. The usual way in which
these societies are formed is as follows. Where residents in a project vote
for mutual ownership a corporation is formed which takes over the
operation of the project for a transitional period of two years, with an
option to purchase at the end of that time. If this association then
exercises its option, a purchase agreement is drawn up. In such cases,
the sale price having been fixed by joint appraisal by representatives of
the selling organisation and of the purchasing association, the latter
takes over ownership of the buildings and is given 45 years in which to
pay off the agreed price by regular monthly instalments including 3 per
cent, interest on the balance outstanding. The co-operative gives the
tenant-member a contract entitling him to perpetual use of the dwelling
allocated to him; he makes a monthly payment to the association covering
his share of the total purchase price. In order to provide a reserve
cushion from which the association can buy up the share paid by members
having to withdraw and can assist members over periods of hardship,
the members are expected to pay off their debt over a shorter period—
generally 30 years—and at a somewhat higher rate of interest than that
paid by the association.1 Although the residents in some of these projects
1

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, Bureau of Labor Statistics: Organiza-

tion and Management of Cooperative and Mutual Housing Associations (Washington,
D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office, 1946), p. 14.

112

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

who organised themselves along co-operative lines during the Second
World War were prevented for various reasons from drawing up a
purchase agreement, they none the less performed a satisfactory social
function by assuming responsibility for the administration of their
projects on behalf of the Federal Government.
Although it is not so frequent or so characteristic as in Canada
for members themselves to help to build their homes, this type of cooperative does none the less exist in the United States. An example is
the Penn-Craft Community experiment, sponsored by a private nonprofit body, the American Friends' Service Committee, and launched in
1937 for a group of industrial workers in a mining district. The aim of
the project was not only to provide housing but also to give members
greater financial security and a more pleasant social life. To facilitate
personal ownership the American Friends' Service Committee assumed
responsibility for surveying, technical services and installation, for the
management and supervision of the building operations and for the
financial arrangements. Each member was required to make a down
payment of S500, and the Committee arranged for a loan, repayable over
a 20-year period at an interest rate of only 2 per cent. This project consisted of individual houses each with its own garden. Members had to
promise to devote their spare time to working either on their own homes
or on those of their fellow members. Under the Penn-Craft Community
building programme, as soon as a member finished paying off his loan
he was granted ownership of his dwelling.
FINANCING

A feature of American housing co-operatives has been their tendency
to seek financial aid for building projects from private bodies in the first
instance. Families joining a co-operative are naturally required to
contribute individually towards the financing of their future homes, and
are encouraged to save towards the down payment. However, since
members' contributions can only go a small way towards what is needed
for the purchase of land and the construction of co-operative projects
as big as those which have been tackled, for instance, in New York City,
the co-operatives have to seek financial help from outside. The large
trade unions, particularly in New York, have played an important part
indirectly by procuring loans, offering the security of their own sponsorship of the project.
This early method of financing had satisfactory results in specific
instances, as evidenced by what was achieved in New York from 1926
onwards. But it placed a very heavy burden on the promoters of the

UNITED STATES

113

projects, especially in the early days when banks, insurance companies
and other sources of finance were not yet familiar with the technique and
characteristics of the co-operative system. In addition it was necessary
to explore the possibilities of financing on a nation-wide scale with a
view to promoting the founding of housing co-operatives all over the
country.
In 1939, in its desire to reduce building costs for the benefit of the
middle income group, and in particular for families in more modest
circumstances, New York became the first state to authorise the use of
public funds for loans, and to grant tax exemption, to non-profit organisations engaged in building operations, among which co-operatives already
occupied an important place.
But the deciding factor which provided fresh impetus for the country's co-operative housing movement was the institution of special
financial arrangements by the Federal Government in 1950. Congress
amended the Federal Housing Act to bring co-operatives into the federal
programme for the insurance of loans, thus making it much easier for
them to obtain credit, though still relying on private institutions as their
main source of funds.
Under this and subsequent amendments to the Housing Act, the
Federal Housing Administration (F.H.A.) insures mortgage loans
granted to housing co-operatives for up to 90 per cent, of the assessed
value of the property—or up to 95 per cent, if at least half the members
are war veterans. The repayment period covered by such insurance may
be as long as 40 years, this being the maximum period permitted by law.
According to official figures, during the first three years of operation of
this mortgage insurance scheme the F.H.A. had already guaranteed
$211 million worth of private loans granted for the financing of 22,625
co-operative dwellings.
An Act passed in 1956 served as a further spur to co-operative
housing. It allows sponsoring bodies to obtain loans for up to 85 per
cent, of the estimated building costs and start constructing even before
the actual society itself is formed.
In January 1958 the sphere of action of housing co-operatives was
widened still more when they were also granted permission to apply for
federal loan insurance under the slum-clearance programme.
Legislation in New York State already enabled housing co-operatives
to take advantage of the financial facilities offered to companies demolishing old buildings and constructing new blocks conforming to
prescribed standards. Under these provisions a number of co-operatives
were formed in New York City even before 1950, some of them being
financed, at least in part, by trade union pension funds. The land for

114

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

such projects is generally made available by the city authorities, which
prohibit the occupancy of buildings which do not satisfy public health
requirements. New construction work is financed through private
institutions, such as banks or insurance companies, the city authorities
granting the societies a 25-year exemption from the usual tax on new
buildings in order to bring down construction costs.
In the case of co-operative associations of the mutual home ownership
type, whose members are for the most part residents of Governmentbuilt estates and which have been formed in order to take over and
administer the buildings they occupy, financing is much simpler. A
member's down payment giving entitlement to a dwelling amounts to
only 5 per cent, of the cost of constructing that dwelling1, and the main
technical and financial problems which beset other types of co-operative
do not occur. In these cases it is another body (generally a federal
agency) which prepares the plans, finances the project and builds the
houses. For these reasons this type of co-operative has attracted much
interest from the workers' movement, which considers it to be a good
formula for enabling workers to acquire homes.
Associations in which members' personal labour is a fundamental
element, and it is therefore more difficult, as a general rule, to obtain
financial help from outside, frequently adopt the following system:
(1) they collect all the money that members have saved; (2) they construct
a limited number of dwellings to the extent that such savings allow;
(3) the first houses are mortgaged as soon as they are completed, and
the funds thus made available are used to begin the construction of a
fresh batch of dwellings, and so on.
Individual members joining a co-operative for the purpose of acquiring a home in a specific project are normally expected to pay an admission fee and make a down payment sufficient to cover at least part of
the initial building costs, as well as paying a monthly rental which goes
to pay off the loan and meet administrative and insurance expenses plus
some service charges.
The revenue from admission fees is used in the main to cover the
expenses of forming and incorporating the society. The fee is usually
quite low, varying between $50 and $100.
The down payment, generally made at the time when construction
begins, varies greatly according to the building costs involved in the
different projects, which may consist of individual houses or of large
blocks of flats for hundreds of families. In most cases it is equivalent
to 10 per cent, of the total cost of constructing the particular dwelling.
1

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR: Organization and Management

operative and Mutual Housing Associations, op. cit., p. 15.

of Co-

UNITED STATES

115

In assessing the cost of each dwelling unit account is taken of a variety
of factors including floor space, number of rooms and quality of materials
and labour.
The monthly rental to be paid once a member has moved into his
home also depends on a number of factors such as the sale price of the
dwelling, the length of time he has been given to pay off the loan, the
interest charged on the loan, the cost of insurance and the property tax
he is required to pay. In societies which deal with only one or two of the
phases of the co-operative housing process and are then dissolved, the
monthly payment is generally agreed on the basis of the individual
contract signed by the member and the financing agency which has
arranged the mortgage. In the case of housing co-operatives in the
proper sense of the term, the monthly payment is generally sufficient to
cover both administrative expenses and the cost of services supplied
through the society for the benefit of the community. The charges for
such services are agreed upon by a majority vote of the resident members
at the general meeting. In 1949 in the mutual home ownership corporations formed to acquire projects constructed by the Federal Government
the monthly payment which residents had to make ranged between
$31.41 and $70.54. In the other type of society, which deals with all the
phases of co-operative housing from the acquisition of the land to the
administration of the project and the organisation of communal services,
the monthly payment in New York City amounted to Î90 in 1949. This
type of co-operative society generally signs a collective contract for
certain services such as water, electricity and gas, which it then supplies
to residents, thereby considerably reducing the cost. For example the
Amalgamated Cooperative Apartments in New York arranged with the
Edison Company to have one central electric meter for the families on
its estate. The same co-operative arranged for bulk purchase of milk,
eggs and other basic commodities for sale to resident members at wholesale prices.
To make it easier for members to keep up the payments on their
homes co-operative housing promoters have spared no effort to stimulate
savings. A significant role has been played here by the credit unions,
which have special arrangements for the financing of house building.
In Michigan, for example, families interested in acquiring a home by
co-operative means first of all enrol in a savings scheme, which means
that the promoters of co-operative housing there are either the credit
unions themselves or their members.
The way in which housing co-operatives are financed in the United States
is illustrated by the experiment carried out in New York with Amalgamated
Cooperative Apartments, which has served as a model for societies subse-

116

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

quently formed. The initial funds to cover the cost of land and building,
amounting to 11,400,000, were obtained through prospective residents' down
payments and short-term loans arranged with private institutions. Members'
contributions totalled $479,000; $250,000 was lent by The Jewish Daily Forward; $172,000 came from a first bank mortgage on land already acquired,
and the rest also came in the form of a loan, from six subsidiary organisations
of the trade union which inspired and sponsored the project, the Amalgamated
Clothing Workers' Union, which also guaranteed these loans on behalf of
the co-operative. When construction was completed the Metropolitan Life
Insurance Company arranged a mortgage which covered the total cost of
construction, thus making it possible to pay off the short-term loans which
had provided the original funds for the project.
Once this preliminary stage offinancingwas over, to meet the cost of mortgage payments, interest, land tax (under New York State housing policy the
society was granted a 20-year exemption from the tax imposed on real estate),
insurance, the administration of the project and certain services such as electricity and heating, the co-operative calculated that each member would need to
pay a monthly sum of $10.75 per room until the mortgage was paid off, but
decided to charge $11 so as to leave a small reserve margin which could be
drawn on in any emergency. This sum was lower than that normally paid by
ordinary tenants for a flat in any of the city's modern blocks.1
In 1961, taking a further step towards self-sufficiency, the United
Housing Foundation, which has provided housing through its projects
for over 20,000 families, inaugurated its own insurance scheme for
affiliated co-operatives, the Community Insurance Exchange.2
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

One of the outstanding merits of the American co-operative housing

movement is that, without having to call on the Government for direct
aid through subsidies, it places decent accommodation within the reach
of thousands of families who would otherwise not have been able to
obtain it. As President Kennedy put it when opening a new co-operative
estate for 2,820 families in New York in May 1962, co-operative housing
is a programme which helps people to help themselves to solve their
own problem.
As a testimonial to the solidarity of the co-operative housing
organisations it is worth recording that the 13 big co-operative projects
constructed during the first phase by the United Housing Foundation
were able to survive the years of world economic crisis without having
to seek a new method of financing and without the members being
forced to leave their homes.
One of the positive factors underlying these satisfactory results is
1
Co-operation (New York, The Cooperative League), Vol. XIV, No. 2, Feb. 1928,
pp. 23-24.
2
Co-operative News Service (London, International Co-operative Alliance),
No. 14, Dec. 1961.

UNITED STATES

117

that the residents organised on co-operative lines have been able to hold
the costs of administering their projects at a lower level than is possible
under programmes where the housing is constructed, financed and administered by public bodies. In this respect testimony before the Senate
Subcommittee on Housing indicated monthly per-dwelling operating
costs of $5.14 and $5.19 in two mutual housing projects, as against
$10 in a nearby public housing project.1
The co-operatives covering all phases from the selection of the site
to the administration of the project and the provision of complementary
services have not merely helped their members to acquire decent accommodation. The same goes for the mutual home ownership corporations
which have acquired property constructed by the Government. They
have gone much further, creating a new type of community where neighbours can get to know one another better, since they all have a common
interest and participate on equal terms in the financial and social activities
organised by the co-operative. Co-operatives of this comprehensive type
organise retail shops and day nurseries, as well as libraries, recreation
rooms and playing fields, discussion and study clubs, art groups, dances,
etc.
But one of the most significant social contributions made by cooperatives towards solving the housing problem has been the beneficial
influence on family life. Not only have they stimulated the founding of
new homes by facilitating the acquisition of decent accommodation, but
they have created an environment which favours the development of
family life. This is true not only of relatively smaller cities, as exemplified
by the Dallas Park Cooperative Housing Association which was able to
announce at the end of its first ten years of existence that there had not
been a single case of juvenile delinquency within the community and that
divorces were few and far between2, but also in cities like New York.
The co-operative established in 1926 in Van Cortlandt Park, which is in
fact one of the most overpopulated districts of New York, announced
that in more than 30 years of existence there had yet to be recorded a
single case of serious juvenile delinquency among the hundreds of
families living in that development. It is also worth noting that 75 per
cent, of the families now residing there are either the same families who
founded the co-operative or their descendants.3
Although the most notable achievements of co-operative housing
in the United States have been brought to fruition in the country's largest
1

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR: Organization and Management

operative and Mutual Housing Associations, op. cit., p. 15, footnote 13.
2
The Cooperative Builder (Superior, Wisconsin), 19 May 1949.
" V O O R H I S : op. cit., p . 45.

of Co-

118

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

city, this does not mean that the co-operative approach to the housing
problem has been adopted exclusively in the great urban centres. Of
course, no large-scale projects have been carried out in rural areas : the
trend has been towards small projects, which have achieved satisfactory
results and have signposted the way in which the rural population may
be helped to acquire better accommodation on favourable terms. An
example of how co-operative energy and methods can be used to aid
housing development in rural areas may be taken from an experiment in
Oklahoma. This venture had its beginnings in eight villages in the
western part of the state under the auspices of the American Legion, a
non-profit organisation which is active all over the country, and with
the financial backing of the Federal Housing Administration. The great
point about this experiment is that it applied to small rural communities
methods such as mass production which it had been believed until then
could only be used in urban centres. While a project of this type may
seem insignificant when compared with the great urban developments
(the largest of the 1952 projects consisted of only 50 units and the smallest
of 12), they are great and remarkable achievements to the small communities and to the families to whom they render real service. The number
of families who obtained homes of their own as a result of these first
attempts at co-operation in Oklahoma was 514. Since then further
projects of this type have been undertaken in different parts of rural
America.1
Although remaining on a minor scale compared with the advanced
stage of development in the nation's building industry, co-operative
housing today plays an important part in the country's housing policy,
and there is every prospect of a steady increase in its contribution towards
solving the accommodation problem. Among the positive factors
making for the promotion of co-operative housing the following may be
mentioned: the growing stimulus and assistance given by the Federal
Government to non-profit housing projects, including those organised
on co-operative lines 2 ; the continued interest and financial support from
workers' organisations 3 ; and the plans to encourage the conversion of
municipal housing estates into co-operative mutual housing associations,
as has been done in New York City.4

1

Howard Leland SMITH: The Oklahoma Cooperative Housing Story (Washington,
D.C., Federal Housing Administration, Cooperative Housing Division, 1952).
2
International Housing Bulletin, No. 6, June 1961, pp. 112-113.
3
Ibid., No. 4, Apr. 1961, p. 79.
•VOORHIS: op. cit., p. 51.

PART V
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

CHAPTER XI
COLOMBIA
HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

Although the co-operative housing movement in Colombia began
only a short time before the Second World War, it is one of the most
advanced in Latin America. It owed its origins not to any special
encouragement by the State but to private initiative by groups of poorly
paid clerical workers.
In 1936 the country had still not recovered from the effects of the
slump which began in 1929. Wage and salary earners alike faced real
hardship because of their low earnings and the chronic shortage of
housing, which became steadily worse with the virtual standstill in the
building industry. It was financially impossible for anyone depending
on a small wage or salary to contemplate building his own home, and
this gave a group of office workers in the town of Medellin the idea of
setting up a housing co-operative as one way of obtaining decent housing
for their families. Investigation of the idea began in 1936, and in 1939
the first experiment was launched.
ORGANISATION

General Characteristics
The Colombian co-operative housing movement has the following
characteristics: as in Spain and almost all the Latin American countries,
it started as an offshoot of the consumer co-operative movement; it
caters almost entirely for the middle class; it is an urban movement;
and its membership is highly individualistic.
At first there were no housing co-operatives as such and departments
were set up under existing credit or consumer co-operatives to build
houses for members. Houses were looked upon simply as consumer
goods as far as co-operative organisation was concerned. Production
co-operatives formed by building workers were not successful.
The enormous gulf observed in most parts of Latin America between
the haves and the have-nots exists in Colombia also. However, the

122

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Colombian housing co-operatives draw their members not so much
from among the poorest classes as from the middle classes: craftsmen,
office workers, teachers, artists, etc. This is not a matter of deliberate
choice but reflects the fact that educational standards in the middle class
have always been higher while at the same time such persons have not
been able to benefit so much from public housing schemes.
The Medellin scheme was quickly followed by clerical workers in
Bogotá, Cali and Barranquilla and later spread elsewhere. The movement
did not, however, cater solely for clerical workers, and successful cooperatives for manual workers were also organised in various parts
of the country.
Especially at first, housing co-operatives, like most co-operatives in
Colombia, were mainly an urban phenomenon, although the bulk of the
country's population is rural. It is true that at various times after the
passing of the General Co-operatives Act in 1931 isolated attempts
were made to organise co-operatives in the rural areas, but it is only in
quite recent years that a genuine agricultural co-operative movement
has been launched. Plans are now being made to use this as a starting
point for a rural co-operative housing movement.
In Colombia there have never been any housing co-operatives of the
type that is characteristic of the Scandinavian countries and has prospered elsewhere in Europe, as well as in the United States. The general
preference of Colombian co-operators is for individually owned houses
rather than for projects composed of large numbers of flats.
Characteristic Type of Housing Co-operative
The usual type of housing co-operative in Colombia caters for future
individual owners. Societies generally buy large areas of building land
on reasonable terms near the towns and assume responsibility for development (with the help of the local authorities) and for dividing up the site
into plots for single-family homes. The co-operative also arranges the
necessary loans and awards contracts for the building. In this way cooperatives have constructed a number of residential districts which are
among the most attractive in Medellin and a number of other towns.
Not all of these schemes have remained co-operative in character.
Some societies have been wound up as soon as the building has been
completed and the title deeds handed over, the members themselves
becoming individually responsible for discharging any outstanding
financial obligations. There is then the danger that homes built as part
of co-operative schemes may later be sold for speculative purposes on
the open market without any control.

COLOMBIA

123

In other cases, however, the society remains responsible for managing
the estate and retains ownership of the facilities provided for the convenience of the residents, e.g. schools, shops, sports fields, parks. In
addition, although the members personally own their homes, they agree
at a general meeting on certain rules which they undertake to observe;
for example, in no circumstances may dwellings be used except as homes,
and it is forbidden to use a dwelling or part of it as a store, workshop
or place of entertainment; usually dwellings may not be let, and if they
are the co-operative itself must make the necessary arrangements ; and
in order to preserve visual unity, no home may be altered without the
approval of the co-operative.
If the co-operative continues to be responsible for the management it
tries to provide various additional services. One of the first ways in
which a co-operative helps a member after he has been assigned his house
is to advise him on interior decoration or furnishing.
Mutual-Help Co-operatives
Societies based on mutual help are not very common in Colombia,
although experiments along these lines have been made. A good
example is the " La Providencia " workers' co-operative in the town of
Pereira. The members, most of them skilled building workers, spent
three or four hours a day working on the co-operative project after
working hours and also gave up free time at week-ends. They were
divided into teams according to their trades and could be assigned to
work on any house without knowing beforehand which would be
allocated to them. It was only after the whole project was completed
that allocation was made in accordance with a specially devised system.
In this way the co-operative built a modern working-class housing estate
for several hundred families.
Colombian Federation of Housing Co-operatives
Although co-operative housing schemes have been in operation in
Colombia for more than 20 years, an organised movement cannot be said
to have been in existence for the same length of time, starting as it did as
an offshoot of other co-operative movements. According to the official
figures, out of 485 co-operatives of all classes in existence in Colombia
on 31 December 1950, 253 had rules establishing housing departments. 1
Moreover, the few societies solely concerned with housing which were
1
Sergio CARVALLO HEDERRA: Cooperativas de Habitaciones (Washington, D.C.,
Pan-American Union, 1952), p. 90.

124

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

established at a later date began to function as isolated units and neither
pooled their resources nor benefited by one another's experience.
Gradually, however, the co-operatives felt the need to co-ordinate
their work and combine their efforts. After several national conferences
on technical subjects, a Colombian federation of housing co-operatives
was formed in February 1962.
FINANCING

As in any other country, the co-operatives are based in principle on
the savings which members contribute towards the cost of their housing.
In some societies the members make a good deal of their contribution
in labour rather than in cash.
Nevertheless, since the purchase and preparation of sites and the
building of the homes themselves are expensive and members' savings
usually very limited, the main source of finance for co-operative housing
in Colombia, as elsewhere, consists of long-term loans against mortgages
of the property.
Credit for housing in Colombia is insufficient for the lower income
groups. Whereas in other countries such as Sweden it is possible to
obtain mortgage loans covering up to 95 per cent, of the value of the
property, so that a member only has to find the remaining 5 per cent.
himself, it is common in Colombia for a member to have to find up to
45 per cent, of the total cost.
There are two main publicly financed bodies with specific responsibility for financing co-operative housing projects : the Central Mortgage
Bank and the National Credit Institute.
The Central Mortgage Bank has financed a number of co-operative
schemes but its terms are far too stringent for families of moderate means
since usually it only lends up to 60 per cent, of the value of the dwelling.
It makes these loans not in cash but in warrants or bonds which are
subject to 15 per cent, discount. It also takes over the management of
the property under mortgage and its interest rates are high while repayment periods are fairly short.1
The National Credit Institute is the body with official responsibility
for dealing with housing matters. By law it is required to earmark not
less than 20 per cent, of its resources for co-operative housing programmes, but in actual fact few societies have been able to finance
their schemes in this way because of the terms demanded by the Institute.
1
Francisco Luis JIMÉNEZ: Estudio General de la Situación Económico-Social de
las Cooperativas de Vivienda en Colombia (Medellín, Federación de Cooperativas
de Habitaciones de Colombia, 1962; mimeographed document).

COLOMBIA

125

This does not mean that the State is unaware of the seriousness of
the housing position or is not determined to remedy it. The Government
has, for example, made efforts to encourage the private building industry,
but this has not been very effective in the case of housing for the lower
income groups, which is not profitable. The Government has also
launched house-building programmes through the National Credit
Institute, which is divided into two departments, dealing respectively
with urban and rural housing.
The commercial banks usually supply co-operatives with interim
short-term loans to finance their building, while final loans are granted
against a mortgage.
Some co-operatives also have their own credit schemes to finance
housing for their members. Thus the Agrarian Credit Fund Employees'
Co-operative grants loans to its members against a first, second or third
mortgage to finance the purchase, construction or repair of a dwelling
or the payment of debts incurred for that purpose. These loans are
repayable over a period not exceeding four years. 1

Other occasional sources of finance are local authorities, various
private companies which help to finance housing schemes for their
workers, and certain insurance companies.
To sum up, housing co-operatives in Colombia lack an established
system which can supply the credit at low rates of interest and on easy
repayment terms which is needed to encourage participation by families
of moderate means and make it possible to plan on a comprehensive,
long-term basis.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

Despite the restrictions, especially of a financial character, which
have held back the growth of this type of co-operative in Colombia,
the movement's contribution towards solving the housing shortage has
been appreciable and is an example of what can be done in this field even
with the limited technical and financial resources available in the developing countries.
According to the figures for March 1962, there were at that date
60 housing co-operatives in Colombia including several multi-purpose
societies which were also carrying out large-scale housing schemes.
It is regrettable that many societies, including those which met a great
social need by building pleasant residential districts for middle-class
families, have been wound up as soon as the building was finished.
1
Orientación Cooperativa (Bogotá, Cooperativa de Empleados de la Caja de
Crédito Agrario, Feb. 1962).

126

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Co-operatives in Colombia had sufficient land on 31 March 1962 for
no fewer than 22,000 homes which were due to be built over the following
two years.1 About 30 per cent, of these sites had already been prepared
by the co-operatives; a further 30 per cent, were being prepared and the
remaining 40 per cent, had still not yet been developed.

1

See JIMÉNEZ: op.

cit.

CHAPTER XIT
INDIA

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

Despite the efforts made by the Government of India since independence to tackle the country's housing problem, the shortage of
adequate housing for the lower income groups in both towns and
villages is still acute, and in relative terms it has even become worse.
There are a number of explanations for this deterioration in recent
years. In the first place, although India was not in the zone of operations
during the Second World War, virtually the whole building industry was
paralysed for a long period. Other causes include the refugee problem
caused by the partition of the country, the increase in the population, the
growing industrial development in the towns, the legitimate desire for
better housing among the poor sections of the community as their living
standards rise, and the increase in prices of building materials and
labour since the war. The Government is relying heavily on the cooperative method in implementing its policy of trying to provide adequate
housing for a large section of the population.
The use of co-operative methods to provide housing is not, however,
new in India, since the earliest society of this type was estabUshed nearly
half a century ago in Bombay with such success that it has served as a
model and an inspiration for later co-operatives.
Despite this, the co-operative housing movement did not manage to
develop sufficiently to play a significant part in solving housing problems
during the 35 years which followed the founding of the first society.
It was only from 1950 onwards that co-operative housing began to
develop under the influence of the first two five-year plans.
Table V shows the progress of housing co-operatives in India during
part of this period.
ORGANISATION

The development of the movement has not been uniform. The
former state of Bombay (now divided into Maharashtra and Gujarat) has

128

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

TABLE V. INDIA: DEVELOPMENT OF HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES, 1957-60
Year

Co-operatives

Membership

Housing
units built

Value in
thousands of rupees

1957-58
1958-59
1959-60

4,177
4,744
5,563

249,302
281,642
322,000

44,345
44,721
45,675

342,670
331,682
384,100

Source: INTERNATIONAL CO-OPERATIVE ALLIANCE: Statistics of Affiliated Building and Housing Cooperatives (London, 1962; mimeographed document).

taken the lead, with 48 per cent, of the total, and the other regions in
order of importance are Madras, Andhra Pradesh, Mysore, Punjab and
West Bengal.
There are four main types of housing co-operative:
(i) societies organised by building workers for the purpose of building
homes for sale on the housing market;
(ii) societies specialising in supplying loans to finance house building.
These are, in fact, housing credit co-operatives;
(iii) societies established to acquire sites for members' future homes.
It sometimes happens that these societies also help their members
over other phases of the building process, e.g. site preparation,
finance or technical matters;
(iv) societies which retain ownership of the property. These co-operatives assign dwellings to their members as if they were their own,
but members can only dispose of them subject to certain restrictions laid down in the rules in order to prevent possible speculative
selling. Co-operative communities of this sort have provided such
facilities as electricity, roads, schools, hospitals, sports fields and
sewers.
In other states housing co-operatives have been organised for
particular sections of the population. For example, in Maharashtra,
Madras and Gujarat societies have been set up for industrial workers,
poorly paid clerical workers, backward sections of the population and
persons made homeless by floods. In Andhra Pradesh, Madras, Punjab
and Madhya Pradesh societies have been formed for civil servants, and
in West Bengal this method has been used to help large numbers of
refugees to acquire new homes.
Of the different types of housing co-operatives encountered in India,
the most widespread is the fourth. Although there are a number of
variations on this model, most of the societies formed in recent years,
especially in Maharashtra, consist of individual co-operative projects for
communities or estates along the lines of garden cities with all the

INDIA

129

necessary services. By and large, the pattern of organisation is akin to
that of some of the European and North American housing co-operatives
described earlier. The co-operative itself retains ownership of the
property, installations and surrounding land. Each member lives in his
home as if it were his own and makes a down payment in the form of
share certificates, followed by monthly payments which include repayment of such loans as he may have needed.
A Co-operative Housing Federation was founded at Bombay in
1948 with the following objectives:
to acquire land, houses and property, both movable and immovable,
for the benefit of the Federation or its members and to expend money
as may be deemed necessary in cultivation and development;
to take steps for procurement of building materials by member societies ;
to advise, guide, assist and inspect member societies and arrange for
efficient and regular supervision;
to assist member societies in obtaining loans ;

to convene periodical meetings and conferences.1
Since then other states have set up similar federations as the first step
towards the formation of a nation-wide confederation covering and
serving all the housing co-operatives in the country.
FINANCING

The cost of co-operative housing schemes in India is largely met by
financial aid from the Central Government under its national housing
plan, supplemented by special schemes by a number of states to help
particular sections of the population. This does not mean that members
are not asked and encouraged to contribute towards the cost of their
own homes, but, as noted earlier, even in the most highly industrialised
countries the cost of building is such that societies of this type have to
rely to a large extent on external sources of finance. Although in India,
as everywhere else, the movement relies heavily on these outside sources,
there is no change in the essential co-operative principle that success
depends on an initial contribution from each member followed by regular
repayments of the mortgage loans.
Financial and other assistance from the Central Government to
co-operatives of this type is given as part of the national housing policy,
which in turn is dovetailed into the country's general economic development in accordance with the five-year plans.
1

UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 113.

130

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

The main schemes by which co-operatives can benefit under the
Government of India's housing policy are as follows:
Subsidised Industrial Housing Scheme
The scheme for subsidised industrial housing, which was started in
1952, recognises the great importance of housing co-operatives. During
the secondfive-yearplan some changes were fnade in the terms on which
loans and subsidies are provided. At present the Central Government
lends co-operatives up to 65 per cent, of the estimated cost of a house or
housing scheme for industrial workers, and also grants a subsidy equal
to 25 per cent, of the building cost. Industrial workers who are members
of a co-operative can obtain a further advance—which is not repayable—
from their society's welfare fund. This advance may be up to 10 per cent.
of the building cost, so that the scheme meets the whole cost of housing
for eligible workers.
Low Income Group Housing Scheme
Under a scheme started in 1954 persons whose annual personal
income does not exceed 6,000 rupees can obtain a loan which may
cover up to 80 per cent, of the cost of their dwelling, including the land.
Generally speaking, the cost of building a house under this scheme may
not exceed 10,000 rupees, so that the maximum loan granted under it
may not normally exceed 8,000 rupees. Under the third five-year plan,
which is now in operation, at least a third of the money made available
under this scheme must be used to finance the purchase of adequate
housing for the worst-off sections of the community whose annual
incomes do not exceed 1,800 rupees. These loans are not usually made
direct to individuals, however, but to non-profit organisations, to be
channelled where possible through co-operatives specially set up to
serve these sections of the population. Normally, loans given under this
scheme are charged at 5 per cent, interest and are repayable over periods
of up to 30 years.
Middle Income Group Housing Scheme
The middle income group is here defined as the section of the population in which annual family incomes are higher than 6,000 rupees but
lower than 15,000. Loans can be made covering up to 80 per cent, of the
cost of building (including the land), subject to a loan ceiling of 20,000
rupees; the cost of a house built under the scheme may not normally
exceed 25,000 rupees (excluding the value of the land). Loans are

INDIA

131

repayable over 25 years, and the interest rate is 5 ]/2 per cent. The states
obtain the necessary funds to finance the scheme from the Life Insurance
Corporation. As a rule, financial arrangements for these loans are not
made with individual borrowers but with co-operatives set up to carry
out housing projects for the middle income groups.
Village Housing Projects Scheme
Housing co-operatives consisting of individuals living in certain
rural areas are given financial aid in the form of loans which may cover
up to two-thirds of the cost of construction. Normally, houses built
under the scheme may not cost more than 5,000 rupees, since these
co-operatives require members to build their own homes. A period of
up to 20 years is allowed for repayment of the loans, and interest is
charged at the rate of 5 per cent. Although financial assistance is provided for purchasing the land needed for streets and communal buildings,
the scheme is based on mutual aid by the members themselves.1

The national housing policy of the Central Government is normally
supplemented by the state governments, which have their own co-operative departments to help in forming societies among the sections of the
population that such schemes are designed to benefit. In addition the
state governments assist co-operatives in purchasing and developing
building sites, drawing up the plans, obtaining materials and estimating
costs.
Some states also have their own housing schemes, which are largely
based on a co-operative form of organisation, and have even set up
their own financial agencies to help finance the national schemes or to
finance local schemes designed to help a particular section of the state's
population. Thus in Maharashtra State the Government, through the
welfare department, has granted loans and subsidies to finance the
co-operative housing of sweepers. In the Bombay metropolitan district
it is also helping, through the Maharashtra Housing Finance Society,
to finance co-operatives covered by national low income group housing
schemes.
In Madras the Government has not confined itself to granting loans
but has helped housing co-operatives as well by giving them advice on
technical matters and preferential treatment in the purchasing of land
1
H. D. NARGOLWALA: "Co-operative Housing—Problems and Perspectives",
in All India Co-operative Review (New Delhi, National Co-operative Union of India),
Vol. XXVII, No. 6, Sep. 1961, p. 382.

132

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

and materials. The state of Madras has also launched a scheme to clear
the overcrowded city centres by organising co-operative communities
in satellite cities equipped with all the necessary services.1
As the great majority of families seeking decent housing cannot
afford a substantial down payment towards the cost of their homes
and since financial institutions in the developing countries are not
usually in a position to make low interest loans to co-operators for this
purpose, it is quite common in India for members of co-operatives to
supply their labour instead of a cash contribution.
Under the third five-year plan a major effort is being prepared to
foster credit co-operatives with the aim of encouraging small personal
savings and using them to finance housing schemes.
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

When related to the magnitude of the housing problem affecting
large sections of the population, or compared with the total number of
dwellings built in India from 1950 to 1960, the number of houses built by
co-operatives in those years appears at first sight to be an insignificant
contribution towards solving the problem. Although the Government
of India has, especially since the achievement of independence, carried
out some impressive housing projects and used the opportunity to
encourage co-operative organisation, this type of co-operative does not
yet appear sufficiently mature in India, nor is it yet established on a
nation-wide scale. This goes to explain why the movement has not
made the fullest use of the facilities made available to it under the
schemes launched in recent years as part of the Government's housing
programme.
Nevertheless, co-operatives have begun to make a definite contribution towards easing the housing shortage. The number of housing
co-operatives doubled between 1955 and 1960, and both their membership and their registered capital showed marked increases.
Bearing in mind, therefore, the difficulties occurring in the developing
countries, it can be said that in recent years the Indian co-operative
housing movement has made significant progress. Housing co-operatives
have made no mean contribution within the limitations imposed by
their resources, and they have been of special assistance to the low
income groups in towns and villages alike, but above all to the industrial
workers in the big cities.

1

UNITED NATIONS: Housing through Non-Profit Organizations, op. cit., p. 113.

CHAPTER XIII
UNITED ARAB REPUBLIC

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

The history of the Egyptian co-operative movement falls into three
periods, beginning in 1908, 1923 and 1953 respectively.
The first period was composed entirely of private efforts, without
any official backing. A number of experiments were made in both the
towns and the villages, especially in the field of consumer co-operation,
but no attempt was made to use this method as a way of tackling the
housing problem.
In 1923 the Government began to take an interest in the movement
and passed the first enactment on the subject which has since been
amended a number of times. The passing of this Act marked the
beginning of the second stage in the development of the movement,
during which a number of efforts were made by members of the public
to organise co-operatives of various types for different economic or
social purposes. These were for the most part farming and consumer
societies.
The modern Egyptian co-operative movement, however, only began
in 1953, which marked the start of the third period in the movement's
history. One very important factor in its development during recent
years has been the fact that the Government has shown growing appreciation of the social and economic advantages afforded by co-operation
and has therefore made provision for the movement in its economic
development plans. Housing co-operatives only date from the beginning
of the third stage in 1953.
ORGANISATION

Like the other types of society, Egyptian housing co-operatives have
only sprung up in the past decade as a result of Government encouragement under the national housing plan; this encouragement was given
legislative expression in Acts Nos. 317 of 1956, 267 of 1960 and 319 of
1961. In 1961 the Government set up a special body, the Egyptian

134

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Organisation for Co-operative Housing, to provide technical and
financial assistance to this type of society.
Co-operative housing in Egypt has been mainly a middle-class
movement. Originally it consisted of local societies which subsequently
formed regional federations. A number of the local co-operatives are
formed by persons in the same occupation, e.g. army officers, university
teachers, officials of the judiciary, police officers.
In accordance with their members' wishes, Egyptian housing cooperatives have concentrated on building single-family homes for their
members, but in recent years they have also put up large modern blocks
of flats surrounded by gardens and equipped with efficient communal
facilities.
These co-operatives do not themselves normally engage in house
building for their members. In most cases they use private subcontractors,
either direct or through the General Organisation of Contracts. There
are also a few Egyptian co-operatives consisting of building workers
which provide employment for their members and help to deal with
the housing problem by carrying out the various building operations
involved in housing projects.
Farming co-operatives, most of which are multi-purpose societies,
usually have their own departments specialising in building homes for
their members, in most cases as part of the National Land Reform
Programme.
Self- or mutual-help house-building schemes are not unknown in
Egypt either, but have mainly been used in rural areas, hitherto only on
an experimental scale. Nevertheless, the success achieved in the few
cases where the technique has been used suggests that it might help to
solve the housing problem in the rural areas if organised along cooperative lines.
Some Egyptian co-operatives transfer ownership to their members
as soon as their financial obligations are paid off, while others retain
ownership of the property and allow their members to become privileged users.
FINANCING

There is no co-operative in Egypt with sufficient resources to finance
its own house-building programmes and, as almost everywhere else in
the world, the movement depends to a large extent on outside funds,
mainly from the Government.
The Government recognises the important part that co-operation can
play in overcoming the housing shortage, which is particularly acute for

UNITED ARAB REPUBLIC

135

families in the lower income groups, and finance is made available to
the movement as part of the national housing programme.
At first, Government aid, which could amount to 60 per cent, of the
total cost of a project, consisted mainly of loans which the Government
paid direct to the bank to finance the building operations. These loans
bore a low rate of interest (3 per cent.) and were repayable over 20 years.
Nowadays, financial aid made available by the Government through the
Egyptian Organisation for Co-operative Housing may amount to 70 per
cent, of the cost. The interest rate remains at 3 per cent., and the repayment period is still 20 years.
Another official step to help the financing of co-operatives has been
to entitle co-operatives to acquire publicly owned land at cost for use
as building sites.
Apart from the Government, there are a number of other financial
institutions which make funds available for building co-operatives.
These include the commercial banks, insurance companies, the postal
savings scheme, the co-operative social security scheme, the savings
funds and a number of private firms which contribute towards the
cost of homes for their workers. Their loans usually cover up to 60 per
cent, of the building cost and bear an interest rate of between 5 and
6 per cent.
Naturally, the members themselves must, in accordance with cooperative principles, contribute something towards the cost of their
homes, although the amount required depends on the type of scheme.
In the case of homes which will become their personal property, members must put down at least 30 per cent, of the total cost and pay off the
remainder in monthly instalments. On the other hand, in the case of
large blocks of flats or housing estates which remain the property of the
co-operative and in which the residents are simply privileged users,
members need only purchase five share certificates for each room in
their dwelling, in addition to which they must also pay a small monthly
charge by way of rent for the accommodation allocated to them.
In some cases, Government aid for housing for wage and salary
earners of moderate means has been somewhat more generous. For
example, when a co-operative estate of 300 houses was built near the
Dokki Agricultural Museum, the manual and clerical workers who
received homes under the scheme were only required to make a down
payment equal to 10 per cent, of the total cost, i.e. between E £400
and 600. The Government loan financing the remainder was divided
into monthly instalments which in no case exceeded the rents payable
in the district for similar housing, the big difference being that in this
case the residents became owners of their homes after 15 years.

136

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES
SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE

Between 1953 and 1963 Egyptian housing co-operatives built about
4,000 homes and established a number of new communities with all
modern services (except schools and hospitals, which are provided by
the local authorities).
Encouraged by this success and the financial facilities offered by the
Government, public opinion in Egypt has shown a marked interest in
co-operation as a way of dealing with the housing problem. In 1954
the Government launched a six-month campaign to call the public's
attention to co-operation as a way of providing houses, but since then
the pressure to start co-operative building schemes has come from the
public itself.
In recognition of this, the Government established the Egyptian
Organisation for Co-operative Housing and started a five-year cooperative housing plan (1960-65), for which it earmarked a sum of
E £15 million, with an intermediate target of 5,000 completed homes
by the end of 1963.1

1

Information provided by the Egyptian Organisation for Co-operative Housing.

PART VI
CO-OPERATION AND THE HOUSING PROBLEM
IN THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

CHAPTER XIV
SUGGESTIONS FOR ADAPTATION OF THE CO-OPERATIVE
FORMULA IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
Shortage of housing is not a problem which affects only the developing countries. Broadly speaking, there is not a single country where
shortages of decent accommodation do not present a serious problem,
but the experience gained in the more industrialised countries may be
useful to those in the course of development.
Co-operative methods have been shown to have real advantages in
helping to solve the housing problem. The preceding chapters give an
account of what has already been done in some countries. Without in
any way suggesting that the developing countries should blindly follow
patterns that have been tried out in more industrialised countries, it may
be said that the co-operative principle of encouraging people to help
themselves is likely to be of particular value for developing countries.
It would be utterly wrong to treat the co-operative formula as a
panacea, however; it is not the only way of solving the housing problem;
nor is it the easiest or the quickest. Even in industrialised countries
where great co-operative enterprises are now flourishing, many of the
earlier attempts met with failure, although not because co-operative
methods were used but owing to the way in which the co-operative
formula was applied to deal with a particular situation. Moreover, the
lesson of these setbacks has helped the societies founded subsequently
to avoid making the same mistakes.
Organisation
THE THREE BASIC FORMS

In housing co-operatives, as in other types of co-operative, the
members are the foundation on which the organisation is built up. The
descriptions given in the preceding chapters show that there are three
main ways in which families needing accommodation may unite to form
a co-operative. These three forms differ in the degree of active participation required of members in founding and operating a society.

140

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

(1) The form which demands most direct participation by members
is undoubtedly the self-help type of co-operative, of which examples are
given in Chapter IX. Those interested first form a group to discuss their
housing needs and possible ways of satisfying them, and only later do
they found a society and begin construction, in which all members
participate directly through their personal labour. It is a very simple and
practical form of organisation which may be useful in dealing with
housing problems in areas which are mainly rural, with settlements or
small towns.
(2) The characteristic feature of the second form is that there is a
promoting body—generally another non-profit organisation—which
conceives the project, buys the land, takes the first steps towards
executing the plan, and contacts persons interested in acquiring a
home by participating in a particular co-operative programme. This
system has been followed in various countries, particularly in urban areas.
The role of the members in this case, especially as far as the actual building is concerned, is more passive and indirect. The main danger is that
societies may be formed which are co-operatives in name only. Nevertheless, where efforts have been made from the outset to see that the
prospective residents are educated in co-operative principles, and there
has been a central co-operative body to co-ordinate such activities and
promote the purposes of the movement, this method has resulted in the
establishment of successful co-operative communities.
(3) In the third form, instead of having an outside sponsoring body,
there are " mother " societies engaged in house construction in one area
or another all the time, and individuals frequently join them without
reference to any particular building project. As soon as he joins, a
member begins to participate actively in the affairs of the society, and
prepares to form part of a " daughter " co-operative to comprise all the
future residents in a new project. There is a central body for the whole
country, with " mother " societies in all the larger towns and " daughter "
co-operatives for each housing project. The whole system is run by the
members through their representative authorities. Despite its apparent
complexity, this form of organisation contains valuable and positive
features which could be adapted to less industrialised countries.
SELECTION OF THE TYPE OF CO-OPERATIVE

As shown in the previous chapters, co-operative housing can be
organised in a number of different ways. Methods which have been
highly successful in one country have often been less effective when
transplanted to another environment. The following remarks about the

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

141

main types of housing co-operatives mentioned in this study may be
helpful in selecting the features that can be adapted to local conditions
to foster co-operative housing in the developing countries.
Comprehensive Housing Co-operatives
Experience shows that a society which retains ownership of the
property (while treating its members as privileged users) can do most to
create a co-operative spirit. Where a permanent relationship exists,
many community facilities can be provided (e.g. kindergartens, recreation
rooms, playing fields, libraries, shops). These are housing co-operatives
in the proper sense of the term. Their features include the following:
(i) They make better use of the building land available. This is an
important advantage in the case of projects near big towns, since the
housing problem is tending to be aggravated by such factors as the
rise in population, higher living standards, a higher marriage
rate, greater economic independence for young people, higher
expectation of life and an influx of people from the rural areas in
search of better jobs in the towns. This argues in favour of larger
projects, especially since in a few years' time it will undoubtedly be
difficult to find land for building in many towns in a number of
countries.
(ii) It creates a joint interest in the upkeep of the building or group of
buildings in the project, while individual members who have the
same security of tenure as if they personally owned their dwellings
tend to take more interest in the care and decoration of their homes.
(iii) It eliminates any possibility of speculative selling. Not only are
members unable to speculate at all during the stages preceding
completion of the project, but they are not allowed to sublet except
subject to certain conditions which are laid down in the rules
specifically to prevent any transactions for profit.
(iv) It makes it easier to move to a new home on the same project if
family circumstances change, e.g. as more children are born.
(v) It offers scope, especially on big housing schemes for several hundred
families, for employing co-operative techniques to maintain quality
and cut costs, as compared with the open building market.
(vi) It acts as a practical school of democracy, creating close links
between families, who learn to live together in a community by taking
an active part in the management of their project and making use
of the same communal services.

142

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Personal Mutual-Help Co-operatives
In order to encourage wage earners in the lower income groups or rural
dwellers to acquire adequate housing, the developing countries might
consider adapting the type of personal mutual help co-operative described
in Chapter IX. These societies are remarkable for the practical way in
which they tackle their difficulties, and for their small-scale but effective
achievements in cases where large-scale projects are out of the question.
Another advantage of this type of co-operative is that, by allowing
members to contribute their own labour, it stimulates their initiative and
attaches them to their new homes, as well as creating close community
links among the group as a whole.
It is easier to provide adequate housing for families of limited means
in this way because members are able to contribute their own labour to
make up for not having the money needed to finance any other type of
construction. At the same time this reduces the amount of capital and
interest to be paid off.
In planning mutual-help schemes, it is advisable to draw on the experience of other countries in this field (examples being given in Chapter IX)
and to begin by organising a campaign to inform and educate members
so that they can play the most active part in the project. The next step
is to enlist the interest of central governments and local authorities so
that they can make the necessary arrangements to provide finance, as
well as to secure the collaboration of universities, trade unions and
other non-profit bodies operating in the same field. Logically the
resources of the separate groups should then be combined by forming
a regional or national federation which can teach them to make better
use of co-operative techniques.
In 1956 the Sixth Conference of American States Members of the
International Labour Organisation stated in paragraph 26 of the general
resolution concerning co-operatives—
Where housebuilding schemes are being developed through non-profit institutions or aided self-help schemes, consideration should be given to introducing
into them some of the techniques of co-operative organisation, notably those
designed to secure and retain the interest of occupiers in property maintenance
and management, as well as to secure the advantages of joint purchase and
ownership of land and bulk procurement of supplies and materials.1
Co-operatives of Future Owners
The comprehensive form has not always been accepted in some
countries, where members either insist that their homes should become
1

Official Bulletin, Vol. XXXIX, 1956, No. 8, p. 465.

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

143

their personal property or national legislation requires a co-operative
to hand over the title deeds to its members once construction is completed.
When, for legal or financial reasons or because of members' own
preferences, a co-operative hands over the title deeds, it should in all
cases take adequate precautions to forestall speculation. The following
measures can be recommended :
The co-operative should be given a preferential purchase option.
It should be agreed that no dwelhng can be sold to a third party except
with the consent of the management committee and at a specified
price based on an agreed estimate.
The member should undertake not to let or sublet any part of his dwelling
except with the prior consent of the management committee and even
then only temporarily and subject to certain conditions.
The member should agree, in the event of the winding-up of the society,
to sell the whole of his property through the co-operative, any surplus
over the original investment being shared out, but only after making
due allowance for depreciation so as to ensure that members do not
make a profit. Any balance then outstanding could be used to promote this type of co-operation or to help any other non-profit body.
Management Co-operatives
In the case of co-operatives for future owners, it is quite common in
some countries for societies to be wound up as soon as the building is
completed, and sometimes even beforehand. In other words, the cooperative system is only used in the stages involving building, land
purchase, site preparation and finance. But in many countries cooperatives remain in existence and take over the management of their
projects, or alternatively new societies may be established for the purpose.
As a rule, the members of these management co-operatives individually
assume a proportionate share of the obligations incurred, and a cooperative form of organisation is used for the actual management of the
project and the provision and operation of any extra services for the
community as a whole.
Although it is common for co-operatives which retain the ownership
of property to continue to manage it as well, there are some countries
where the usual practice once the building is completed is to form a new
society consisting of the privileged users of the housing. This new
co-operative takes over the management of the project and the obligations in the form of mortgage loans.

144

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

The co-operative management of housing schemes by the residents
themselves has usually led to high standards of maintenance, not only
of the buildings themselves, but also of the streets, avenues, gardens and
communal services which are usually part of the purpose of co-operative
housing schemes.
Local urban authorities faced with the need to find the money for large
housing schemes for families in the lower income groups might therefore
consider the advisability of forming management co-operatives to enlist
the residents' interest in matters affecting their own housing. They
would thereby relieve themselves at the same time of the tedious responsibilities of property management and ensure that the houses and services
themselves are well maintained. They might also consider whether
it would not be better to transfer ownership of the property to the
residents organised in a mutual ownership association, which could
take over the management and financial obligations. Moreover, maintenance and administrative costs are usually lower in co-operatives than
on municipal estates, where the residents have less incentive to look for
ways of saving money.

Tenants'" Co-operatives
The system of tenants' co-operatives is also worth study because by
eliminating the initial payment it makes it far easier for many families of
moderate means to acquire decent housing. Governments might encourage schemes of this kind by giving existing co-operatives facilities
for obtaining additional finance for the purpose.
Such a scheme, on the lines discussed in Chapter V, could be launched
in countries where there is already a soundly based co-operative movement which is in a position to benefit from experience in this field.

Building Workers' Co-operatives
Another form of co-operative organisation which has not yet been
widely used in many countries as a means of overcoming the housing
shortage is the co-operative formed of building workers. This type of
society has done much to bring about high standards of housing and has
made it possible for thousands of families in the lower income groups
to acquire their own homes. It has a variety of useful features which are
worth examining with a view to their introduction in less industrialised
countries.

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

145

Certain Essential Requirements
CO-OPERATIVE EDUCATION AND TRAINING

Experience in countries with a long history of co-operation has shown
that, whatever the problems involved in finance, land purchase and
development or actual building, the first essential is a true co-operative
spirit, and this is something frequently lacking among prospective
co-operative dwellers. Before the actual societies are formed, an educational campaign is likely to be required which is by no means confined
to the four walls of the schoolroom, in order to provide a new concept
of community life and encourage active participation. At the same time
competent leaders can be trained to run the future undertakings, and
basic instruction can be given in the building trades. The study group
method described in Chapter IX could be of particular value for self-help
co-operatives.
Experience in countries where the co-operative movement is highly
developed has shown that educational programmes must be designed for
both members and employees, providing a systematic series of courses
and a good information service. It has been found that, even after the
educational courses have been completed, large societies must encourage
personal contact between leaders and members, and among the members
themselves, for the purpose of discussing the problems of their future
housing programme. To supplement the formal co-operative training in
this way regular informal family meetings are organised, particularly
on traditional festive occasions, so as to maintain members' interest and
enthusiasm.
It is therefore very important that, wherever it is intended to adopt the
co-operative system as a means of solving the housing problem, thought
should be given first of all to the planning of a good educational programme geared to the particular situation of the country. Many people
join a co-operative simply because they need a home and feel that an
organisation of this type may offer greater financial facilities, but they
do not know, and often do not want to know, anything about the
principles and methods of co-operation. An educational campaign of
the type suggested might be centred around study groups, lectures,
discussions and publications, and help might be sought from workers'
organisations, adult education centres or other institutions in the country.1
1
Realising the importance of co-operative education and training, the I.L.O. has
issued the following publications: An Introduction to Co-operative Practice, Studies and
Reports, New Series, No. 32 (Geneva, 1952) ; Co-operative Management and Administration, same series, No. 57 (Geneva, 1960); Co-operation, a workers' education manual
(Geneva, 1956).

146

HOUSING COOPERATIVES
FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES

A national federation can be of great value in co-ordinating activities
and providing technical and legal facilities. What frequently happens in
some countries is that isolated societies are formed which have to embark
upon a venture fraught with problems as regards organisation, financing,
technical surveys, the supply of materials, construction and project
administration without being able to draw on collective experience,
both good and bad.
If co-operation is to make a significant contribution towards solving
a country's housing problem it is strongly recommended either that a
central body should be set up or that the existing co-operatives should
co-ordinate their efforts through a national federation. Owing to the
volume of its operations on behalf of its affiliated societies, such a body
would be able to reduce building costs by applying co-operative methods
on a national scale, purchasing materials and equipment wholesale and
even entering the field of production. It could also provide the services of
architects, lawyers, auditors or draughtsmen, whom it would be very
difficult, if not impossible, for local co-operatives on their own to engage.
Once the federation was established it could also assume responsibility
for promoting the formation of new housing co-operatives in the
country, in the light of national needs and in accordance with a plan of
action previously drawn up as part of the government's social policy.
RELATIONS BETWEEN CO-OPERATIVES

The co-operative movement comprises a number of branches catering
for different needs, but the basic organisational principles and the
ultimate purposes are always the same, because co-operation is a single
movement even though the industrial developments of modern times have
led to specialisation, the division of responsibilities and the restriction of
functions to certain clearly defined social objectives. There is, therefore,
a natural tendency for branches of the co-operative movement to complement each other, and advantage should be taken of this fact in carrying out any type of co-operative programme. Thus, co-operative building
schemes should be supported by savings, credit or insurance co-operatives
and by consumer and industrial production societies such as building
workers' co-operatives or associations of handicraft workers that might
be set up under the same auspices. When establishing housing cooperatives in the developing countries, it is important to maintain
contact with other sections of the movement, not only locally but nationally and internationally as well.

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

147

ECONOMIC ORGANISATION

While there is no doubt that co-operative methods can permit
considerable savings in the acquisition of land, the purchase or
manufacture of materials, building and maintenance, the success of
a housing co-operative depends on thorough preliminary study, a true
co-operative effort on the part of the members, and able and informed
leadership.
NORMAL MARKET PRICES

One of the most significant contributions of co-operative housing
is to reduce building costs through joint effort. However, this legitimate
interest in bringing down costs so as to make it possible for a greater
number of people with low incomes to acquire homes through cooperative projects should not lead co-operatives to calculate the financial
contribution to be made by members on the basis of actual costs, as this
would expose them to a grave risk. Co-operatives can bring down costs
by eliminating speculation, purchasing materials wholesale or going
in for production themselves, but it is sound financial practice, and in
line with the original Rochdale principles, for the members' contribution
towards costs to be based on normal market prices. This practice is
generally followed by consumer societies, and it can also be applied by
housing co-operatives, which thus have a buffer against any possible
contingency. The co-operative usually returns any surplus to its members at the end of the financial year, once all the costs of amortisation,
interest, management, taxes and services have been met.

National Housing Policy
The housing problem in any one country cannot be considered in
isolation from the economy as a whole and must be related to the whole
process of economic development.
In this connection the International Labour Conference stated in
the Workers' Housing Recommendation, 1961 that—
Housing policy should be co-ordinated with general social and economic
policy, so that workers' housing may be given a degree of priority which takes
into account both
the need therefor and the requirements of balanced economic
development.1
1

The full text of the Recommendation is given in the Official Bulletin, Vol. XL1V,
1961, No. 1, p. 4.

148

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

Co-operation as one of the methods of tackling the housing problem
will develop on a larger scale if a country possesses a national policy
defining the legal position of housing co-operatives, the measures that
can be taken to encourage them and their position in the over-all housing
and town-planning programme.
SPECIAL LEGISLATION

Experience shows that co-operatives function more smoothly and
efficiently if the legal framework within which they operate is clearly
defined. In many countries the co-operative housing movement at first
had to adjust itself to earlier legislation governing associations of other
types. But it is very difficult to adapt general company law to the complicated forms of organisation and operation peculiar to housing
co-operatives. In other words, a country wishing to encourage cooperative organisation in housing should have special legislation which
recognises the distinctive characteristics of this type of society, protects
its organisation and operation, and makes provision for technical and
financial aid.1
HOUSING AGENCY

One of the first steps required to implement a national housing
policy is the appointment of a central agency to co-ordinate the various
activities in this field. Such an agency should have a section with
responsibility for encouraging the formation of co-operatives and power
to give them technical and financial help. Especially in the developing
countries, where co-operatives are not sufficiently well established to
be able to provide their own central research and technical help facilities,
it would be advisable for governments themselves to set up authorities
to provide these services on a nation-wide scale. Even in highly industrialised countries where co-operation has a long history and other
branches of the movement are strongly organised, it has been found
worth while to establish a central body "of this type.
The International Labour Conference expressed this view in Paragraph 8 of the Workers' Housing Recommendation, 1961—
The competent national authorities, having due regard to the constitutional
structure of the country concerned, should set up a central body with which
should be associated all public authorities having some responsibility relating
to housing.
1
Specific legislation is desirable not only for housing co-operatives but also for
other co-operatives, and for the same reasons. Thus general legislation should include
special provision for the distinctive features and needs of housing co-operatives.

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

149

BUILDING SITES

One of the factors which do most to push up the cost of housing is
speculation in building land. It would be a sensible step for governments
to encourage local authorities to take suitable measures to eliminate or
curtail speculation in land suitable for building schemes, especially on
the outskirts of major industrial towns. The local authorities could
then make this land available at cost or on long-term renewable leases
to co-operatives or other non-profit bodies concerned with house
building.
CREDIT FACILITIES

For reasons stated below in connection with financing it is important
that the national housing policy of countries wishing to promote this
type of co-operation should provide for adequate credit facilities in the
form of long-term repayment periods and low interest rates to enable
co-operatives to discharge their social functions.
Another measure that could be taken in some countries as part of
a financial aid scheme would be to guarantee mortgage loans to families
of moderate means. An arrangement of this type, which reduces any
element of risk, has the further advantage of attracting private capital
into co-operative housing programmes.
This is in accordance with the proposal in Paragraph 16 of the
Workers' Housing Recommendation, 1961, that—
National mortgage insurance systems or public guarantees of private mortgages should be established as a means of promoting the building of workers'
housing in countries where a sound credit market exists and where such
systems are considered appropriate.
STABLE INTEREST RATES

In order to prevent delay in launching large-scale housing schemes
for families in the lower income groups, another measure that could be
taken to provide cheap finance is to stabilise interest charges for housebuilding schemes by co-operatives and other non-profit organisations.
These interest rates should be at a reasonable level, since otherwise the
reduction in building costs brought about by the use of co-operative
techniques, however substantial, may be cancelled out by higher interest
charges.
SUBSIDIES

This is not the place to consider whether or not developing countries
would be well advised to introduce a system of subsidies, to offset the

150

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

rising cost of building, reduce co-operative residents' monthly payments
equivalent to rent or help to meet the cost of special housing schemes for
large families or the elderly. Nevertheless, various economic factors
make it impossible to leave the provision of adequate housing for large
families in the lower income groups entirely to co-operative efforts and
even less to the building industry. There is undoubtedly a case for government subsidies to help individuals who otherwise could not afford to do
so to join co-operative housing schemes. In modern society adequate
housing is a social and economic necessity and, as long as incomes of the
worst-off section of the population do not increase, some form or other
of subsidies would appear to be fully warranted.
AGENTS OF SOCIAL POLICY

In principle, and according to the theory of co-operation, co-operatives are autonomous private societies, but in many countries they have
acted as agents of government social policy in the field of low-cost
housing. This has come about because they have shown that, in addition
to being technically and socially qualified private bodies, they are also
responsible and easily controlled by governments wishing to ensure that
public funds are well used and members' interests properly safeguarded.
The developing countries would therefore do very well to consider the
great opportunities afforded by the co-operative method in carrying
out a national housing policy. This presupposes mutual benefits
and responsibilities. In such cases it is reasonable that a government
department should approve a co-operative's rules and supervise its
operations in order to protect members' interests and the taxpayers'
money and to prevent possible speculation, although it should refrain
from interfering in the internal organisation of societies or handicapping
their operations with too much red tape. An unduly prolonged policy
of official paternalism may destroy the most significant contribution
that co-operation has to make, for it must always be borne in mind that
co-operatives are not a ready-made benefit but are evidence of people's
own efforts to promote the common good.
Financing
In principle, co-operatives are able to carry out their own programmes
without outside help, and they should in fact aim at being financially
self-supporting by use of their own resources and characteristic methods.
In the developing countries, however, if co-operatives really want to
make a significant contribution towards solving the housing problem

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

151

they will need financial help from outside, as wages are generally too
low for building operations to befinancedby members' savings.
Since co-operatives are non-profit bodies, private investors are not
normally interested, since they do not expect to receive an adequate
return for their money and may even fear its loss. Hence the principal
source of finance is the State, through its special banks or credit institutions. If co-operatives are held to fulfil an important social function,
there is every justification for the State to help low-income families by
investing public funds in programmes that cannot but be expensive.
And co-operative housing schemes can relieve the State of having to
carry the whole burden of a popular housing programme.
Naturally, the general principle must be observed that members
make some financial contribution, even limited, in order that operations
may begin. The most common forms of such contribution are the payment of an admission fee and the purchase of membership shares to
enable the society to build up capital.
Since neither of these methods can go the whole way, additional funds
have to be obtained in some way. In countries with a long history of
co-operative activity members have always been required to save every
week until they have accumulated sufficient to serve as a down payment
on their homes. Saving has always been encouraged by such co-operatives
and is now even an integral part of their building programmes.
Elsewhere modern savings and credit unions help low-income
families to pool their savings in order to finance house building. This
system, which is very simple to organise, serves not only to collect
members' savings but also to obtain additional resources through
provision of ordinary credit. In recent years this type of co-operative
has financed interesting co-operative housing projects with satisfactory
results in developing countries.1
The purpose of saving in this way is to enable the member to meet
the down payment, equal to a given percentage of the cost of constructing the dwelling allocated to him, the balance being paid in regular
monthly instalments to amortise the mortgage loan.
For long-termfinancingthe mortgage loan is definitely the system to
be preferred, whether on an individual or—as is more common—a
collective basis. It frequently happens, however, that, until building is
completed and the co-operative can obtain a proper mortgage loan, it
needs to be tided over by means of short-term loans. If a country really
1
The Workers' Housing Recommendation, 1961 states in Paragraphs 14 and 16
that governments and employers' and workers' organisations should stimulate the
creation of co-operatives and other non-profit associations and take appropriate action
to ensure that savings of both individuals and co-operatives may be used to finance
workers' housing projects.

152

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

wants to promote co-operative housing it would be well advised to
channel private funds earmarked for social purposes into short-term
housing loans. Such funds may come from unemployment insurance or
pension funds, provident or welfare schemes, either those of trade unions
or other non-profit organisations or those set up by public or private
undertakings for the benefit of their employees. The same funds might
also provide short-term loans to place the down payment within the
reach of many families who would otherwise find it impossible to
participate in co-operative programmes.
As regards the long-term financing, the co-operative must arrange a
mortgage on thè buildings concerned, but it might do well to consider a
system to examine members' financial situation, except in small communities where all the members know one another well.
In the same way, to provide against the possibility of economic crisis
or heavy unemployment in certain industries, it would be wise to ensure
that the residents in a particular project are not all employed in the same
industry. The experience of co-operative associations which found a
large proportion of their members unable to meet their commitments
during the depressed years of the 1930s is a lesson to be remembered.
Housing Co-operatives and the Building Industry
In the countries where co-operation is most highly developed
societies have grown from small-scale associations of individuals, who
pooled their scanty resources to acquire adequate housing for their
families, into large central organisations with their own subsidiaries
and a considerable influence on the building industry as a whole.
If, therefore, the developing countries wish to encourage co-operative
organisation as a way of speeding up the rate at which the demand for
housing is met, they should take steps, such as passing special legislation
and making credit facilities available, to enable housing co-operatives
to make the most efficient use of the resources of the building and allied
industries.
In the first place, although all housing co-operatives do not have to
be organised in the same way, any co-operative must have a clearly
defined, though not necessarily inflexible, structure. While a co-operative
society is an association of individuals, all of whom have the same duties
and the same rights, it is also an economic undertaking and must be
organised and managed as such. Moreover, if co-operatives are to
compete successfully with big contracting firms they must not only
develop better building techniques but—as has been emphasised earlier—

SUGGESTIONS FOR THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

153

they must form nation-wide organisations to co-ordinate their activities,
pool their resources, help member societies to benefit by each other's
experience and carry out bulk purchases, produce the materials they
need (depending on local circumstances), set up research centres and
laboratories to test materials and methods, and supply technical and
legal aid to member societies.
In addition, suitable measures must be taken as part of national
housing policies to put a stop to any restrictive practices by certain
building contractors, materials suppliers and other sections of the
building industry. Where there is a shortage of building materials, tools
and equipment, it would be as well to consider granting co-operatives
priority in building factories to produce the articles in short supply and
in importing any equipment that may be necessary for the purpose.
In countries where there are already building co-operatives and
building workers' co-operatives, the two types of organisation should
co-ordinate their activities and even make joint arrangements to test
new building methods and materials. This in turn would lead to better
planning and organisation, greater standardisation of materials and
simplification of traditional working methods.
Housing co-operatives in the developing countries should also
organise training in the building trades. Building workers' co-operatives
have particular interest in providing programmes for skilled and semiskilled grades such as managers, architects, engineers and supervisors.
One major achievement of the co-operative movement in general
—and one which should be borne in mind in establishing or overhauling a
country's housing policy—is that it has taken the lead in setting minimum
standards for the housing of its members and their families and, in the
process, so far from increasing has actually reduced building costs.
Co-operatives in developing countries have been noteworthy for their
insistence on providing such essential services as running water, sanitary
facilities and sewerage in low-income family projects.
Model Urban and Rural Neighbourhood Communities
In formulating their national housing policies, governments should
bear in mind that co-operation is not simply a way of helping members
to acquire new homes, but is also a movement with a programme which
ranges from teaching members to make good use of their homes to
founding communities with all the services they need.
Co-operatives are in the best position to build model housing estates
and neighbourhood communities. Co-operative building is the product

154

HOUSING CO-OPERATIVES

of teamwork, in which the future residents are able to incorporate their
ideals and desires. As a result, such housing schemes usually not only
form a well-planned whole, but constitute neighbourhoods with their
own community spirit, fostered by constant social contacts made in the
course of co-operative activities.
Even in the large cities co-operatives can serve as a nucleus for a new
community spirit. The social life they organise among members, and
the ancillary services which are usually provided on housing projects,
such as consumer and credit co-operatives, kindergartens, schools,
public transport, playing fields, recreation rooms and lecture halls, can
all serve as a nucleus for a new pattern of society, as the projects
described in Chapter X so clearly show.
Another role that can be played by co-operatives is to help in the
resettlement of refugees by building projects near workplaces, as
described in Chapter VI.
Although housing co-operatives have tended to be most popular in
urban areas, their methods and principles are also applicable, at least to a
large extent, in rural districts, especially when small isolated associations
of farmers federate to form a central body which can give them efficient
technical and financial services.
Within the broader national perspective two primary considerations
should guide the planning and construction of large-scale housing
projects. Firstly, major housing schemes should normally be sited fairly
close to places of employment. If communal services are not already
available in the district, provision must be made for schools, shopping
centres, recreation facilities for residents of all ages, places of worship
and medical services, enabling workers and their families to live in welllaid-out residential districts. Secondly, the need to relieve congestion
in the cities calls for a policy of urban decentralisation involving the
construction of satellite or new towns, which can attract some sections of
industry and commerce out of the large cities. In planning and carrying
out programmes of this type the co-operative movement's great fund of
experience can be adapted to local conditions for the benefit of the
developing countries.