I N T E R N A T I O N A L LABOUR OFFICE INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION 1945-1957 GENEVA 1959 STUDIES AND REPORTS New Series, No. 54 b^. PRINTED BY "LA TRIBUNE DE GENÈVE", GENEVA, SWITZERLAND CONTENTS Page INTRODUCTION 1 PART O N E POLITICAL MIGRATION CHAPTER I. National Refugees in Germany General Historical Review The Integration of Refugees in the Economy of the Federal Republic of Germany The Nature of the Problem Integration, Economic Policy and Social Policy Progress of Integration since 1946 Consequences of the Influx Demographic Consequences Economic Consequences Social Consequences Conclusions 7 7 11 12 15 20 25 25 28 30 33 The Integration of Refugees in the German Democratic Republic . . . . Scope of the Problem Aid to the Refugees and Their Integration in the Economy The Consequences of Immigration 34 34 37 40 Bibliographical References 40 CHAPTER II. Other Population Shifts in Europe Refugees and Displaced Persons General Survey International Action: U.N.R.R.A., the I.R.O., the U.N.H.C.R. and I.C.E.M Relief, Assistance and Legal Protection Voluntary Repatriation Resettlement Settlement in Countries of Asylum Conclusion National Refugees in Italy, Finland and Turkey Italy Finland Turkey 43 43 43 45 48 49 49 53 56 57 57 57 60 IV INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Transfers and Repatriations in Eastern Europe Nature and Scope of the Various Movements Poland Other Countries Transfer and Resettlement Arrangements Consequences Bibliographical References CHAPTER III. Immigration into Israel Background and Data Background Data Demographic Features Breakdown by Country of Origin Social and Economic Data Absorbing the Immigrants General Foreign Aid Investment, Full Employment and Inflation Economic Trends from 1948 to 1957 From 1948 to 1951 : Suppressed Demand Inflation 1952: The Change from Suppressed Demand Inflation to Cost Inflation From 1953 to 1957: Towards Economic and Financial Stability . . . Arrangements for the Integration of Immigrants Immigration Results Settlement of the Country Economic Expansion Distribution of Income Conclusion Bibliographical References CHAPTER IV. Population Shifts in Asia and the Middle East 61 61 62 64 66 68 70 72 72 72 76 76 77 79 81 81 83 85 86 86 88 89 90 94 94 95 97 98 98 100 The Palestine Arab Refugees Background Statistical Data Relief and Assistance Integration Plans 101 101 102 105 107 Population Movements between India and Pakistan Historical Survey 108 108 Consequences of the Population Shifts Demographic Consequences Economic and Social Consequences 109 Ill 113 Government Action India Pakistan 117 117 119 CONTENTS V Page Population Movements in the Far East Repatriation of Japanese Repatriates and Refugees in South Korea Chinese Refugees in Hong Kong and Formosa Refugees in South Viet-Nam Bibliographical References 120 120 124 126 129 130 PART TWO ECONOMIC MIGRATION SECTION A. MAJOR POST-WAR CURRENTS 135 CHAPTER V. Continental Movements Europe Sweden United Kingdom Belgium France Switzerland Other Countries Conclusions The Americas United States Immigration Emigration Latin America Africa Asia and Oceania Bibliographical References 137 137 138 139 142 145 148 150 150 151 151 151 153 155 157 160 163 CHAPTER VI. Intercontinental Movements European Emigration General Countries of Origin North-western Europe United Kingdom Netherlands Secondary Emigration Countries Central Europe Federal Republic of Germany Austria and Switzerland Southern Europe Italy Spain Portugal Malta Greece 164 164 164 169 169 169 173 176 178 178 180 181 183 185 185 187 187 VI INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Countries of Destination United States and Canada United States Canada Latin America Argentina Brazil Venezuela Other Countries Africa Asia Australia and New Zealand Australia New Zealand Conclusion 188 188 188 191 192 192 194 195 197 198 201 201 201 204 204 Other Intercontinental Movements 205 Bibliographical References 207 SECTION B. ECONOMIC MIGRATION FACTORS 211 CHAPTER VII. Laws and Regulations 212 Emigration Laws Immigration Laws Western Europe United States and Canada United States Canada Latin America Africa West and South-east Asia Australia and New Zealand Bibliographical References CHAPTER VIII. The Labour Demand and Supply throughout the World . . . 212 214 214 217 218 220 222 ' 225 227 228 230 231 The Demand for Labour General Europe United States and Canada United States Canada Latin America Africa and Asia Australia and New Zealand 231 231 233 237 237 239 241 245 247 The Labour Supply General The Factors of Emigration Overpopulation and Emigration in Europe Overpopulation and Emigration outside Europe 249 249 250 255 261 CONTENTS VII Page Conclusion Bibliographical References CHAPTER IX. Organised and Assisted Migration 263 265 268 National Machinery 268 Emigration Countries Administrative Structure of Emigration Services Work of Emigration Services Immigration Countries Administrative Structure of Immigration Services Work of Immigration Services Bilateral and Multilateral Agreements Treaties Migration and Recruiting Agreements Social Security Agreements 268 269 271 275 276 281 285 285 286 289 Intergovernmental Organisations The Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration The United Nations and Its Specialised Agencies European Regional Organisations 290 292 296 299 Non-Governmental Organisations Employers' and Workers' Organisations Voluntary Organisations 300 300 301 Bibliographical References 302 SECTION C. EFFECTS O F ECONOMIC M I G R A T I O N CHAPTER X. Demographic Effects 303 303 Effects on the Size of the Population Analysis by Continent Analysis by Country European Countries American Countries Countries of Africa Countries of Asia Australia and New Zealand 303 303 305 305 307 309 311 312 Effects on the Age Structure and Sex Distribution of the Population . . . Effects on Age Structure Countries with an Emigration Surplus Ireland and Malta Italy and Portugal Other Countries Countries with an Immigration Surplus European Countries American Countries Other Countries Effects on Sex Distribution 313 312 313 313 315 317 318 318 319 321 323 Effects on Natural Population Trends 331 Vili INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Effects on the Labour Force 334 Countries with an Emigration Surplus 335 Europe United Kingdom Ireland Netherlands Federal Republic of Germany Italy Spain and Portugal Malta and Greece Non-European Countries Countries with an Immigration Surplus 335 335 339 339 341 342 343 345 346 347 Europe Sweden Belgium France Switzerland 347 347 348 350 352 The Americas Canada United States Argentina Other Countries 353 353 355 356 357 Africa 358 Australia and New Zealand 360 Bibliographical References 361 CHAPTER XI. Economic and Social Effects 362 Effects on Emigration Countries General Effects on Overpopulated Countries Effects on Countries with Full Employment 363 363 366 376 Effects on Immigration Countries General Western Europe United States and Canada Latin America Africa Australia and New Zealand 378 378 381 383 386 388 390 Effects on the Migrants General The Problem of Settlement Occupational Integration of the Migrants Bibliographical References CONCLUSIONS • • • 393 393 393 404 408 410 CONTENTS IX LIST OF TABLES Page Table 1. Germany: Expellee Population on 29 October 1946 Table 2. Western Germany: National Refugee Population, 1946-57 . . . . Table 3. Federal Republic of Germany: Net Immigration, 1950-57 Table 4. Western Germany: Distribution of Refugees by Region between 29 October 1946 and 31 December 1957 Table 5. Western Germany: Size of the Civilian Labour Force, 1946-57 . . Table 6. Western Germany: Employment and Unemployment (Wage Earners and Salaried Employees), 1948-57 Table 7. Western Germany: Employment and Unemployment (Wage Earners and Salaried Employees) on 30 June 1948 and 30 June 1950 Table 8. Federal Republic of Germany : Comparative Breakdown of the Labour Force by Occupational Status (Expellees and Remainder of the Population), on 13 September 1950 Table 9. Federal Republic of Germany: Comparative Unemployment Data for Expellees and Total Population, 1950-57 Table 10. Federal Republic of Germany: Comparative Breakdown by Age Groups of Expellees and Remainder of the Population on 13 September 1950 Table 11. Federal Republic of Germany: Percentage of Males to Females in the Various Age Groups (Expellees and Remainder of the Population) on 13 September 1950 8 9 10 11 17 17 21 22 23 26 27 Table 12. Federal Republic of Germany: Comparative Birth and Infant Mortality Rates (Expellees and Population as a Whole), 1950-56 . . . . Table 13. Federal Republic of Germany: Expellee Manual Workers Employed on 13 September 1950, by Industry Table 14. Federal Republic of Germany: Type of Housing Occupied and Status of Occupants (Expellees and Population as a Whole) on 13 September 1950 32 Table 15. Federal Republic of Germany: Occupation Density in Normal Housing Accommodation (Expellees and Population as a Whole) on 13 September 1950 32 28 31 Table 16. Eastern Germany: Comparative Breakdown, by Age Groups, of the Population on 29 October 1946 Table 17. Eastern Germany: Percentage of Males to Females in the Various Age Groups (Expellees and Remainder of Population) on 29 October 1946 Table 18. German Democratic Republic: Estimated Breakdown, by Age and Sex, of the Population in 1956 36 35 36 Table 19. Summary of I.R.O. Operations, 1947-51 47 Table 20. Refugees Resettled by the I.R.O., by Country of Departure, 1947-51 50 Table 21. Refugees Resettled by the I.R.O., by Country of Destination, 1947-51 Table 22. Refugees Presumed to Be Covered by the High Commissioner's Mandate Resettled under the Auspices of I.C.E.M. between 1 February 1952 and 31 December 1957 51 Table 23. Israel: Jewish Immigration, by Country of Birth, 1946-57 . . . . 74 Table 24. Israel: Breakdown by Age of the Jewish Population on 8 November 1948 and 31 December 1957 and of Immigration between 1948 and 1957 77 52 X INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Table 25. Israel: Breakdown by Sex of the Jewish Population, on 8 November 1948 and 31 December 1957 Table 26. Israel: Jewish Population, by Country of Birth, on 8 November 1948 and 31 December 1957 Table 27. Israel: Immigrants by Occupation in Country of Origin, 1950-57 Table 28. Israel: Balance of Payments, 1950-56 Table 29. Israel: Gross Investment by Branch of the Economy, 1949-56 . . Table 30 : Israel : Distribution of the Jewish Population by Area on 8 November 1948 and 31 December 1957 Table 31. Israel: Comparative Trends in the Jewish Population of the Countryside, Major Cities and Other Urban Areas, 1948-57 Table 32. Israel: Jewish Employed Persons, by Branch of the Economy, in November 1948 and June 1957 Table 33. Former Arab Population of Palestine, by Country of Residence, in September 1949 Table 34. Refugees Registered with U.N.R.W.A., by Year and Country of Residence, 1950-57 (Figures on 30 June) Table 35. Breakdown of Economically Active Palestine Arab Refugees by Previous Occupation, 1951 Table 36. India: Breakdown of Refugees by Area, 1951 Table 37. Pakistan: Breakdown of Refugees by Area, 1951 Table 38. India: Occupational Breakdown of the Refugee and Local Population, 1951 Table 39. Pakistan: Breakdown by Occupational Status of the Refugee and Local Populations, 1951 Table 40. India: Expenditure by the Government on Displaced Persons, 1947/48 to 1957/58 Table 41. India: Credits for Integration of Displaced Persons under the Second Five-Year Plan, 1956-61 Table 42. Japan: Repatriates, by Country of Departure and Civilian or Military Status, 1945-56 Table 43. Hong Kong: Estimated Population Growth from 1 September 1945 to 30 June 1954 Table 44. Sweden : Migration to and from the Rest of Europe, by Countries of Origin and Destination, 1946-57 Table 45. United Kingdom: Net Immigration of Nationals of European Countries, by Nationality, 1946-57 Table 46. United Kingdom: European Workers Admitted under Group Recruitment Schemes or Individual Permits, 1946-57 Table 47. United Kingdom: Arrivals from and Departures to the Republic of Ireland, 1946-57 Table 48. Belgium: Migration of Aliens to and from Other European Countries, 1948-57 Table 49. France: Permanent Immigration of Workers and Their Families, by Nationality, 1946-57 Table 50. France: Seasonal Immigration, by Country of Origin, 1946-57 . . Table 51. Switzerland: Residence Permits Issued for the First Time to Foreigners Authorised to Take up Employment, by Type of Permit and Nationality, 1946-57 78 78 80 84 86 94 95 96 102 103 104 110 Ill 114 115 117 119 121 127 138 140 141 142 143 146 146 148 CONTENTS XI Page Table 52. Switzerland: Foreign Workers Subject to Employment Restrictions, by Nationality, 1949-58 Table 53. United States: Migration to and from the Rest of the American Continent, 1946-57 Table 54. United States : Immigrant Farm Workers Admitted into the Country, by Country of Origin, 1946-57 Table 55. Canada: Immigration from the United States, 1946-57 Table 56. United States : Movements of United States Citizens to and from Venezuela, 1950-56 Table 57. Argentina: Net Immigration of Nationals of Other South American Countries, by Nationality, 1946-57 Table 58. Venezuela: Migration by Nationals of Other Latin American Countries, by Nationality, 1950-57 Table 59. Union of South Africa: Migration of Europeans to and from the Rest of the African Continent, 1946-57 Table 60. India: Official Movements to and Returns from Other Asian Countries, 1946-56 Table 61. Migration between Australia and New Zealand, 1946-57 . . . . Table 62. Gross Emigration from Europe, 1946-57 Table 63. European Emigration by Region, 1946-57 Table 64. Distribution of European Emigration by Major European Region, by Two-Year Periods, 1946-57 Table 65. Distribution of European Emigrants by Continent of Destination, 1946-57 Table 66. Gross and Net Emigration from Nine European Emigration Countries, 1946-57 Table 67. United Kingdom: Intercontinental Emigration and Immigration, by Countries of Destination and Origin, 1946-57 Table 68. United Kingdom: Emigration by Major Country of Destination, 1946-57 (Comparison between the United Kingdom Figures and Those Compiled by Immigration Countries) Table 69. Netherlands: Intercontinental Emigration and Immigration, by Continents and Countries of Destination and Origin, 1946-57 Table 70. Netherlands: Emigration, by Major Country of Destination, 1948-57 (Comparison between Netherlands Statistics and Those Compiled by Immigration Countries) Table 71. Federal Republic of Germany: German Overseas Emigration, by Country of Destination, 1946-57 Table 72. Federal Republic of Germany: Non-German Refugees Emigrating Overseas, by Country of Destination, 1947-51 Table 73. Refugees Resettled by the I.R.O. in Countries outside Europe (Excluding Israel), by Nationalities and Country of Destination, 1947-51 Table 74. Italy: Intercontinental Emigration and Immigration, by Countries of Destination and Origin, 1946-57 Table 75. Italy: Emigration by Major Country of Destination, 1946-57 (Comparison between Italian Statistics and Those Published by Immigration Countries) Table 76. Spain: Overseas Emigration and Immigration, by Countries of Destination and Origin, 1956-57 149 152 154 154 155 156 157 159 160 162 165 167 167 168 169 170 173 174 176 179 180 181 182 183 184 XII INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Table 77. Portugal: Overseas Emigration and Immigration, by Countries of Destination and Origin, 1946-57 Table 78. Malta: Annual Overseas Emigration, 1946-57 Table 79. United States: Migration from and to Europe, by Countries of Origin and Destination, 1946-57 Table 80. United States: European Immigration from 1 July 1945 to 30 June 1957, by Country of Birth Table 81. Canada: European Immigration, by Country of Origin, 1946-57 . Table 82. Argentina: Migration from and to Europe, by Nationality, 1946-57 Table 83. Argentina: Comparison between Statistics of Passenger Arrivals by Sea (Second and Third Class) and Number of Immigrants Intending to Settle, 1946-57 Table 84. Brazil: Immigration from Europe, by Nationality, 1946-57 . . . Table 85. Venezuela: Migration from and to Europe, by Nationality, 1950-57 Table 86. Uruguay: European Immigration, by Nationality, 1948-56 . . . . Table 87. Union of South Africa: Migration from and to Europe, by Countries of Origin and Destination, 1946-57 Table 88. Australia : Migration from and to Europe, by Countries of Origin and Destination, 1946-57 Table 89. New Zealand: Migration from and to Europe, 1946-57 Table 90. Migration from Far Eastern Countries to the Four Major Immigration Countries in the Americas and to Australia, 1946-57 Table 91. Migrants Moved with I.C.E.M. Assistance, by Countries of Origin and Destination, 1952-57 Table 92. World Population, by Continent, in 1946 and 1957, and Balance of Intercontinental Migration in the Intervening Period Table 93. Population Growth and Net Immigration for 17 European Countries, 1946-57 Table 94. Population Growth and Net Immigration for Eight American Countries, 1946-57 Table 95. Australia and New Zealand: Population Growth and Net Immigration, 1946-57 Table 96. Italy: Age Distribution of the Population in 1951 and of Overseas Emigration and Immigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 97. Portugal: Age Distribution of the Population in 1949 and of Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 98. Netherlands: Age Distribution of the Population in 1950 and of Emigration and Immigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 99. United Kingdom: Age Distribution of the Population in 1950 and of Overseas Emigration and Immigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 100. Sweden: Age Distribution of the Population in 1950 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 101. Canada : Age Structure of the Population in 1951 and of Immigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 102. United States: Age Structure of the Population in 1950 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 103. Argentina : Age Structure of the Population in 1947 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 186 188 189 190 191 193 194 194 196 197 199 202 203 207 295 304 305 308 312 315 316 317 317 319 320 321 321 CONTENTS XIII Page Table 104. Union of South Africa: Age Structure of the Population in 1950 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 105. Australia: Age Structure of the Population in 1951 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 106. New Zealand: Age Structure of the Population in 1951 and of Immigration and Emigration from 1946 to 1957 Table 107. Emigration Countries: Sex Distribution of Adult Migrants during the Post-War Period Table 108. Immigration Countries: Sex Distribution of Adult Migrants during the Post-War Period Table 109. Canada: Distribution of Immigrants by Sex, 1946-57 Table 110. Australia: Distribution of Immigrants by Sex, 1946-57 Table 111. United Kingdom: Distribution of Overseas Emigrants by Sex, 1946-57 Table 112. United Kingdom: Overseas Emigration and Immigration (by Sea), by Occupation and Sex, 1946-49 Table 113. United Kingdom: Overseas Emigration and Immigration (by Sea), by Occupation and Sex, 1951-57 Table 114. United Kingdom: European Immigrants Recruited Collectively under Official Programmes, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 115. United Kingdom: Individual Employment Permits Issued to Foreign Workers, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 116. Netherlands: Emigration and Immigration, by Occupation and Sex, 1948-57 Table 117. Federal Republic of Germany: Emigration, by Occupation and Sex, 1953-57 Table 118. Italy: Overseas Emigration and Immigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 119. Spain: Overseas Emigration and Immigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 120. Portugal: Emigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 121. Sweden: Aliens in Employment on 1 January 1947 and 1 January 1958, by Occupation Table 122. Belgium: Immigration and Emigration, by Occupation, 1948-57 . Table 123. France: Alien Workers Placed in Employment by the National Immigration Office, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 124. Switzerland: Foreign Workers Subject to Employment Restrictions in 1950 and 1958, by Occupation Table 125. Switzerland: Employment Permits Issued to Seasonal Workers in 1949, 1952, 1954 and 1957, by Occupation 353 Table 126. Canada: Immigration, by Occupation, 1946-52 354 Table 127. Canada: Immigration, by Occupation, 1953-57 Table 128. United States: Foreign Immigration and Emigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 Table 129. Argentina: Immigration and Emigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 355 356 357 Table 130. Brazil: Immigration, by Occupation, 1946-50 and 1953-57 . . . . 358 Table 131. Union of South Africa: Immigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 . . 359 322 322 323 325 326 328 328 330 336 337 338 338 340 341 342 344 345 348 349 350 352 XIV INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Page Table Table Table Table 132. Australia: Immigration and Emigration, by Occupation, 1947-57 133. New Zealand: Immigration and Emigration, by Occupation, 1946-57 134. Italy: Savings Remitted by Italian Emigrants, 1946-55 135. Greece: Savings Remitted by Greek Emigrants, 1948-57 . . . . 360 361 368 371 INTRODUCTION Since the end of the Second World War, migratory movements on a quite unprecedented scale have taken place throughout the world. Millions of people have been driven from their homes and the population structure of entire countries radically altered. Political upheavals involving the redrawing of frontiers, transfers of sovereignty and changes of regime have forced entire populations into exile and caused mass movements far in excess of those normally resulting from supply and demand on the world employment market. Thus a characteristic feature of migratory currents during this period, apart from their size, has been the existence of political, as distinguished from economic, migration movements. This fundamental distinction, on which the over-all plan of this study is based, is not simply a matter of form. It stems from a basic difference between the two phenomena, in cause and effect as well as in pattern. The political movements were the product of exceptional circumstances and in most cases were sweeping and precipitate, their momentum quickly spent. Economic migration currents, on the other hand, have tended to flow fairly steadily in fixed channels. Whereas individual choice has played only a very small part in the former, which were usually the result of threats or coercion, it has been a decisive factor in the latter, which were the voluntary, if not always spontaneous, expression of a desire for better conditions. Moreover, the former have usually affected entire groups of human beings who were uprooted for good, whereas the latter have largely involved young adults, often only temporarily. In many ways the two types of migration have had opposite effects. Political migration has often exerted a disrupting influence on the economies of the countries where it originated, while in receiving countries it has led, at least in the short run, to heavier expenditure, unemployment and inflationary pressures. Economic migration, on the other hand, has benefited both emigration and immigration countries by providing an outlet for the energies of millions of men. Whereas the refugees have often been forced down the occupational and social ladder, the migrant worker has usually been able to better his lot. On the other hand, the former have usually been absorbed in a community 2 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 with the same language and traditions and have thus been spared difficulties of assimilation often experienced by the latter. The distinction between political and economic migrations therefore has a very real basis in fact. Nevertheless, the dividing line is not always hard and fast. In some instances, economic migratory movements have been swollen by groups of persons migrating for essentially political reasons. Many refugees, in re-emigrating from the countries where they first found asylum, have been concerned as much with personal security as with higher living standards ; some receiving countries have accepted on humanitarian grounds more refugees than, strictly speaking, they need have done ; and events such as the Korean war and the international tension which accompanied it probably helped to increase European emigration in 1951-52. Conversely, economic factors have sometimes reinforced political migration currents, as in the case of the recent influx from Eastern into Western Germany. These necessary qualifications, however, do not detract from the validity of the basic distinction between migration in which material interest plays little or no part and that in which it is the decisive factor. Of course the term " economic migration " must be understood as applying not only to the migrant workers themselves but also to members of their families accompanying or rejoining them, as well as to persons travelling abroad for the purpose of marriage. It may be added that the distinction between the two types of movements—political and economic—is usually reflected in national statistics. A country which first gives refugees asylum usually registers them as such and not as immigrants. Furthermore, they are generally counted at a later stage and not on arrival as is the usual rule with migrants. It may be thought surprising that the latter type of movement should have been dealt with more fully in this report than the former, despite the fact that far fewer people have been involved. There are a number of reasons for this. One is that, while political migration phenomena, taken as a whole, have been on a larger scale, they have also been more localised. Another is that they have not, by and large, raised any problems of legal protection, since the migrants have usually obtained (where they did not already possess) the nationality of the receiving country. A final reason is that these movements are largely a thing of the past, whereas migration by workers constitutes a permanent feature of the world's economy and as such gives rise to permanent, structural problems of the kind in which the International Labour Organisation has a constitutional interest. This reason alone, in a study which sets out not only to relate facts but also to draw certain conclusions likely to afford useful guidance for the future, warrants giving them more attention than INTRODUCTION 3 to sporadic events whose most immediate effects are hardly felt any more. On the other hand, political migration phenomena are of interest in so fas as they illustrate the impact which population transfers not due to the normal operation of supply and demand on the international employment market can have in such areas as national development, employment, wages and public finance. Although this study is largely concerned with the factual aspects of the subject, it is realised that facts and figures by themselves mean very little : they must be explained and, so far as possible, fitted into a coherent pattern. This accounts for the considerable attention given to detailed statistical analysis. The entire work has been designed to reflect this dual preoccupation, both in detail and in broad outline. The first part deals with political migration, considered chiefly from the standpoint of its consequences, and primarily with the two best-known examples : Western Germany and Israel. The second part deals with economic migration and is divided into three sections. The first of these contains a general statistical review of the various movements ; the second discusses their underlying reasons, both economic and non-economic; and the third attempts to weigh up their demographic, economic and social consequences. The conclusion sets out a few principles based on recent experience which, it is hoped, can afford useful guidance in framing national and international policy. Extensive use has been made throughout the study of unpublished I.L.O. material. Many of the statistical data in particular have been obtained from the replies of countries to the annual questionnaire sent out by the Office in preparation for the publication of the Year Book of Labour Statistics.1 The source material used in the preparation of the study is listed for reference purposes at the end of the various chapters. 1 As regards the presentation of statistical data throughout this study, the figures given in the various tables have, as a rule, been rounded off on the basis of the exact figures given in the sources. This includes the totals which, as a result, may not in all cases represent the exact sum of the rounded-off figures. PART ONE POLITICAL MIGRATION ñ CHAPTER I NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY The heaviest political migration movements of the post-war period have taken place in Germany, which has had to find room within its shrunken frontiers for more than 12.5 million refugees from the lost eastern provinces or from abroad. This immense westward shift of the German people, which has revolutionised the ethnic map of Central Europe, has been not only one of the most important demographic results of the Second World War but a landmark in German history as well. The resulting problems of adjustment have literally dominated the country's economic and social life during the 12 years following the end of the war, and only now is the final solution within sight. General Historical Review The surrender of Germany in the spring of 1945 was followed by the dismemberment of its pre-war territory, the eastern provinces being divided up between Poland and the Soviet Union. Simultaneously, the Allied Powers decided to transfer within the new frontiers all peoples of German stock still living outside them. This decision, which was embodied in Article XIII of the Potsdam Agreement (2 August 1945), also by implication forbade all Germans from the territories whose evacuation had been ordered, and who had left them before the end of the war, to return to their former homes. It affected virtually the entire population of the former eastern provinces, together with the German minorities in Czechoslovakia, Hungary and pre-war Poland. During 1946 mass transfers took place in accordance with a plan drawn up by the Allied authorities. Of the 9.5 million " expellees " (Heimatvertriebene) on German soil when a census was held on 29 October 1946 1 1 The census did not cover displaced persons being cared for by the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration. For the purposes of the 1946 and subsequent censuses in Western Germany, expellees were defined as Germanspeaking persons who before 1 September 1939 lived in the German provinces located east of the Oder-Neisse line, in the Saar, or abroad. This definition therefore covers a wider segment of the population than the persons transferred under the Allied plan. Thus it includes some persons of German ethnic origin who were transferred to what is now German territory between 1939 and 1943 under agreements between the Government of the Reich and the governments of the countries concerned. It also covers Germans living abroad who went back to Germany of their own free will after the outbreak of hostilities. The expellees also include children born of expelled fathers in Western Germany. INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 some two-thirds were there as a result of this transfer plan, which by that time had been virtually completed, and the others, whether servicemen or civilian refugees, were persons who in one way or another had left their homes before the plan was put into operation. Table 1 gives the breakdown of the expellees by areas of origin and resettlement. TABLE 1. GERMANY: EXPELLEE POPULATION ON 29 OCTOBER 1946 (In thousands) Zone of resettlement Area of origin 1 British American French Soviet Berlin Total Czechoslovakia . . . . Former East German provinces Poland Rumania Soviet U n i o n 2 . . . . Other 78 1,466 8 841 4 2,397 2,453 215 37 87 212 750 66 68 40 381 37 8 3 7 31 2,274 246 57 57 126 92 9 1 3 11 5,606 544 166 195 762 Total . . . 3,082 2,771 95 3,602 120 9,670 3 1 By place of birth. origin. ! Including the Baltic States. 'Including 13,000 expellees of unknown By this time the proportion of expellees to the total population (64 million) was already 15 per cent. ; it was highest in the Soviet zone (20.8 per cent.) and lowest in the French zone (1.9 per cent.). The distribution of the different groups of expellees among the occupation zones was largely dictated by the Allied transfer plan, whereby the population of the territories beyond the Oder-Neisse line were to be sent to the Soviet and British zones and the majority of the Sudeten Germans to the American zone. But this plan itself merely conformed to the facts of geography and many spontaneous transfers followed the same pattern. In the three Western occupation zones as a whole, where the number of expellees was already of the order of 6 million, the census held on 29 October 1946 showed that there were in addition more than 1 million persons from the Soviet occupation zone or from Berlin (most of whom did not go back). These formed the nucleus of the second group of national refugees, known in Western Germany as " transmigrants " (Zugewanderte). Needless to say, this huge influx, taking place within a mere two years, represented a crushing burden for the devastated German economy. Moreover, the burden was not equally distributed within each of the 9 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY occupation zones. The rural districts which had been largely spared by the war contained the majority of the voluntary refugees and they were also designated by the Allied authorities as reception areas for the bulk of the populations transferred on their orders, with the result that some of these areas, particularly Schleswig-Holstein and Mecklemburg, were literally swamped with refugees by the end of 1946. Thus the territory which later was to become the Federal Republic of Germany had by this date received 7 million national refugees and the future German Democratic Republic more than 3.5 million. By the end of 1957 the former had received a further 4.5 million refugees and the latter at least 1 million. But East Germany lost a substantial proportion of its refugee population by emigration to Western Germany, with the result that its total population reached its peak around 1949, whereas that of Western Germany continued to mount steadily. While the demographic position has thus undergone far-reaching changes since 1946, it is unfortunately impossible to gauge them with any accuracy for Germany as a whole, owing to the inadequacy of the statistics available for Eastern Germany. Although by the end of 1946 the three Western occupation zones had received the bulk of the expellees assigned to them under the Allied plan, the influx of national refugees of both types has gone on until the present day. In the middle of 1948 their total number was a little over 8 million; by the end of 1950 it was 9.5 million; and by the end of 1957 it exceeded 12 million. Table 2 shows the different stages of this steep rise (which, of course, includes also the natural population increase since the end of 1946). This increase was due to a whole series of different movements, namely the final transfers under the Allied plan; the repatriation of refugees who had found temporary asylum in Denmark; the return of prisoners of war; and, above all, the arrival of expellees who had originally settled in the Eastern zone or of migrants from that zone or from TABLE 2. WESTERN GERMANY 1 : NATIONAL REFUGEE POPULATION, 1946-57 (In thousands) 29 October 1946 s 1 July 1948 13 September 1950» 1 July 1952 1 July 1956 31 December 1957 . . 5,963 6,997 7,876 8,175 8,656 9,148 Transmigrants 1,021 1,188 1,555 1,819 2,474 3,029 Total . . . 6,984 8,185 9,431 9,994 11,130 12,177 Group Expellees 1 Not including West Berlin and the Saar. ' General censuses. 10 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 3. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY 1950-57 1 (In thousands) Origin 1950 1951 1952 1953 Berlin2 Soviet zone . . . Saar Former East German provinces . Foreign countries . Prisoners of war . Miscellaneous. . . 25.8 217.0 0.6 37.4 172.8 -0.8 68.4 98.1 -0.4 164.8 185.8 1.8 Total . . . 379.1 NET IMMIGRATION, 1954 63.4 1956 1957 48.5 60.1 77.7 56.3 184.1 242.7 247.4 255.2 2.2 3.1 3.5 — 18.8 7.1 1.3 1.4 0.9 18.0 -37.7 -43.5 -15.5 -20.8 53.4 2.8 5.6 4.1 — 45.5 -44.0 -60.5 5.0 2.3 137.5 1955 348.8 221.1 1.5 -5.7 7.4 1.6 12.8 -6.0 2.8 1.2 76.3 27.7 0.2 1.0 310.9 329.4 416.6 1 The figures refer to all migrants whether Germans or foreign nationals and whether refugees of others. The negative balance shown for foreign countries between 1951 and 1956 is due to the growth or emigration, but this does not mean that the influx of refugees from Eastern Europe completely ceased during these years. * Including East Berlin. Berlin. This latter movement accounts for the bulk of immigration to the Federal Republic since 1950, as shown by table 3. In addition to growing substantially since 1946, the refugee population in Western Germany has also changed its geographical distribution (table 4). Schleswig-Holstein, Lower Saxony and Bavaria, which at the end of 1946 accommodated two-thirds of the refugee population, had little more than two-fifths by the end of 1957. The share of the North Rhine-Westphalia area, on the other hand, more than doubled between these years, rising from 12.4 to 27.5 per cent. The maldistribution of the early years, which was due to the abnormal conditions of the immediate post-war period, has gradually given way to a pattern more in line with both the possibilities and the needs of the economy. Even so, the refugee population is still far from evenly distributed. On 31 December 1957 it represented 23.9 per cent, of the total population for the Federal Republic as a whole (as against 15.9 per cent, on 29 October 1946), as compared with 35 per cent, in Schleswig-Holstein, 34 per cent, in Lower Saxony and only 13 per cent, in the RhinelandPalatinate. There are no statistics which give an equally precise picture of the situation with respect to expellees in Eastern Germany.1 However, by 1 For a discussion of this problem see P. H. SERAPHIM: Die Heimatvertriebenen in der Sowjetzone, Schriften des Vereins für Sozialpolitik, Neue Folge, 7/1 (Berlin, Duncker & Humblot, 1954), pp. 61 ff. See also G. IPSEN: " Die Bevölkerung Mittelund Westdeutschlands bis 1955 ", in Informationen (Bonn, Institut für Raumforschung), No. 27-29/54, 2 July 1954. 11 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY TABLE 4. WESTERN GERMANY x : DISTRIBUTION OF REFUGEES BY REGION BETWEEN 29 OCTOBER 1946 AND 31 DECEMBER 1957 (In thousands) On 29 October 1946 On 31 December 1957 ExTranspellees migrants Total TransExPercentage Abpellees migrants Absolute Percentage of over-all solute of over-all figures total figures total 845 63 1,493 26 714 537 49 575 1,662 127 36 291 11 153 99 16 83 204 972 99 1,784 37 867 636 65 658 1,866 13.9 1.4 25.6 0.5 12.4 9.1 0.9 9.4 26.8 638 238 1,663 98 2,340 845 282 1,288 1,756 141 150 465 49 1,014 321 144 415 330 779 388 2,128 147 3,354 1,166 426 1,703 2,086 6.4 3.2 17.5 1.2 27.5 9.6 3.5 14.0 17.1 5,963 1,021 6,984 100.0 9,148 3,029 12,177 100.O Total Region Schleswig-Holstein. . . Hamburg Lower Saxony Bremen North Rhine-Westphalia Hesse Rhineland-Palatinate . Baden-Württemberg . . Bavaria . . . . Total . . . 1 Not including the Saar. drawing on various sources it can be concluded that the number of expellees (referred to in Eastern Germany as Umsiedler) rose sharply until 1949 and then levelled off or even fell slightly. Until 1949 direct immigrants from the evacuated territories and returning prisoners of war and civilian internees considerably exceeded the number of expellees emigrating to Western Germany. Since 1950, on the other hand, immigration has dwindled to nothing and natural growth has probably not made up for the loss of population to the West. By the end of 1956 the total refugee population in Eastern Germany was officially estimated at 4.3 million—or roughly the same number as at the beginning of 1948.1 The Integration of Refugees2 in the Economy of the Federal Republic of Germany The population increase caused by the national refugees in Western Germany was enormous, not only in absolute figures but also in relative terms: by the end of 1946 it already amounted to 19 per cent, and in time it rose to more than 30 per cent. This massive influx, apart from 1 Information supplied to the International Labour Office by the Ministry of Labour and Vocational Training of the German Democratic Republic. 2 This section, like the chapter as a whole, only deals with refugees of German nationality. Questions affecting foreign refugees are discussed in the following chapter although many hundreds of thousands of these refugees have, through their continued presence in Western Germany contributed to aggravate the situation. 12 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 raising a tremendous problem of integration, was bound to have farreaching repercussions on the process of economic reconstruction which could otherwise have been undertaken only by a population slightly smaller than that of 1939 \ and with an acute shortage of males. Owing to the presence of the refugees, the country became overpopulated instead of the reverse and this acted for a long time as a drag on its economic life. Even today, while the problem has virtually been solved, it has left behind it a heavy legacy of social costs and other burdens. THE NATURE OF THE PROBLEM The integration of refugees in Western Germany was vastly different from the usual process by which a market economy absorbs migrants. For one thing, the flood of refugees, by its scale and nature, was very different from the usual type of immigration current; moreover, it occurred at a time of economic dislocation, in a country faced with underemployment and shortages of all kinds, and in short with a series of conditions diametrically opposite to those normally found in immigration countries—with recovery further hampered by temporary political obstacles. This combination of factors made the integration of the German refugees staggeringly difficult. The size and suddenness of the migratory influx into Western Germany after the end of the war are best illustrated by the fact that the population increased by nearly one-third in 12 years (a proportion which, though exceeded by Israel, is still a huge one for an increase due exclusively to migration) and that three-fifths of the movement took place before the end of 1946. Even if the nation's capital assets had remained intact and economic development had resumed its course immediately after the surrender, the absorption of such a tremendous human mass would inevitably have created problems of the utmost seriousness and led to a sharp fall in the standard of living. Occurring in a country which had suffered immense destruction 2, where internal and external trade had completely broken down and in which the policies of the Occupation Powers prevented industry from producing at normal capacity, this influx of refugees converted an already critical situation into a catastrophic and apparently insoluble one. 1 About 38 million, as compared with a little more than 39 million on 17 May 1939. 2 This destruction mainly affected urban property and transport and communications. Industry, on the other hand, particularly mining and heavy industry, suffered relatively little. NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 13 It is true that the years following 1946 brought a reversal of Allied occupation policies. The Tri-Zone received American aid, the currency was reformed, restrictions on industrial production and external trade were gradually lifted and occupation costs were reduced, all of which helped reconstruction to get under way after 1948. The problem, in fact, was henceforth no longer one of integrating the refugees in a disorganised, weakened and stagnating country, but in a dynamic, expanding economy increasingly similar to those normally found in immigration countries. Nevertheless, the shortages characterising the early stages of the expansion process, which the presence of the refugees had greatly aggravated, and the glut which they had created on the labour market, persisted for years. Generally speaking, the integration of the refugees in Western Germany, compared with the classic process of absorbing immigration in an expanding economy, had three unusual features. First, the relative scale of the migration was unprecedented. Secondly, it was superimposed on the reconstruction of a partly disorganised economy instead of taking place during a period of normal growth. And thirdly, its full impact was felt virtually from the start, since most of the immigration preceded rather than accompanied the process of expansion. Given the circumstances it is hardly surprising that only after nearly ten years, and at the cost of heavy sacrifices, was Western Germany finally able to absorb this massive immigration. The problem was aggravated by a number of other factors. The initial pressure from the refugees on the employment market was increased by the fact that those who had not formerly been in wageearning employment were now often forced to look for work, their impoverishment often being worse than that of the local population. The result was gross overcrowding in many occupations, particularly female ones, in the face of an already large surplus of adult women workers. Many of the refugees could only be absorbed by the economy provided they changed their occupation ; the adjustment was not always easy and it frequently meant a step down in the social scale. Many of them were compelled, in addition, to leave the areas where they had settled—rural areas, for the most part, where jobs were few and far between—to go and work in the towns where industry was beginning to expand but where housing conditions were such that they had either to accept temporary separation from their families or to make expensive and tiring journeys between their homes and places of work. The problem of finding jobs for the refugees was thus bound up with the 14 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 problem of occupational and geographical mobility, further complicated by psychological resistance among those concerned. Furthermore, the refugee population in the early stages comprised a high proportion of disabled persons and war widows and orphans who had to be provided with pensions, the cost of which added appreciably to the already heavy burden of non-productive expenditure that had to be met out of public funds. In short, this influx of refugees caused a tremendous amount of additional economic andfinancialdislocation and social hardship in Western Germany : it increased the shortage of capital,floodedthe labour market and swelled the demand for staple consumer goods, thereby endangering monetary stability, the equilibrium of the employment market and the balance of external trade; and it caused a sharp fall in average living standards. Indeed, directly or indirectly, it constituted a fresh source of inequality: by making capital scarcer and manpower more plentiful it generally favoured the employers and operated against the workers ; by adding to the surplus of female as compared with male labour it further depressed the conditions of women workers ; and, generally speaking, its over-all effect was a social downgrading of those involved in it. Thus the absorption of the refugees was not simply a matter of economic development and equilibrium: it had far-reaching social repercussions as well. It could not be achieved solely by large-scale investment in greater production capacity and the creation of jobs to make use of the refugee labour force as quickly and as fully as possible. The local population also had to make heavy sacrifices to help put the refugees on their feet again. At the same time it would be wrong to ignore, on the credit side, that it was the refugee influx which provided Western Germany with the male workers it needed for its recovery1—particularly as the average standard of skill of these workers was fortunately high. As they also spoke the same language and had the same background, they were readily adaptable, and being homeless and impoverished by emigration they were relatively willing to move to the industrial towns where jobs were available. Thus, a highly mobile labour supply became available at just the right time, i.e. as the economy was entering a period of rapid expansion. This asset became increasingly apparent as recovery progressed and the demand for labour expanded: indeed, in recent years acute shortages among some classes of male workers have only been 1 For a discussion of this subject see F. EDDING : The Refugees as a Burden, a Stimulus and a Challenge to the West German Economy, Publication IV, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1952). NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 15 prevented by migration from Eastern Germany. Moreover, the labour surplus which existed in Western Germany for several years helped to keep wages at a relatively low level and thus facilitated the investment needed to restore the economy. Lastly, by forcing the economy to set its sights higher than would otherwise have been necessary, the influx of refugees stimulated its growth to a size and power it would probably not have reached normally. INTEGRATION, ECONOMIC POLICY AND SOCIAL POLICY The approach adopted to the refugee problem was bound to depend largely on the Government's general economic policy and its readiness to intervene in social affairs. This policy consisted of two phases. The first lasted until the currency reform of 1948 and was characterised by rigid controls. The second, which started in the summer of 1948, involved a return to a competitive economy. Signs of this change appeared towards the end of the period of military administration but the final break between the old and the new policies did not take place until the autumn of 1949 when the first Government of the Federal Republic took over. The problem of integrating the refugees must therefore be seen against this background of two successive, and widely differing, economic policies. The chief aim of the policy followed by the military authorities until 1948 was to combat inflation. But instead of tackling the causes of the evil they merely tried to curb it through such means as rationing and taxation, and in so doing succeeded only in stifling the whole economy with controls. The result was that instead of providing an incentive to produce, particularly in industry (which was also subject to certain output restrictions), this policy perpetuated the existing shortages and brought almost all monetary transactions to a standstill. The policy was clearly a disastrous failure and in June 1948 it was decided to reform the currency—the first step towards scrapping the previous aims and methods. As far as aims were concerned, no further attempt was made to fight inflation directly by regulating output and trade. Instead, emphasis was placed on speeding up the formation of fixed capital so as to rebuild the country's productive equipment as quickly as possible and on expanding sufficiently to meet the needs of the increased population. As far as methods were concerned, the economy was no longer held on a tight rein (except by means of credit control) and prices and wages were allowed to find their own level through the operation of market forces. 16 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 This policy gave absolute priority to investment and, in order to prevent the danger of inflation that this entailed, the tax structure was overhauled so as to overtax wages (mainly by means of indirect taxation) and to undertax profits even to the extent of exempting a substantial portion altogether. In this way the largest possible share of the national income was switched from consumption to investment. Simultaneously, an all-out export drive was launched in order (as American aid fell off) to bring the balance of payments into equilibrium despite the burden of external debt and the need to import larger quantities of foodstuffs and raw materials. Increased exports also meant that there was less available for consumption at home. These drastic steps proved remarkably effective. The gross national product in real terms increased by about 85 per cent, between 1949 and 1957; the stability of the new currency was maintained; the balance of payments was restored despite the cuts in aid from abroad and its complete cessation after 1952 1; and industry was re-equipped and even considerably expanded. Nevertheless, private consumption rose steadily, particularly in recent years, e.g. in 1955 it was 50 per cent. higher than in 1950. Needless to say, economic aid from the United States played a great part in this expansion process, particularly during the early years 1948-50. Between the end of hostilities and 31 August 1951 Western Germany received 3,328 million dollars in American aid 2 or considerably more than the United Kingdom and France, to which must be added 721 million dollars from the British Government. This aid covered the cost of much of the imports needed to support the population and reconstruct the economy. 1 The balance of current transactions has in fact shown a heavy surplus since 1952. The following figures, which are taken from the United Nations Statistical Yearbook, illustrate the trend in the balance of payments (in millions of dollars) for Western Germany from 1948 to 1955 and show the progress made during that period. Source of income Goods and transportation 1948 . . . -1,030 1950 1951 1952 -888 -654 1949 Private donations 125 43 3 Official donations Official capital : 930 684 46 -89 17 8 174 -25 Errors and omissions . . . . . . . 30 7 121 -4 27 11 413 5 139 8 491 428 116 1953 1954 1955 838 934 711 - 6 -117 -143 133 122 133 -16 -34 -46 -8 30 -3 2 - 5 8 -148 109 - 3 5 - 1 9 1 - 3 3 1 - 1 4 0 - 1 1 0 51 - 4 8 1 - 5 1 9 - 5 6 3 - 6 5 3 - 4 6 3 28 - 4 9 - 8 5 69 -34 -66 2 Made up of 2,016 million dollars from the G.A.R.I.O.A. (Government and Relief in Occupied Areas) and 1,312 million dollars under the European Recovery Programme (Marshall Plan). See A. PIETTRE: L'économie allemande contemporaine (Paris, M. Th. Génin, 1952), Chapter XVII, pp. 468 fï. 17 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY TABLE 5. WESTERN GERMANY: SIZE OF THE CIVILIAN LABOUR FORCE, 1946-57 (In thousands) Total labour force Year 1946 1 1950 2 1954 3 1957 4 Men Women 12,191 14,125 15,309 15,877 1 Census of 29 October 1946. * Estimated average for the year. Absolute figures Percentage of population 19,327 22,074 24,190 25,202 44.1 46.6 49.0 49.8 7,137 7,949 8,881 9,325 » Census of 13 September 1950. • Estimated on 31 March 1954. One of the major consequences of the economic boom which has resulted from the policy pursued since 1948 has been the very rapid increase in the volume of employment since 1950. Between 1946 and 1957, the active population rose from 19.3 million to 25.2 million, i.e. an increase of 30 per cent., whereas unemployment, after reaching a peak of nearly 1.6 million in 1950, fell at first very slowly and after 1954 very quickly. This huge expansion in employment was wholly accounted for by the growth in the number of wage earners—from 13.5 million in 1949 to 18.6 million in 1957. Tables 5 and 6 illustrate this remarkable expansion. It was this rapid increase in the volume of employment which made it possible for the refugees to be progressively absorbed by the economy. Nevertheless, for a long time they remained a source of grave concern, and the authorities had not only to grant them relief but also to help TABLE 6. WESTERN GERMANY: EMPLOYMENT AND UNEMPLOYMENT (WAGE EARNERS AND SALARIED EMPLOYEES), 1948-57 Employment Unemployment Year ' 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1 In thousands As percentage of 1949 figure In thousands As percentage of employment figure 13,468 13,542 13,827 14,556 14,995 15,582 16,286 17,175 18,056 18,611 99.5 100.0 102.1 107.5 110.7 115.1 120.3 126.8 133.3 137.4 451 1,230 1,580 1,432 1,379 1,259 1,221 928 761 662 3.2 8.3 10.3 9.0 8.4 7.5 7.0 5.1 4.0 3.4 The 1948 figures refer to the situation on 30 June: the others represent estimated annual averages. 18 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 resettle them and compensate them as far as possible for the losses they had suffered. As a result, the bulk of the resources that the economy could spare for welfare purposes were devoted to this national-aid scheme. During the early years these arrangements were in the hands of the local governments, helped by various voluntary bodies: not until 1948 were they co-ordinated at the national level. Since then there have been so many different schemes that space does not allow giving a detailed account of them; they will merely be described in outline, starting from the time when the federal Government began to administer them and (under section 120 of the Basic Law (Grundgesetz) of 23 May 1949) to assume full responsibility. Aid to the refugees was concentrated first of all on the most urgent need—housing. From 1945 onward camps were set up to receive them; these camps were organised and run by the local governments which bore almost all the expense for some years. After 1949 the camps became the responsibility of the Federal Ministry of Expellees and were governed by uniform regulations. The refugees were also covered by the general welfare and social security laws, and inevitably drew a large share of the available benefits, e.g. unemployment benefit, maintenance allowances for old persons and the disabled left destitute by the war, and furnishing allowances. The authorities, for their part, made every effort to integrate the refugees as quickly as possible into the working population. In so doing, they concentrated largely on removing the causes of unemployment peculiar to the refugees. Chief among these was the concentration of large numbers of them in areas where there was little scope for development and where a strong demand for labour could not be expected to appear spontaneously. There were two ways of coping with this situation. On the one hand the redistribution of the refugees throughout the country could be speeded up—a process which was already taking place, though too slowly, through voluntary migration. Alternatively, capital could be invested in the overpopulated areas so as to raise the level of employment. In actual fact both methods were used. From the end of 1949 onwards the federal Government carried out a policy of population transfers (Umsiedlungen) to the industrial cities of the Rhineland so as to relieve the three overpopulated Länder of Schleswig-Holstein, Lower Saxony and Bavaria, where the rate of unemployment was exceptionally high. The federal Parliament provided the Government with the necessary funds to carry out three successive transfer schemes affecting a total of 1,050,000 persons, of whom 850,000 had actually been transferred by 30 June 1956. NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 19 Migration from one Land to another, whether individual or organised, nevertheless had one serious drawback in that it was not confined to the unemployed. Many workers who already had jobs, including large numbers of semi-skilled workers, were attracted to the more rapidly developing areas where prospects were a good deal better. This cancelled out some of the benefit which the overpopulated Länder derived from this internal migration. Accordingly, the federal Government simultaneously made credit available in districts where unemployment was worst. Loans were granted for the expansion of existing firms, the establishment of new industries and the construction of housing. There have been four successive plans since 1950, the latest being specifically designed to cope with the hard core of refugees still remaining in the reception camps. The wage earners among the refugees were not the only ones, however, to require special assistance from the authorities. There were in addition many craftsmen, tradesmen and professional workers who were unable to continue in their former occupations because they had lost all their capital. In the general interest as well as on grounds of social justice, the authorities felt bound to prevent these self-employed workers or employers from sinking into the proletariat and thus depriving the community of their socially useful skills and experience. Official aid was accordingly provided for many of them in the shape of long-term loans granted by the Expellees' Bank, a special body founded in 1950 and since entrusted, under the new name of Expellees' and War Victims' Bank, with the handhng of funds provided under the EquaUsation of Charges Act (Lastenausgleichsgesetz) of 20 August 1952. This public loans policy was coupled with tax reliefs. A third class of refugees, the farmers, numbering some 300,000, presented the authorities with an even greater problem. Their resettlement was not simply a matter of finance : there was the further obstacle of lack of land for new farms. Every effort was made under two successive enactments, dated 10 August 1949 and 15 May 1953, to find a solution commensurate with the size of the problem and its social importance, but owing to all the difficulties in the way of integrating landless farmers the Government finally, in addition to its other efforts, had to help them to settle abroad. Another feature of the authorities' efforts to resettle the refugees has been their housing policy. This has helped to expand the volume of employment and, by increasing the supply of housing in the industrial towns, has allowed labour to move where it was needed. Two building subsidy schemes were launched under two Acts, dated 24 April 1950 20 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 and 25 August 1953 respectively, from which, either directly or indirectly, the refugees were those who benefited most. Official help for the refugees was not, however, confined to their economic integration. The Equalisation of Charges Act of 1952 rounded off this policy by compensating refugees for their capital losses out of public funds. This Act, which applies to all war victims—refugees as well as others having suffered losses of property—substituted compensation for relief as the legal principle behind the benefits provided by the federal Government. The significance of this change was not simply moral. The Act enlarged the whole scope of the schemes for aiding the refugees and the homeless and for systematically sharing out the burden of war damage, so that at the end of 27 years the burden will have been equally borne by the entire population. PROGRESS OF INTEGRATION SINCE 1946 Having described the background against which the process of integral tion took place, the next step, logically, would be to describe the process itself with the help of employment statistics. Unfortunately, such figures as exist are, at best, incomplete. They are almost non-existent in the case of the transmigrants and are inadequate even in the case of the expellees, who are counted separately only in a few series, censuses, population estimates and unemployment statistics. The following account is therefore necessarily incomplete and imprecise in some respects. However, available manpower statistics do at least reveal the main stages in the process. During the first stage, from 1946 to 1948, the great majority of the refugee labour force succeeded in finding work because of the heavy demand for male workers resulting from war losses, the absence of large numbers of prisoners, and also a disproportionate expansion of employment in certain sectors, particularly agriculture and services. Thus, the volume of wage-earning employment increased between 30 June 1946 and 30 June 1948 from less than 10 million to around 13.5 million. Moreover, despite the return of the prisoners and the persistent influx of refugees, unemployment on 30 June 1948 was no higher than 450,000. This, however, was due to overstaffing in some industries and to a very low level of productivity—amounting, in effect, to disguised underemployment. Thus, it reflected a fundamentally unhealthy situation, which did not survive the return to a competitive economy. The upheaval in the employment market caused by the change of economic policy in 1948-49 marked the beginning of the second stage in the process of integration which, perhaps arbitrarily, may be assumed to have come to an end towards the close of 1950. In many ways this stage was the most critical of all. By causing a sharp contraction in employ- 21 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY TABLE 7. WESTERN GERMANY: EMPLOYMENT AND UNEMPLOYMENT (WAGE EARNERS AND SALARIED EMPLOYEES) ON 30 JUNE 1948 AND 30 JUNE 1950 30 J u n e 1948 Category Absolute figures (thousands) 30 June 1950 Percentage of wage-earning a n d salaried labour force A b s o l u t e figures (thousands) Percentage of wage-earning a n d salaried l a b o u r force Employed . . . . Unemployed . . . 13,468 451 96.8 3.2 13,845 1,538 90.0 10.0 Total . . . 13,918 100.0 15,384 100.0 ment in the less productive sectors of the economy, the new policy brought on a steep rise in unemployment despite the existence of newmanpower needs in industry, and this highlighted the huge surplus of the existing labour force by comparison with the normal number of jobs. Thus the years 1948-50 were marked by a distinct relative fall in wageearning and salaried employment, as can be seen from table 7. Thus a situation of disguised underemployment, due directly or indirectly to the influx of refugees, and largely sustained by continued immigration since 1946, developed into one of structural unemployment which, though it represented the price that had to be paid for getting the economy back on its feet, hit the refugee population particularly hard 1 and caused a temporary but appreciable worsening of their social and economic position. The unemployment statistics which, since 1949, have distinguished between the expellees and other classes of workers, 1 The drop in employment only affected the three Länder where the proportion of refugees was highest, viz. Schleswig-Holstein, Lower Saxony and Bavaria, which explains why the rise in unemployment in these regions was particularly sharp. The following figures, representing employment and unemployment of wage earners and salaried employees in each Land on 30 June 1948 and 30 June 1950 (in thousands), illustrate the special position of these three overpopulated Lander (figures in italics). Unemployment Employment O n 30 J u n e 1948 O n 30 J u n e 1950 O n 30 J u n e 1948 Schleswig-Holstein O n 30 June 1950 778 561 632 578 21 14 203 94 Lower Saxony . . 1,970 180 1,791 187 59 7 Í55 23 N o r t h RhineWestphalia . . 3,859 1,190 680 1,721 2,529 4,317 1,235 727 1,951 2,427 122 42 5 34 146 229 128 63 83 ¡59 13,468 13,845 451 1,538 Rhineland-Palatinate Baden-Würltemberg Total . 22 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 8. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: COMPARATIVE BREAKDOWN OF THE LABOUR FORCE BY OCCUPATIONAL STATUS (EXPELLEES AND REMAINDER OF THE POPULATION) ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950 (In percentages) Occupational category Expellees Remainder of population Total Self-employed Employed in family business . . Public servants Salaried employees Wage earners 5.2 1.8 3.7 14.3 75.0 16.5 16.7 4.0 16.3 46.5 14.7 14.4 3.9 16.0 50.9 Total . . . 100.0 100.0 100.0 give some idea of the extent of this phenomenon. On 30 June 1950, out of 1,538,000 unemployed there were 513,000 expellees, i.e. exactly a third of the total number, and the rate of unemployment 1 was nearly three times as high among the expellees as for the rest of the population (15.3 as against 5.5 per cent.). The 1950 census revealed other signs of hardship, e.g. the fact that the ratio of the labour force to the total population amounted to only 42.5 per cent, among the expellees as compared with 47 per cent, for the remainder of the population and despite a slightly higher percentage of persons of working age among the former; it also disclosed a much higher proportion of wage earners (75 per cent, as against 46.5 per cent.) among the expellees (table 8). Thus, not only were the expellees as a whole particularly hard hit by unemployment, but many of them, such as the self-employed, older workers and women, were excluded against their will from the working population because they could not find suitable jobs, while many of the formerly self-employed were forced to take wage-earning employment.2 1 Calculated on the basis of the labour force covered by the September 1950 census. 2 It may be of interest also to compare the breakdown of the 1950 expellees by occupational status (as given in table 8) with the corresponding figures for the 1939 labour force in the German eastern provinces and in the Sudetenland. The relevant percentages are given in the following table. Category Self-employed . . . in family business . Public servants . . Salaried employees Wage earners . . . Former German eastern provinces (1939) Sudetenland (1939) Expellees (1950) 14.8 20.3 5.4 10.3 49.2 17.7 17.1 1.9 10.3 53.0 5.2 1.8 3.7 14.3 75.0 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 23 TABLE 9. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY : COMPARATIVE UNEMPLOYMENT DATA FOR EXPELLEES AND TOTAL POPULATION, 1950-57 Unemployment imong expellees 1 Year 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1 Annu al average. Í January. Comparative unemployment rate a In thousands As percentage of total unemployment Expellees Total population 527 461 415 360 321 225 179 151 33.4 32.2 30.0 28.7 26.3 24.2 23.5 22.8 6.9 5.8 5.1 4.3 3.8 2.6 2.0 1.7 3.3 3.0 2.9 2.6 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.2 ' Annual average unemployment figure as percentage of population on The few figures which have been quoted show how much still remained to be done at the end of 1950 to put an end to the refugees' position as a depressed social class—a problem which could only be aggravated by the continued influx of refugees from Eastern Germany and by the increase in the labour force resulting from the natural growth of the population. Nevertheless, the position of the refugees in relation to the local population has steadily improved since the end of 1950, and this constitutes the third phase in the process of integration. During this period, thanks to the federal Government's efforts, unemployment among the expellees fell sharply—more so, in fact, than among the rest of the population. As a result, the rate of unemployment among the expellees no longer differs widely from the general rate (table 9). The general decline in unemployment, which since 1955 has never exceeded a normal level, did not bear out the pessimistic forecast which continuing immigration from the East might have inspired at the beginning of this third period. The refugees of recent years, who included a high proportion of young adults, most of them males, have been absorbed without much difficulty by the rapidly expanding labour force. Indeed, this extra manpower has met an increasingly apparent need and without it the tempo of development of recent years might not have been achieved. So far from having hampered the integration of the earlier refugees who were being kept idle against their will, it seems to have helped by contributing to the boom. Moreover, there can be no doubt that the enormous growth in the volume of employment since 1950, particularly wage-earning employ- 24 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 ment, which rose from 13.8 million (1950 average) to 18.6 million (1957 average) also affected the expellee population, especially the women among whom, for various reasons, the rate of employment had hitherto been abnormally low. A survey of the expellee population carried out in 1954-55 showed that over half (52.2 per cent.) of the persons covered belonged at that time to the labour force. Nevertheless, although the number of persons surveyed (nearly 5.7 million) was very large and represented about two-thirds of the expellees living in the Federal Republic at that time it cannot, despite its size, be taken as an absolutely representative sample.1 The female employment rate, in particular, still seems lower among the expellees than among the remainder of the population. A fairly large number of refugees appear to have succeeded since 1950 in setting up on their own either for the first time or once again. Thus, whereas on 13 September 1950 only 11,500 farms were owned by refugees (expellees and immigrants), there were over 44,000 in 1956, while in the handicrafts the number of refugee employers increased from 38,000 in 1949 to 62,000 in 1954. Similarly, in industry the number of firms run by refugees rose, accounting in 1955 for more than 11 per cent, of the total 1 See K. HORSTMANN: " Die berufliche Eingliederung der Vertriebenen ", in Wirtschaft und Statistik (Stuttgart, Statistisches Bundesamt), 10th Year, No. 4, Apr. 1958, pp. 207-212. The results of the survey as a whole are as follows (figures in thousands) : (a) General Breakdown by Economic Status Category Self-supporting but not gainfully occupied . . . Total . . . Absolute figures Percentage of population 2,973.5 2,694.4 279.1 1.209.2 1,508.1 52.2 47.3 4.9 21.2 26.5 5,690.9 100.0 (b) Breakdown of Persons in Employment by Type of Occupation Category Total . . . Absolute figures Percentage of population 169.6 35.7 148.2 538.7 1,802.3 6.3 1.3 5.5 20.0 66.9 2,694.4 100.0 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 25 number of industrial undertakings. 1 Lastly, the survey of 1954-55 showed (in so far as its results can be relied upon) that the proportion of selfemployed workers had risen from 5.2 per cent, in 1950 to 6.3 per cent, and that there had been an even more marked increase in the proportion of public servants and salaried employees, coupled with a distinct fall in the proportion of wage earners. These changes indicate a substantial improvement in the social status and employment position of the refugee population. Despite the achievements of recent years, however, the integration of the refugees cannot be considered as complete. The problem has no doubt been solved in purely quantitative terms, in the sense that the overwhelming majority of able-bodied refugees are now in productive employment. However, a good deal probably remains to be done towards regrading these workers, who have not always found the jobs for which they were best suited. In other words, the problem has become qualitative instead of quantitative—but this very fact measures the progress accomplished over the past ten years. CONSEQUENCES OF THE INFLUX Thus, in ten years or so, Western Germany has succeeded in absorbing over 12 million immigrants, to the extent at least of finding work for the majority of them. What demographic, economic and social repercussions this process had on the country's life remains to be discussed. Demographic Consequences The population of Western Germany suffered such heavy losses during the war that it would not yet have reverted to its 1939 level had no immigration taken place in the meantime. By the end of 1957 the native population of the Federal Republic still fell half-a-million short of the 1939 total 2 , whereas the total population had increased by 30 per cent. The present figure is thus the resultant of two fortuitous events : the losses caused by the war and the migratory influx which followed it. Not only has the latter more than offset the former, numerically speaking, but it has had a beneficial effect on the age and sex structure of the population, which during the war had greatly deteriorated. 1 2 Some 10,600 out of a total of 94,600. 39,350,000. 26 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Germany's war losses were largely military, and had completely upset the balance between the sexes among the young adult generations. The census of 13 September 1950 showed that females outnumbered males by nearly 3 million and, in the 25-45 age group, by more than 1.7 million, representing a ratio of 100 to 77.1 These military losses, combined with the low birth rate of the war years, had raised the average age of the population, 9.5 per cent, of which consisted of people over the age of 64 in 1950, as compared with 7.3 per cent, in 1939. Moreover, by breaking up a large number of married couples and reducing the marriage rate they had a lasting effect on the number of births. However, the proportion of adult males would have been even lower and the average age of the population even higher but for the immigration of large numbers of refugees with a higher proportion of adult males and a lower average age. Tables 10 and 11 illustrate this cushioning effect on the basis of the 1950 census figures in which—unfortunately—immigrants other than expellees, among whom there were slightly more men than women, were lumped together with the rest of the population. Had they, instead, been classed with the expellees, the contrast between the two sections of the population—refugees and non-refugees—would appear even more clearly. The immigration which has taken place since 1950 has TABLE 10. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY *: COMPARATIVE BREAKDOWN BY AGE GROUPS OF EXPELLEES AND REMAINDER OF THE POPULATION ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950 Age groups 0-15 15-21 21-25 25-35 35^15 45-65 65 and a be)ve Total . . . 0-45 1 Expellees Rest of population Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) 1,966.0 733.6 529.0 1,138.3 1,223.2 1,716.0 569.9 25.0 9.3 6.7 14.5 15.5 21.8 7.2 9,270.0 3,464.9 2,324.2 4,885.5 6,236.8 9,783.0 3,854.0 7,876.2 100.0 5,590.3 71.0 Total Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 23.3 8.7 5.8 12.3 15.7 24.5 9.7 11,237.0 4,198.4 2,853.2 6,023.8 7,460.0 11,499.4 4,423.9 23.6 8.8 6.0 12.6 15.6 24.1 9.3 39,819.5 100.0 47,695.7 100.0 26,182.2 65.8 31,772.4 66.6 Percentages Not including West Berlin. 1 Out of a total population of 47,696,000, males numbered 22,351,000 and females 25,345,000; and out of 13,484,000 adults between the ages of 25 and 45, 5,874,000 were males and 7,610,000 were females. 27 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY TABLE 11. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY 1 : PERCENTAGE OF MALES TO FEMALES IN THE VARIOUS AGE GROUPS (EXPELLEES AND REMAINDER OF THE POPULATION) ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950 Age groups Expellees Rest of population Total . . . . 104.4 103.9 102.5 81.9 84.6 78.9 69.3 104.3 103.1 95.5 72.9 78.4 83.3 84.0 104.3 103.2 96.8 74.5 79.4 82.6 81.9 Total . . . 89.0 88.0 88.2 0-15 15-21 21-25 25-35 35-45 45-55 65 and above 1 Not including West Berlin. continued to exert a corrective influence. In most cases it has been purely voluntary and due to economic as much as to political considerations. As a result, it has been far more reminiscent demographically of the traditional type of migratory movement, in that it has included a high proportion of individuals under the age of 40 and among them more men than women. 1 Moreover, as is shown by table 12, the birth rate has been persistently higher among the expellees than among the remainder of the population. Paradoxically enough, the expellees have also been healthier, as is shown by the mortality statistics. Infant mortality, in particular, was for a long time markedly less among the expellees than among the local population and even today it is still somewhat lower. Nevertheless, leaving out of account the immigration from Eastern Germany, which has had a wholly corrective effect, the remainder of the immigration has brought about only a relative improvement in the demographic structure of Western Germany. The expellee population 1 The breakdown by sex of the net immigration into the Federal Republic between 1950 and 1957, the bulk of which was accounted for by immigration from the East (Berlin, Eastern Germany and the former East German provinces) was as follows (figures in thousands): Sex 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Men . . . . Women . . . 230.2 180.1 97.7 109.6 79.0 69.1 176.3 172.6 107.5 113.6 170.0 140.9 175.6 163.8 215.7 200.9 Total . . . 410.2 207.4 148.1 348.8 221.1 310.9 339.4 416.6 Out of a total net immigration figure of 2,403,000 the surplus of males was more than 100,000 (1,252,000 men, or 52.1 per cent., as compared with 1,151,000 women, or 47.9 per cent.). 28 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 12. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: COMPARATIVE BIRTH AND INFANT MORTALITY RATES (EXPELLEES AND POPULATION AS A WHOLE), 1950-56 Number of births per thousand inhabitants Year 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 Infant mortality per thousand live births Expellees Population as a whole Expellees Population as a whole 17.0 18.1 18.1 17.8 18.0 17.7 17.9 16.2 15.8 15.7 15.5 15.7 15.7 16.2 37 39 36 36 35 34 31 55 53 48 46 43 42 39 had, after all, been affected by war losses in the same manner as the local population, and its structure was similarly unbalanced as a result, though not to quite the same extent. Therefore, all that can be stated with any confidence about the demographic consequences of the influx of refugees is that the age and sex structure of the West German population would have been still more unfavourable and the birth rate even lower if it had not taken place. But it has by no means filled the gaps caused by war losses among the younger adult generation. Economic Consequences Such a complex human phenomenon as forced immigration on a large scale can obviously not be reduced to simple economic terms, and in the case of Western Germany there is still a good deal of controversy as to whether it helped or hindered the country's recovery. At first sight it might be thought that the influx of refugees caused so much extra non-productive expenditure and initially lowered the general standard of living to such an extent that the question need not be asked at all. Now, however, that the refugees are completely integrated it has become clear that the economy has derived a number of benefits from their presence. These include a bigger domestic market, a better supply of labour, and lower overhead expenses per member of the population, which between them amply make up for the additional unproductive expenditure which still has to be made on some of the refugees. The fact that productivity has risen does not, however, by itself prove that immigration has been beneficial for the Federal Republic : it would have to be shown, in addition, that the present productivity level could not have been achieved or, in other words, that the country NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 29 would have made a less spectacular economic recovery, had the influx not taken place. Obviously, it is impossible to quote chapter and verse in support of such a claim or to make out anything like a conclusive case. Nevertheless, the arguments put forward by the pessimists do appear to be outweighed by those of their opponents. It is perfectly true that it was many years before the refugees' capacity for work was fully employed, and for a long time they remained less productive than the rest of the population. It is also true that heavy sacrifices had to be made by the West German economy to help them recover whatever wealth they had possessed, and totally lost as a result of the war. At the same time the fact that productivity was lower among the refugees does not necessarily mean that what they took out of the national product for consumption or the rebuilding of their capital exceeded their contribution to output. This was unquestionably the case during the early years but has long since ceased to be so, though at what precise moment would be hard to say. It has also been contended that the influx of refugees had an unfavourable effect, at least during the early years, on the productivity of the local population—directly by keeping some of them out of work and indirectly by diverting to unproductive uses the resources which could have been devoted to investment in higher productivity. In other words, the level of productivity would have been higher initially if the immigration had not taken place. But it is less certain that productivity in this case would have been able to rise as quickly as it did once the economy had begun to recover in earnest and it is becoming increasingly clear as time goes by that immigration has provided the impetus right from the start of the reconstruction period. It is hard to see, moreover, how the active population of Western Germany, severely handicapped by war losses and with many men kept abroad for some time as prisoners of war, could have coped so quickly with the problem of reconstruction without large-scale immigration of men workers. It is true that the immigration that actually took place was far removed from the economic optimum and controlled immigration with fewer unproductive elements would no doubt have been preferable. But it did in part meet a vital need and it is pointless to ask whether Western Germany could have dealt with its labour shortage in any other way. The real question is whether, and if so to what extent, the benefits of immigration as it actually occurred offset its disadvantages. To some extent, the foregoing considerations answer this question. However, apart from helping to ease a critical manpower shortage, the refugees had a further beneficial effect on the German economy, since 30 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 it may be argued that, by keeping up strong pressure on the employment market for many years and thus exerting a depressing influence on wages as well as enabling employers to pick and choose, they helped to create these conditions and thereby facilitate the heavy investment which the reconstruction of the economy and the employment market " bulge " caused by the coming of age of the post-1936 generations would have required in any case. It is likely that without this pressure, combined with that brought to bear on the economy as a whole by the influx of a population with, initially at least, no capital, the rate of economic expansion during the years following 1950 would not have been achieved. While the former has gradually fallen off and today is negligible, the latter continues to be felt and has been one of the factors making for the continuance of development at a rapid rate during recent years. Furthermore, the relatively low level of wages has stimulated exports and this too has given a further impetus to expansion. Thus, the heavy initial sacrifices which the local population had to bear were gradually recovered in the form of the growing benefits which the economy derived from the presence of the refugees. This process of recovery operated in exactly the same way as in the case of economic migration, with the sole difference that it was much slower owing to obvious factors, such as the weight of the original burden and the impoverished state of the population which had to bear it. Heavy though the cost may have been, it would appear that, despite the increase in public expenditure on the refugees resulting from the Equalisation of Charges Act, 1952, this cost has already been recovered. Social Consequences The main social effect of the wide and persistent gap between the average income of the refugees and that of the local population in Western Germany was to complicate the country's social structure by drawing a sharp dividing line between the two groups. A number of indications bear witness to the lower living standards of the refugee population as a whole. Several of them have already been referred to, e.g. the lower employment rate among the refugee population as a whole, despite the fact that the refugees comprise a higher proportion of persons of working age, and among them a higher percentage of men; and the fact that within the refugee labour force there is a far bigger majority of wage earners and a much higher rate of unemployment. Despite the improvement which has taken place since 1950, these difficulties are still appreciable. Two other noteworthy signs of inferiority should also be mentioned—the generally depressed position of the NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 31 refugees in the scale of manual jobs and their lower housing standards. The first of these points is brought out by table 13, which shows that on 13 September 1950 the proportion of refugees, or at least of expellees, in relation to the total number of manual workers, exceeded TABLE 13. F E D E R A L REPUBLIC O F G E R M A N Y : EXPELLEE M A N U A L W O R K E R S EMPLOYED ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950, BY I N D U S T R Y Absolute figures (thousands) Industry Percentage of all workers in employment Agriculture, forestry, fishing, etc. . . Mining, quarrying, power Metallurgy, engineering Manufacturing Construction Commerce, banking, insurance . . . Private services Transport Public and quasi-public services . . Unspecified 337.2 148.3 292.7 507.0 311.6 48.2 196.6 77.9 155.0 6.8 34.1 17.5 15.7 18.9 24.4 14.4 23.2 13.4 26.3 19.5 Total . . . 2,081.2 20.7 the average in those occupations where earnings were and are lowest, i.e. agriculture, building and public and private services, and were below the average in the others, particularly mining, metallurgy, commerce and transport. Figures are not available regarding the changes since the end of 1950, although the position has probably improved.1 As regards housing, tables 14 and 15 show how much lower the refugees' standards were at the date of the census, with a far higher proportion of households living in emergency or communal housing, a higher percentage of households in sublet accommodation, and a much greater occupation density in premises occupied by refugees. The situation has greatly improved since then, but by and large the refugees are still less well housed than the local population. To sum up, the economic and social position of the refugees was characterised at the time of the 1950 census and is still characterised by the following features: a smaller proportion of economically active persons and a higher proportion of persons living on private means, pensioners and dependants; an overwhelming majority of employees, including a much higher percentage of manual workers than among 1 See the results of the 1954-55 survey in K. HORSTMANN: ' Die berufliche Eingliederung der Vertriebenen ", op. cit. 32 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 14. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: TYPE OF HOUSING OCCUPIED AND STATUS OF OCCUPANTS (EXPELLEES AND POPULATION AS A WHOLE) ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950 Expellee households All households Type of housing In thousands Percentages of total In thousands Percentages of total Normal accommodation . Emergency accommodation Communal housing . . . 2,310.2 89.1 14,633.9 95.1 217.8 66.9 8.4 2.5 626.8 135.2 4.1 0.8 Total . . . 2,594.9 100.0 15,395.9 100.0 . . 581.3 1,728.9 25.2 74.8 9,417.2 5,216.6 64.4 35.6 Total . . . 2,310.2 100.0 14,633.9 100.0 Status of occupants in normal accommodation Owners and tenants Subtenants the rest of the population ; and among the latter a higher proportion in the worse-paid jobs and a higher rate of unemployment. A further point is that the local population initially owned all the capital and has derived more of the benefit from the capital accumulation which has taken place since. In other words, the refugee population had and still has a relatively much smaller share of the national product than the local population. The difference in living conditions between the two groups was further accentuated by the fact that the former suffered more than the latter from the housing shortage. These contrasts have already TABLE 15. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY : OCCUPATION DENSITY IN NORMAL HOUSING ACCOMMODATION (EXPELLEES AND POPULATION AS A WHOLE) ON 13 SEPTEMBER 1950 Persons per room Less than 0.75 0.75 to 1.25 1.25 to 2 2 to 3 More than 3 Total . . . Percentage of expellee population Percentage of total population 3.1 30.1 42.4 15.7 8.7 16.9 39.6 33.0 7.3 3.2 100.0 100.0 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 33 become less glaring and progress is continuing, thanks to the policy of equalising the burdens and the drive to rehouse the refugees, but despite the energy displayed by many of them in making up lost ground, the refugee population as a whole is still markedly worse off.1 To be complete, it would be necessary to point out that the degree of hardship suffered by the refugees has varied, depending on their social and occupational group, their age, sex and even the particular time at which they settled in Western Germany. Those who entered in recent years, in particular, have on the whole been absorbed more quickly and more completely than the earlier immigrants. Mention should also be made of the repercussions of immigration on the distribution of income in the local population. The main effect, by creating a constant labour surplus, was to exert a downward pressure on wages and, incidentally, to depress women's wages proportionately more than men's. In other words, the migratory influx increased the relative share of capital in the national income and lowered the share of labour. The onset of full employment called a halt to this trend which had gone on since 1948, but did not reverse it. Conclusions Two conclusions appear to emerge from the foregoing discussion. One concerns the effectiveness of the methods used to absorb the influx of refugees, and the other its long-term effects on the country's economic and social development. As regards the methods used to put the West German economy back on its feet, at a time when it had to bear not only the burden of reconstruction but also that of maintaining a large population surplus, suffice it to say that they were remarkably effective in the circumstances in which they were employed. The liberal policy followed by the federal Government probably owes its success mainly to the fact that the necessary technical, psychological and political conditions for intensive investment already existed—technical in that the country had both a highly developed industry and a skilled labour force, and psychological and political in that the German workers made no social demands likely to hinder the investment effort, and that the entire population willingly shouldered the sacrifices required by a policy which could only bear fruit in the long run. As regards the long-term consequences of immigration on the economic and social development of the Federal Republic, it has already been explained that, even though productivity was depressed for a long time 1 HORSTMANN, op. cit. 34 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 as a result, the cost of this relative setback was largely borne by the refugees themselves, and that the sacrifices made by the local population were only temporary. Furthermore, all the indications are that the German economy could not have achieved its present level of productivity without the extra help provided by the refugees. Thus the heavy sacrifices initially borne by the local population in order to cope with the influx of newcomers have been, in effect, a highly productive investment. However, the experience of the Federal Republic of Germany during the post-war years—in spite of certain similarities with that of other countries which at one time allowed uncontrolled immigration— affords no basis for over-optimistic conclusions as to the impact of mass migration on high-productivity economies in general. Various special circumstances made it easier for the refugees to be absorbed in Western Germany, e.g. the gaps in the active population caused by the war, which would in any case have made it necessary to import men workers ; the high level of skill of the immigrants who, though unable to provide the economy with capital in the form of equipment, contributed valuable labour; and finally the size of the task of reconstruction which temporarily swelled the demand for labour, partly because of the urgency of the need and partly because of the loss of capital equipment. Nor can severe social hardships, such as the disruption of the employment market and resulting inequalities in the distribution of income, be ignored. These represented the price that had to be paid for the economic benefits of immigration, and even though they were borne mainly by the immigrants themselves, the entire population felt their dampening effect on social progress. This fact must be set off against the refugees' undeniable contribution to economic growth. The Integration of Refugees in the German Democratic Republic SCOPE OF THE PROBLEM Relatively speaking, the refugee problem was just as great in Eastern Germany, where in 1956 the immigrants represented nearly one-quarter of the total population—4.3 out of 17.7 million. Since 1945 the influx of expellees has, it is true, been virtually offset by large-scale emigration to Western Germany, so that the present population of the German Democratic Republic exceeds the 1939 level 1 by little more than a million. Nevertheless, before emigration siphoned part of it off, the population of Eastern Germany, swollen by the influx of refugees, was for some 1 16.7 million. 35 NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY years much larger, reaching a peak of 19.1 million in 1948, after which it declined steadily. Thus during the immediate post-war years, at a time when the country's economic and social structure was being radically altered, immigration considerably worsened a position which was already critical in many ways. Moreover, the appreciable decrease in the population which has taken place since has had the major drawback of involving mainly young adults, most of them males, thus accentuating the unbalance in the population's age and sex structure; and since, in the first place, the structure of the refugee population as revealed by the census of 29 October 1946 (tables 16 and 17 *) was distinctly more unbalanced, at least as regards the distribution of the sexes in the adult age group, than that of the local population (nor does there appear to have been much improvement since2) it is hardly surprising that, accordTABLE 16. EASTERN GERMANY 1 : COMPARATIVE BREAKDOWN, BY AGE GROUPS, OF THE POPULATION ON 29 OCTOBER 1946 Rest of population Expellees Age groups Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 0-14 . . . . 14-21 . . . . 21-25 . . . . 25-35 . . . . 35-45 . . . . 45-65 . . . . 65 and over 951.4 360.6 221.0 383.5 528.0 857.9 298.3 26.4 10.0 6.1 10.7 14.7 23.8 8.3 3,113.0 1,178.1 694.9 1,501.4 2,141.8 3,654.7 1,429.1 22.7 8.6 5.1 10.9 15.6 26.7 10.4 4,064.4 1,538.7 915.9 1,884.9 4,512.6 2,669.8 1,727.5 23.5 8.9 5.3 10.9 15.4 26.0 10.0 Total . . . 3,600.7 100.0 13,713.0 100.0 17,313.7 100.0 2,444.7 67.9 8,629.1 63.7 11,373.9 65.7 CM5 1 Total Excluding East Berlin. 1 In comparing the figures shown in these tables with those given in tables 10 and 11 for Western Germany, it is important to bear in mind that the former refer to the position at the end of 1946 whereas the latter refer to a date four years later. At the end of 1946 a large number of adult males were still outside the frontiers and were only repatriated during the following years. The two pairs of tables are therefore not comparable. Nevertheless, as early as the end of 1946 the ratio of men to women in the adult age groups was already markedly higher in Western Germany than in Eastern Germany (73.2 per cent, as against 66.9 per cent, in the 14 to 65 age groups). Thus the movement of adult males from the Eastern zone was discernible before the end of 1946. 2 The immigration which took place after the end of 1946 doubtless involved an appreciably higher proportion of adult males than the expellee population covered by the October 1946 census, i.e. it included repatriated prisoners of war and workers kept behind temporarily in territories transferred to foreign administration or ownership. But this was partly offset by the emigration of adult males which subsequently took place among the expellees. 36 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 17. EASTERN GERMANY 1 : PERCENTAGE OF MALES TO FEMALES IN THE VARIOUS AGE GROUPS (EXPELLEES AND REMAINDER OF POPULATION) ON 29 OCTOBER 1946 Age groups Expellees Rest of population Total 0-14 14-21 21-25 25-35 35-45 45-65 65 and over . . . 103.3 87.8 36.7 40.6 54.8 70.1 73.0 103.8 92.8 56.1 48.1 64.2 80.5 79.8 103.7 91.6 50.9 46.5 62.3 78.4 78.5 Total . . . 70.5 75.3 74.3 46.4 57.0 54.7 21-45 1 Excluding East Berlin. ing to recent population estimates (see table 18) the population has aged appreciably since 1946, while the shortage of males has remained substantial, particularly in the over-30 age groups, despite the natural increase of the population and the return of the men who, at the time of the 1946 census, were outside the borders of the Soviet zone. Indeed, the shortage has steadily grown in recent years because of emigration to the Federal Republic. TABLE 18. GERMAN DEMOCRATIC REPUBLIC 1 : ESTIMATED BREAKDOWN, BY AGE AND SEX, OF THE POPULATION IN 1956 Number of inhabitants Age groups In thousands 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-35 35-45 45-55 55-65 65 and over ,. . Total . . . 3,539.7 1,561.5 2,371.2 988.6 1,848.6 2,718.3 2,352.4 2,335.4 20.0 8.8 13.4 5.6 10.4 15.3 13.3 13.2 104.3 102.7 93.4 64.2 61.5 72.8 71.6 69.7 17,717.9 100.0 80.9 Source: United Nations Demographic Yearbook, 1957. Including East Berlin. 1 As percentage of total population Males as percentage of females NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 37 Thus the demographic background to the integration of the refugees was distinctly more favourable in Western than in Eastern Germany. From the start the population of the latter contained fewer active males and on top of this there was a steady loss by emigration; furthermore, the population of Eastern Germany was swollen by an influx of expellees containing a still lower proportion of active males. The result was a sharper deterioration in the ratio between the working and non-working population and a steeper rise in unproductive expenditure. Moreover, the country itself was less industrialised and conditions were not as favourable for a rapid expansion of employment. While in some respects emigration helped to ease the problem by freeing a certain number of jobs, it also had a disrupting effect on the economy which has been acutely felt in recent years. However, in view of the relatively small size of the refugee labour force and also of the acute shortage of labour immediately after the war, the male workers were absorbed with relatively little difficulty, particularly as a large segment of the refugee population was of rural origin and the economy of Eastern Germany, being largely agricultural, was better suited to a policy of direct resettlement. Apart from this, the social policy adopted in Eastern Germany tended to reduce the local population to the level of a proletariat, where it was in much the same position as the refugees. Consequently, the two sections of the population merged together more quickly and completely. AID TO THE REFUGEES AND THEIR INTEGRATION IN THE ECONOMY Available data do not always give a clear picture of the way in which the refugees were integrated in the East German economy or of the difficulties encountered in the process. The Soviet military administration, and later the Government of the Democratic Republic, did not consider that aid to the refugees and their absorption in the economy posed any particular problem or called for special action. In 1945 the refugees became entitled to the same treatment as the local population in respect of social security and relief, i.e. they became eligible for all forms of relief to the needy, such as the distribution of clothing and household utensils, grants and loans from the State, political organisations, the trade unions and the churches. Until 1947,45 per cent. of the persons helped in this way were refugees. No special measures were taken to help the refugees to obtain housing. They were accommodated with the local population or lived 38 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 in camps and huts in the same way as local people who had lost their homes. All available accommodation was requisitioned as early as 1946 (as were all new homes) and allocated to both groups of the population in accordance with the same criteria, e.g. need, family circumstances and political record. The housing situation which for a long time was critical for the local population as well as for the refugees has improved considerably in recent years, but the demand is still far from being satisfied. The Government is making every effort to solve the problem as quickly as possible. The absorption of the refugees into the labour force took place automatically because of the gaps in the active population caused by war and emigration, the splitting up of the big estates under the 1945 land reform scheme, the policy of industrialisation which has been pursued since 1949 and the Government's general employment policy which, from the start, has been designed to achieve full employment even at the cost of relatively low productivity. In point of fact the great majority of the refugees had been found jobs by 1948 and since then they do not appear to have raised any particular problem. Moreover, the employment situation has shown a steady improvement since 1950. Whereas the population of working age remained stationary, the volume of employment increased from 5.3 million in 1950 to 6.4 million in 1955, while unemployment fell from 125,000 to 43,000. A high proportion of the refugees were resettled in agriculture which, at the end of 1956, occupied 29.5 per cent, of the refugee labour force and only 20.5 per cent, of the total labour force. The proportion of refugees absorbed by agriculture was, however, notably higher during the immediate post-war period when, as a result of land reform, large numbers of farmers and handicraft workers were resettled on the land. By the end of 1945 over 85,000 refugee families had been allotted holdings carved out of the confiscated estates, and many more thousands were settled in the following years. This scheme, however, was not wholly successful. The small size of the holdings, inadequate equipment, bad housing conditions (which often led to a lowering of health standards) and the inexperience of many of the settlers who were not farmers by trade led to a number of failures. The Government has tried to overcome these difficulties by granting loans for the purchase of equipment, improving housing standards and cutting compulsory deliveries. But there has been a large-scale drift from the land among both the refugees and the local population since 1950 as employment opportunities in the towns have expanded. The same is true of farm workers on both private and state farms, particularly the young men. NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 39 A distinctly higher proportion of the refugees entered industry, building and handicrafts, which accounted for over a third (34.2 per cent.) of the refugee labour force at the end of 1956 as against a proportion of 46.2 per cent, for the population as a whole. It was not always easy to fit them into urban occupations because many of the refugees had originally been settled, or at least housed, in rural areas and had to be moved again. The Government tried to control these moves by making the employment service responsible for them, and a major shift was organised by the authorities towards the industrial towns of Saxony and Thuringia. Such movements at first mainly affected skilled workers who were urgently needed by industry, but they later covered all workers who had any industrial experience. This policy was coupled with the establishment of new industries in the predominantly agricultural areas. Large numbers of refugee handicraft workers were resettled, at least in the early years, but few small employers, despite the loans given to some of them to start up in business again. The numbers of both have since fallen sharply as a result of the collectivisation policy which has forced many employers to join production co-operatives or to take jobs as employees of state concerns. In this respect the refugees have merely conformed to a general trend whereby the proportion of wage earners rose from 72 per cent, in 1950 to 79 per cent, in 1956 at the expense of the self-employed and workers in family businesses whose numbers during the same period fell by more than 400,000. The numbers of selfemployed handicraft workers and shopkeepers, in particular, dropped sharply and many of them preferred to emigrate rather than give up their independence. After the professional workers they account for the highest proportion of emigrants, there being no difference in this respect between the refugees and the local population. Lastly, private and public services and administrations afforded large numbers of jobs to the refugees, particularly the women; in fact the proportion of refugees in these sections of the economy was substantially higher at the end of 1956 than that of the local population. Thus, despite the redistribution of refugee manpower which has taken place, especially since 1950, under the impact of industrial expansion, there are still a number of major differences between its occupational structure and that of the local population, the main difference being, of course, the far higher proportion of persons employed in agriculture. This is not only due to the fact that the great bulk of the refugees were initially resettled in the rural areas, but also to the fact that they originally comprised a high percentage of farmers. Their arrival thus enabled Eastern Germany to carry out its policy of industrialisation without causing undue shortages of farm labour. 40 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 THE CONSEQUENCES OF IMMIGRATION Despite the profound differences between the two Germanys in matters of economic policy, the same problems arose in both as a result of the economic and social impact of immigration, but scarcity of data in the case of Eastern Germany precludes the kind of thoroughgoing analysis that has been attempted for Western Germany. Nevertheless, the conclusions appear to be much the same in both cases. The first is that the economy certainly benefited, both during reconstruction and during the period of industrial expansion that followed, from the availability of a larger labour force, despite an initial drop in over-all productivity and an excess of non-productive individuals among the refugees. The second conclusion is that in Eastern as well as in Western Germany the refugee population probably had to face special problems of adjustment, and while these were no doubt attenuated considerably as a result of the levelling process which took place under the new regime, a certain amount of inequality must have existed for quite a long time between the two sections of the population. Although these differences have gradually faded with time and the growing up of the younger generation, t is unlikely that they have yet completely disappeared. Bibliographical References Statistical Sources Western Germany. Unless otherwise stated, the statistics quoted in this chapter for Western Germany are taken from the following publications of the Federal Office of Statistics (Statistisches Bundesamt) : Statistisches Jahrbuch (published annually since 1953); Statistische Berichte (series VIII/7, VIH/12 and VIII/20); and Statistik der Bundesrepublik Deutschland (1950 census and section 114 which consolidates the statistics for expellees and refugees); and Wirtschaft und Statistik (published monthly since 1949). Reference can also be made to G. REICHLING: Die Heimatvertriebenen im Spiegel der Statistik, Schriften des Vereins für Sozialpolitik, Volume 6/JII (Berlin, Duncker & Humblot, 1958). The results of the 1946 census are given in a number of books, particularly that by F. EDDING, H. E. HORNSCHU and H. WANDER referred to below. Eastern Germany. For Eastern Germany the 1946 census figures have been taken from the book by P. H. SERAPHIM referred to below, and the remaining data from a document supplied by the Ministry of Labour and Vocational Training of the German Democratic Republic and unpublished data compiled by the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. NATIONAL REFUGEES IN GERMANY 41 Other Sources Western Germany. For Western Germany, in addition to the annual reports of the Organisation for European Economic Co-operation and the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe, the following works have been used: F. EDDING, H. E. HORNSCHU and H. WANDER: Das deutsche Flüchtlings- problem (Kiel, Institut für Weltwirtschaft an der Universität Kiel, 1949). Das deutsche Flüchtlingsproblem, Sonderheft der Zeitschrift für Raumforschung (published at Bielefeld in 1950 by F. Eilers Verlag GmbH for the Institut für Raumforschung, Bonn). ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION ADMINISTRATION, TECHNICAL ASSISTANCE COMMISSION ON THE INTEGRATION OF THE REFUGEES IN THE GERMAN REPUBLIC: The Integration of Refugees into German Life, Report to the Chancellor of the Federal Republic of Germany (Washington, D.C., 1951) (one volume of text and one volume of appendices). F. EDDING : The Refugee as a Burden, a Stimulus and a Challenge to the West German Economy, Publication IV, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1951). R. NIMPSCH: Übervölkerung Bevölkerungsausgleich und Arbeitsmarkt (Cologne, Bundverlag GmbH, 1952). INSTITUT ZUR FÖRDERUNG ÖFFENTLICHER ANGELEGENHEITEN e.V. : Europa und die deutschen Flüchtlinge, Wissenschaftliche Schriftenreihe des Instituts (Frankfurt-am-Main, 1952). EUROPEAN CENTRE FOR POPULATION STUDIES: Etudes européennes de popu- lation : main-d'œuvre, emploi, migrations ; situation et perspectives (Paris, Institut national d'études démographiques, 1954) (papers and record of proceedings of the European Population Conference held in Paris in May 1953). G. IPSEN: " Die Bevölkerung Mittel- und Westdeutschlands bis 1955 ", in Informationen (Bonn, Institut für Raumforschung), No. 27-29/54, 2 July 1954. E. PFEIL and E. W. BUCHOLZ: Eingliederungschancen und Eingliederungserfolge, Mitteilungen aus der Institut für Raumforschung, No. 35 (Bad Godesberg, 1958). K. HORSTMANN: " Die berufliche Eingliederung der Vertriebenen 1954/1955 ", in Wirtschaft und Statistik, new series (Bonn, Statistisches Bundesamt), 10th Year, No. 4, Apr. 1958, pp. 207-212. Use has also been made of the following studies published by Duncker & Humblot, Berlin, in Volumes 6 and 7 (Vol. 6: Grundfragen; and Vol. 7: Einzeldarstellungen) of the Schriften des Vereins für Sozialpolitik (Neue Folge) series under the general title " Untersuchungen zum deutschen Vertriebenenund Flüchtlingsproblem " : H. ARNDT: Die volkswirtschaftliche Eingliederung eines Bevölkerungszustroms, Wirtschaftstheoretische Einführung in das Vertriebenen- und Flüchtlingsproblem (6/1, 1954). G. SCHMÖLDERS: Finanzierungsprobleme im Zusammenhang mit der wirtschaftlichen Eingliederung der Heimatvertriebenen (6/II, 1955). G. REICHLING: Die Heimatvertriebenen im Spiegel der Statistik (6/III, 1958). G. ALBRECHT: Die wirtschaftliche Eingliederung der Heimatvertriebenen in Hessen (7/II, 1954). H. J. VON KÖRBER: Die Heimatvertriebenen und Flüchtlinge aus der Sowjetzone in Westberlin (7/III, 1954). 42 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 I. ESENWEIN-RÖTHE : Die Eingliederung der Flüchtlinge in die Stadtstaaten Bremen und Hamburg (7/IV, 1955). F. EDDING: Die wirtschaftliche Eingliederung der Heimatvertriebenen und Flüchtlinge in Schleswig-Holstein (7/V, 1955). Eastern Germany. For Eastern Germany, in addition to the Economic Survey of Europe in 1957, use has been made of other unpublished data compiled by the Economic Commission for Europe and a document communicated by the Ministry of Labour and Vocational Training of the German Democratic Republic to the International Labour Office under the title Überblick über die Lage der Umsiedler in der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik und die Untersstützung die ihnen zuteil wurde anhand der gesetzlichen Bestimmungen. The following has also been used: P. H. SERAPHIM: Die Heimatvertriebenen in der Sowjetzone, volume 7/1 of the Schriften des Vereins für Sozialpolitik, new series (Berlin, Duncker & Humblot, 1954). CHAPTER II OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE Apart from the exodus of German refugees, the changes in national frontiers and regimes which took place in Europe after the Second World War led to other large-scale population movements, mainly from eastern Europe towards other countries of the same area or towards central and southern Europe and the Near and Far East. Broadly speaking, these movements have been of three types : voluntary departures, outright expulsions and organised transfers. In addition to the people displaced in one way or another since the ending of hostilities, there were all those who for one reason or another had been forced to leave their countries of origin during the war itself and who were either unable or unwilling to go back. The persons affected by these various movements fall under two major headings: on the one hand, the " displaced persons " and the refugees in the commonly accepted sense of the term, both types being aliens in the countries receiving them, and, on the other hand, the " national refugees " and transferred minorities which from the start were granted the privileges of citizenship in the receiving countries. Refugees and Displaced Persons GENERAL SURVEY Movements of refugees and displaced persons took place at different times and were due to a whole series of events which it is not possible to describe in detail here. The war itself and the occupation of Central and Eastern Europe, first by the German and later by the Soviet armies, set off the first series of large-scale movements by soldiers, prisoners of war, political deportees, forced labourers and fugitives. Once the war was over a substantial proportion of these displaced persons were repatriated, either directly by the Allied military authorities or with their assistance under the auspices of the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration (U.N.R.R.A.). However, some of them, the majority of whom were in Germany at the time, were unwilling to 44 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 return home because of the new political regimes established in their native lands. In 1946 their number was estimated at 850,000. At the same time, a further mass movement took place from these countries, mainly towards Germany and Austria, and remained heavy until 1948. Since then it has fallen considerably but has not ceased altogether. It once more assumed major proportions in 1956-57, the main country of origin being Hungary, but with other refugees coming from Yugoslavia and China. Germany received the overwhelming majority of the post-war refugees—at least temporarily—although proportionately Austria received an even higher number, and because of its geographical position gave asylum to the bulk of the Hungarian refugees in 1956-57. Italy received large numbers of Yugoslavs, while Greece and, to a lesser extent, Turkey, also provided asylum for some of the refugees. In addition, Austria received a number of persons of German ethnic origin who had been expelled from various eastern European countries, particularly Rumania and Yugoslavia and who, not having the status of nationals of the receiving countries, can be classed as refugees in the accepted sense. The European refugees from China were initially received in Hong Kong. Unfortunately, it is impossible to give a complete statistical picture of these multi-directional movements since, for the most part they were not subject to any control. By 1946-47 the great majority of the displaced persons (perhaps 7 million in all) had gone back to their countries of origin so that this part of the first movement was statistically cancelled out before it was possible to gauge its exact extent. The only accurate figures available relate to the refugees and displaced persons who registered with the appropriate international organisations. But large numbers of them, for various reasons, did not do so and settled down independently. Moreover, the mandates of the international organisations responsible for the refugees—the Intergovernmental Committee on Refugees (I.G.C.R.)., the International Refugee Organisation (I.R.O.) the Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (U.N.H.C.R.) and U.N.R.R.A.—did not cover exactly the same categories of persons and in some cases included pre-war while excluding post-war refugees. Lastly, there is little information available about the natural population trend among the refugees or about those who acquired a new nationality and ceased, legally speaking, to be refugees. However, the statistics relating to the refugees who on 1 January 1952 were covered by the mandate of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, taken in conjunction with the other relevant data, disclose that some 2 million European displaced persons and refugees came at one time or other under international mandate as a OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 45 result of the war or the events of the immediate post-war period.1 This estimate does not include the much earlier emigrations by Russians, Armenians and Assyrians 2, or by Spaniards, but does take account of the refugees who by 1 January 1952 had acquired a new nationality. The Polish refugees, numbering about half a million (including servicemen of the Polish Expeditionary Corps, demobilised in the United Kingdom or elsewhere), formed by far the largest national group. Next in order of importance came the Hungarians (250,000, including the refugees of 1956-57), persons of German ethnic origin (Volksdeutsche) who took refuge in Austria, Baits, Ukrainians and Yugoslavs. The Russian, Czechoslovak and Rumanian groups were relatively small. All these national groups contained Jews, who had fled from political persecution and often accounted for a large proportion of the total group. Little is known of the demographic and occupational characteristics of these refugee populations. It may be stated, however, that among the displaced persons and refugees from Eastern Europe a definite majority consisted of young persons of working age and that there were appreciably more men than women. There was also a large number of very young children. Furthermore, the majority of those who had already worked for a living were either farm workers or skilled industrial workers and this, coupled with their relative youth, made it easier for most of them to find jobs. On the other hand, these populations did contain substantial minorities of non-manual workers who found the process of adjustment very painful. INTERNATIONAL ACTION: U.N.R.R.A., THE I.R.O., AND I.C.E.M. THE U.N.H.C.R. The earliest attempts to help European refugees through international action date back to the years immediately following the First World War. However, the efforts made to deal with the problems arising out of mass population movements after the Second World War were on a quite 1 On 1 January 1952, the number of European refugees under the mandate of the United Nations High Commissioner was some 1,250,000 in Europe, Africa and Asia (excluding Israel). By adding the number of persons repatriated or resettled by the I.R.O. outside Europe, Africa and Asia (900,000) and the Hungarian refugees of 1956-57, and deducting the former Russian, Armenian, Assyrian and Spanish refugees (some 250,000), one arrives at a total of roughly 2 million. 2 The Assyrians were a Christian minority group who before the First World War lived in Kurdistan and Persian Azerbaijan. During the war they were driven from the Ottoman Empire and subsequently resettled, mainly in Greece, Iraq, Lebanon and Syria. An agreement concerning their status was concluded in 1928. 46 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 unprecedented scale. With the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration and, above all, the International Refugee Organisation, such action also took on entirely new forms. In 1944, realising the scale and urgency of the problem of assisting the populations, whether displaced or not, which had been victims of the war, the governments of the United States and 43 other countries decided to establish the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration which was given responsibility, among other things, for assisting displaced persons. But the whole problem of refugees and displaced persons was so important that special action and appropriate machinery were obviously needed, and on 12 February 1946, the General Assembly of the United Nations decided to establish the International Refugee Organisation as a non-permanent specialised agency. This body started work in July 1947, and continued operations until the end of 1951. The tasks assigned to it included those formerly discharged by the League of Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, the Intergovernmental Committee for Refugees and U.N.R.R.A. It was responsible for giving legal protection to persons covered by its mandate, for providing such relief as they needed and for helping them either to go back to their countries of origin or to settle elsewhere. It was in this last field—resettlement—that the I.R.O., acting as a gigantic emigration agency, had the most marked and novel impact. To cope with its responsibilities it had a large staff1, and ample financial resources.2 Table 19 gives a general picture of its operations. The I.R.O. had been set up for only a limited period in the hope that the problem of the European refugees could be settled quickly. However, despite the extension of its mandate until the end of 1951, the tasks assigned to it had not been fulfilled even by that date: not only were more than 400,000 persons, many of them in camps, still awaiting resettlement but new refugees kept on arriving, though at a much slower rate. In order to relieve the I.R.O. of part of its work load, the United Nations in 1949 established the Office of the High Commissioner for Refugees, which took over responsibility for their legal protection. The High Commissioner took up his duties in January 1951 and his terms of reference have since been extended to include some of the functions which the I.R.O. had continued to discharge until the end; others were transferred to the Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration, which was set up in November 1951.3 1 3,000 officials at the peak of its activity, most of whom were taken over from U.N.R.R.A. and the Intergovernmental Committee for Refugees. 2 Between July 1947 and December 1951, its total expenditure amounted to nearly 430 million dollars. 3 See below, Chapter IX. 47 OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE TABLE 19. SUMMARY O F I.R.O. OPERATIONS, (Thousands of persons) 1947-51 Country of registration Action taken Repatriated . . . Resettled . . . . Registered as having died or disappeared . . . . Total cases dealt with Total number of outstanding cases Registered for protection purposes only Austria Belgium France Western Germany Italy Miscellaneous 1 4.7 145.2 0.1 8.7 0.7 31.4 46.9 719.5 3.1 70.5 17.3 63.4 67.3 7.2 7.1 Total 72.8 2 1,038.4 15.4 165.3 8.8 32.2 833.7 80.9 87.7 97.2 1,208.6 15.5 2.0 11.6 68.6 22.2 7.3 127.7 7.7 9.3 181.1 71.4 3.7 9.9 282.7 188.5 20.1 224.9 973.8 106.8 104.9 1,619.0 Total cases regis- Source : I.R.O. : Statistical Report (July ¡947-Dec. 1951). 1 Including 7,800 refugees registered in the Middle East, 15,800 in East Africa and 40,200, including 11,100 Chinese, in the Far East. * Including 11,200 Chinese repatriated to various Far Eastern countries. The first of these two agencies provides all the refugees with legal protection and, if they still need it, with material assistance. It also helps them to become stabilised through repatriation, settlement locally or emigration and resettlement. The second makes the necessary arrangements (selection, administrative formalities, transport and placement) in the case of refugees choosing to emigrate. In 1954 the General Assembly of the United Nations authorised the High Commissioner's Office to undertake a programme designed to achieve " permanent solutions " to the refugee problem, and since the latter has no authority to engage in operational work its efforts to this end have been directed primarily towards preparing and co-ordinating schemes to facilitate integration locally or resettlement elsewhere, in co-operation with governments and voluntary organisations. For this purpose it can draw upon a special fund made up of voluntary contributions from governments and private bodies. Apart from public agencies such as the I.R.O., the High Commissioner's Office and I.C.E.M., a number of voluntary organisations, whether lay or religious1, have played a very important part and considerably enhanced the effectiveness of the former. 1 These organisations are grouped together in a Standing Conference of Voluntary Agencies Working for Refugees. 48 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 RELIEF, ASSISTANCE AND LEGAL PROTECTION Refugees and displaced persons were speedily provided with relief and assistance in one form or another through the combined efforts of the authorities in the various receiving countries, voluntary organisations and the appropriate international agencies. Owing to the housing shortage in these countries the refugees could initially be accommodated by the authorities only in camps, where provision was made for their support (including that of refugees who managed to find accommodation elsewhere). The number of camps and their inmates has declined over the years, and by the summer of 1957 they contained no more than 58,000 persons in five receiving countries (Austria, Western Germany, Greece, Italy and Turkey), whereas ten years previously there had been 350,000 in Austria, Western Germany and Italy alone. The task of running these camps and maintaining the refugees, which had originally been discharged by the local civilian or military authorities and later by U.N.R.R.A., was one of the main responsibilities of the I.R.O. for many years, and after the I.R.O. was dissolved it was taken over by the governments themselves. In the days of the I.R.O. the authorities provided not only accommodation and maintenance but also assistance in many other forms, ministering to practically all the needs of the vast and heterogeneous refugee population. The I.R.O. set up medical and hospital services and provided a wide range of preventive and treatment facilities. As part of its welfare policy, it organised vocational training and language courses to equip the refugees to earn their own living, and sought in every possible way to counteract the effects of idleness and discouragement. It also tried, wherever possible, to enlist the active support of the refugees themselves and some of them were assigned to medical or administrative duties or employed in the manufacture of clothing for the camp population. Some of these relief and assistance arrangements, e.g. emergency relief, aid to " difficult cases " and vocational training, have been taken over by the High Commissioner's Office. Loans have also been granted to craftsmen to help them set up in business on their own account and a large-scale effort has been made to improve the refugees' housing standards. In order to meet the refugees' longer-term interests, relief and assistance were combined with legal protection granted first by the I.R.O. and later by the High Commissioner's Office to all refugees covered by their mandate. Such protection is automatically available to all who are unable or unwilling to avail themselves of the protection of a government. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 49 This eligibility for protection distinguishes the refugees referred to in this section from all the other European refugees covered by this study. It is mainly designed to prevent them from being discriminated against and to ensure that whatever country they live in they are granted their full economic and social rights. In fact, some governments have even been induced by international action to grant certain privileges to the refugees as compared with other aliens. Lastly, the High Commissioner's Office supervises the enforcement of the international instruments which are designed for the protection of refugees or which directly affect them. The most important is the Convention concerning the status of refugees, concluded in 1951 1, which lays down a set of general principles governing their rights and makes provision for governments to issue them travel documents. VOLUNTARY REPATRIATION Large numbers of displaced persons were voluntarily repatriated before 1947, but the exact figures are not known. Since that date such movements have ceased to be of any significance. The I.R.O., at any rate, has repatriated 61,700 persons, 38,000 of them to Poland and nearly 7,000 to Yugoslavia. Since 1952 it has been impossible to keep as close a check on the " official " repatriations because the High Commissioner's Office is not always notified of the action taken on the applications it forwards to the countries of origin. It would appear, however, that during the last few years repatriations have not exceeded more than a few hundred a year (not including Hungarian refugees having left the country after 1956, of whom 15,700 altogether had been repatriated by the end of March 1958). RESETTLEMENT The vast majority of refugees, at least after 1947, preferred to settle locally or, far more often, to be resettled in other countries rather than be repatriated. Most of this re-emigration took place under I.R.O. auspices between 1947 and 1951. The I.R.O. was able to carry out this immense undertaking because of the humanitarian sympathy shown by many governments, which 1 By June 1958 this Convention had been ratified by the following 22 countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Federal Republic of Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, Monaco, Morocco, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, Tunisia, U.S.S.R., United Kingdom and the State of the Vatican. 50 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 gave the refugees preferential treatment under their general immigration policy. The United States even passed emergency legislation to admit several hundred thousand refugees who would not have been able to enter under the ordinary immigration laws. 1 Some countries deliberately took in the disabled, the sick and the aged. On the other hand, the efforts made to resettle the refugees were not inspired by generosity alone. The refugees were a useful source of labour for certain countries, and up to a certain point were given priority treatment for this reason. In carrying out its resettlement programme the I.R.O. negotiated with various governments and concluded formal agreements with many of them. It also set up a full-scale emigration service to handle administrative formalities, part of the selection procedure, transport arrangements 2, and to pay part of the cost. Considerable efforts were also made by the I.R.O. to resettle non-manual workers, an undertaking in which it was assisted by the I.L.O. After the I.R.O. was wound up the High Commissioner's Office and I.C.E.M. continued to deal in the same way with the hard core of refugees who remained at the end of 1951 and with the refugees of later years, particularly the Hungarians who left their country in 1956-57. The figures quoted in tables 20, 21 and 22 show the scale of the resettlement schemes carried out up to the end of 1957, under the TABLE 20. REFUGEES RESETTLED BY THE I.R.O., BY COUNTRY OF DEPARTURE, 1947-51 (In thousands) Countries of departure 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 Total France Western Germany. Italy Miscellaneous . . 10.6 0.1 1.1 70.7 3.9 1.3 43.2 1.3 8.1 152.5 28.2 2.8 51.8 2.2 6.4 259.1 12.6 4.7 21.8 1.1 6.5 140.2 11.1 3.8 17.9 3.9 9.4 97.0 14.7 4.6 145.2 8.7 31.4 719.5 70.5 17.2 Total . . . 87.7 236.1 336.7 184.5 147.5 992.4 . . . . 5.6 1.9 12.9 4.2 2.8 1.8 6.8 3.7 3.3 0.3 3.1 24.3 19.3 2.8 . . . 95.1 255.9 345.3 191.5 150.8 1,038.7 Europe : Austria Middle East Far East Unknown Total Source: I.R.O.: Statistical Report (July 1947-Dec. 1951). 1 2 See below, Chapter VII. The I.R.O. at one time had its own fleet of ships and aircraft. 51 OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE TABLE 21. REFUGEES RESETTLED BY THE I.R.O., BY COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1947-51 (In thousands) Countries of destination 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 Total Africa North and Central America and Caribbean : Canada United States . . Other countries . 1.0 1.2 0.9 0.5 0.1 3.7 1.1 9.3 0.3 40.8 12.3 0.7 28.6 128.3 0.5 15.9 88.1 0.2 30.4 90.8 0.1 123.5 328.9 1.9 Total . . . 17.3 53.9 157.4 104.2 121.4 454.2 South America : Argentina Brazil . . Chile . . Paraguay Venezuela Miscellaneo us . . 3.3 1.8 0.2 0.5 2.8 0.6 18.3 7.7 1.5 4.3 9.0 3.0 6.4 13.8 1.9 0.5 1.5 1.4 2.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 2.7 1.3 1.7 4.2 0.7 0.2 1.3 1.5 32.7 28.8 5.1 5.9 17.3 7.8 Total . . . 9.2 43.8 25.6 9.4 9.6 97.6 Asia : Israel Miscellaneous . . 7.5 63.8 1.6 53.7 0.6 5.4 0.3 1.7 0.2 132.1 2.9 Total . . . 7.5 65.5 54.4 5.7 1.9 135.0 Europe : Belgium France United Kingdom . Miscellaneous 1 15.9 8.6 29.5 3.4 5.9 16.0 50.9 4.0 0.4 12.2 2.1 1.1 0.2 1.2 2.8 1.1 0.1 0.3 1.1 1.8 22.5 38.5 86.3 11.5 Total . . . 57.4 76.8 15.9 5.3 3.3 158.8 Oceania : Australia . . . . New Zealand . . 1.3 14.3 0.1 89.7 1.0 65.2 1.1 11.6 2.6 182.2 4.8 Total . . . 1.3 14.4 90.7 66.3 14.3 187.0 Miscellaneous and unknown . . . . 1.3 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 2.5 95.1 255.9 345.3 191.5 150.8 1,038.7 Tota Source: I.R.O.: Statistical Report (July 1947-Dec. 1951). 1 Mainly the Netherlands and Sweden. TABLE 22. REFUGEES PRESUMED TO BE COVERED BY THE HIGH COMMISSIONER'S MANDATE l RESETTLED UNDER THE AUSPICES OF I.C.E.M. BETWEEN 1 FEBRUARY 1952 AND 31 DECEMBER 1957 (In thousands) Countries of immigration Countries of emigration Argentina Australia Brazil Canada Chile Israel New Zealand Total Union of South Africa Other countries U.S.A. Venezuela Absolute figures Percentages Overseas European pa Z > a o z. > Europe : Austria . . . West. Germany Greece . . . Italy . . . . Other countries 1.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.8 14.7 2.7 0.3 5.8 6.3 1.9 1.3 0.3 1.3 1.4 25.0 5.2 0.4 4.0 12.3 0.4 0.1 2.0 0.2 0.9 0.2 0.1 19.8 0.1 Total . . . 2.2 29.9 6.2 47.0 1.6 22.1 1.3 Far East . . . Other regions 0.1 3.1 0.1 3.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.4 Total . . . 2.3 33.2 9.8 47.3 1.9 22.5 1.0 t-> 0.1 0.1 35.5 25.7 1.8 2.5 19.3 0.7 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.7 0.2 0.6 0.3 29.4 0.4 0.7 2.2 5.2 113.4 36.6 4.0 18.1 66.2 45.5 14.7 1.6 7.3 26.6 1.7 84.7 1.4 2.3 37.9 238.3 95.7 0.3 0.3 0.1 1.4 0.7 10.0 0.8 4.0 0.3 85.3 1.5 3.8 38.6 249.1 100.0 1.3 0.2 0.1 H O z •p>. 1.3 1.7 Source: I.C.E.M. : Information concerning Refugee Movements Effected by I.C.E.M. during the Period 1 February 1952 to 31 December 19J7, Doc. MC/INF/53 (mimeographed). 1 Only a part of the statistical data concerning refugees is based on accurate counts of persons whose refugee status has been individually examined according to a recognised eligibility procedure. The term " refugee " in statistics issued by the Office of the U.N.H.C.R. should therefore be interpreted as applying to '* persons presumed to come within the competence of the Office of the U.N.H.C.R. according to its Statute". OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 53 auspices first of the I.R.O. and alter of I.C.E.M. They show that officially about 1.3 million European refugees were resettled under international mandate between1 July 1947 and December 1957. Of these, some 1,050,000 1 emigrated under I.R.O. auspices: 720,000 from Germany, 145,000 from Austria, and 70,000 from Italy. Included in this total were nearly 360,000 Poles, over 160,000 Baits, over 110,000 Ukrainians and over 80,000 Yugoslavs. The main countries of resettlement were the United States (31.7 per cent.), Australia (17.5 per cent.), Israel (12.7 per cent.), and Canada (11.9 per cent.). The I.C.E.M. had, by the end of 1957, arranged for some 250,000 refugees to emigrate. Nearly half (113,000) came from Austria, most of them being Hungarian refugees who had entered during 1956-57. The four major countries of destination remained the United States (35.6 per cent.), Canada (19.7 per cent.), Australia (12.5 per cent.) and Israel (9.3 per cent.). These figures naturally do not cover movements made without assistance from international agencies, which have doubtless raised the total number of post-war European refugees resettled outside their original country of asylum to well over the official figure of 1.3 million. SETTLEMENT IN COUNTRIES OF ASYLUM Lastly, substantial numbers of displaced persons and refugees were absorbed in the countries where they first found asylum.2 Unfortunately it is impossible to quote any statistics in this respect since many of the refugees adopted the nationality of the receiving country (particularly persons of German ethnic origin who took refuge in Austria) so that legally speaking there is nothing to distinguish them from the remainder of the population. Absorption by the local economies was not always easy as all of these countries were already overpopulated, as some of them still are to this day. Moreover, those of the refugees who settled there did not always do so of their own free will but because they did not come up to thé selection standards of the main immigration countries. It was this situation that led the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees to launch a scheme aimed at providing satisfactory employment for refugees who had not yet managed to do so themselves, under the so-called " permanent solutions " programme. 1 1,039,000 persons up to the end of 1951 plus about 10,000 in the early part of 1952. This section does not cover countries such as Belgium and France, which were at one and the same time countries of immigration and asylum. 2 54 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 In Greece the influx of refugees of G r e e k 1 or foreign origin merely added to the existing state of overpopulation and had to be absorbed by an economy which had been disrupted for several years by the strife following the ending of the Second World War. The result was that the refugees merely swelled the numbers of unemployed and underemployed. Of the 16,000 who were still left in the country by the summer of 1957 only half were permanently settled.2 The position is not much better in Italy where there has been a large manpower surplus ever since the war and the authorities have had to take special steps to fit a large number of national refugees into the economy. On top of this, refugees from Yugoslavia have continued to enter the country until the present day. Out of a total of some 20,000 refugees under mandate only half can be considered to have been integrated.3 These figures, however, are insignificant compared with the number of refugees under mandate who were permanently settled—usually under better conditions—in Western Germany and Austria. In the Federal Republic of Germany the number of refugees under mandate has steadily fallen, despite the natural population increase and new arrivals, from 800,000 in 1948 to 220,000 in 1957. Most of this fall was accounted for by emigration; naturalisation, which involved some 25,000 persons, did not play an important part. The number of foreign refugees living in the Federal Repubhc is therefore of the order of 250,000—a relatively negligible figure compared with the total number of national refugees. The integration of these foreigners was slow during the early years, but progressed rapidly during the boom of the fifties. The authorities have also taken steps to facilitate the process, and the status of foreign refugees in Western Germany is in many ways more favourable than what the 1951 Convention provides for. Until the last few years, however, the number of unemployed among the foreign refugees remained high, and when the I.R.O. was dissolved they lost the employment opportunities which that agency had provided 1 These were refugees of Greek stock from Rumania and the Soviet Union to whom the Greek Government refused to grant Greek citizenship. They became the responsibility first of the I.R.O. and later of the High Commissioner's Office. 2 This figure and those quoted hereafter are given in a survey carried out by the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees during the summer of 1957 of the position of the refugees in a certain number of countries. See United Nations, General Assembly: Survey of the Non-Settled Refugee Population in Various Countries, Report submitted to the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, Document A/AC. 79/111, 28 Apr. 1958 (mimeographed). 3 According to information supplied by the Ministry of the Interior, the number of foreign refugees authorised to work in Italy in October 1958 was 1,264, of whom 546 were self-employed. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 55 for them. Since then, the number of unemployed has fallen sharply with the trend towards over-full employment and the easing of the housing shortage, which has made large-scale internal migration possible. The Federal Institute for Placement and Unemployment Insurance has issued a series of instructions to local placement officers since 1955 with the aim of ending unemployment among the foreign refugees. At the present time the unemployment problem appears to have been reduced to a fairly small number of difficult cases. The Hungarian refugees seem to have had no trouble in finding jobs. The scale of the problem has been much greater in Austria. While, as in Western Germany, the number of foreign refugees fell substantially since 1948, this was due primarily to naturalisation, which involved nearly 300,000 persons, most of them refugees of German ethnic origin, rather than to emigration. By the summer of 1957 the number of refugees under international mandate living in Austria was no more than 77,000, of whom 35,000 were settled and the remainder about to emigrate. Allowing for emigration by persons who had previously been naturalised, the number of refugees who finally settled down in Austria may be reckoned at not less than 300,000. Despite the large gaps caused by the war in the Austrian labour force, which the refugees partly filled, it was not easy to absorb an influx amounting to a population increase of nearly 5 per cent. Austria before the war suffered from underemployment and it was many years after the end of hostilities before full employment could be achieved, thanks to the Government's policy of industrial development. The refugees, therefore, were only absorbed gradually and the trouble many of them had in finding work was a major cause of emigration up to 1953. Since then, however, their position has steadily improved. For a long time their only major employment outlet was in agriculture, which has suffered from a persistent shortage of labour since the war. Most of the refugees, partly because of circumstances and partly also because of official restrictions, had virtually no alternative. Many of them, however, came from country districts and found it quite easy to settle down. But with the recent growth of industry and the mechanisation of agriculture which has accompanied it, the situation has changed completely, and with the raising of the restrictions on the employment of refugees outside agriculture, many of them have entered other occupations which initially were only open to fairly small numbers of highly skilled workers. The result is that the refugee population of Austria— most of whom are by now naturalised citizens—has in recent years made great strides towards complete integration. 56 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 CONCLUSION The problem of European refugees under international mandate has been virtually solved. Some of them have re-emigrated to overseas countries where, in most cases, they have immediately been absorbed and have usually settled down satisfactorily, while others have remained in Europe where, admittedly, their lot has been a more difficult one ; but by and large the plight of the refugees as such is largely a thing of the past. How far they still show signs of the economic and social inferiority which usually characterises immigrant populations, and what proportion of them have been forced down the scale as a result, is another matter and one on which no precise data are available. All that can be said is that their lot has varied tremendously, depending on a number of factors such as nationality, employment background, the attitude of the local population and, of course, the character of each individual. The latter has probably been decisive. To sum up, while the integration of some 2 million foreign refugees, now complete, must be reckoned a general success both for the refugees themselves and for the countries that have given them asylum, the physical and psychological cost of this readjustment must not be underrated. Above all, it is important not to lose sight of the human problem raised by those refugees who have not yet been absorbed (and whose number in the summer of 1957 was put at 113,000 by the High Commissioner's Office *) and also of those whose abilities have not been put to proper use, e.g. professional workers who were forced to take manual jobs and adjus \ to them as best they could, or manual workers qualified for much more highly skilled jobs. The hard core of refugees, particularly those who are still in the camps, constitutes a baffling problem. Many of them, because of age, health or personality, are what are usually called " difficult cases " and all the efforts made so far to resettle them have been a failure. Because of these continued difficulties and the trouble encountered by some refugees in finding housing, the General Assembly of the United Nations instructed the High Commissioner in the autumn of 1957 to intensify his search for a permanent solution to the problem of refugees whose cases were still outstanding. At the same time, in order to meet the continuing need for international protection, the High Commissioner's mandate, which was due to expire on 31 December 1958, was extended for five years. 1 This figure included refugees from Hungary and Yugoslavia who were in the process of being resettled or being helped to emigrate. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 57 National Refugees in Italy, Finland and Turkey The war and its aftermath also led to mass movements by persons normally described as " national refugees ". These are refugees who have kept their original nationality or who, having lost it, have been granted the nationality of the country of asylum whose language they speak and whose culture they share. These movements have usually taken the form of expulsions, irrespective of whether or not a change of frontier was involved. In addition to the German expellees who have been dealt with at some length, this second category comprises Italian nationals from territories lost by Italy as a result of the war, Finnish nationals from the Finnish territory ceded to the Soviet Union and Bulgarian nationals of Turkish ethnic origin expelled from Bulgaria. ITALY Italian national refugees include, first of all, some 200,000 expellees who, under the peace treaty, were forced to leave the part of VeneziaGiulia and the Dalmatian coast ceded to Yugoslavia. In addition there were some 30,000 Italian nationals from the Dodecanese Islands and 220,000 who were repatriated from the former Italian colonies in Africa. This influx of national refugees (in the widest sense of the term) constituted a heavy burden for a country already faced with a large manpower surplus. The Italian Government took steps to assist this refugee population and a number of private bodies also helped. Official reception centres were set up through which about one-third of the refugees passed. Some of them re-emigrated, and on this account were given preferential treatment; of those repatriated from North Africa, some later went back. Nevertheless, most of the refugees and repatriated citizens appear to have settled down as best they could in Italy itself and by 1953 about 160,000 of them had found work. Little else is known about their fate. FINLAND Far more complete information is available concerning the population movements which have taken place in Finland and the way in which the refugees have been absorbed. There have been two such population shifts in Finland. The first occurred as a result of the Moscow treaty signed on 12 March 1940 58 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 whereby Finland ceded Finnish Karelia and the territory of Salla to the Soviet Union. The second took place following the armistice (confirmed by the Paris treaty of 10 February 1947) which terminated the second Finno-Soviet War in 1944. Under this armistice, Finland finally relinquished the territories she had ceded in 1940 and was also required to sell the districts of Petsamo and Janikoski. Both the 1940 treaty and the 1944 armistice provided for the evacuation of the entire Finnish population living in the territories concerned. The first evacuation affected 485,000 persons—the vast majority of them from Karelia. The second involved far fewer people since not all the people transferred in 1940 had gone back to their old homes when Finland had reoccupied this area during the war. These refugees represented a major problem since the transfers suddenly increased the population living within the new frontiers of Finland by some 15 per cent. Their absorption was no easy task for a country which had been seriously weakened economically by war damage and by the loss of certain territories. The relatively short time within which it was nevertheless carried out was due to the low population density, which gave fairly wide scope for resettlement on the land, as well as to the swift industrial development of the post-war years and the Government's energetic action in giving top priority to the matter. The experience acquired in the resettlement schemes which followed the first evacuation also helped to make the process faster and smoother after the second. Despite the short time allowed, both evacuations were orderly, thanks to efficient transport and accommodation arrangements. Most of the evacuees were sent to the southern part of the country, which is the most advanced and most thickly populated. Communities were, as far as possible, kept together. Only part of the refugees went on public relief—380,000 persons during the first evacuation and 138,000 during the second. According to a census carried out in 1940, over half of the refugee population (55.2 per cent.) consisted of persons employed in agriculture, while 16.9 per cent, were industrial workers and 28.1 per cent, had worked in the service trades. These proportions were much the same as among the remainder of the population, although the percentage engaged in agriculture was markedly higher among the refugees. Absorption in occupations other than agriculture was not particularly difficult as there was immediately after the war an acute shortage of labour, both skilled and unskilled, in many trades owing to the needs of reconstruction and reparations. This expansion of employment, however, was accompanied by galloping inflation which would probably OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 59 have been difficult to avoid in any case, but was made a good deal worse by the presence of the refugees. This first phase of expansion, which enabled large numbers of refugees to enter non-agricultural employment, was followed by a second phase during which there were marked gains in productivity and the economy went through a period of consolidation. On the other hand, resettlement in agriculture, which involved something like half the refugee population, called for special measures because there was no need for an increase in the farm labour force and large numbers of demobilised soldiers were also anxious to buy their own farms. Emergency legislation was accordingly passed in both 1940 and 1945—the 1945 enactment being the more drastic of the two—to provide the displaced farmers with holdings of their own. Most of the land required was obtained by means of partial expropriation varying progressively in accordance with the area owned ; compensation was paid on the basis of 1944 values. The remainder was obtained by bringing new land under cultivation. As a result of these measures, the number of holdings of less than 25 hectares doubled whereas the number of those above this limit fell by 20 per cent. By 30 June 1950 over 37,000 new farms had been set up and equipped and more than 80 per cent, of the applications had been met. Some of the evacuees, however, either refused the land they were offered or later gave it up and left farming altogether, particularly as industrial expansion had created ample employment opportunities in other fields. By 1950 the problem of integrating the refugees into the Finnish economy had been virtually solved, but only at the cost of heavy sacrifices on the part of the rest of the population. These sacrifices were considerably increased by the compensation legislation which was passed both in 1940 and in 1945. The latter enactment, patterned after the former, introduced heavy new taxes, including a progressive capital levy (in addition to the land expropriation scheme). A small share of the actual compensation was paid in cash, the rest being in the form of government bonds or shares in a holding company, the capital of which was provided by a large number of companies and institutions which were required to hand over 20 per cent, of their assets. Payments under this scheme, coupled with the cost of repairing war damage, led to consideraable inflation, although to some extent the recipients of compensation were protected against rising prices because their bonds were pegged to the cost-of-living index. Despite this very heavy burden of taxation it was only sufficient to meet about two-fifths of the refugees' claims. These sacrifices—of which the landowners doubtless had to bear the brunt—have probably, as in Germany, been more than offset by the refugees' contribution to economic growth over the last 12 years. As 60 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 early as 1950, the average standard of living was above the pre-war level and the net result of this influx of refugees may well have been to hasten the egalitarian trend in Finnish society. TURKEY There are a number of analogies between the absorption of the refugees of Turkish ethnic origin expelled from Bulgaria and that of the national refugees who entered Finland. The problem, however, was less acute in Turkey where the number of refugees was small compared with the total population. On 12 August 1950 the Bulgarian Government decided to expel the final remnants of the Turkish minority who had been living in Bulgaria for many centuries. Under this decision, 250,000 persons were given three months to leave the country. The result was a large-scale exodus, which formed a sequel to the voluntary emigration of preceding years and extended until November 1951. However, only 154,000 persons, i.e. considerably less than the planned figure, left the country during 1950 and 1951. Initially, the influx was so large and sudden that the Turkish Government was quite unable to provide the refugees with the assistance they needed. It took time to set up satisfactory reception facilities, although technical assistance was supplied by the I.R.O. and direct aid by the World Health Organisation and a number of voluntary organisations, including the International Red Cross. Centres were opened both at the frontier and at Istanbul, where the refugees were given emergency assistance by the Government before being dispersed throughout the provinces. The local authorities were made responsible for the final phase of the assistance programme, and for apportioning its cost among the population as a whole. Simultaneously, the Government undertook a resettlement scheme. No special measures were needed to find jobs for the non-agricultural workers, of whom there were relatively few and who appear to have been fitted in without any difficulty because of the rapid expansion of the Turkish economy at the time. On the other hand, as most of the refugees were farmers or rural handicraftsmen, a major effort was made in the field of land settlement. The Government also launched a housing drive. Under legislation passed in 1950, all refugees who had been engaged in farming in Bulgaria were entitled to a free grant of land and farm implements. A special agency was set up under the Ministry of Agriculture to handle this scheme which appears to have operated fairly smoothly thanks to an abundance of uncultivated land, most of it OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 61 state-owned and consisting mainly of property abandoned by the Greeks between 1922 and 1928; the rest was obtained either by land clearance or by expropriating property owned by religious bodies. Provision was made where possible for the refugees to be resettled in a natural environment similar to that in which they had lived previously. The area of the holdings was calculated having regard to the quality of the land, the nature of the crops and the size of the family units. An attempt was also made to distribute as many refugees as possible among existing communities. By the end of 1952 most of them had been resettled, a total of 85,000 hectares, averaging about 5 hectares per holding, having been shared out among nearly 16,000 families. Large quantities of implements, livestock and seeds were made available and loans totalling 7.2 million dollars were granted to some 15,000 families. The resettlement scheme covered 44 out of the 63 provinces, most of them along the shores of the Black Sea and the Aegean Sea and in southern and eastern Anatolia. Most of the families were settled in existing villages and only about 50 new ones were built. There are no accurate figures regarding the Government's outlay on this huge scheme although its cost has been estimated at about 20 million dollars. A small part of this cost—about 2.8 million dollars—was met by means of bank loans; a larger share—8.3 million dollars—was provided by American aid (through the Economic Co-operation Administration); and the remainder came from the country's regular budget, which had to be enlarged temporarily to meet the cost. Thus the resettlement of the refugees took place smoothly and relatively quickly. The prosperity which the country was enjoying at the time undoubtedly helped, but even more important was the energetic action taken by the Government. Transfers and Repatriations in Eastern Europe Little is known about the population transfers which took place between the eastern European countries and the repatriations to those countries from other parts of Europe or from the Soviet Union and even less is known about their economic and social repercussions. In most cases it is impossible to do more than quote a few statistics. NATURE AND SCOPE OF THE VARIOUS MOVEMENTS Most of the movements which fall under this heading can be classed with those discussed in the preceding section, both as regards their 62 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 purpose and the legal status of the population groups concerned. The aim of such transfers was to leave the countries of origin with a homogeneous population, and the persons affected were granted the nationality of the countries in which they were resettled. However, owing to the way in which these moves were organised, i.e. under negotiated agreements which gave the persons concerned a variety of safeguards and material facilities and provided for co-operation between the authorities of the various countries, such persons cannot be classed as refugees and certainly not as expellees.1 The resulting population shifts took two forms: transfers of minorities and repatriations. The transfers affected not only populations living in areas which changed sovereignty as a result of the peace treaties, but ethnic minorities in general. The repatriations involved persons who had been driven either westward or eastward by the war, e.g. members of the armed forces, prisoners of war, political deportees and forced labourers, together with a number of pre-war economic migrants and political emigrants who were induced to return to their homelands by assiduous propaganda from all the eastern European countries. The economic straits in which some of them found themselves by the time the war ended seem to have contributed towards the success of this propaganda, which even so was only partial. Poland Of all the eastern European countries, Poland was the scene of the largest population shifts in one direction or another. At the Yalta Conference the Curzon line was, apart from some changes in detail, accepted as Poland's eastern frontier and this was confirmed by the Moscow treaty of 15 February 1951. Subsequently, the Potsdam Agreement gave Poland all the provinces within the pre-war frontiers of Germany to the east of the Oder-Neisse line, with the exception of the northern half of East Prussia which was annexed by the Soviet Union. Thus the territory of Poland, after losing some 70,000 square miles to the Soviet Union, was enlarged by another 45,000 square miles of former German territory. The great bulk of the population of the territories annexed by the Soviet Union, which in 1939 totalled nearly 12 million inhabitants, was made up of nationalities other than Polish, mainly Lithuanian, Byelorussian and Ukrainian. The Poles nevertheless formed a substantial minority, which at the end of the war was estimated at 2 to 3 million. At the same time a significant, though 1 With the exception of the Hungarian minority which really was expelled from Czechoslovakia or, of course, the minorities of German ethnic origin. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 63 much smaller, minority of Lithuanians, Byelorussians and Ukrainians were left to the west of the new frontier. Even before the war ended, it had been decided that these populations should be exchanged. In September 1944 Poland signed three agreements (with the Soviet Socialist Republics of Byelorussia, the Ukraine and Lithuania) whereby it was decided to exchange the Poles and Jews who were living in the territories ceded by Poland to the Soviet Union for the Lithuanians, Byelorussians and Ukrainians still living to the west of the new frontier. The population of these territories was officially defined as including all those who were living there in 1939 and had been forced to move by the war. As a result of these agreements something like half a million individuals—50,000 Lithuanians, 30,000 Byelorussians and 420,000 Ukrainians—left Poland, while 1.5 million Poles and Jews x were transferred the other way, mostly in 1945-46; of these, 788,000 came from the Ukraine, 256,000 from Byelorussia, 178,000 from Lithuania and 256,000 from other parts of the Soviet Union. The exchange, however, was a voluntary one and some of the non-Polish minorities remained in Poland and were later moved to villages or towns in the west or north of the country while a number of Poles stayed behind in the Soviet Union, particularly in the bigger towns, such as Vilna, Pinsk and Lwow. In addition, half a million Poles came back to Poland during the years 1945-48 from the Soviet Union, where they had been moved during the war. The total number of Poles involved in this movement has been estimated at 1.2 million, but this figure appears to have been greatly exaggerated. Many others had managed to reach western Europe either during or immediately after the war. These repatriations were resumed in 1956 after the signing of an agreement with the Soviet Union on 18 December 1955 which covered all persons who had not been sentenced by the Soviet courts. Some 20,000 persons were repatriated in this way in 1956 and a further 80,000 in 1957. The process was due to be completed by the end of 1958. However, at that time the number of persons awaiting repatriation was still considerable. Nearly 1.5 million persons 2 were repatriated from western Europe during the years 1946-48, most of them from Germany. An agreement signed with France on 13 March 1946 led to the repatriation of some 50,000 Polish immigrants who had settled there between 1 To be exact, 1,503,000 of whom 723,000 were transferred in 1945 and 644,437 in 1946. 2 To be exact, 1,466,000. 64 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the two wars. These repatriations virtually came to a halt in 1950 and did not begin again until 1954 when an amnesty was granted to political exiles, with the result that a further group of over 40,000 went back in 1954-55. Since then the numbers involved appear to have been negligible. In addition, as mentioned earlier 1 , the expulsion of the German minority was decided on at Potsdam. This expulsion involved some 2.2 million persons 2 and had not been completed by the end of 1946, since nearly 540,000 Germans left the country in 1947 and a further 40,000 in 1948. There was also large-scale direct emigration to Israel between 1948 and 1950 and again after 1957.3 On balance, the net gain to the country's population—i.e., the surplus of transferred and repatriated Poles over emigrants, whether voluntary or forced, who were of foreign origin—though difficult to compute with any accuracy for a variety of reasons, amounted to about 1 million persons. The result was to make the local population almost completely homogeneous. Other Countries Czechoslovakia was mainly affected by the expulsion of the Sudeten German minority, decided on at Potsdam, which involved some 2.4 million persons.4 This expulsion was not complete, however, since at least 200,000 Germans remained in the country and have been granted Czechoslovak nationality. The Czechoslovak Government has also negotiated agreements with a number of governments, such as those of the Soviet Union, Hungary, Rumania and Yugoslavia, for the transfer to Czechoslovakia of populations of Czech or Slovak stock living abroad. Under two agreements signed on 29 June and 10 July 1946 with the Soviet Union in connection with the cession by Czechoslovakia of the Carpatho-Ukraine, it was decided to repatriate the small Czechoslovak minority in the province and the Czechs and Slovaks in Volhynia. No large-scale transfer appears to have taken place under the first agreement, although under the second, which was carried out between January and May 1947, some 30,000 people were sent back to Czechoslovakia. The agreement with Hungary, whereby some 70,000 Hungarians in Czechoslovakia were to be exchanged for 60,000 Czechs in Hungary, 1 See above, Chapter I. To be exact, 2,214,000. In point of fact the bulk of the German minority in both the old and the new Poland left before the expulsion took place. 3 See below, Chapter III. 4 Not counting those who left before the expulsion. 2 OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 65 was never signed. Instead the Czechoslovak Government ordered individual members of the Hungarian minority, estimated at 600,000 persons, to leave the country. About 100,000 individuals were expelled in this way between 1946 and 1948. Since then the Government's policy towards this minority has changed: the Hungarians are allowed to remain in the country and have been granted complete equality before the law. An agreement was also signed on 10 July 1946 with Rumania for the transfer of some 30,000 persons of Czech or Slovak origin and at the same time the Yugoslav Government gave its approval to the repatriation of the Czechoslovak minority in Yugoslavia. In addition to the return of these minorities from abroad, some 20,000 1 Czechoslovaks also came back from France, Belgium and Germany where they had settled between the two wars. A small proportion of the Czechoslovak minority in Austria likewise returned and, above all, there was the repatriation of Czechoslovak displaced persons from Germany and the Soviet Union between 1945 and 1947 (probably around 100,000). While it is impossible to quote any accurate figures, these various movements undoubtedly represented a substantial loss of population for Czechoslovakia, since the repatriation and transfers of her nationals did not come anywhere near filling the gaps left by the expulsion of Germans and Hungarians. Large-scale movements also took place to and from Hungary, although the only organised mass transfer out of the country was that of 178,000 persons representing part of the German minority whose expulsion had been agreed on at Potsdam. In the other direction, some 130,000 Hungarian displaced persons were repatriated between 1946 and 1947 and some 100,000 expellees came in from Czechoslovakia. In addition, an exchange of minorities with Yugoslavia took place under an agreement signed in September 1946, which provided for an exchange of 40,000 persons on each side. It would appear, however, that the transfers to Hungary under this agreement were appreciably higher than this figure, whereas the transfers in the other direction fell below it. These officiai figures, in any case, do not give a complete picture of migration to and from Hungary after 1947. They do not, for example, take into account the repatriations which took place in 1945, the influx during that same year of some 120,000 persons from the northern part of Transylvania (which had been ceded back to Rumania) nor the repatriations which took place after 1947, mainly from the Soviet Union. On balance, Hungary, unlike Czechoslovakia, had a large immigration surplus between 1945 and 1948. 1 Up to May 1947. 66 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The opposite happened in Rumania, despite the large areas ceded under the Paris treaty of 10 February 1947. This treaty merely confirmed, at least as regards the eastern and southern frontiers, the settlement made in 1940, whereby Bessarabia and Bukovina were ceded to the Soviet Union and the southern Dobrudja to Bulgaria. In the first two of these territories the Rumanian population had already been given a choice between adopting Soviet nationality or going back to Rumania, and only a fairly small proportion had opted for transfer. In the third a population transfer had taken place in 1940-41 and this had settled once and for all the minority questions still at issue between the two countries. As regards the repatriation of displaced persons, it has been estimated that some 80,000 of them returned in 1947-48 and that still more came back later. In the other direction, apart from the transfer of the Czechoslovak minority (some 30,000 persons) under the agreement of 10 July 1946, large numbers of Germans (about 200,000) and Hungarians (about 120,000) left Transylvania in 1944-45, without any expulsion being ordered. In addition, 70,000 members of the German ethnic minority were deported to the Soviet Union and from 1948 onwards there was heavy Jewish emigration to Israel without any obstacle being placed in its way by the Government.1 All of these various movements added up to a substantial emigration surplus. Bulgaria and Yugoslavia were in the same position, the former owing to the expulsion of more than 150,000 members of the Turkish minority in 1950-51, and the latter because of the departure of part of the Italian minority in Venezia-Giulia and Dalmatia (some 200,000 persons) and the transfers of Hungarians and Czechoslovaks under the agreements negotiated with the Governments of Hungary and Czechoslovakia referred to earlier. TRANSFER AND RESETTLEMENT ARRANGEMENTS The conditions in which these movements took place varied enormously depending on the time at which they occurred and the countries carrying them out. At first, transport and reception facilities were inadequate, to say the least. It was often technically and financially impossible for countries having suffered severely from the war to provide the migrants even with the most elementary facilities. Many of them, for instance, had to travel hundreds of miles on foot. Nevertheless, the position improved once machinery had been set up to organise the transfers and assist the migrants. Repatriation centres providing free accommodation, food and medical care were usually set up close to the frontiers and in the districts chosen for the collective resettlement of the 1 See below, Chapter III. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 67 displaced populations. The employment authorities seconded officials to give the immigrants any advice and assistance to help them find useful work as quickly as possible. Transport was also supplied to the place of final settlement. The agreements under which these transfers took place contained clauses allowing migrants to take their possessions with them, often including handicraft or farming implements, and the migrants were usually able to avail themselves of this privilege because the agreement gave them adequate time in which to make the necessary arrangements. They were also allowed to sell any property not earmarked for nationalisation. Needless to say, measures of this nature were confined to the transferees and were not extended to those actually expelled, i.e. the Germans and the Hungarians, whose property was confiscated in all cases.1 In the case of population exchanges properly so-called, the agreements provided for corresponding exchanges of property. Before leaving, migrants were required to obtain from the authorities in their country of origin a certificate specifying the nature, amount and value of the property left behind. Even in cases where there was not, strictly speaking, an exchange, the same procedure was sometimes followed so that the migrants could later substantiate their claims to compensation. Moreover, the property confiscated from the expellees in Czechoslovakia and Poland was used partly for the resettlement of the transferred or repatriated populations, to whom the land was either given outright, if they were entitled to compensation, or, if not, sold on very favourable terms. Special concessions were usually made to ease the lot of transferred and repatriated persons, who often had to face considerable hardship. Poland, for example, granted them complete exemption from customs duties and free transport within the country. Their right to housing and suitable employment was formally recognised. Periods of employment abroad were taken into account in reckoning holiday and pension rights, and free medical care was made available until they qualified for benefit under the sickness insurance scheme. More recently, grants have been made to needy repatriates in order to tide them over the initial stages of resettlement, and long-term loans have been made to the self-employed to set them up again in their trades or on the land. Again, in Poland, repatriated persons received a flat-rate grant of 1,000 zlotys each, plus an additional benefit not exceeding 2,000 zlotys for breadwinners and 1 In Czechoslovakia a special national fund set up by the Ministry of Agriculture took over part of the land left behind by the expelled German minority amounting to 930,000 hectares of farmland and 100,000 hectares of forest. 68 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 1,000 zlotys for single persons, depending on their resources and family circumstances. CONSEQUENCES The consequences of the transfers and other population shifts which have taken place in eastern Europe since the war are difficult to assess, not only because most of the necessary information is lacking but also because they were preceded or accompanied by far greater upheavals, such as population losses, major frontier changes, breakdowns in production and trade brought about by the war, not to mention the drastic economic and social changes introduced by the new regimes. The result was that, with the exception of Poland and Czechoslovakia, where population movements did occur on a large scale, they tended to be overshadowed by other events. On the whole, with the sole exception of Hungary, eastern Europe was clearly the loser by these developments, all the more so as the relative decrease in the labour force in the various countries was probably greater than the corresponding figure for the population as a whole. This undoubtedly acted as a drag on economic progress, particularly since the German and Jewish minorities were usually more highly skilled and productive than the remainder of the population. The case of Hungary, Rumania and Bulgaria can be quickly passed over since, whether they were the gainers or the losers, the net result of the population shifts affecting them was fairly slight. In Hungary, however, which by 1956 had gained several hundred thousand new inhabitants, the influx of expelled, transferred or repatriated persons aggravated the rural underemployment situation which had always plagued the economy and which, despite the land reform scheme, remained a persistently troublesome economic and social problem. In Rumania the economy seems to have suffered mainly from the virtually complete disappearance of the Jewish minority, which left large gaps in trade, the handicrafts and the professions. In Bulgaria the departure of the Jews had the same effect although they were relatively less numerous. The transfer of the Turkish minority, on the other hand, by leaving large areas of farmland vacant, probably helped to absorb the surplus rural population for which the Bulgarian Government had tried to find temporary work in other countries.1 Far more important were the consequences of the population shifts in Poland and Czechoslovakia, where they were on a very considerable scale. In Poland the net result of the war was a steep fall in population from 32.1 million in 1939 to 24.8 million in 1950. The population exchange 1 See below, Chapter VIII. OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE 69 with the Soviet Union led to a gain of about 1 million over the number of inhabitants originally occupying the area comprised within the new Polish frontiers, but the spontaneous departure or expulsion of the German element emptied the provinces acquired under the Potsdam Agreement of something like 10 million people, i.e. the great bulk of their former population. On top of this heavy loss came the departure of well over half a million Jewish displaced persons, refugees and voluntary emigrants, who left the country for good. The first as well as the main problem which faced Poland once the war ended was therefore to resettle the former German provinces, now abandoned by the rich and industrious population to which they owed their high degree of industrial development. The Government encouraged internal westward migration from the east and centre of the country and systematically channelled the populations transferred from the Soviet Union and some of the repatriated Poles from the west and the east towards these provinces. This process of resettlement entailed largescale expenditure on reconstruction and raised an acute training problem since, not only was it found impossible to replace the former population by anything like an equal number of Poles, but it proved even more difficult to train the newcomers up to a comparable standard of skill. Efforts were concentrated on the Silesian area which, owing to its industrial capacity, is vital to the country's general development. The departure of the remnants of the Jewish minority in Poland also had important economic repercussions in a number of urban areas. It slowed down commerce and the handicrafts and led to lower efficiency in the nationalised retail trade and small-scale industries by depriving the new state concerns of the staff they needed. It also helped to produce a critical shortage of professional workers. The net result of the population shifts which affected Poland was to hold up economic development by creating a general shortage of labour. Owing to the flow of manpower from the farms to more urgent jobs this shortage even affected agriculture, which before the war had suffered from an exactly opposite problem. The situation was further aggravated by a general shortage of skilled workers. Like Poland, Czechoslovakia suffered a substantial population decrease within its present frontiers—from 14.7 million in 1939 to only 12.4 million in 1950. As in Poland the departure of the Germans involved a loss of skilled workers who were difficult to replace—so much so in fact that the Government kept some of them behind temporarily and, in some cases, permanently. The departure of the Jewish minority had similar effects as elsewhere. The cession of the Carpatho-Ukraine also deprived the country of a region which had been a traditional reservoir 70 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 of farm labour. Czechoslovakia, therefore, like Poland, was faced with a labour shortage after the war and this accounts for the Government's efforts to persuade Czechs abroad to return home and also to bring in Italian, Rumanian and Bulgarian workers—a policy which, however, has had slight success.1 As in Poland, the only way to overcome this shortage was to redistribute the population. Large-scale internal migrations were organised by the Government, mainly from Slovakia (a rural area with a traditional manpower surplus) towards various other parts of the country, some of them outside the frontier districts where the great majority of the German population used to live. Land and forests which had formerly belonged to Germans or Jews and which were among the most productive in the country were handed over to Czechoslovak farmers from the interior of the country, mainly Slovakia. In spite of these measures, however, the shortage of agricultural labour remained critical during most of the postwar period, and farm productivity lagged because of insufficient equipment and the lack of skilled workers. In industry, labour shortages were equally serious even though the capacity of the production facilities left behind by the Germans and Jews was for various reasons lower than before the slump of the thirties. The substitution of Czechoslovaks for the previous managements and skilled workers also led in many cases to a fall in standards of workmanship and productivity. One result was that the mining, textile, glassmaking and certain chemical industries, which formerly were in German or Jewish hands, found it difficult to meet their production targets. Bibliographical References General J. B. SCHECHTMAN: European Population Transfers, 1939-1945 (New York, Oxford University Press, 1946). E. M. KULISCHER: Europe on the Move (New York, Columbia University Press, 1948). G. FRUMKIN: Population Changes in Europe since 1939 (New York, Augustus M. Kelley, Inc., 1951). J. VERNANT: The Refugee in the Post-War World (London, George Allen & Unwin Ltd., 1953). Works Dealing with Non-National Refugees and Displaced Persons Reports of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (New York, 1953, 1955 and 1957), General Assembly Official Records. UNITED NATIONS: 1 See below, Chapter VIII. 71 OTHER POPULATION SHIFTS IN EUROPE UNITED NATIONS: Survey of the Non-Settled Refugee Population in Various Countries, Report submitted to the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, by Prof. P. J. IDENBURG, Document A/AC.79/111, 28 Apr. 1958 (mimeographed). UNITED NATIONS OFFICE OF THE HIGH COMMISSIONER FOR REFUGEES : Statis- tical bulletins issued from time to time on various subjects (mimeographed). — The Financial Aspects of Integration of the Refugees in the Austrian Economy, Report submitted to Mr. G. J. van Heuven Goedhart, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, by Gilbert JAEGER, Document HCR/RS/3, 29 Feb. 1952 (mimeographed). — The Integration of the Refugees into the Greek Economy, Document HCR/RS/7, 10 Feb. 1953 (mimeographed). — The Assimilation of the Refugees in Germany, Document HCR/RS/9, Mar. 1954 (mimeographed). INTERNATIONAL REFUGEE ORGANISATION: Statistical Report, with summaries covering the 54 months of its operations (Geneva, undated (mimeographed)). — Migration from Europe (Geneva, undated). — Occupational Skills of Refugees (series of surveys carried out by the I.R.O. (Geneva, various dates)). L. W. HOLBORN: The International Refugee Organisation (London, New York and Toronto, Oxford University Press, 1956). Works Dealing with National Refugees in Italy, Finland and Turkey UNITED NATIONS : Report on the Status and Conditions in Turkey of Refugees from Bulgaria, Document A/AC.36/12, 28 July 1952 (mimeographed). MINISTERO DEGLI AFFARI ESTERI : Documentazione sul problema della sovra- popolazione presentata al Consiglio d'Europa (Rome, Tipografia del Ministero degli Affari Esteri, 1953). A. DE GADOLIN: The Solution of the Karelian Refugee Problem in Finland, Publication V, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martin us Nijhoff, 1952). H. L. KOSTANICK: " Turkish Resettlement of Refugees from Bulgaria, 19501953 ", in The Middle East Journal (Washington, D.C., The Middle East Institute), Vol. IX, No. 1, Winter 1955, pp. 41 ff. Works Dealing with Transfers and Repatriations in Eastern Europe UNITED NATIONS : Economic Survey of Europe in 1957 (Geneva 1958). O. JASZI: " T h e Problem of Sub-Carpathian Ruthenia ", in Czechoslovakia: Twenty Years of Independence, edited by R. J. KERNER (University of California Press, Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1940), pp. 193-215. E. BARKER: Truce in the Balkans (London, Percival Marshall, 1949). H. WANKLYN: Czechoslovakia (London, George Philip and Son, Ltd., 1954). E. WISKEMANN: Germany's Eastern Neighbours (London, New York and Toronto, Oxford University Press, 1956). Trybuna Ludu (Warsaw), 1 Dec. and 30 Dec. 1956 issues. Dziennik Ustaw (Polish Official Gazette), 1947, No. 35, and 1952, No. 11. CHAPTER III IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL The immigrants who came to Israel following the proclamation of the country's independence in May 1948 were engaged in a unique historical process. The size of the influx, compared with that of the local population, and the tremendous resulting problem of absorption; the homogeneity of the migrants' ethnic background, contrasted with the diversity of their geographic origins ; and the ideological basis of the movement, which made it largely an act of faith—all of these differentiate it radically from all other recorded migration phenomena. Never before had migration played a comparable part in the growth of any nation, nor had any other movement taken place in the face of such uncompromising physical conditions. While the Israeli economy has yet to become fully solvent, the progress accomplished to date strikingly illustrates what a determined people, using modern methods, can do in even the most thankless natural surroundings when it bends all its energies and abilities to the task. Background and Data BACKGROUND The massive immigration flow which went to Israel in the years following the granting of independence marked the final episode in the long history of the Zionist movement. The latter, though launched towards the end of the nineteenth century, accomplished very little before Turkish domination in Palestine came to an end. Only under the British mandate following the First World War did the Jews begin to immigrate in any numbers, owing partly to the sympathetic attitude of the British authorities, but mainly to the growing threat to the Jewish communities of Central and Eastern Europe. There were two main immigration waves: in 1924-25 and in 1934-36, both of which were preceded and followed by lulls; these two waves brought the Jewish population in Palestine, which in 1914 totalled only 85,000, to 456,000 by 1939. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 73 Towards the end of the mandate, however, under pressure from the Arab community, the British authorities changed their policy towards Jewish immigration, and at one point even contemplated stopping it altogether. After the war they found themselves under fire from both the Arabs and the Jews and until 1948 only allowed in a few immigrants, although they were unable to prevent fairly large numbers from entering illegally. The decision taken by the United Nations on 27 November 1947 to partition Palestine and to create an independent Jewish nation ended the state of acute tension between the British administration and the two communities and immediately opened the country to the biggest wave of immigration it had yet known. The huge size of this wave—900,000 persons between 15 May 1948 and 31 December 1957—was due to a combination of two factors: the policy of the Israeli Government, which not only was liberal but strove actively to promote immigration, and the precarious position of many Jewish communities as a result of the war and the political upheavals which followed it. The immigration policy of the new State was inspired by a twofold concern—the desire to remain faithful to the Zionist ideal by giving all the Jews who wished to do so an opportunity of settling in Israel and at the same time to increase the country's population as quickly as possible. Accordingly, not only was the principle (reaffirmed in the Law of Return of 5 July 1950) of completely untrammelled Jewish immigration1 incorporated in the Declaration of Independence of 14 May 1948, but tremendous efforts were made to receive as many immigrants as possible. For many Jews abroad the birth of the State of Israel, apart from giving them a chance to end an exile which their religious traditions had always taught them to regard as temporary, came at a time when, owing to political developments in various countries, particularly in central and eastern Europe, the future was beginning to look rather bleak. This, coupled with the memory of the terror they had endured there for so many years, deterred those who had been displaced by the war from going home and impelled those who had remained at home to leave. Others, in North Africa and the Middle East, felt threatened by the rise of Arab nationalism. The result was that many hundreds of thousands of Jews were anxious to emigrate to Israel as soon as they could obtain permission and the wherewithal to do so. Both during the mandate and after, the Jewish Agency for Palestine, as supreme executive body of the World Zionist Organisation, acted as 1 Subject to certain limitations based on considerations of safety and public health. Non-Jewish immigrants, while allowed to enter the country, are not covered by the Law of Return. TABLE 23. ISRAEL 1 : JEWISH IMMIGRATION, BY COUNTRY OF BIRTH, 1946-57 fin thousands) -J Countries of birth Africa : Algeria, Tunisia and Morocco Egypt Libya Total . . . 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total — — — — 17.9 7.1 14.1 0.3 9.5 6.7 9.0 0.6 11.4 2.0 6.6 0.1 7.6 3.6 11.0 31.6 43.8 24.0 — 1.2 1.2 _ 0.2 1.1 _ 0.2 1.0 0.1 0.6 0.1 1.0 0.1 167.2 16.2 32.6 6.9 10.0 5.0 12.2 32.4 44.9 24.1 223.2 4.2 1.0 0.4 0.1 1.1 1.1 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.6 — 1.3 1.2 0.2 1.5 1.1 0.5 0.2 0.1 0.6 1.8 — 1.0 — 0.8 — 1.6 29.1 126.3 38.1 45.5 22.8 0.1 0.3 6.8 0.1 1.1 0.5 0.5 0.3 8.5 39.4 25.8 20.1 — — — — — — — — — — 1.8 1.7 26.3 35.1 6.3 10.5 32.5 2.4 8.7 3.7 9.4 89.1 1.2 0.7 2.9 0.3 — — — — z H Asia : Iran Iraq Turkey Yemen Miscellaneous 3 Total . . . 4.4 — 1.7 0.7 0.3 0.1 1.7 0.7 4.9 71.3 57.8 103.3 6.7 2.8 3.2 1.3 2.7 4.7 261.1 20.0 15.7 5.3 6.8 47.3 13.6 10.6 1.0 0.6 0.9 2.7 26.5 46.2 3.2 1.2 0.3 0.5 1.3 3.5 40.2 2.0 0.5 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.6 3.7 0.8 0.4 0.2 — 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.7 — 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.5 — 2.4 0.5 2.1 7.7 4.7 1.0 15.7 2.6 1.6 4.3 32.2 24.8 7.7 — — — 25.5 6.6 10.2 39.7 23.4 9.8 19.4 149.9 138.0 48.2 ISA 88.8 119.3 81.3 49.0 6.0 1.6 1.0 1.9 6.7 35.8 428.2 0.8 2.5 2.3 0.6 0.2 - 0.2 0.2 - 3.6 10.5 2.5 0.9 0.5 0.9 0.9 0.6 0.6 1.5 24.2 169.4 173.9 10.3 17.5 36.3 54.7 69.7 947.2 m 7> •Z > H O •z > r S O Europe * : Bulgaria Czechoslovakia Germany Hungary Poland Rumania Miscellaneous ja 0.5 1.6 0.4 1.4 5.8 4.3 4.4 Total . . . 18.4 U.S.S.R* - 0.1 Rest of world and unknown . . 0.6 0.2 8.4 6.6 19.7 111.4 239.1 Total . . . l — 21.2 a 23.4 — — ' Up to 15 May 1948, Palestine under British mandate. Includes the whole of Africa except Egypt for 1946 and 1947 and the whole of Africa except Algeria, Tunisia, Morocco and Libya for 1952-56; for 1957 the whole of Africa except North Africa. " Includes all Asian countries for 1946-47. * 1937 territories. s Not including the Baltic States. O IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 75 a link between the Jewish communities abroad and the Jews in Palestine. Moreover, through a special co-ordination committee, it co-operated (and continues to co-operate) with the Israeli Government in framing the immigration policy of the new State. In some countries, where the Jewish Agency was not allowed to operate, the American Joint Distribution Committee or other unofficial organisations provided the emigrants with the facilities needed to make the journey to Israel. In practice, a distinction had to be made between applicants who could afford to emigrate and settle at their own expense and those whose transport and temporary maintenance had to be paid for by the Jewish Agency : the former received immigration visas immediately, whereas for the latter the co-ordination committee instituted a quota system. This system was, however, sufficiently flexible for priority to be given to certain groups in urgent cases. For instance, every effort was made in 1949-51 to evacuate the Jewish communities in Iraq and Yemen as speedily as possible. By 31 December 1957 some 900,000 persons had reached Palestine under the auspices of the Jewish Agency since the proclamation of Israeli independence, and nearly 950,000 since the beginning of 1946. Table 23 gives a breakdown of post-war immigration by year and by country of birth. Roughly speaking, four periods can be distinguished. During the first, extending until the end of the British mandate, immigration was restricted and did not rise above the average level reached between the two wars. In addition to some 50,000 immigrants officially registered up to 15 May 1948—mostly Jews from central and eastern Europe who had been in refugee camps—there were several thousand illegal immigrants, most of them also from Europe. The second period, beginning with the proclamation of independence and ending in the summer of 1951, witnessed a tremendous increase in immigration. There were over 650,000 arrivals between 15 May 1948 and 31 July 1951, an annual average of over 200,000. This influx was fed simultaneously from three sources: I.R.O. camps in Germany and Austria which, at the beginning of 1948, still contained over 200,000 Jews from central and eastern Europe (mainly Poland and Rumania); heavy direct immigration from Poland, Rumania, Bulgaria and Yugoslavia which the governments concerned tolerated, though not without some reluctance ; and the communities of North Africa and the Middle East, some of which, such as those in the Yemen, Iraq and Libya, were transferred virtually wholesale to Israel. The third phase of the process extended from the summer of 1951 to the early part of 1955. During this period, immigration fell back to a much lower level. This was, of course, due in part to the sheer size 76 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 of the previous movements which had dried up a number of important sources of emigration. In addition, the eastern European countries stopped granting emigration permits to their nationals. As a result, the only large-scale flow which persisted during these years was from North Africa. However, during the fourth period, covering the last three years, immigration jumped sharply, though without reaching the levels of 1948-51, as a result of disturbances in the Arab world and the renewed willingness of the Polish authorities to allow emigration. The large-scale immigration of the last 12 years has also been accompanied by a certain amount of re-emigration, which reached its peak in 1952. This movement, however, was never substantial, having amounted on the whole to less than 10 per cent, of total immigration. DATA Demographic Features Allowing for the immigrants who entered illegally towards the end of the British mandate and for several thousand tourists who came after the proclamation of independence without an immigration visa but were granted permission to settle, gross immigration between 1 January 1946 and 31 December 1957 was probably of the order of 960,000 while the net intake exceeded 875,000—a far larger number than the total Jewish population of Palestine on 31 December 1945 (564,000). Thus the immediate result of immigration since the beginning of 1946 was to increase the population by over 150 per cent. Apart from this direct effect, however, the age composition of the immigrants, the even balance between the sexes and the above-average fertility of certain groups x have all had far-reaching indirect results. The annual surplus of births over deaths rose from 13,000 in 1946 to 41,000 in 1957, and virtually the whole of this increase can be attributed to the new immigrants. Thus immigration and, still more, the natural increase resulting from it, have caused a number of changes in the age composition of the population, e.g. an increase in the proportion of children and of persons over the age of 55 and a fall in the proportion of juveniles and young adults (table 24). The age structure of the population is thus slightly less favourable today than it was in 1948, at least judged by the ratio between 1 Notably the Asian and African Jews, whose large families and high fertility rate contrasted with the small families of the immigrants from Europe (owing to the low birth rate and high infant mortality rate of the war years) and their lower fertility rate. 77 IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL TABLE 24. ISRAEL : B R E A K D O W N BY A G E O F THE JEWISH POPULATION ON 8 NOVEMBER 1948 1 A N D 31 DECEMBER 1957 A N D O F I M M I G R A T I O N BETWEEN 1948 2 A N D 1957 Population on 8 November 1948 Age groups Immigration, 1948-57 Population on 31 December 1957 Absolute Absolute Absolute PercenPercenPercenfigures figures figures tages tages tages (in thousands) (in thousands) (in thousands) 0-15 . . . . 15-25 . . 25-35 . . 35-45 . . 45-65 . . 65 and over Unknown 205.0 125.5 119.1 129.8 107.1 28.2 2.1 28.6 17.5 16.6 18.1 15.0 3.9 0.3 272.3 172.5 139.5 122.5 148.1 36.0 5.4 30.3 19.4 15.6 13.6 16.5 4.0 0.6 612.5 256.2 252.6 223.1 337.6 80.7 Total. 716.7 100.0 896.3 100.0 1,762.7 1 Census data. — 34.7 14.5 14.3 12.7 19.2 4.6 — 100.0 * Since 15 May 1948. the productive age groups and the remainder of the population. It should be noted, however, that a relative increase in the non-productive element would have been inevitable even if there had been no immigration after the end of the mandate, since the 1948 age structure still bore the mark of immigration before that date, which had brought in an exceptionally high proportion of young persons between the ages of 15 and 34. Post1948 immigration thus merely accentuated a trend inherent in the original population structure. The present situation is in any case extremely satisfactory, and despite a natural rate of increase which seems bound to remain very high (of the order of 2 per cent.), the ratio between the labour force and the non-productive population will probably not fall appreciably in the future. Moreover, recent immigration has comprised virtually equal proportions of men and women over the age of 15 and has thus reduced the surplus of adult males disclosed by the census of 8 November 1948 (table 25). Breakdown by Country of Origin Table 23 has shown that immigration after 1948 was fed from a large variety of sources. Its most distinctive feature compared with immigration during the mandate, most of which came from Europe, was the fact that it contained a majority of Jews from the Moslem countries of North Africa and the Middle East. The result was that the composition of the Israeli population by area of origin changed considerably (table 26) 78 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 25. ISRAEL : BREAKDOWN BY SEX OF THE JEWISH POPULATION ON 8 NOVEMBER 1948 AND 31 DECEMBER 1957 Absolute figures (in thousands) Age groups Percentages On 8 November 1948 On 31 December 1957 Males Females Males Females Males Females 0-15 . . . . 15-25 . . 25-35 . . 35-45 . . 45-65 . . 65 and over Unknown 105.5 63.7 61.4 67.7 57.4 13.5 1.1 99.5 61.8 57.7 62.1 49.7 14.7 1.0 297.5 123.7 128.8 112.5 163.1 43.1 — 315.1 132.5 123.8 110.6 174.6 37.6 — 51.5 50.8 51.6 52.2 53.6 47.8 50.9 48.5 49.2 48.4 47.8 46.4 52.2 49.1 48.6 48.3 51.0 50.4 48.3 53.4 — 51.4 51.7 49.0 49.6 51.7 46.6 Total. . . 370.3 346.4 868.7 894.1 51.7 48.3 49.3 50.7 192.9 181.5 365.1 366.9 51.5 48.5 49.9 50.1 15-45 . . . . On 8 November 1948 On 31 December 1957 Males Females TABLE 26. ISRAEL : JEWISH POPULATION, BY COUNTRY OF BIRTH, ON 8 NOVEMBER 1948 AND 31 DECEMBER 1957 Absolute figures (in thousands) Countries (or areas) of birth Percentages On On On On 8 November 31 December 8 November 31 December 1948 1948 1957 1957 253.4 588.2 35.4 33.4 12.2 57.5 218.9 296.9 1.7 8.0 12.4 16.9 270.7 459.3 37.8 26.1 24.1 62.1 3.4 3.5 85.0 11.3 1.7 113.4 23.9 11.8 1.6 0.2 6.4 1.3 462.6 1,174.5 64.5 66.6 Foreign countries or areas : Africa Asia Poland, Rumania and U.S.S.R Bulgaria, Greece and Yugoslavia Austria, Czechoslovakia, Germany and Hungary . . . Rest of world Unknown Total . . . 0.7 Unspecified Total . . . 716.7 0.1 1,762.7 100.0 100.0 and the relative importance of the European element, which had formerly been overwhelmingly predominant, dropped sharply whereas the Jews of African and Asian origin now form quite a substantial minority. Their IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 79 emergence as a significant factor in the country's economic, social and even political life has added a further difficulty to the general problem of integration: that of amalgamating two important sections of the population still separated by wide cultural differences. Social and Economic Data The Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics did not publish any occupational classification of immigrants before 1 September 1948 and it changed its system of classification after 1950, so that it is impossible to supply uniform data on this point for the whole period. Table 27 gives a breakdown by occupation of the immigrants who entered from 1950 on; it omits the figures for the preceding years which are deficient in several respects.1 In social and economic terms, immigration since 1950 has had two main characteristics which are clearly brought out by table 27. These are the high proportion of economically inactive persons and, among the labour force, the high proportion of workers in service (tertiary) occupations. While the proportion of dependants among the immigrants who came in between 1950 and 1957 is officially put at 62.8 per cent., the total percentage of non-self-supporting elements was appreciably larger since many of the immigrants whose source of income could not be ascertained—probably a majority—belonged to the non-productive group. Among the labour force itself only a small number had been employed in primary industry, the remainder being split more or less evenly between the secondary and tertiary sectors and the largest group (handicraft and industrial workers) comprising many more of the former than of the latter.2 Thus among the post-1950 immigrants there were more than twice as many dependants as there were workers and almost as many workers from the tertiary sector as from the other two put together. Furthermore, among the latter there were few who had worked in either agriculture or industry proper. During this phase the chief sources of immigration were North Africa and the Middle East, so that the general pattern to a large extent reflects the demographic and social structure of the Jewish communities in these areas. The composition of the immigration flow before 1950, most of which came from Europe, was somewhat different since it comprised more economically active persons; on the other hand, 1 The statistics for the period between 1 September 1948 and 31 December 1949 include a large proportion of men who declared no occupation, with the result that the proportion of active persons is less than 20 per cent. 2 A particularly high proportion had worked in the leather, clothing and food trades. TABLE 27. ISRAEL : IMMIGRANTS BY OCCUPATION IN COUNTRY OF ORIGIN, 1950-57 oo O (In thousands) Total 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Absolute figures Percentages 4.5 3.5 0.7 0.4 0.5 0.6 1.1 3.9 15.2 2.7 . . . . 7.6 7.8 2.4 1.4 18.8 3.7 1.2 1.8 0.3 6.7 10.6 2.7 1.2 14.3 4.9 1.1 1.8 0.3 1.1 0.9 0.5 0.2 2.5 0.8 0.3 0.2 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.1 1.3 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.1 2.1 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.7 0.8 0.6 0.3 5.4 0.4 0.6 0.3 1.4 1.3 0.9 0.5 7.3 0.7 0.7 0.5 3.7 1.6 0.5 0.6 10.5 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.1 22.3 24.0 7.9 4.3 61.9 11.9 5.0 5.6 0.8 4.0 4.3 1.4 0.8 11.2 2.2 0.9 1.0 0.1 . . . 49.4 47.0 7.3 3.3 4.6 9.8 14.3 23.2 158.9 28.6 36.0 47.7 8.6 5.2 0.5 35.8 60.0 6.6 7.3 4.6 4.4 7.3 1.8 0.7 0.7 1.7 3.2 1.1 0.3 0.1 3.0 7.5 0.5 0.5 0.3 6.0 16.2 0.3 1.1 1.2 9.3 22.3 0.8 0.6 3.1 11.8 26.4 1.4 2.4 0.5 108.1 190.6 21.0 18.2 10.9 19.5 34.2 3.8 3.3 2.0 97.9 114.5 14.8 6.4 11.8 24.8 36.1 42.5 348.8 62.5 22.2 12.5 1.2 0.6 1.0 1.8 4.5 4.0 47.7 8.6 169.4 173.9 23.4 10.3 17.5 36.3 54.9 69.7 555.4 100.0 Occupational status Gainfully occupied: Professional and technical workers Managerial, administrative and Farmers1 Transport workers Craftsmen and industrial workers Labourers Building workers Service workers Unspecified Total . . . . clerical Not gainfully occupied: Children Students Old people Total . . . Source of income unknown Total 1 And other workers in primary industry. . . . IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 81 the proportion of workers in tertiary occupations, particularly professional workers, was even higher than among the post-1950 immigrants. 1 If it is further borne in mind that the immigrants brought very little capital with them, most of them having left nearly all their possessions in their countries of origin, the net social and economic gain resulting from the influx of so many individuals in the non-productive age groups, women without any working experience and men with no agricultural or industrial background will seem to have been slight indeed. This situation was, of course, largely the result of an intentionally liberal and, until recent years, completely non-selective immigration policy. Notwithstanding, the newcomers, as will be seen further, settled down in their new jobs far more rapidly and successfully than might have been expected. Absorbing the Immigrants GENERAL The absorption of immigrants during the period immediately following the proclamation of independence raised a tremendous problem for the new State, not only because of their sheer numbers but also to some extent because of the types of persons involved. For three years a flood of newcomers, out of all proportion to the average volume allowed in during the mandate, poured into a territory which was over 20 per cent, smaller than the former State of Palestine and half of which was a desert, doubling the local Jewish population. As mentioned earlier, the Israeli Government refused to make any discrimination among the immigrants, most of whom had neither the capital nor the skills needed in an infant economy, and deliberately made unrestricted Jewish immigration the cornerstone of its policy, overriding all other considerations. The extent of the economic and social problems which such a course would entail was readily apparent from experience acquired during the mandate, and the risk was taken advisedly. Under the impact of the flood of immigrants the balance of Israeli economy was suddenly and completely upset. Even before 1948 immigration had created a number of acute problems owing to the barrenness of the country and the heavy investment needed to develop it. As a result 1 This is not borne out by the statistics for the years 1948 and 1949, which in fact show a high proportion of industrial workers; but these statistics, as already explained, are far from complete. 82 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the British authorities had been forced to keep immigration within relatively narrow bounds and to give preference to immigrants with capital of their own. Despite this policy, however, the Palestine Jews would have been unable to achieve a standard of living comparable to that of Europe if the country's own scanty funds and the capital brought in by the immigrants had not been supplemented by large-scale injections of foreign capital in the form of either direct investment or (above all) of gifts from world Jewry to the Palestine Foundation Fund and the Jewish National Fund. The infant economy of Jewish Palestine thus had the benefit of foreign aid on an exceptional scale which enabled it to expand sufficiently fast for immigration to be a help rather than a hindrance and at the same time to maintain the country's balance of payments; but the far larger number of immigrants that the Israeli Government now proposed to admit could obviously not be absorbed without a collapse in living standards, unless far greater help could be obtained from abroad. The crucial question was how far such help would be forthcoming and whether the country would be spared the inconveniences of austerity or the greater evil of inflation—the problem being further complicated by the large portion of its resources which the Government was forced to devote to national defence. Two factors helped Israel out of this predicament. The first was the departure of the bulk of the Arab population which had been living on Israeli territory before the country was partitioned by the United Nations. The number of Arabs who left substantially exceeded the number of Jewish immigrants during the first few years l , and this made it easier to provide land, housing and, to some extent, jobs for the newcomers. However, while the Jewish and Arab economies had lived side by side they had remained largely alien to one another, with a considerable difference in respective degrees of development. As a result a high proportion of jobs that were part and parcel of the Arab economic system disappeared with the Arabs themselves. Moslem standards of farm productivity and housing were also a good deal lower than those of the Jewish population and despite the Arabs' departure a great deal of investment in construction of all kinds was still necessary. It would therefore be wrong to assume that what took place was a process of simple substitution. The Israeli economy undoubtedly benefited by the departure of the Arabs 1 The non-Jewish population living within the present boundaries of Israel was 736,000 persons on 31 December 1946, with the exception of nomads. Had there been no emigration, and allowing for the natural increase since that date it should by now total some 950,000 persons instead of the 213,000 counted on 31 December 1957. Thus the departure of the Arabs more than offset the total Jewish immigration between 1948 and 1951. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 83 but far from enough to offset the extra burden of immigration. Moreover, this departure, owing to its suddenness, led to a fall in food output, while the political events which had caused it simultaneously resulted in the cutting off of food supplies from neighbouring countries just when the influx of immigrants made heavier imports necessary. The second favourable factor was a psychological one—the persistence in Israel of a pioneer spirit which bears witness to the vitality of the Zionist ideal. This spirit, which the early settlers had to a large extent succeeded in imparting to the newcomers, not only inspired workers to unusually high standards of performance (at least in terms of quantity) but ruled out any serious possibility of social friction. The original population accepted the immigrants without any discrimination and the attempts of the General Confederation of Labour (Histadrut) to prevent wages from being forced down by immigrant labour were designed as much to stop the newcomers from being exploited as to safeguard the living standards of workers already established in the country. These psychological factors, combined with the experience already acquired by the Jewish community in Palestine in dealing with practical immigration problems, e.g. in the field of vocational training, helped the Government to plan efficiently and facilitated the absorption of the newcomers. Despite these favourable circumstances the Israeli Government's policy of unrestricted immigration was unquestionably an economic gamble, particularly as the outcome depended largely on external factors. The Government could not confine itself to soliciting foreign aid. It also had to plan economic development in such a way as to make the best possible use of such aid as was forthcoming, and this could not be expected to last indefinitely. FOREIGN AID In view of the tremendous pressure to which the somewhat shaky Israeli economy was about to be subjected, a disastrous fall in average real incomes was inevitable unless substantial aid could be obtained from abroad to cover the cost of the sharp rise in imports. Such a rise was inevitable, both as regards consumer goods to meet the rapidly increasing demand and capital goods to increase home production and employment. As the country could not increase its exports—or even, temporarily at least, maintain them at existing levels— the huge gap in its balance of payments could only be covered by gifts or credits from abroad. Thus the country's economic future depended first and foremost on external aid, the size and duration of which were at best problematical. 84 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 As things turned out, it was substantial and took a number of different forms, e.g. funds collected by Zionist organisations in all the Jewish communities throughout the world, particularly in the United States, official aid from the United States Governmentx, reparations from the Federal Republic of Germany 2, loans from the Import-Export Bank and the International Monetary Fund 3 public loans ", private loans, direct investment5 and funds brought in by the immigrants themselves. Thus between May 1948 and the end of 1957 the State of Israel benefited by large-scale imports of capital, mostly in the form of grants. Table 28 shows the importance of these capital movements in the country's balance of payments from 1950 to 1956. They remained significant in 1957. This influx of capital (which was used in roughly equal proportions for the purchase of consumer goods and capital goods), while both steady and substantial, was not, however, sufficient to obviate the need for a policy of austerity during a number of years. The use of gifts and long-term credits to finance the import of consumer goods, though a TABLE 28. ISRAEL : BALANCE OF PAYMENTS, 1950-56 (Millions of dollars) Item Goods and transportation Investment income . . Other services . l . . . Private donations . . Private capital . . . . Official donations 2 . . Official capital: Long-term Short-term . . . . Errors and omissions . 1950 1951 -261.8 -329.1 - 1.1 - 0.8 - 17.4 - 24.2 113.9 118.3 14.0 44.4 62.0 60.0 87.6 28.1 106.1 1952 1953 -269.6 - 11.9 - 25.2 104.8 22.9 86.4 -217.3 85.0 8.5 - 0.9 1954 -197.4 - 16.4 - 16.7 - 29.2 - 22.0 133.3 84.6 11.2 17.1 129.3 88.2 47.7 52.2 10.5 - 62.4 14.8 - 27.5 1955 1956 -234.6 -243.5 - 18.6 - 22.6 - 29.5 - 91.8 83.2 122.6 9.3 2.8 127.2 120.5 64.2 1.4 - 2.6 70.2 19.5 22.3 Source: United Nations Statistical Yearbook, 1957. 1 Including capital brought in by immigrants. * American aid and German reparations. 1 Such aid was granted to Israel in 1951 in the form of gifts spread over a number of years. 2 Under an agreement signed in Luxembourg on 10 September 1952 these came to more than 820 million dollars, about half of which have already been used. 3 The Import-Export Bank has granted two loans to the Government of Israel, one in January 1949 and the other in December 1950. The International Monetary Fund made a loan of 3.75 million dollars in 1957. 4 Chiefly the large " independence " loan launched in the United States in May 1951. 6 An Act of 29 March 1950, designed to encourage capital investment, grants major concessions to foreign investors, particularly as regards taxation and customs duties, to induce them to invest in the country's development. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 85 necessary stopgap measure, reflected a thoroughly abnormal state of dependence on the outside, to which an investment policy designed to narrow the gap in the balance of payments was the only possible answer. This meant that it was essential for consumption of imported or exportable products to be cut back temporarily for the sake of investment, if a sound economy was to be built up on the new demographic basis resulting from immigration. INVESTMENT, FULL EMPLOYMENT AND INFLATION However, an investment drive of the kind required involved a serious risk of inflation, especially in view of the poverty of the country itself. This meant that the Government had to keep a firm grip on the situation, taking care not to overstep certain limits. Various considerations of social policy, however, stood in the way of strict orthodoxy and monetary stability. Top priority had to be given to setting the immigrants up as soon as possible with jobs and houses, and since such a policy of full employment and accelerated construction was incompatible with conventional financing methods, a certain amount of inflation was inevitable—all the more so as defence expenditure and trade union resistance to any fall in real wages constituted further sources of inflationary pressure which it was quite impossible to eliminate. The inevitable outcome was too much money chasing too few goods and services, and the problem was not so much to stop inflation altogether as to prevent it from getting out of hand. The situation called for careful handling, since any stoppage or even a marked slow-down in the rate of monetary expansion was liable to have deflationary consequences, i.e. to cause unemployment and hamper development. On the other hand, in view of the extreme precariousness of the balance of payments, any increase in imports of consumer goods to mop up excess purchasing power could only have an adverse effect on the import of capital goods, and would run directly counter to the policy which had been decided upon and which offered the only hope of achieving economic independence in the long run. In attempting to resolve this dilemma—permanent unbalance of the country's internal finances versus a worsening of its debtor position visà-vis foreign countries—the Government had a number of powerful weapons at its disposal. Apart from the classic devices of a planned economy, it was able, either directly or through the Jewish Agency, to control the bulk of the foreign capital available for investment and to ensure that it was used to the best advantage for the development of the 86 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 29. ISRAEL : GROSS INVESTMENT BY BRANCH OF THE ECONOMY, 1949-56 (Millions of Israeli pounds ; 1956 prices) Branch 1 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 92 104 96 110 144 135 125 186 66 182 56 Agriculture 1 Industry, handicrafts, mining and electric power Communications Housing and construction . Services2 89 123 89 76 — 222 235 65 73 130 107 111 78 57 51 181 136 172 47 36 33 149 71 194 63 Total . . . 340 557 611 532 446 511 612 615 Including irrigation, forestry,fishingand land clearance. 1 Including public building. economy as a whole. The distribution of investment among the various branches of the economy from 1949 to 1956 is illustrated by table 29.1 Economic Trends from 1948 to 1957 The various phases that the Israeli economy has gone through since 1948 have been determined by shifts in economic policy, which has not varied in its aims but has undergone major changes in practical execution, particularly in the early days, when there was inevitably a certain amount of trial and error. By and large the expansion of the economy to keep up with the enormous increase in population which took place after 1948 was astonishingly rapid, but its balance was, and to a certain extent remains, precarious. The policy of full employment, the construction drive, the need to keep down imports of consumer goods to limit the deficit in the balance of payments, and labour resistance to any wage cuts have combined to feed the process of inflation, which has still not yet been brought to a halt. FROM 1948 TO 1951: SUPPRESSED DEMAND INFLATION The Government realised from the start that the rate at which the immigrants were coming into the country made a policy of austerity essential and that, even so, inflation could not be avoided. It was only at the end of the War of Independence, however, in the second half of 1 The figures for 1957 are not comparable, since they are expressedin 1957prices; however, data published by the Bank of Israel show that investment increased by over 20 per cent, compared with the previous year and that most of this increase was devoted to transport, housing, construction of all kinds, and services. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 87 1949, that the inflationary process got under way and, in order to keep it in check, it was decided to impose certain controls. By that time, unfortunately, a prevailing attitude of easygoing confidence had already fostered a number of illusions and led to a certain amount of waste. The anti-inflationary measures taken were not wholly effective because, instead of tackling the problem at its source, i.e. preventing the formation of an excessive money supply, the Government merely froze wages and the prices of staple items in the cost of living, in an attempt to stop a race between them. It was able to do this because the majority of consumer goods which entered into the cost-of-living index were imported and their delivery prices were fairly stable; they were marketed at an exchange rate of one Israeli pound for 2.8 dollars. But this policy only produced a semblance of equilibrium, since in fact none of the conditions of financial stability had been achieved. In order to cope with its military expenditure and carry out the investments made necessary by the influx of immigrants, the Israeli Government was constantly forced to create new means of payment 1 without any equivalent increase in the quantity of goods and services available since imports of consumer goods had been severely restricted and local output had not risen fast enough. This situation led to the rationing of most essential goods. The ensuing accumulation of surplus purchasing power in the hands of the public—which only a policy of stiff taxation could have prevented —coupled with rationing and other controls placed on the supply of essential goods and services, resulted in what has been termed a process of " suppressed demand inflation ". This not only produced a flourishing black market but, above all, caused such an increase in all prices of uncontrolled goods and services that economic development would, if matters had been allowed to continue, have been seriously hampered by the distortions which were beginning to appear in the general price structure. As profits were higher in non-essential trades, capital and labour 2 were inevitably attracted towards them, although their prosperity could do nothing to improve the balance of payments or the economic situation in general. The fact that most of the essential goods whose prices had been frozen until the beginning of 1952 were imported only aggravated the threat to the country's economic future. By discouraging local production of certain types of goods, it made it harder to reduce the deficit in the balance of payments and was even liable to make it worse. 1 Between January 1949 and September 1951, the total means of payment in the economy more than doubled from 111 to 252.3 million Israeli pounds. 2 Whereas an increase in the proportion of workers in agriculture and industry would have been desirable, there was an actual decrease from 39 to 37 per cent. between the middle of 1947 and the middle of 1952. 88 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Moreover, the cheapness of imported goods tended to encourage the purchase of raw materials which were used wastefully or of machinery which led to technological unemployment at just the wrong time. Matters came to a head towards the end of 1951. By this time prices and incomes in the uncontrolled section of the economy were soaring and the deficit in the balance of payments, widened by the need for higher imports to meet the essential needs of a population which had suddenly doubled, was reaching alarming proportions. Meanwhile, the country's internal and external credit position was deteriorating. The fact had to be faced that, despite the substantial growth in output, the economy was still seriously unbalanced owing to the way in which the authorities, after having allowed inflation to develop (as in fact they could hardly avoid doing) had then tried to keep it in check : the cure had proved worse than the disease and a new approach was needed. 1952: THE CHANGE FROM SUPPRESSED DEMAND INFLATION TO COST INFLATION In February 1952 a series of measures were taken to halt inflation and break the vicious circle in which the economy was caught. The year before the Government had put an end to the issue of Treasury and Land Bills which had been the main source of inflation. It was announced that these issues would not be resumed and that the bulk of the development budget would henceforth be covered by funds obtained abroad. Tighter controls were imposed on credit so as to channel resources into given sections of the economy, i.e. agriculture, industry and the export trades. Lastly, the Israeli pound was pegged to the dollar, except for the purchase of essential products on the priority list, for which a more favourable exchange rate was temporarily maintained. In this way it was hoped to revert to a normal price pattern and to improve the balance of payments by sharply reducing the incentive to import. In June 1952 these steps were supplemented by the launching of a compulsory loan designed to siphon off into the development budget any surplus purchasing power which had not already been absorbed by the rise in prices. These reforms did not immediately bring about the stability the Government hoped for. The devaluation of the Israeli pound led to a steep rise in the cost of living and made an adjustment of wages necessary. This in turn caused a substantial increase in production costs and had to be followed by a further expansion in the money supply to prevent deflationary consequences in the shape of falling sales and unemployment. Thus, suppressed demand inflation had merely been replaced by 89 IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL cost inflation. Fortunately, owing to a combination of favourable factors, this new form of inflation was not as far-reaching or as serious as its predecessor. The years after 1952 were marked by a rapid return to a more balanced financial position which in itself reflected improved economic conditions. FROM 1953 to 1957 : TOWARDS ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL STABILITY Despite the gradual lifting of price controls and the introduction of a sliding scale for wages \ inflation during the next few years was not as severe as might have been expected, and in fact slowed down very quickly. The cost-of-living index, which had risen by 66 per cent. in 1952, rose by only 20 per cent, in 1953 and 7.5 per cent, in 1954. This was particularly remarkable as the Government's financial policy, so far from being over-cautious, had been concentrated on avoiding deflation rather than inflation. The trend towards financial stability was due to two main reasons, namely the ending of mass immigration in the summer of 1951 and the increase in non-repayable capital aid from abroad after 1952. The former of these two factors made it possible to shift the emphasis in investment policy from housing to agricultural and industrial development 2 ; this was partly because the housing shortage had become less acute and partly because labour was scarcer. The new switch in policy made it possible to increase over-all productivity much more rapidly. Similarly, the increase in foreign aid made it possible to maintain imports of consumer goods at a high level and to end rationing without compromising the investment drive. The expansion of domestic production was thus sufficient to check inflation and gradually stabilise prices. The improvement in the economic position was evidenced by a number of other signs—the rise in the rate of production increase, the fall in unemployment 3 , the movement of labour from the less productive sectors of the economy to agriculture and industry, the relative fall in income derived from tertiary activities and the corresponding rise in 1 Wages themselves remained frozen, but there was a cost-of-living bonus tied to the cost-of-living index. 2 See table 29 above for the annual distribution of gross investment by branch of the economy. 3 The daily average number of unemployed showed the following trend between 1949 and 1957 (in thousands): 1949 1950 1951 1.1 5.9 6.3 1952 1953 1954 9.4 17.7 13.4 A rate of 3 per cent, was only exceeded in 1953. 1955 1956 1957 10.7 12.3 12.5 90 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the other two sectors, the growth of exports and, lastly, the reduction in imports of consumer goods in relation to raw materials and capital goods. The trend towards economic stability has been less marked, however, in the past few years. Inflationary pressures began to build up again from 1955 onwards. The resumption of immigration which, without reaching the 1948-51 levels, increased the already booming demand for consumer goods, has forced the Government to speed up the housing programme once more and provide the newcomers with services of all kinds. The military operations of 1956-57 represented a further burden, while at the same time the Government was unable to obtain any substantial increase in foreign aid to meet the extra cost. Credit was further tightened and the total volume of means of payment increased substantially.1 The balance of payments also deteriorated once more owing to the increase in imports and the widening of the gap between domestic and foreign prices. Owing to the rapid increase in output, however, this new inflationary pressure was kept within fairly narrow bounds and living standards did not suffer appreciably. Consumer prices only rose by 6.4 per cent. in 1956 and by 6.5 per cent, in 1957, while average wages rose slightly more. These new inflationary trends did not prevent unemployment from increasing slightly (to 12,500 in 1957) because of the difficulty of finding work for the new immigrants, most of whom were unskilled. Although by 1957 the balance-of-payments position had improved to some extent, the new difficulties which had arisen owing largely to political developments, had shown up the persistent economic weakness of the new State. They had also demonstrated that any further mass immigration would inevitably create a need for further investment and additional foreign aid. Arrangements for the Integration of Immigrants The Jewish Agency, and not the Government of Israel, assumes responsibility (as it did during the mandate) for supporting the immigrants until they find work and for housing them until permanent accommodation is ready. Arrangements for the settlement of the new arrivals have changed considerably since 1948. The entire procedure has been greatly speeded 1 Between 1954 and the end of 1957 it rose by more than 60 per cent.—from 348.5 to 576 million Israeli pounds. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 91 up and now aims at transferring immigrants directly from the boat to their place of work. During the early years the immigrants were first sent to a reception camp from which, after a few days, all those who could not obtain housing by their own means or move directly into employment were transferred to a transit camp. Normally the able-bodied were not expected to stay in these camps very long, and during the first year most of them could in fact be housed in urban areas or villages abandoned by the Arabs. After a while, however, as this readily available housing was used up and the rate of building continued to lag far behind the volume of immigration, the transit camps (which between May 1948 and March 1950 had increased in number from seven to 36) tended to become congested. On top of the shortage of permanent housing there was the difficulty of finding work for the immigrants near the camps, with the result that large numbers of them had to endure the idleness as well as the discomforts of camp life for months on end. For example, on 1 March 1950 nearly half of the 90,000 immigrants in transit camps had been there for five months or more, and while Hebrew lessons and vocational training courses were given, more than this was needed to counteract the adverse psychological effects of prolonged inactivity. The Jewish Agency therefore decided in the summer of 1950 to disperse the immigrants into work camps known as maabarot (temporary villages) which were set up wherever permanent or temporary jobs were available, e.g. near the farm settlement centres, in the suburbs of the new towns or in the neighbourhood of large public works schemes. These villages rapidly absorbed the population of the transit camps which were progressively closed down. By the end of 1952 the villages contained a record population of 230,000 people. They emptied in turn as permanent housing was built by the Government on neighbouring sites. As new construction gradually caught up with the population's needs, new reception arrangements for the immigrants were introduced in 1955, abolishing any intermediate stage between the boat and the place of work. An immigrant who is unable to find his own housing is now taken direct to a village or town where a permanent job and home await him. These arrangements form part of the schemes for developing hitherto neglected areas. The Jewish Agency has thus managed to meet the immigrants' essential needs during the transition period. But their integration has involved a number of other practical and, in some ways, interrelated problems, such as the steering of the immigrants into sections of the 92 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 economy which the Government wishes to expand and the provision of permanent housing. The Government was reluctant to use compulsion to direct immigrants into essential primary and secondary occupations which required more labour for expansion, particularly since the law of supply and demand was quite effective in channelling the newcomers into such trades (which in the main were completely new to them). This process was, of course, helped by the fact that the Zionist movement has managed to kindle an enthusiasm in the country for manual work in general and for work on the land in particular. Nevertheless, certain difficulties did arise and they called for government action. The first was the lopsided distribution of the population throughout the country and its over-concentration in the big towns. This was an inheritance from the days of the mandate when the farm settlements only absorbed a small part of the Jewish population, the bulk of which settled in the cities. Inevitably, during the early days of the immigration wave, it was also in the cities that the newcomers had least difficulty in finding homes and jobs; in fact, by the end of 1950 nearly half the Jewish population was concentrated in the three urban areas of Haifa, Tel-Aviv-Jaffa and Jerusalem. Accordingly, the Government's development policy was linked with a plan for spreading the population out more evenly. The aim was to attract labour towards the empty parts of the country by launching public works schemes and above all by building more farm settlements to which every effort was made to channel the immigrants. On the whole the new villages were populated without much difficulty because of the facilities provided, which afforded the prospect of a reasonable standard of living.1 But the cost of the scheme was very high and it could only be carried out with large-scale financial assistance from the Jewish Agency. Thanks to this help, the new State was able to take effective possession of large areas of its territory in the extreme north and south, particularly in Galilee and the Negev while at the same time solving the problem posed by the absorption of tens of thousands of immigrants. The second difficulty was the inadequate skill of most of the immigrants. Tremendous efforts were required by the Ministry of Labour, the Ministry of Agriculture and the Settlement Department of the Jewish Agency to train workers, both young and adult, for their new tasks.2 The former benefited from the progress made since 1948 in the vocational 1 Although on occasion indirect pressure had to be used, e.g. the cut in building and public works credits in the big cities during the 1952-53 switch in economic policy. 2 Annual expenditure on vocational training is of the order of 4 million Israeli pounds. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 93 guidance and training of young people in general. Since 1949 the Youth Aliyah, which is the section of the Jewish Agency dealing with the education of young immigrants, has provided training and found work, mainly in agriculture, for about 20,000 of them from the Moslem countries. Accelerated vocational training courses, both basic and advanced, for industrial trades and certain services have also been organised for adults in co-operation with the Histadrut, although owing to the shortage of instructors and facilities and the general lack of money, training could not be given on a large enough scale during the years when immigration was at its peak. Between the foundation of the State and the end of 1957 about 100,000 adult pupils were given vocational training for 200 non-agricultural trades, either in special centres or in schools. The agricultural settlers were usually trained by instructors on the farms themselves, the course of training varying according to the type of settlement. Large-scale efforts were also made on the Government's initiative to rehabilitate the disabled so as to make full use of all available manpower resources. Thus the MALBEN Organisation x has organised large numbers of rehabilitation courses in hospitals and in specially equipped centres. The housing drive, however, has probably represented the most successful effort to fit the immigrants into the general development plan. It not only helped to meet the needs of the greatly increased population, but also changed the population pattern in the general interest. Here too the Government and the Jewish Agency worked in close co-operation. The scale of the housing drive since 1949 is evidenced by the high proportion of housing expenditure (the greater part of which was borne from public funds) in total gross investment.2 The new housing built between 1949 and 1957 totalled over 508,000 rooms, more than 73 per cent, of which was financed in whole or in part by the Government, the Jewish Agency or various public bodies. The geographical pattern of public and private building was, however, different. In accordance with the population policy, public building was largely concentrated in the countryside and the new towns, particularly in the extreme north and south, whereas private building tended to concentrate in the Tel-AvivJaffa and Haifa areas. The housing problem, which was nearing a solution, once more became acute with the new wave of immigration, and at the beginning of 1957 the Ministry of Labour drew up a three1 A relief agency for physically handicapped immigrants set up in 1949 under the sponsorship of the American Joint Distribution Committee, the Jewish Agency and the Israeli Government. During the first year, one-half of its expenses were paid by the first of these three bodies, which subsequently took over full financial responsibility. The name MALBEN represents the initials of the organisation's full Hebrew title. 2 See above, table 29. 94 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 year plan to provide permanent housing for all those—numbering 20,000 at the end of 1957—who still needed it. A total of 500 million Israeli pounds was set aside for this purpose. The over-all situation position is slowly improving, but by and large housing conditions among the Jewish population are not much above the fairly low standards which existed during the mandate. Immigration Results SETTLEMENT OF THE COUNTRY The integration policy pursued by the Israeli Government has brought about substantial changes in the distribution of the population. These are illustrated by table 30. TABLE 30. ISRAEL : DISTRIBUTION OF THE JEWISH POPULATION BY AREA ON 8 NOVEMBER 1948 AND 31 DECEMBER 1957 On 8 November 1948 Districts Northern Haifa Central Tel-Aviv Jerusalem Southern Unknown Total . . . Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 60.5 140.7 106.3 302.0 84.1 6.0 17.1 8.5 19.6 14.8 42.2 11.7 0.8 2.4 716.7 100.0 On 31 December 1957 Absolute figures (thousands) ages 180.6 303.4 368.7 617.1 171.2 121.7 10.3 17.2 20.9 35.0 9.7 6.9 Increase Absolute figures (thousands) Per- — 120.1 162.7 262.4 315.1 87.1 115.7 -17.1 198.5 115.6 246.8 104.3 103.5 1,928.4 -100.0 1,762.7 100.0 1,046.0 145.9 — Per- ages The table shows that the population increase between 8 November 1948 (the date of the first Israeli census) and 31 December 1957 varied greatly from one area to another. It was well below the average (145.9 per cent.) in the areas containing the major cities, i.e. Haifa, Tel-Aviv and Jerusalem. On the other hand it was well above this average in the most thinly populated districts, i.e. the Northern district (despite the presence of a strong non-Jewish minority) and the Central and the Southern districts. This latter area, which is almost entirely covered by the Negev Desert, was virtually uninhabited at the start of the period and its present settlement, although still sparse, is a completely new development. As the Government had hoped and planned, the countryside IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 95 TABLE 31. ISRAEL : COMPARATIVE TRENDS IN THE JEWISH POPULATION OF THE COUNTRYSIDE, MAJOR CITIES AND OTHER URBAN AREAS, 1948-57 On 8 November 1948 On 31 December 1957 Areas Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Countryside Haifa, Tel-Aviv, Jaffa, Jerusalem Other towns Reception centres and unknown 105.1 14.7 396.8 22.5 291.7 277.5 413.0 168.5 57.6 23.5 683.5 679.0 38.8 38.5 270.5 510.2 65.5 311.5 29.8 4.2 3.4 0.2 -26.4 -88.6 100.0 1,762.7 100.0 1,046.0 145.9 Total . . . 716.7 Increase Percentages and the small and medium towns inland benefited most from the influx of immigrants. This is brought out by table 31. Thus, the immigration that took place after 1948 not only raised the population of Israel to two-and-a-half times its former level but enabled the country to make rapid strides towards a more balanced distribution of this population, without which its resources could not have been properly exploited. However, the present situation is still not considered fully satisfactory, and a two-pronged drive for agricultural settlement, aimed both at newly arrived immigrants and at the inhabitants of the big cities is now under way. ECONOMIC EXPANSION Immigration was accompanied by rapid economic expansion, at least after the end of 1949, as evidenced by the increase in the labour force and in total production. The figures given in table 32 show that between the census of 8 November 1948 and June 1957 the number of persons in employment increased by more than 280,000, i.e. by about 90 per cent. Taking account of the already sharp increase that had taken place between May and November 1948, it had in fact just about doubled in little over nine years. The increase in production was also considerable, particularly in agriculture where output had fallen when the Arabs left. Between 1948 96 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 32. ISRAEL : JEWISH EMPLOYED PERSONS, BY BRANCH OF THE ECONOMY, IN NOVEMBER 1948 AND JUNE 1957 November 1948 June 1957 Branch of the economy Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Agriculture Industry and handicrafts (including extractive industries) Building and public works Transport and communications . . . . Water, gas, electricity and sanitation . . Commerce, banking, insurance Public and private services Unspecified . . . . 38.1 12.1 93.0 15.6 85.8 16.4 16.7 27.3 5.2 5.3 22.4 9.3 6.8 2.5 36.4 80.8 40.8 11.5 25.6 13.0 133.1 55.1 40.7 15.1 81.2 176.6 2.7 Total . . . 314.8 100.0 597.5 100.0 Employed persons as percentage of total population 43.9 Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 13.7 29.7 35.1 and 1957, the area under cultivation increased by more than 125 per cent.—from 1,650,000 to 3,840,000 dunams. 1 The main effort was concentrated on irrigation, with the result that the total irrigated area increased from 300,000 dunams to 1,226,000 during the same period. This, together with the doubling of the labour force, led to a rapid growth in the output of most products, particularly vegetables, fruit, oil seeds, fodder and animal products. Industrial expansion, for its part, took the form of a steep rise in the output of electric power (from 329,200 kWh in 1949 to 1,142,600 in 1956), expansion in certain traditional industries such as foodstuffs, cement and fertilisers and, in recent years, the establishment of a wide range of completely new industries. Nevertheless, despite the increase in the labour force and the rise in output, it cannot be claimed that the immigrants have been completely integrated or that the economic problems resulting from immigration have been fully overcome.2 The growth in employment has been slower than the growth in the population, due not only to changes in the age distribution of the population since 1948 but also to a substantial fall in female employment. A breakdown of the labour force by occupation l 4 dunams=1 acre. It is estimated that of the workers who have joined the labour force in recent years some 10 per cent, were not absorbed and 20 per cent, were only partly employed. 2 97 IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL also shows that a markedly higher proportion of workers are now employed in services than in 1948 x—too many, in fact, for a country whose agricultural and industrial output is still far from meeting its needs. Lastly, owing to lack of capital or skill, the output of industry, and above all of agriculture, is still very often lower than it should be. Not only, therefore, is the present labour force relatively small but its productivity has not yet reached a satisfactory level. In all, the expansion of production, though remarkable for a country with such scanty natural resources, seems barely to have kept pace with the increase in population that has occurred since 1948. Nevertheless, with the achievement of financial stability since 1953, a major campaign has been launched in a variety of directions to step up productivity, e.g. through improvements in farming methods, farm mechanisation, the extension of vocational training, industrial concentration, more efficient organisation and output bonuses. This campaign, which has gone hand in hand with large expansion schemes in both agriculture and industry, should gradually lead to a better distribution of the labour force and, as a result of rising efficiency, to a distinctly faster rate of production growth. Such a trend has in fact already been apparent over the past few years. DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME Foreign aid, by keeping the market amply supplied with consumer goods 2 , prevented the fall in productivity caused by immigration from leading to a sharp and lasting drop in real average incomes. Moreover, it limited the fall that did occur by greatly increasing the volume of productive capital. As a result the decline in the income of labour compared with that of capital—the classic consequence of uncontrolled large-scale immigration—was comparatively slight. For the great majority of wage earners the inflation caused by the influx of immigrants led to nothing more than a halt between 1950 and 1953, and a slackening 1 This is, of course, due in part to the fact that less capital is necessary to create new jobs in services than in other trades. 2 Details regarding consumption and income per head between 1948 and 1950 are not available but the following indices (1950=100) show that from 1953 onwards both rose sharply. Year 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 Income Consumption 110 93 93 106 114 120 106 105 105 122 126 128 98 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 between 1955 and 1957, in the rise of real wages. The only exceptions were the most highly paid workers, who were more directly affected by the Government's social policy of providing everybody, and particularly the unskilled immigrants, with a decent standard of living. Similarly, the difference between the social and economic status of most immigrants and that of the earlier settlers—another classic feature of mass migrations—was relatively unimportant. Nor did immigration, in most cases, involve a fall from a previously higher status: a very large number of the immigrants from the Moslem countries, and even many of those from Eastern and Central Europe, are now just as well off in Israel as they were before and in many cases distinctly better off. Conclusion The challenge to the laws of nature and economics which immigration to Israel from 1948 to 1951 represented could obviously not have succeeded so remarkably if the country had been left to fend for itself. The terms of the problem were fundamentally altered by the scale on which foreign aid was made available. As a result, the population was spared any lasting fall in its standards of living, unemployment was kept in check, inflation was conquered and the economy was able to achieve its spectacular expansion. The size of this outside contribution must not, however, be allowed to overshadow the sheer hard work put in by the entire population in coping with the tremendous handicaps resulting from the size of the influx, the poverty of the country, the inadequacy of its capital equipment and the low standards of skill of the new arrivals. But the problem will not be finally solved until the Israeli economy has ceased altogether to depend on foreign assistance, and this will take a good many years, particularly if the new wave of immigration which began in 1955 continues. Assistance will also be required for a long time to come to finance needed investment. Finally, a marked improvement in standards of skill and working methods remains imperative. Bibliographical References Statistical Sources Unless otherwise stated the statistics quoted in this chapter are taken from the following publications of the Central Bureau of Statistics in Jerusalem: Statistical Abstract of Israel, 1949-50 to 1956-57 ; and Statistical Bulletin of Israel (monthly), since 1950. IMMIGRATION INTO ISRAEL 99 Other Sources Apart from information supplied directly to the International Labour Office the following have been used: UNITED NATIONS: The Manpower Contribution of Immigration into Israel, by Benjamin G I L (paper submitted to the World Population Conference, Rome, 1954), Document E/CONF. 13/130, 30 Apr. 1954 (mimeographed). BANK OF ISRAEL : Annual reports. MINISTRY OF COMMERCE AND INDUSTRY : Israel Economic Bulletin (Jerusalem), monthly. UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, BUREAU OF THE CENSUS: Israel: Jewish Population and Immigration, by Norman LAWRENCE, International Population Statistics Reports, Series P-90, No. 2 (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office, 1952). H. B. M. MURPHY: " T h e Resettlement of Jewish Refugees in Israel, with Special Reference to Those Known as Displaced Persons ", in Population Studies (Cambridge, The University Press), Vol. V. No. 2, Nov. 1951, p. 152. R. BACHI: " L a population juive de l'Etat d'Israël", in Population (Paris, Institut national d'études démographiques), Seventh Year, No. 3,JulySep. 1952, p . 405-452. M. LEVY: Israel Economie Survey, 1953-54 (Jerusalem, The Economic Department of the Jewish Agency, 1955). R. BACHI: (Edited by, on behalf of the Eliezer Kaplan School of Economics and Social Sciences): Studies in Economic and Social Sciences, Scripta Hierosolymitana, Vol. I l l (Jerusalem, The Magnes Press, Hebrew University, 1956), including in particular " Monetary and Price Development in Israel, 1949-1953 ", by D . PATINKIN, and " Professions and Social Structure in Israel " , by J. BEN DAVID. — Trends of Population and Labour Force in Israel, Report prepared for a symposium on " The Challenge of Development ", held in Jerusalem on 26 and 27 June 1957 (Jerusalem, the Eliezer Kaplan School of Economics and Social Sciences, the Hebrew University (mimeographed)). M. SICRON: Immigration to Israel, 1948-53 (Jerusalem, Falk Project for Economic Research in Israel and Central Bureau of Statistics, 1957). Economic Review of Israel, No. 22, Jan. 1958, Three-Monthly Economic Review series (London, The Economist Intelligence Unit, Ltd.) The Israel Economist (Jerusalem), published monthly since 1949 (successor to the Palestine Economist). CHAPTER IV POPULATION SHIFTS IN ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST The political changes that have taken place in Asia and the Middle East since 1945 have, as in Europe, led to a number of large-scale population shifts : in the Near East the exodus of the Arabs from Palestine, which followed the establishment of the State of Israel; in India, the two-way movement of part of the Hindu and Moslem minorities left by the 1947 partition outside the frontiers of the State to which they owed religious allegiance; and, in the Far East, the repatriation of the Japanese who had settled in their country's former dependencies and of the Koreans who had settled in Japan and Manchuria, the influx of Chinese refugees into Hong Kong and Formosa, and the flight of refugees from North to South Korea and, more recently, from North to South Viet-Nam. Unlike most of the major post-war population shifts in Europe, these movements were neither forced nor planned; they were not, therefore, properly speaking, transfers. Rather, they were due in most cases to a more or less rational belief on the part of those concerned that trouble lay ahead—a belief which often assumed panic proportions, with the result that such movements generally developed into headlong flights which did great damage both to individuals and to communities. The resulting economic problems varied from one country to another. Those countries which received the refugees or repatriated persons were themselves, by and large, overpopulated and, with the exception of Japan, unindustrialised, so that most of them had the utmost difficulty in providing elementary relief for the newcomers, let alone integrating them in their economies. In the Near East the burden of relief was almost entirely assumed by the United Nations, while in India and Pakistan the need was largely met by private charity. Nowhere, however, except in the Near East, did the influx of refugees cause more than a minor worsening of the long-standing problem posed by a rapidly growing population coupled with slow capital accumulation and backward production methods. Thus, while the refugees swelled the povertystricken masses, the over-all effect of such population shifts on the local demographic situation was not always very noticeable; nor is their ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 101 economic impact on the countries concerned easy to measure by the standards used in earlier chapters, particularly since most of the necessary numerical data are lacking. What follows, therefore, is a description rather than a statistical account of these various movements. The Palestine Arab Refugees BACKGROUND The flight of the Arab population from the territory of Israel was a consequence of the decision taken by the United Nations General Assembly on 29 November 1947 to partition Palestine between the Jewish and Arab communities which had hitherto lived there side by side. This decision, while it left only a small Jewish minority in the territory granted to the Arabs, gave the Jews an area inhabited by at least 400,000 Arabs—nearly as many as there were Jews. The decision was rejected by the Arabs, and this led in 1948-49 to a war between Israel and the neighbouring States, as a result of which the Israelis occupied, and subsequently held, a slice of territory beyond the demarcation line, though still within the former frontiers of Palestine, in which some 340,000 Arabs were living. These events led most of the Arabs inside the former frontiers of Palestine to seek refuge in the neighbouring countries, hoping to return before long. In fact, however, their exile has already lasted for more than ten years, and the danger that most of them may go on indefinitely simply eking out an existence on international relief is a very real one. The first to leave were about 30,000 well-to-do Arabs from Jerusalem, Haifa and Jaffa, who decided to take shelter in the neighbouring countries as soon as the United Nations decision was announced. A second exodus on a much larger scale began in March 1948 and continued until the opening of hostilities; this also involved townsfolk, mostly from Haifa, Jaffa and various other cities. By mid-May 1948 the number of Arab refugees was already a quarter of a million. The later movements took place in such confusion that it is impossible to reckon the exact numbers involved. Nevertheless, by October their number exceed half a million and by the end of the year it was approximately 750,000. In other words, the war had driven the great majority of the Arab population of Palestine into exile. According to an official Israeli Government estimate, only some 100,000 Arabs were left in Israel by 19 December 1948. 102 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 STATISTICAL DATA The scale of this flight by the Arabs is difficult to assess with any accuracy since the refugees refused to be counted. The relief rolls also seem to have been swollen considerably because many people were registered more than once and because a number of the local poor managed to register as refugees even though they were not entitled to do so. The high rate of increase of the refugee population complicated the problem still further. As a result, the numbers involved can only be estimated roughly. At the end of 1945, 736,000 Arabs were living within the present frontiers of Israel. Reckoning the nomad population as well, and allowing for the natural increase as well as subsequent illegal immigration, the total Arab population at the end of 1947 can be generously estimated at about 860,000. At the end of 1948 there were only about 110,000 left, which means that some 750,000 must have emigrated. An estimate made in September 1949 of the distribution of the Arab population of the former territory of Palestine (see table 33) appears to bear out this calculation. It shows that the number of refugees at that date, when a proportion of them had already gone back to Israel, was a little TABLE 33. FORMER ARAB POPULATION OF PALESTINE, BY COUNTRY OF RESIDENCE, IN SEPTEMBER 1949 Country of residence Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Non-refugees : 150 11.8 105 299 8.3 23.6 554 43.7 200 220 88 100 100 5 15.8 17.4 6.9 7.9 7.9 0.4 Total refugees . . . 713 56.3 Total . . . 1,267 100.0 Outside Israel: Central Palestine Total non-refugees . . . Refugees : Central Palestine Jordan Syria Lebanon Iraq Source: S. G. THICKNESSE: Arab Refugees: A Survey of Resettlement Possibilities (London and New York, Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1949). 103 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST TABLE 34. REFUGEES REGISTERED WITH U.N.R.W.A., BY YEAR AND COUNTRY OF RESIDENCE, 1950-57 (FIGURES ON 30 JUNE) (In thousands) Country of residence 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . 198.2 199.8 204.4 208.6 212.6 214.6 217.0 221.0 506.2 465.7 469.6 475.6 486.6 499.6 512.7 517.4 127.6 106.9 104.9 102.1 101.6 103.6 102.6 102.6 82.2 82.9 84.2 85.5 86.2 88.2 90.0 92.5 i i i i i 45.8 24.4 19.6 Total . . . 960.0 879.7 882.7 871.7 887.1 906.0 922.3 933.5 Gaza area Jordan Lebanon Syria Israel Source: United Nations: Annual Report of the Director of the United Nations Relief and Works Agency for Palestine Refugees in the Near East, Covering the Period 1 July 1956 to 30 June 1957, General Assembly Official Records, Twelfth Session, Supplement No. 14 (A/3686) (New York, 1957). 1 In June 1952, the Israeli Government decided to assume responsibility for the last Arab refugees remaining within its territory. over 700,000. Some who, having gone «back, could not return to their former homes should, however, be reckoned as refugees in Israel and added to the above estimate. The number of refugees registered for international relief was, however, much higher. In the summer of 1949 it reached something like a million persons, although this figure, for reasons already indicated, is probably too high. Annual statistics have been regularly published by the United Nations Relief and Works Agency for Palestine Refugees in the Near East since May 1950, when this organisation took over responsibility for the refugee relief programme (table 34). As the table shows, the total number of 960,000 refugees in the care of U.N.R.W.A. on 30 June 1950 fell sharply (by about 80,000) during the following 12 months. This was because a check-up had been carried out among the refugees, resulting in the removal of a number of names from the rolls, particularly in Jordan, and also because of progress accomplished towards resetthng refugees in Israel. The latter process was virtually complete by June 1952, when the Israeli Government decided to assume full responsibility for those remaining within its territory. Since 1952 the total number of refugees has, on the whole, increased, owing to natural growth, except in Lebanon, where some of them have been gradually absorbed into the remainder of the population. Not only was the influx of refugees enormous in itself, but in two of the receiving territories it produced a huge increase in the population. 104 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The biggest relative increase occurred in the Gaza area where there are nearly two refugees for every three inhabitants. It was also very high in Jordan where it amounted to about 80 per cent, of the existing population. This was on top of the burdens already borne by the local population which, in Gaza as in Jordan, had already suffered heavily from the economic consequences of the partition of Palestine. In Lebanon and Syria, the refugees accounted respectively for a little under 7 and a little over 2 per cent, of the local population. The statistics also give some idea of the composition of the refugee population by age. Its most striking feature is its extreme youth, nearly 45 per cent, of the refugees consisting of children under the age of 15. This high percentage is the result of a high birth rate, coupled with a remarkably low infant mortality rate which may be ascribed to proper health care. The large number of children and of expectant mothers, or mothers with young families, is one of the salient features of the problem of resettling the refugees and an additional source of difficulty. A breakdown of the refugee population by previous occupation reveals a very small proportion of economically active persons and a heavy preponderance of farmers and unskilled workers. In. 1951 only 150,000 refugees out of a total of 880,000 could be reckoned as having had an occupation in Palestine, nearly 40 per cent, of them as farmers and 20 per cent, as servants or labourers. Detailed percentages for each occupation are given in table 35. TABLE 35. BREAKDOWN OF ECONOMICALLY ACTIVE PALESTINE ARAB REFUGEES BY PREVIOUS OCCUPATION, 1951 Occupation Labouring and domestic service Agriculture and fishing Industry and construction Commerce and clerical Professions and other services Landlords, students and miscellaneous Percentages 20.0 37.9 14.6 15.6 4.5 7.4 100.0 Lastly, a breakdown of the refugees by religious affiliation shows a very large majority of Moslems and a small minority of Christians, varying in size according to the country of residence. Before the mass flight, 70,000 Arab Christians were living within the frontiers of what is now the State of Israel, but only a little over half of them were among the refugees. The proportion of these Arabs is highest in the Lebanon— ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 105 about one-quarter of the total in June 1951—whereas in Jordan, Syria and the Gaza area the proportions were 6, 1.7 and 0.3 per cent. respectively. RELIEF AND ASSISTANCE During the first few months following their departure, the refugees were given a certain amount of relief by the governments of the countries in which they took shelter. Nevertheless, the burden soon proved too heavy for these countries and the United Nations Mediator in Palestine, for obvious humanitarian reasons, asked for and obtained international assistance for this purpose, which was later rapidly increased. As early as August 1948 the United Nations International Children's Emergency Fund (U.N.I.C.E.F.) granted large-scale cash assistance, and in the following month began to provide staff as well. The Mediator then drew up a project for helping the homeless and called in a number of voluntary organisations to assist in distributing the supplies he had collected. In November 1948 the General Assembly of the United Nations established the United Nations Relief for Palestine Refugees to distribute relief in kind. It became apparent, however, by the end of the summer of 1949 that the refugee problem was not going to be settled quickly and that further action was called for. An Economic Survey Mission for the Middle East was appointed and made a report to the General Assembly in November 1949 recommending the establishment of an agency with responsibility for distributing relief to the refugees on a reduced scale and, above all, for preparing public works schemes in the interests of the receiving countries and the refugees themselves in order to enable a growing proportion of the homeless to become self-supporting. The United Nations General Assembly endorsed these recommendations and set up the United Nations Relief and Works Agency for Palestine Refugees in the Near East (U.N.R.W.A.) which took over the assets and liabilities of the U.N.R.P.R. and began operations in May 1950. In December 1954 the United Nations decided to keep the Agency in being until 30 June 1960. Its relief and assistance activities include the provision of food, accommodation and clothing, together with medical, health and social services (particularly schools). As the Agency's budget is limited, it has been forced to keep its benefits down to the bare minimum. Despite this, it has been able to give the refugees a standard of living which is no lower than that of a large section of the local population. By providing 106 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 food, which is by far the biggest item in the relief budget, it has managed to prevent undernourishment, the normal issue being supplemented by special rations for children, expectant or nursing mothers, hospital patients and tubercular cases not in hospital. Refugees who manage to find work are, of course, better fed. In 1950 less than a third of the refugees were still living in camps run by the Agency, the great bulk of them having managed to rent accommodation or to find some sort of shelter, however rudimentary. In order to prevent the emergence of a " professional refugee " mentality, they were encouraged to find their own accommodation. Nevertheless, many of them, having exhausted their savings or given up any hope of finding work, drifted back to the camps. This, together with the natural process of growth, resulted in a rise, instead of a fall, in the camp population which, by 1957, accounted for 38.6 per cent, of the total number of refugees. The Agency tried to avoid establishing permanent or semi-permanent camps in areas with few opportunities for employment and at first accommodated the refugees under canvas. But in the end it had no alternative but to build permanent camps to which those who had been living in tents or other inadequate accommodation were gradually transferred. At the same time it tried to make it clear to its charges that better housing for them did not mean permanent settlement or abandonment of their political claims. The refugees' health had been one of the foremost concerns of the international relief organisations. From the start the programme of the United Nations Mediator had made provision for the supply of medicines, and as soon as the U.N.R.P.R. began functioning it made plans, in co-operation with the World Health Organisation, U.N.I.C.E.F. and a number of voluntary organisations, to meet certain essential needs. Later the Agency managed to provide the refugees with various preventive facilities in addition to normal hospital services, e.g. insect control, sanitary inspection of living quarters, detection and control of endemic or epidemic diseases, vaccination, and education in health and hygiene. Owing to lack of money and staff the Agency was unable to provide medical care of a standard substantially higher than that provided under local public assistance arrangements, and therefore had to concentrate on sanitation and preventive medicine. A fairly comprehensive school system was built up by U.N.R.W.A. with the help of U.N.E.S.C.O. and the I.L.O. During the 1956-57 school year, 169,000 refugee children of both sexes were receiving elementary or secondary education at the Agency's expense, either in schools run by the Agency itself or in official or private establishments in their country of residence. A number of abler pupils were awarded university ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 107 scholarships. Substantial progress has also been made in vocational training. The social welfare side of the Agency's work has also covered a wide field, ranging from the distribution of clothing and milk to social assistance, and including the organisation of leisure activities, evening classes and training courses for welfare workers. The Agency has likewise set up a placement service for refugees willing to work, and makes loans to those who wish to emigrate but cannot afford to do so. It also keeps in touch with a number of official bodies and employers in its efforts to find work for the refugees. INTEGRATION PLANS The United Nations Economic Survey Mission, in its report issued in December 1949 1 , emphasised the need to provide stable employment for the refugees as the only way out of what looked like a hopeless impasse in view of the existing political situation. It made detailed suggestions concerning public works schemes which could be carried out using refugee labour, and provided a plan for taking the refugees off relief and enabling them to earn their own living. Action was taken on these recommendations and various schemes were launched, including the establishment of new industrial undertakings. By 1950-51 jobs had been found for an appreciable number of refugees but most of these schemes had to be abandoned because they were uneconomic. In more advanced economies, public works of this kind would have stimulated other industries and created more jobs, but in this case they were simply operating in a vacuum. Apart from these difficulties, which were inherent in the economic structure of the receiving countries, there was also the opposition of governments and the refugees themselves to any plan which smacked of resettlement. Thus this initial programme ended in failure. In January 1952 the United Nations General Assembly gave its approval to a new programme which, it was hoped, would be of more direct benefit to the receiving countries. This provided for the expenditure of 200 million dollars on various schemes which would provide work for the refugees over a number of years and open the way for the permanent resettlement of some of them. The two biggest schemes called for the irrigation of some 125,000 acres in Jordan through the 1 United Nations : Final Report of the United Nations Economic Survey Mission for the Middle East, United Nations Publications, Sales No. 1949. IIB.5 (New York, 1949). 108 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 damming and canalising of the River Jordan, and of about 50,000 acres in the Sinai Peninsula by diverting Nile water from the canal linking the river with the Suez Canal. Apart from the thousands of jobs which these schemes would create directly, between 100,000 and 150,000 refugees would be permanently resettled under the first scheme and between 50,000 and 70,000 under the second. Owing, however, to political and technical difficulties, both of these main schemes have had to be postponed indefinitely. On the other hand, U.N.R.W.A. has succeeded in carrying out a number of smaller schemes, such as the establishment of small farm settlements and handicraft concerns, mainly in Syria and Jordan. Further schemes of this type are being carried out as rapidly as funds allow. Syria and Iraq appear to offer further scope for such agricultural development schemes, but these do not seem likely to materialise in the near future. Thus, even assuming that the political climate in the area does gradually improve, it is hard to see how the problem of the Palestine refugees can be finally settled for many years to come. Population Movements between India and Pakistan HISTORICAL SURVEY The large-scale population shifts which took place between India and Pakistan were the direct result of the Indian Independence Act of 18 July 1947, whereby British sovereignty was transferred to these two new States—India, with a Hindu majority, and Pakistan, with a Moslem majority. One of the arguments in favour of establishing a separate Moslem State was the fact that the bulk of the Moslem minority in India (about 60 per cent.) was concentrated in two fairly well-defined regions and therefore the geographical basis for the proposed partition already existed. These two regions, however (76 out of the 435 districts which made up British India), contained a large Hindu minority amounting to roughly a quarter of the population. In 1947 it was decided to partition the country on religious lines, Pakistan being formed of two groups of districts with a strong Moslem majority (separated from each other by some 1,000 miles of Indian territory), ' one of which became West Pakistan and the other East Pakistan, the former six times as big as the latter but with only three quarters of its population. The whole of the remainder became the Union of India with three times the area of Pakistan and four-and-a-half times its population. ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 109 The immediate—and tragic—result of this decision to partition the country was a huge two-way exodus of minority groups seeking to join their co-religionists on the other side of the frontier. These movements had in fact begun even before partition took place. During the early months of 1947 many hundreds of thousands of Hindus from the Punjab and the Northwest Provinces had left their homes, while a flight of Moslems had also taken place to the west during the period immediately preceding independence. The two-way movement, however, did not reach its peak until after independence when for months on end a horde of refugees poured in both directions, swamping all available means of transport or travelling on foot in small groups or in long straggling columns. By the end of 1948 Pakistan had received 6.7 million refugees and India approximately the same number. The movements went on for a long time afterwards, since for Pakistan as a whole the number of refugees rose from 7.2 million at the 1951 census to 8.4 million at the 1957 census while in India their number increased from 7.3 million to 8,850,000 between the same dates. 1 These figures show the net results of the population exchange, including natural growth. On the other hand, the actual size of the various movements is impossible to ascertain since, apart from deaths on the way, for which there are no figures at all, a fairly large number of refugees went back to their homes. A figure of 18 million can, however, be claimed as a minimum for the total number of people who left their homes. While this figure was divided about evenly between the two countries, the demographic impact of the movement was quite different in each case, since the proportion of refugees to the total population, as disclosed by the 1951 census, amounted to a full 10 per cent, in Pakistan, as compared with 2 per cent, only in India. Within Pakistan itself, moreover, the density of the refugee population was very uneven, ranging from about 20 per cent, in the western part of the country to about 1.7 per cent, in the east. CONSEQUENCES OF THE POPULATION SHIFTS In order to be properly appreciated, the difficulties caused by the influx of refugees into India and Pakistan must be viewed against the general economic background in the two countries, both of which have very low levels of productivity and standards of living. The refugee problem in fact merged into—and, to some extent, no doubt aggravated—• the far wider problem of improving the living standards of the peoples, of 1 Ministry of Rehabilitation (India): Report, 1957-1958. 110 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 whom the majority live on the borderline of hunger, and millions are without work or shelter. Nevertheless, among the economic and political problems that India and Pakistan had to grapple with after the granting of independence, those arising out of the population shifts which followed partition for a time definitely overshadowed the others. In the first place, the departure of the refugees left gaps in the economies of the two countries which the incoming refugees, whose occupational pattern was completely different, could only partially fill. In some industries this dislocation had serious consequences and the authorities had to take action to deal with them (mainly by providing vocational training facilities). In the second place, the task of relief and resettlement in both countries was hamstrung by the desperate inadequacy of resources to deal with the situation. Both countries had the utmost difficulty in providing the refugees with the relief they needed, although their demands were well below what would be considered the bare minimum in the West. This difficulty TABLE 36. INDIA: BREAKDOWN OF REFUGEES BY AREA, 1951 Refugees Population (in thousands^ Absolute figures (thousands) 63,215.7 480.3 0.8 6.6 9,043.7 24,810.3 56,307.2 274.5 2,099.1 202.4 3.0 8.5 0.4 3.8 28.8 2.8 90,161.2 2,576.0 2.9 35.3 75,600.8 40,661.1 52,268.0 16.6 409.9 195.9 0.0 1.1 0.4 0.2 5.6 2.7 1,744.1 12,641.2 3,493.7 17,093.6 495.4 2,376.0 356.0 389.8 28.4 18.8 10.2 2.3 6.8 32.5 4.9 5.3 Total . . . 34,972.6 3,617.2 10.3 49.6 Over-all total . . . 356,879.4 7,295.9 2.0 100.0 Area Northern India (Uttar Pradesh) Eastern India : Assam West Bengal Other . . . . Total . . . Southern India Western India Central India North-western India : Delhi Punjab P.E.P.S.U. 1 Other Source: 1951 census data. Patiala and East Punjab States Union. 1 percentAs percent- Asage of age of total number population of refugees 111 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST TABLE 37. PAKISTAN: B R E A K D O W N O F REFUGEES BY AREA, 1951 Refugees Area Population (in thousands) East Pakistan (East Bengal) West Pakistan : Punjab Bahawalpur Sind Other 41,932.3 699.1 1.7 9.7 18,814.2 1,822.5 4,605.9 5,583.0 4,908.3 372.9 540.3 89.1 26.1 20.5 11.7 1.6 67.9 5.2 7.5 1.2 Total . . . Federal District (Karachi) . 30,825.6 1,122.4 5,910.6 616.9 17.0 55.0 81.8 8.5 Over-all total1. . . 73,880.0 7,226.6 9.8 100.0 percentAbsolute As percent- Astage of figures age of total number (in thousands) population of refugees Source: 1951 census data. 1 Excluding population of frontier districts not covered by census. was not only due to the lack of money but also to the absence of certain facilities and the administrative disorganisation caused by partition. As a result, most of the refugees' immediate needs were met, in accordance with the Indian tradition, by private hospitality, so that the burden of maintaining them became not so much a national as a regional and even an individual responsibility. The very uneven distribution of refugees within each of the two countries naturally forced the receiving areas to bear much more of the cost of integration than the others, and this situation, despite the efforts of the two governments to distribute the burden more equally, has persisted to this day owing to a variety of factors common to most underdeveloped economies and ranging from low productivity to inadequate administrative resources. Similarly, and for the same reasons, the refugees were not able to make their full contribution to production and economic development. Demographic Consequences Although these refugee movements involved equal numbers on both sides and therefore, at the national level—and even, in many cases, at the regional level—represented merely a person-for-person population exchange, they nevertheless altered the geographical distribution of the population in both countries to some extent. The 1951 census figures regarding the distribution of refugees by area (tables 36 and 37) and a 112 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 comparison between the 1941 and 1951 census figures regarding the distribution of the population by religious groups and by area give some idea of the changes caused by this two-way exodus in the geographical pattern of the population. In India, the 1951 census shows that only the north-west and eastern areas, i.e. in the main, those adjoining the two halves of Pakistan, received refugees in any numbers. Eastern India received nearly 2.6 million, of whom nearly 2.1 million entered West Bengal alone, while north-west India received 3.6 million, of whom nearly 2.4 million entered the Punjab and 0.5 million the state of Delhi. The concentration of refugees was, and still is, heaviest in these two areas, representing 2.9 per cent, of the population in eastern India as a whole (8.5 per cent, in West Bengal); and 10.3 per cent, in north-west India as a whole (18.8 per cent, in the Punjab and 28.4 per cent, in Delhi state). Elsewhere the refugees form sizeable groups in absolute terms, e.g. in Uttar Pradesh and Bombay state, but their proportion is negligible. A comparison between the 1941 and 1951 censuses also shows that the areas which received most refugees were, in the main, those from which there was heavy Moslem emigration, i.e. West Bengal, Uttar Pradesh, Delhi, Patiala and East Punjab States Union, the Punjab and Rajasthan. The movements in both directions, however, did not balance out everywhere. In West Bengal, especially, the number of incoming Hindu refugees was three or four times higher than the number of outgoing Moslems, whereas in the Punjab, where virtually the whole Moslem minority emigrated, immigration had by 1951 filled only half the gaps left. On balance the changes caused by the movement in the distribution of the population throughout India were virtually nil over most of the country but did seriously affect certain provinces, e.g. West Bengal and Delhi state, where they appreciably increased the density of the population, and the Punjab and Patiala and East Punjab States Union, where they had the opposite effect. In Pakistan the influx of refugees affected the western part of the country far more than the eastern part; in 1951 the latter contained less than 10 per cent, of the refugee population although its population was a good deal larger. The Punjab received the bulk of the immigrants (more than two-thirds of the total) but the influx was relatively greatest in the Federal District where, in 1951, 55 per cent, of the population were refugees. As in India the interchange did not balance out everywhere and in the Punjab it would appear that despite the departure of almost all the Hindus there was a heavy surplus of immigrants, whereas in East Bengal the balance was tipped even more markedly the other way. ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 113 These, at least, are the conclusions which emerge from a study of the 1941 and 1951 censuses. Since then movements have continued in both directions which have altered the pattern to some extent but without changing its main outlines. The biggest movements have taken place in Bengal, where 0.5 million Moslems left West Bengal for East Bengal between 1951 and 1956, while over 1.5 million Hindus emigrated to eastern India. Elsewhere the number of Hindu refugees appears to have remained stable, but a further 650,000 Moslems left India for West Pakistan during the same period. Thus, these more recent movements, which have continued to affect mainly the partitioned states of Bengal and the Punjab, have accentuated the disrupting effects of the previous movements by increasing the population density in the Pakistani part of the Punjab and the Indian part of Bengal and by producing the opposite effect in the two other halves. Another major demographic result was an appreciable change in some areas in the ratio of the urban to the rural population. Usually there was an increase in the former, particularly in India, where in 1951 54 per cent, of the refugee population was living in towns, i.e. three times as many as the corresponding proportion among the local population. Economic and Social Consequences The refugees confronted the two countries with both short and longterm economic problems. The former included the mobilisation of transport and the provision of emergency relief. Of these two, the latter placed a heavy burden on the families which took the refugees in and on the governments themselves, whose precariously balanced budgets suddenly had to cope with a steep rise in expenditure, most of which, being for camps, food, clothing and essential medical and health services, was of no real value as an investment. But a second, even more difficult, task remained—the closing down of the camps, which it was in the authorities' interest to do as soon as possible. This meant providing stable employment for the refugees. Those from the country districts were, where possible, provisionally settled on land abandoned by the emigrants, this being the only way of avoiding famine, but the integration of the refugees from the towns was a far more difficult process. The shortage of housing, the lack of jobs and the distortions caused by the two-way movement in the occupational structure of the labour force in the two countries created difficulties on such a scale as to affect national planning priorities. Whereas the bulk of the Moslem refugees were peasants and rural handicraftsmen, 114 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 most of the Hindus were town dwellers, e.g. shopkeepers, government employees and clerical workers. The result was that the departure of the Moslems seriously affected Indian food output and at the same time left a shortage of skilled manual workers, while the majority of the immigrants from Pakistan lacked the skills required to fill the gaps. In Pakistan, on the other hand, the departure of the Hindus deprived the country of civil servants and shopkeepers who were badly needed during the early years of the new State's existence. Furthermore, while the farms and farming facilities abandoned by the Hindus in Pakistan were of a higher standard than those left by the Moslems in India, the immigrants had to master unfamiliar techniques before they could use them. Table 38 gives the occupational breakdown of the refugee population in India compared with that of the local population in 1951. TABLE 38. INDIA 1 : OCCUPATIONAL BREAKDOWN OF THE REFUGEE AND LOCAL POPULATION, 1951 (Percentages) Local population Branch of activity Agriculture : Owner-farmers Non-owner farmers Farm labourers Non-farming landlords Total . . . Other activities : Production other than agriculture . . . Commerce Refugees 47.7 8.7 12.7 1.6 5.6 18.0 4.3 0.9 70.7 28.8 10.5 1.6 5.6 11.6 11.8 4.3 24.0 31.1 29.3 71.2 100.0 100.0 Other services and miscellaneous . . . Total . . . Over-all total . . . Source: 1951 census data. Including dependants. 1 These figures show that in India the refugees increased the proportion of persons in commerce and other service occupations, both of which were already overcrowded. Moreover, the high proportion of refugees living in the towns (54 per cent, as against 17 per cent, for the local population) accentuated an existing deficiency in the country's social 115 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST structure, namely the undue proportion of the population living in towns in relation to opportunities of urban employment. In other words, the presence of the refugees in India aggravated the social problems associated with big cities, e.g. roads, public hygiene, transport, supplies and, above all, employment. There are no equally precise figures illustrating the impact of these movements on Pakistan, and figures showing the proportion of refugees living in the towns and the countryside are completely lacking. Nevertheless, a breakdown of the refugee and local labour forces (given in table 39) shows that, while 75 per cent, at least of the refugees came from rural areas, a little over half (or much less than the proportion of farmers among the original population of Pakistan) had found work in agriculture by 1951. On the other hand, a far greater number of refugees had found non-agricultural employment. TABLE 39. PAKISTAN: BREAKDOWN BY r OCCUPATIONAL STATUS OF THE REFUGEE AND LOCAL POPULATIONS (1951) (Percentages) Local population Occupational category Refugees Gainfully occupied : 23.7 6.7 18.0 15.4 Total . . . 30.4 33.4 Self-supporting, not gainfully occupied . 0.6 69.0 0.9 65.7 Over-all total . . . 100.0 100.0 Non-agricultural activities Even allowing for the fact that some of these refugees may still form part of the rural population, this disproportion does suggest that a substantial section of the Moslem refugees from the countryside settled in the towns, causing the same problems as in India. The foregoing gives an idea of the background against which the integration of the refugees had to take place in both countries. In Pakistan, or at least in the western half, in spite of the relatively large number of refugees, the flight of the Hindus, by emptying large areas of good farmland, made the resettlement of the Moslem farmers much easier. In India the refugees were a comparatively much lighter burden, but, being mainly urban in origin, they naturally settled in towns where they only added to the overcrowding of some occupations, particularly in the tertiary sector. 116 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The exchange of population between the two countries caused not only marked changes in the social and occupational structure of each (mainly for the worse), but also capital gains and losses, the net effect of which is hard to judge. The point has already been mentioned with reference to agriculture, but the problem was a good deal wider than this. Generally speaking, few refugees were able to take mobile assets of any great value with them. Those who had money or valuables usually had to leave them behind, hide them or deposit them with banks. The result was that the quantity of capital in the shape of either mobile assets or real estate which the refugees left behind them represented very large sums and their preservation, exchange and compensation faced both governments with a troublesome problem. The authorities agreed to appoint administrators of abandoned property on either side. In 1955, after the failure of the first agreement which had been negotiated in 1950, lists of movable property were officially exchanged between the two governments and transfers from one country to the other began. The fixed assets left behind were used to compensate refugees, either by being distributed amongst them or by being sold for their benefit. This compensation procedure entailed a great deal of work in checking claims and valuing property. From what is known of the economic and social status of the two groups of refugees, the system adopted would appear to have benefited Pakistan, where the property left behind by the Hindus in the form of land, buildings, industrial concerns and businesses was probably worth appreciably more than what the Moslems left behind in India. The benefit derived by Pakistan from these assets seems, however, to have been limited by the shortage of experienced Moslems capable of managing them and by the general disruption of trade. To sum up, there can be no doubt that the influx of refugees imposed a heavy burden on each of the two countries. Large-scale expenditure was needed for relief and resettlement, which might otherwise have been spent on general economic development. The refugees increased the demand for jobs and consumer goods and distorted the social and occupational structure of the population. All these factors plainly helped to worsen the already precarious economic position of the two countries. The only redeeming feature to emerge from this very general analysis is the impulse the refugees gave to planning and development, e.g. through the construction of new towns and related public works, the bringing into cultivation of new land and the introduction of better farming methods, the extension of certain government departments and the improvement of the planning machinery itself. It is likely, however, that even without the influx of uprooted populations, 117 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST demographic pressure alone would in due course have produced the same results. In any case, such benefits as may have accrued from the population shift probably did not offset the cost of repairing the damage which it caused. GOVERNMENT ACTION The two governments helped in the integration of the refugees by providing assistance in a variety of forms. This entailed great expense and required the setting up of special machinery. India Apart from the distribution of relief, the Government of India has since 1948 made a big effort to speed up solution of the problem of integrating and resettling the refugees. This programme, taking the form mainly of rural and urban loans, construction work and school projects, has figured since 1951 in the two five-year plans for 1951-56 and 1956-61. In all, between the financial years 1947/48 and 1957/58 more than 3,000 million rupees were spent by the Government in relieving the refugees and assisting in their integration—1,700 million on refugees from West Pakistan and 1,300 million on those from East Pakistan. The breakdown of these totals by major items of expenditure is shown in table 40. This financial effort, which was very great during the first years of partition and diminished subsequently, was intensified afresh during the first few years of the second plan period. TABLE 40. INDIA : EXPENDITURE BY THE GOVERNMENT ON DISPLACED PERSONS, 1947/48 TO 1957/58 (Millions of rupees) Displaced persons from Item of expenditure Total West Pakistan East Pakistan . . 19.5 801.1 320.7 598.2 4.5 601.3 359.8 303.8 24.0 1,402.4 680.5 902.0 2.5 Total . . . 1,739.5 1,269.4 3,011.5 ' Grants Loans (excluding housing) Housing Miscellaneous Source: Ministry of Rehabilitation (India): Report, ¡957-58, p. 71. 1 Excluding 29 million rupees in Rehabilitation Finance Administration loans during 1955/56, 1956/57 and 1957/58. 118 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The following figures will indicate the scale of the results. By the end of the financial year 1957/58, 568,000 families from West Pakistan and 546,000 from East Pakistan, making 1,114,000 families and over 4 million persons in all, had been resettled on the land thanks to government assistance. At about the same time the number of housing units for refugees erected by the Government or with its financial aid approached 600,000. Furthermore, many small loans (maximum of 5,000 rupees per family) had been allotted to self-employed persons belonging to small-scale commerce, handicrafts and the professions; and a special Rehabilitation Finance Administration under the Ministry of Finance had arranged much larger credits for the re-establishment of large undertakings. Lastly, in education, big subsidies had been paid to schools so that refugee children in need of assistance might be able to attend them; scholarships had been granted to refugee students ; and vocational training centres had been established or adapted for the teaching of certain trades. By 1957 over 100,000 persons had already been through these centres. The determination of the authorities to help to integrate the refugees is also reflected by the preference given to them in the recruitment of civil servants. In the eastern states of India alone, 143,000 displaced persons were employed in provincial and federal services at the beginning of 1958. Lastly, apart from maintaining refugees in camps, where there were still about 300,000 in February 1957 \ the Government bears the cost of temporary and permanent allowances to the needy, the disabled, and widows and orphans. At the end of the first five-year plan period it was possible to consider integration in the western part of the country as almost completed, but it still raised serious problems in the east, where the influx of refugees continued at a high rate after 1951. Accordingly, the second five-year plan provides much larger credits for the integration of refugees from East than from West Pakistan—668 million and 187 million rupees respectively, the total being 855 million. This figure excludes expenditure on the maintenance of refugees; nor does it include 45 million rupees to be distributed among all refugees by the R.F.A. The proposed allocation of these credits is shown in table 41. Lastly, it should be remembered that the Government of India has undertaken to compensate refugees for their loss of capital. By the end of March 1957,172,000 applications for such compensation had been met, 1 See Government of India, Planning Commission : Second Five-Year Plan, pp. 610 ff. ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 119 TABLE 41. INDIA: CREDITS F O R INTEGRATION O F DISPLACED PERSONS U N D E R THE SECOND FIVE-YEAR PLAN (1956-61) (Millions of rupees) Displaced persons from Item of expenditure Total West Pakistan East Pakistan 14.7 1.6 42.5 144.4 57.2 146.0 57.8 48.0 186.8 48.0 244.6 56.2 37.5 56.0 109.6 112.2 147.1 19.2 52.5 28.2 71.7 28.2 187.0 668.0 855.0 Urban loans Rural loans Development of agricultural land Housing Industrial loans, including cottage industries Education Vocational and technical training Medical facilities Total . . . Source: Second Five-Year Plan, op. cit., p. 611. out of a total of 460,000. The expenditure amounted to 537 million rupees. Pakistan Solution of the main problem, that of resettling the displaced rural population, did not cause any serious difficulties, as there was sufficient land available, particularly in West Pakistan. By September 1955, 95 per cent, of some 1.2 million applications for land received in the Punjab had been satisfied; in Baluchistan, allocation of land abandoned by the Hindus had been completed; it was being completed in Sind, and was going forward satisfactorily in East Pakistan. The resettlement of refugees in the cities was a more difficult task, particularly owing to the acute shortage of housing. According to a count made by the Central Rehabilitation Department in 1955, more than half a million persons, very many of them probably refugees, were homeless in the Karachi urban area alone, and having regard to all those who were accommodated by their relatives and friends, the number of ill-housed persons in Karachi probably reached a million. It was therefore necessary to construct a number of housing centres for refugees in the neighbourhood of the city. The Government took the initiative of constructing six such centres (or " townships ") to house 53,500 famiHes 120 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 in all; they had been practically completed by the end of 1955, and extension was being considered. Outside Karachi (where the situation was most serious) the Government had approved the construction of 27 housing centres (known as " satellite towns ") on the outskirts of various cities in West Pakistan, and of buildings inside some of these cities. A similar effort was made in East Pakistan. Altogether, by late 1957 it had been possible to provide satisfactory housing for only 1.4 million displaced persons out of 2.4 million in the cities of West Pakistan, excluding the capital. The situation was even less satisfactory in the Karachi district, and still less so in East Pakistan. Traders and craftsmen were helped to settle by the Pakistan Refugees Rehabilitation Finance Corporation, established in 1948 with a capital of 10 million, subsequently increased to 30 million rupees. This agency has provided loans in money and in kind, drawn up plans for establishment, supplied raw materials at less than market price, organised industrial units under its own direct supervision and provided working and living accommodation for refugee artisans. Other measures taken by the Government included maintenance allowances for middle-class refugees who had lost their property in India and had no livelihood in Pakistan, free medical care for refugees, and scholarships for needy students. Population Movements in the Far East REPATRIATION OF JAPANESE The armistice of August 1945 closed a chapter not only in the political and military, but also in the demographic history of Japan. It gave the signal for the return en masse of Japanese whom 50 years of emigration had scattered all over the Far East. At the end of this movement, which was more or less completed towards the end of 1948, over 6 million persons—about half civilian and half military personnel—had returned and there were practically no Japanese left in the Far East outside the metropolitan islands. Occurring as they did at a time when the Japanese economy was thoroughly disorganised and had to face not only the tasks of reconstruction and reconversion but also a formidable population pressure, these mass repatriations contributed greatly to making Japan's burden in the immediate post-war years well-nigh intolerable. Military and civilian personnel were brought back under different arrangements. The repatriation of the military, decided at the Potsdam 121 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST Conference, was carried out under the supervision of the Allied forces. The return of the civilians, although generally voluntary, had been rendered inevitable by various circumstances—the collapse of government services which had employed many of them and protected the persons and interests of the remainder; disorganisation of the economic system from which they had derived their livelihood; and in many cases the hostility of the local population. Accordingly, the return started very soon after the cessation of hostilities, and was so rapid that by the end of 1946 over 5 million persons had already re-entered Japan. The rate of the movement in subsequent years is given by the following approximate figures (representing thousands of persons). To the end of 1946 . . . . 1947 1948 1949 1950 to 1956 Total . . . 5,096.3 743.8 303.6 97.8 43.7 6,285.3 There is no information on the distribution of these repatriates by age, sex and occupation. The only data available relate to the countries of departure and the civil or military status of the persons concerned. These are reproduced in table 42. TABLE 42. JAPAN: REPATRIATES, BY COUNTRY OF DEPARTURE AND CIVIL OR MILITARY STATUS, 1945-56 (Thousands of persons) Country of departure U.S.S.R Kurile Is. and Sakhilin Manchuria Dairen North Korea South Korea China Hong Kong Formosa South-East Asia Indochina . . . Philippines Islands near Japan Ryu-Kyu Pacific Islands Australian territories New Zealand Total . . . Civilians Military personnel Total 19.2 276.6 1,003.6 215.0 297.2 415.1 488.1 5.1 322.1 56.2 3.5 1.5 24.2 2.4 12.1 27.5 0.3 8.4 0.4 453.8 16.0 41.9 10.9 25.4 181.2 1,043.9 14.3 157.4 655.3 28.7 14.1 108.9 60.0 57.4 103.5 3.3 130.4 0.4 472.9 292.6 1,045.5 226.0 322.6 596.3 1,532.0 19.3 479.5 711.5 32.2 15.6 133.1 62.4 69.4 131.0 3.7 138.8 0.8 3,178.5 3,106.8 6,285.3 122 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The final repatriation figure was thus about 6.3 million or roughly as much as Japan's natural population increase between 1946 and 1950. The movement—which was practically over by the end of 1948—therefore accounted for about half of the enormous over-all increase which took place from 1945 to 1950; between these dates, despite the departure of 1.2 million foreigners, the population of Japan rose from 72 million to 83.2 million. Integration of the repatriates into the economy required government assistance, but this was restricted both by the inadequacy of available resources and by certain political factors. The urgent need for public investment in some sectors of the economy at a time of budgetary stringency prevented large sums from being spent on the material problems of a minority, however considerable; moreover, the Occupation authorities opposed any legislation which would give repatriates a privileged status before the law. However, they permitted certain limited administrative measures in their favour—free transport to the chosen place of residence, grant of a small allowance 1 , provision of clothing and free medical care; they also authorised the Japanese administration to establish guidance services for the repatriates, to issue them with the most necessary household utensils, and even to make loans to them; but on the whole the assistance which the repatriates received formed part of wider schemes applicable to the entire population and including poor relief, improved housing, land settlement and action by the employment services. Nevertheless, in implementing the Government's housing policy, the Ministry of Social Welfare had at its disposal special credits for the construction or conversion of buildings to house repatriates having no relatives in Japan. About 126,600 families benefited by these arrangements between 1945 and 1956. Employment data on the repatriates are very sparse and no general conclusions can be drawn from them. While they were particularly hard-hit by unemployment during the early years, the position appears to have improved substantially in 1952. This, however, was due more to economic recovery, which picked up speed from 1950 onwards, than to any special measures; and there is reason to believe that things improved still further in the most recent period, when the economy has been remarkably dynamic. The relative youth of the repatriates and the high occupational qualifications of many appear to be among the circumstances which facilitated their integration in the economy. However, the administration, which made special voca1 Paid from 1953 onwards at the rate of 10,000 yens per adult and 5,000 yens per child. ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 123 tional guidance arrangements for their benefit and gave them priority in notifying job vacancies, probably contributed a good deal to the solution of this problem. Apart from its achievements in housing, the Ministry of Social Welfare set up a business credit fund which, between 1946 and 1956, made interest-bearing loans in a total amount of 6,356 million yens ; the number of individual loans was 375,000, 60 per cent, of which went to repatriates. These covered businesses of all kinds, particularly in wholesale and retail commerce, followed by industry, services and agriculture. Lastly, the repatriates benefited by an extensive land settlement scheme launched by the Ministry of Agriculture and Forests at the close of the war to make good the shortage in farm output, which had grown alarming since the loss of the overseas territories. Under this scheme, which included loans for installation and for starting operations, priority was given to repatriates in the allocation of land. According to an official statement made in 1957, about 37,000 repatriate families out of a total of 155,000, had been settled on the land under this programme. Despite the results achieved, the repatriates have continued to cause the Government some concern. Their organisations claimed compensation for the property which they had to abandon abroad, and legislative action was taken to give them at least partial satisfaction.1 The repatriates' housing conditions—still substandard on the whole— remain a critical problem, particularly in view of the gradual deterioration of temporary housing put up immediately after the war. Moreover, despite the economic progress of recent years, unemployment still affects a substantial number of the repatriates. Lastly, despite the Government's efforts, those who have gone in for land settlement have a much harder time than the rest of the farming population owing to the comparatively difficult natural surroundings in which they have been resettled. It may be wondered—leaving aside the problem of the repatriates' living conditions and considering only the over-all impact of their return to Japan on the country's post-war economic development— whether the net effect of the migratory influx was really an unfavourable one. Japan, an overpopulated country with a food production deficit and a still unsatisfactory position as regards employment opportunities, undoubtedly suffered from having to spend a large proportion of its meagre national income on the upkeep of 6 million persons who immigrated within a very short time; but in the long run the presence 1 An Act adopted in May 1957 provides for the payment of temporary allowances to the repatriates (or, in case of death, to their beneficiaries) and for the grant of business loans. Statistics published in July 1958 show that 2,363,000 persons were at the time covered by these provisions. 124 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 of this additional population had some favourable effects on development. It provided a stimulus for increasing the output of agricultural goods and exports, and so for the adoption of more productive techniques. It also met a very real need for certain classes of skilled workers. As in the case of Germany, therefore, it appears certain in retrospect that its advantages were sufficient to dispose finally of the view that it was a national catastrophe. REPATRIATES AND REFUGEES IN SOUTH KOREA The decision to re-establish Korean independence, taken at the Cairo Conference in 1943 and confirmed at Potsdam, was implemented by means of a partition into two States—the Republic of Korea, established in August 1948 south of the 38th parallel, and the People's Republic of Korea, proclaimed in the following month to the north of that line. A conflict was to break out between these States two years later, lasting until the summer of 1953. Each of these stages in the recent history of Korea has been marked by a big population movement. Japan's defeat, opening the way to independence, was followed by the mass return of military and civilian personnel who had been scattered over the former Japanese empire, particularly Manchuria, as well as in Japan itself. Soon afterwards, political complications caused emigration from the north of the 38th parallel, which had been the line of demarcation between the Soviet and United States occupation zones before becoming the state border. Lastly, the war considerably amplified the southward movement, which became for a time a mass exodus accompanying the retreat of the South Korean and United Nations armies. The case of Korea, therefore, resembles that of Germany in some ways—the same sharp split between two political units, and the same succession of repatriation and flight from one zone to the other. Statistical information regarding repatriation and the immigration of refugees into South Korea is scanty and unreliable. The periods at which the largest movements took place—the months after Japan's surrender, and the period of the Korean War—were times of chaos. In March 1946 the Commander-in-Chief of the United States Forces in Korea announced that South Korea had taken in 1 million repatriates from Japan and 0.5 million refugees from the north. A count made in October of the same year showed that there were about 1.8 million repatriates and refugees in South Korea. Two years later, the newly established Government of South Korea published a figure of nearly 2.8 million, including ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 125 2.2 million repatriates and about 600,000 refugees. It was stated in 1950 that two-thirds of the repatriates, or about 1.4 million persons, came from Japan: but it is probable that many refugees, if not many repatriates, escaped administrative control altogether; it therefore seems justifiable to estimate the total number of repatriates and refugees up to 1950 at approximately 3 million. There was no check on the arrival of refugees during the Korean War, and none of the attempts made to register them met with any success. Shortly after the war, a count indicated that, in South Korea, among the 2.5 million persons displaced by the military operations there were 840,000 refugees from the north: this, together with the 3 million repatriates and refugees estimated to have been there before the war, and the total number of persons who had settled in South Korea since 1946, raises the total to over 3.8 million. In 1955 the number was estimated at 4 million. Repatriates and refugees thus swelled the population of South Korea by some 25 per cent., as compared with its size in 1945 (probably not exceeding 17 million).1 Repatriation almost entirely cancelled the effect of the considerable emigration which had taken place between 1925 and 1940.2 Together, repatriates and refugees have greatly accentuated the pressure of population on resources in one of the most densely inhabited countries of the world. Moreover, this aggravated pressure came at a time when the division of the country deprived the south of goods produced in the north; it was a big factor in keeping the South Korean economy in a precarious condition, reflected by a persistently adverse trade balance and a recurrent budgetary deficit. Between the end of the war in the Pacific and the beginning of the Korean War, South Korea received considerable aid from the United States: this enabled the country to subsist and contributed indirectly towards moderating the distress of the repatriates and the refugees from the north. The South Korean Ministry of Social Affairs also took some direct action on the immigrants' behalf. However, the results obtained were almost entirely nullified by the Korean War of 1950. In December 1950 the General Assembly of the United Nations adopted a resolution setting up a United Nations Korean Reconstruction Agency. The aid actually given by the United Nations to South Korea through this agency had reached 620 million dollars by 30 June 1957 ; but it was greatly exceeded by direct aid from the Government of the United States, which gave the South Korean Government assistance amounting 1 It was a little over 20 million at the 1949 census. Nearly 3 million Koreans (actually 2.8 million, or 12 per cent, of the total) lived outside Korea in 1940 (1.4 million in Manchuria, 1.2 million in Japan and somewhat less than 200,000 in the Soviet Union). 2 126 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 to almost double the above figure (apart from military aid). However, the enormous sums involved did not prevent the average income per head from falling, between 1949-50 and 1954-55, from 92.4 to 88.1 dollars l as a result of war and demographic pressure. The precarious economic situation of South Korea has of course not facihtated integration of the repatriates and refugees, whose position is still a cause for concern. CHINESE REFUGEES IN HONG KONG AND FORMOSA In the final stages of the Chinese civil war—i.e., the retreat of the Nationalist armies towards the south and finally the transfer of the official seat of government to Formosa—hundreds of thousands of Chinese fled in various directions. Some went to the Portuguese colony of Macao, but the majority went to the Island of Formosa and the British Crown Colony of Hong Kong. In Hong Kong, where the population trebled between the end of 1945 and the middle of 1956, increasing from 900,000 to 2.8 million, immigration from China took on enormous proportions between 1945 and 1949 and was in fact free of all control. However, it is extremely difficult to determine what proportion of the immigrants were actually political refugees: Hong Kong had for a long time been a centre of immigration from China, and the flood of recent arrivals contained an admixture of several classes : refugees in the proper sense of the term, former residents who had left during the Japanese occupation, and workers in search of employment. There are other difficulties, besides that of distinguishing between refugees and other classes of immigrants. The total immigration figure itself can be estimated only by an indirect method, using annual estimates of the population and official statistics of births and deaths. The result of these estimates, for each year, will be found in table 43, but the registration of births during the period was probably somewhat incomplete and this makes the figures less reliable. According to the data reproduced in this table, net immigration between 1 September 1945 and 30 June 1954 amounted to 1.3 million persons. Immigration reached its peak in the immediate post-war years, and remained high until the end of 1949. From 1950 till 1954, on the other hand, emigrants exceeded immigrants by about 220,000. Most of the immigrants in 1945-47 seem to have been former inhabitants of Hong Kong who had been born there or came in before the war; they had fled to escape the Japanese occupation and were now 1 Constant dollars. 127 ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST TABLE 43. HONG KONG: ESTIMATED POPULATION GROWTH FROM 1 SEPTEMBER 1945 TO 30 JUNE 1954 (Thousands of persons) 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 . . . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 Population on 1 January Natural increase Total increase Net immigration 600 J 900 1,400 1,800 2,000 2,300 2,100 2,175 2,250 2,250 _ + 14 +29 + 34 + 38 +42 +48 + 53 + 57 2 +28 + 300 + 500 +400 +200 + 300 -200 + 75 + 75 + 300 +486 + 371 + 166 +262 -242 + 27 + 22 - 57 - 28 2 - — Source: E. HAMBRO: The Problem of Chinese Refugees in Hong Kong, Report Submitted to the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (Leyden, A. W. Sijthoff, 1955). 1 Population on 1 September * First half of year. returning to settle. During 1949 this return current diminished, but the flow of new immigrants, whom the events in China were inducing to leave the Continent, increased. Many of these persons returned to the Continent later when the situation was more normal, i.e. in or after 1950; however, the new arrivals continued (though at a much slower rate), the repatriation movement went on, and a current of re-emigration also developed. It has been estimated that, out of a total net immigration of 1.3 million persons 60 per cent. (800,000) were repatriates and 40 per cent. (500,000) newcomers, of whom at least one-half can be considered as political refugees. To those who left China because of the events there, it is necessary to add those who had migrated from the Continent previously and whom these same events turned into " refugees on the spot ". 1 Most of the persons who left Hong Kong during the period returned to China, but those who did so after 1950 included only a small number of refugees. Of the refugees who remained in Hong Kong after that date 1 The only data available on this subject come from an inquiry carried out by a mission sent to Hong Kong by the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees for an on-the-spot investigation (See E. HAMBRO: The Problem of Chinese Refugees in Hong Kong, Report Submitted to the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (Leyden, A. W. Sijthoff, 1955, Chapter IV). Questions were put to a number of heads of families who had immigrated after the war. Of these, 53.2 per cent, said that they had left China for political reasons, 37.2 per cent, for economic reasons and 8.5 per cent, for both these reasons together; 1.1 per cent, gave no reply. Moreover, 64.1 per cent, of the persons questioned said that for political reasons they would not return to China. On this very approximate basis the refugee population may be estimated at 320,000. The same inquiry revealed, among those who could be classified as refugees by reason of their replies, an abnormally high proportion of adult males, a prevalence of relatively small families and a large majority of persons formerly engaged in non-manual occupations. 128 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the majority were not disposed to return to the Continent; and of those wishing to leave it appears that the great majority were desirous of settling in Formosa, but were prevented from doing so by the unfavourable economic conditions prevailing there. However, 150,000 refugees have been admitted to Formosa since 1949, coming from Macao or Hong Kong, probably mainly the latter. Emigration to other destinations has been small : a few hundred refugees only appear to have taken advantage of the United States Refugee Relief Act 1 , and about 1,000 persons in comfortable circumstances have emigrated to Brazil. Thus the very large majority of those who came to seek refuge in Hong Kong have remained there, although a large number would like to re-emigrate.2 Many have been able to find a place in the local economy, but at the price of change of occupation and often of a pronounced fall in the social scale. Unfortunately no social and economic data concerning the refugees, as distinct from other immigrants, are available. Of the post-war migrants as a whole, very few among those who came from the agricultural sector seem to have remained there; as for those who were employed on professional work, most of them have had to accept manual jobs or become unemployed. This fall in the social scale seems to have occurred mainly among the refugees. It would appear also that those refugees who were previously employed in manual occupations other than agriculture have almost all found jobs, and that the unemployment which still affected some 15 per cent, of the refugees in 1954 was common only among professional persons and farmers. This relatively favourable situation is explained by the speed of post-war industrial development. Consequently, the only serious social problems remain those of refugee farmers (5,000 families were still awaiting land in 1954) and certain classes of non-manual workers whose skills are unlikely to be used. The Hong Kong authorities and some private institutions have made effective efforts to speed up a solution of the refugee problem, although the action taken was more often in the form of aid to needy persons in general than to refugees as such. The population of Formosa, like that of Hong Kong, rose considerably between 1945 and 1954. Of the total increase (from 5.8 million to 8.6 million) probably a quarter was caused by immigrants coming directly or indirectly 3 from continental China after the seat of government was transferred to Formosa. 1 This Act, passed in 1953, provided for the issue of 5,000 non-quota immigrant visas to Asian refugees. 2 3 See HAMBRO, op. cit., Chapters VII to IX. Via Hong Kong or Macao. ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 129 Migration to and from the Island in 1947-53 has resulted in an immigration surplus of 610,000 persons, 72 per cent, of whom—about 445,000—came during 1949 and 1950. In 1954-55, some 30,000 more persons took refuge in Formosa. There should be added a substantial number of refugees from North Korea. The integration of the refugees in the economic life of the Island has been greatly facilitated by the Government and the Free China Relief Association, but little precise information is available on the subject. REFUGEES IN SOUTH VIET-NAM The latest large-scale population movement in the Far East was that from the north to the south of Viet-Nam. As in the case of Korea, this followed a partition, the former associated State of the French Union having been divided into two zones, one north and the other south of the 17th parallel. The Geneva Agreement of 1954, which put an end to the hostilities between France and the Viet-Minh Government of Hanoi, provided for the organised movement of all persons (no numerical limit was laid down) who might express the wish to go from one zone to the other within 300 days. The information available on this movement, and on those which preceded it while hostilities were still under way, is unfortunately very fragmentary: it neither adds up to a precise statistical picture nor gives an idea of the effect of these movements on the South Viet-Nam economy. It is, however, known that during the latter part of 1954 and early in 1955 some 820,000 refugees from North Viet-Nam sought asylum in the south; the final figure probably exceeded 1 million.1 The exodus was organised and assisted by the French and United States authorities, who arranged for the transport of the refugees, gave them individual financial assistance and provided temporary housing. This movement, even more than those which preceded it during the war, caused grave and immediate problems for the Government of South Viet-Nam. The presence of a considerable number of refugees very much aggravated the economic difficulties which had been left by 15 years of war, and were reflected in insufficient production, disorganisation of trade, widespread unemployment, a big adverse trade balance and an equally considerable budgetary deficit. The problem of integrating the refugees in the economy of South Viet-Nam was, however, solved, more easily than might have been 1 The World Almanac, 1957 (New York, the New York World-Telegram, 1957), p. 445. 130 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 imagined, thanks to the big development programme undertaken by the Government : France and the United States made a great contribution to it, and the United Nations—together with several of its specialised agencies, including the I.L.O.—provided technical assistance. The Government also undertook a big construction programme, mainly in the rural areas, in order to meet the refugees' need for housing. Thus by 1957 the whole refugee population, though still not completely integrated under what could be described as fully satisfactory conditions, was at least assimilated into the general population at levels of employment and productivity roughly equal to the prevailing standards —i.e. still rather low. Fishing, forestry, handicrafts and agriculture absorbed the greater part. Bibliographical References General : Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East (published annually). J. B. SCHECHTMAN : Population Transfers in Asia (New York, Hallsby Press, 1949). J. VERNANT: The Refugee in the Post-War World (London, George Allen & Unwin, Ltd., 1953). UNITED NATIONS Works Dealing with Arab Refugees in Palestine : Annual reports of the Director of the United Nations Relief and Works Agency for Palestine Refugees in the Near East (1951 to 1957). (General Assembly Official Records.) MINISTRY FOR FOREIGN AFFAIRS (ISRAEL) : The Arabs in Israel (Jerusalem, 1958.) S. G. THICKNESSE: Arab Refugees: A Survey of Resettlement Possibilities (London, Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1949). J. B. SCHECHTMAN : The Arab Refugee Problem (New York, Philosophical Library, 1952). W. DE SAINT-AUBIN : " Peace and Refugees in the Middle East ", in The Middle East Journal (Washington, D.C., The Middle East Institute), Vol. 3, No. 3, July 1949, p. 249. " The Arab Refugees, 1952 ", in The Economist (London), Vol. CLXII, 5 Jan. 1952, p. 28. Works Dealing with Population Shifts in India, Pakistan and the Far East UNITED NATIONS : Annual reports of the Agent General of the United Nations Korean Reconstruction Agency (General Assembly Official Records). — Chinese Refugees in Hong Kong (Submitted by the High Commissioner for Refugees to the UNREF Executive Committee at its Fourth Session), Document A/AC.79/47, 10 Dec. 1956 (mimeographed). UNITED NATIONS ASIA AND THE MIDDLE EAST 131 E. I. HAMBRO: The Problem of Chinese Refugees in Hong Kong, Report Submitted to the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (Leyden, A. W. Sijthoff, 1955). " Rehabilitation of Displaced Persons in India ", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LVIII, No. 2, Aug. 1948, pp. 187-198. " Rehabilitation and Resettlement of Displaced Persons in the Indian Union ", ibid., Vol. LXI, No. 4, Apr. 1950, pp. 410-426. " Resettlement and Rehabilitation of Displaced Persons in Pakistan ", ibid., Vol. LXV, No. 3, Mar. 1952, pp. 379-385. MINISTRY OF REHABILITATION (INDIA): Annual reports. — Rehabilitation Retrospect (May 1957). PLANNING COMMISSION (INDIA): Second Five-Year Plan (New Delhi, 1956). Kingsley DAVIS: The Population of India and Pakistan (Princeton University Press, 1951). Pakistan Today and Tomorrow (Karachi, Pakistan Publications, 1951). Pakistan, 1955-1956 (Karachi, Pakistan Publications, 1956). Republic of Korea Statistical Summation (monthly), No. 16, Apr. 1950 (mimeographed). Monthly Civil Affairs Summary for Korea (Seoul, Korea Civil Assistance Command), Jan. and Feb. 1954 (mimeographed). PART TWO ECONOMIC MIGRATION SECTION A MAJOR POST-WAR CURRENTS Before proceeding to describe the economic migration currents which have taken place since the Second World War a few preliminary remarks concerning available sources of information and the use made of them are in order. 1 For one thing, statistical material on the subject is highly unsatisfactory, since it is both incomplete and heterogeneous. This is partly due to the theoretical difficulty of compiling adequate statistics and also to the fact that government departments often do not keep the necessary check on movements. The theoretical problem arises out of the complexity and relative vagueness of the concept of " migrant ". If a migrant is defined as " a person travelling internationally with a view to taking up a civilian job for a certain time in a country other than his usual country of residence (migrant worker) or with the intention of settling down there for a considerable time without any immediate intention of working (nonworking migrant) ", the definition is not precise enough to allow of the establishment of practical, i.e. uniform, simple and clear-cut statistical criteria. On the other hand, any attempt at greater precision would necessarily lead to definitions covering only part of the subject, with the result that the compilation of satisfactory, i.e. both detailed and complete migration statistics would have to involve the collection of elaborate data based on many different criteria. The fact is, however, that countries sacrifice such theoretical needs to considerations of usefulness. They keep only minimum records and in determining the numbers involved in particular movements arbitrarily choose their criteria on grounds of sheer practicality. As a result there are considerable gaps and a general lack of comparability between the figures, all of which correspond to different definitions. In these circumstances it is obviously impossible to draw up a comprehensive, accurate and uniform balance sheet of international migration over the last 12 years. A more or less approximate reckoning is all that can be made on the basis not only of migration statistics proper, but also of figures not specifically collected for the purpose, such as statistics of voyagers or passengers, statistics of work or residence permits and 1 See also United Nations : Problems of Migration Statistics, United Nations Demographic Studies, No. 5 (New York, 1949). 136 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 possibly even census returns. The description in the following two chapters is therefore not designed to provide a mere inventory of current statistics but rather a selective and critical analysis of all existing numerical data relating directly or indirectly to migration, with a view to extracting from them as accurate a knowledge as possible of the essential facts. It should also be pointed out that for the purposes of this description the expression " international migrants " has been used in the widest sense, so as to include in particular people migrating between a metropolitan country and its non-metropolitan territories. However, it was not thought proper to include such movements as those between France and its Algerian or overseas departments or between the United States and the non-continental parts of its territory, as these constitute internal movements from the legal point of view. It should be added that the division between continental and intercontinental movements, dealt with respectively in Chapters V and VI, is not one of mere convenience. The two types of movement exhibit a number of basic differences and are not always covered by the same statistics. In particular, the distances in the case of continental migration are generally shorter, and as a result even the longer-term movements which they include are often of a temporary nature by comparison with intercontinental ones. * * * CHAPTER V CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS The lack of adequate statistics is particularly noticeable in the case of movements taking place within the same continent. The fact that most of them are over land frontiers and for varying periods of time, ranging from daily commuting to more or less permanent migration, makes it very difficult to keep track of each one of them. Since, moreover, the vast majority of countries do not carry out the checks that would be necessary for this purpose, figures not compiled specifically for migration records—statistics of arrivals and departures of travellers, counts of the foreign population and statistics of residence or work permits—often have to be used, and since such figures do not always exist, there are movements in respect of which no numerical data are available at all. In spite of these shortcomings an attempt has been made in this chapter to separate, whenever possible, the various classes of movements according to their duration. In accordance with United Nations standards the demarcation line between permanent and temporary, migration has been drawn at one year of residence.1 An attempt has also been made to assess the extent of frontier movements, but it has rarely been possible to do so with sufficient accuracy, particularly in areas outside Europe and North America for which the information available is not always sufficient even for rough estimates. Europe Europe has been covered by a multitude of migratory cross-currents, of which the most important converged on five countries—Sweden, the United Kingdom, Belgium, France and Switzerland—and branched out from those countries in the form of return movements. In Sweden most of the immigrants came from neighbouring countries ; in the United Kingdom they came from Ireland and indirectly from eastern Europe, and in Belgium, France and Switzerland they came from Italy. The remaining currents were of very minor importance. 1 See paragraph 17 of the recommendations for the improvement of international migration statistics adopted by the United Nations Population and Statistical Commissions (United Nations: International Migration Statistics, Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 20 (New York, 1953), p. 17). 138 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 SWEDEN Over the years 1946-57 as a whole, immigrants to Sweden from other European countries numbered a little more than 310,000 and emigrants to those countries a little over 100,000. Migration to and from other parts of Europe therefore showed a net immigration gain of 210,000. Details by year and by country of origin and of destination are given in table 44. Throughout the period immigration continued at a steady rate, which did, however, slow down on two occasions—in 1949 and again in 1952-54. These two falls are visible from the gross, and even more so from the net, immigration figures. About two-thirds of the total gross immigration (63.4 per cent.) came from the other three Scandinavian countries, with Finland alone accounting for more than one-third (33.7 per cent.) Movements in the reverse direction were relatively numerous towards Denmark and Norway, so that the three Scandinavian countries account for 59.8 per cent, of total net immigration. Sweden also exerted quite a strong attraction on Germans (15.4 per cent, of the gross immigration figure and 16.5 per cent, of net immigration). The rest of the immigration movement involved refugees from the Baltic States and Poland and much smaller numbers of Austrians and Italians. TABLE 44. SWEDEN: MIGRATION TO AND FROM THE REST OF EUROPE, BY COUNTRIES OF ORIGIN AND DESTINATION, 1946-57 (In thousands) Denmark Year . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.7 6.1 6.8 4.9 4.0 4.7 4.1 2.6 2.8 5.6 6.6 5.6 Total 57.5 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1 Immigration And Iceland. 1 Finland Germany Norway Emi- Imgra- migration tion EmiImgra- migration tion Emi- Imgra- migration tion 2.0 1.5 1.9 2.9 2.7 2.4 2.6 3.0 2.4 2.0 2.2 2.4 4.0 6.6 8.9 6.4 11.9 12.8 8.2 6.8 8.4 11.3 9.1 11.0 0.3 0.4 0.6 1.0 1.2 2.0 3.7 3.9 3.0 2.8 3.4 2.7 2.0 3.0 3.6 3.3 4.1 6.1 6.6 3.9 3.5 4.6 4.1 3.4 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.6 1.1 2.0 1.9 2.0 2.2 2.2 3.6 4.2 4.2 3.9 3.2 3.2 2.3 1.9 1.8 2.4 2.3 2.3 1.9 1.2 1.1 1.4 1.7 1.6 1.9 2.1 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.4 28.0 105.4 25.1 48.2 13.3 35.2 18.7 Other countries * Emi- Imgra- migration tion Total Emi- Imgra- migration tion Emigration 16.2 9.7 7.9 3.7 2.8 2.9 3.1 2.0 2.1 3.9 3.7 8.3 0.7 0.7 1.0 1.3 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.8 1.5 1.5 1.8 1.8 5.1 3.9 4.8 7.0 7.5 7.9 10.6 12.8 10.3 9.7 11.0 10.7 66.2 16.1 * Mainly the Baltic States and Poland (1946-49), Austria and Italy. 29.5 29.6 31.4 22.2 26.0 29.6 24.3 17.1 18.6 27.8 25.8 30.7 312.5 101.3 139 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS The Swedish statistics seem to give quite a faithful picture of the situation, at least as regards the balance of arrivals and departures. 1 The fact that they draw no distinction between Swedish nationals and aliens, however, gives rise to a certain amount of uncertainty regarding the nature of the emigration towards other Scandinavian countries, in which there is a mixture of returnees and emigrating Swedish nationals. Moreover, the Swedish statistics are drawn up in such a way that they give no indication of the length of the migrants' stay, although it does seem that a large number of the migrants were temporary entrants from the other Scandinavian countries. UNITED KINGDOM The United Kingdom does not compile statistics of migration to and from the Continent. There is available, however, some information collected for other purposes which gives a rough idea of the inflow of migrants from other European countries and of the numbers returning to those countries. First of all, there are statistics of arrivals and departures of aliens compiled by the Home Office, which give the net migration figures for non-British nationals. As regards nationals of European countries, there was a net immigration of some 245,000 persons over the 1946-57 period. Details by year and by nationality are given in table 45. This total figure calls for a few comments. Not only does it not take into account the movement of Irish citizens, who are not regarded as aliens in the compilation of these statistics, but it does not include, at any rate among the arrivals, either the 95,000-odd demobilised Polish armed services personnel and their dependants who have settled in the United Kingdom under the auspices of the Polish Resettlement Corps since May 1946, or the 25,000 German, Italian and Ukrainian prisoners of 1 For the period 1 April 1948 to 1 April 1957 this can be checked by a rough calculation based on the estimated foreign population on each of these two dates and on the number of naturalisations which took place in the meantime. The details of the calculation are as follows : Foreign population at 1 April 1957 „ 1 April 1948 250,000 -146,300 Difference Naturalisations, 1948-56 103,700 +53.700 Total increase in the foreign population, 1948-56 157,400 During the same period net immigration from Europe involved a total of 141,200 persons. The gap between the two figures is easily explained partly by the natural increase in the foreign population and partly by the fact that the second figure allows for the net emigration of Swedish nationals. 140 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 45. UNITED KINGDOM: NET IMMIGRATION OF NATIONALS OF EUROPEAN COUNTRIES 1 , BY NATIONALITY, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Baits and Finns Germans 1.0 21.2 5.4 -0.5 -0.4 -1.9 -2.5 -0.6 -0.5 0.2 -0.1 — Total . . . 20.9 Italians Poles Miscellaneous ' Total 21.5 60.6 57.9 19.6 14.2 1.7 -5.9 6.0 10.2 16.3 29.0 15.4 246.5 -0.1 5.6 1.8 15.3 7.9 2.2 0.5 1.0 1.6 2.0 1.8 3.9 0.8 2.9 3.6 3.8 4.3 7.3 2.3 2.9 4.9 8.5 8.9 6.8 11.9 8.4 24.1 -4.6 -8.1 -4.2 -1.1 -0.7 0.1 -0.1 1.4 7.9 22.5 23.0 5.6 2.4 2.2 -2.0 3.8 4.9 5.5 18.5 3.2 43.5 57.0 27.1 97.5 _ 1 Excluding passengers of doubtful nationality, for whom the net figures are negligible. * Refugees who came from various countries of eastern Europe, mostly between 1946 and 1948, and from Hungary, mostly in 1956. The other national groups with relatively high net immigration figures are the Austrians, the French, the Greeks and the Norwegians. war who chose to remain in the United Kingdom after their release. Both these groups should be included in the civilian immigration data for 1946. For the years 1946 to 1957 this would give a net immigration figure of some 365,000 for nationals of European countries, the vast majority having arrived during the immediate post-war years and well over half of them being refugees from eastern Europe. Apart from the Polish armed services personnel and the prisoners of war the bulk of the immigrants consisted either of workers recruited in groups under official schemes or of workers admitted to the country under individual employment permits, together with dependants in each case. With regard to these admissions there are figures issued by the Ministry of Labour and National Service and others obtained from the Home Office which are given in table 46. They show that at least 470,000 nationals of European countries were admitted to the United Kingdom between 1946 and 1957 under one or the other of the two procedures.1 This figure includes dependants, of whom there were very few in either case. On the assumption that the number of people who immigrated under other arrangements was negligible the net immigration figure was 225,000 lower than the gross figure. The explanation lies partly in the emigration of many 1 This is certainly a minimum figure, since it does not include persons of doubtful nationality, a majority of whom must nevertheless have been Europeans. 141 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 46. UNITED KINGDOM: EUROPEAN WORKERS ADMITTED UNDER GROUP RECRUITMENT SCHEMES OR INDIVIDUAL PERMITS, 1946-57 (In thousands) Germans Italians persons G.R.* LP. 3 G.R.* i.p. 3 G.R.2 LP.' laneous * Total Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total4. . . — — — — — — — 1.0 6.4 9.3 10.7 6.5 6.3 7.5 8.2 9.4 9.3 0.3 1.9 34.3 2.9 37.0 4.1 1.8 5.8 0.8 7.7 — 3.2 — 4.1 — 5.6 — 8.5 — 11.1 — 8.5 — — — — — — — — — — — — 9.9 74.6 17.4 62.7 73.9 — — 2.1 5.9 1.9 — 0.3 0.1 0.2 1.4 4.8 2.6 1.0 1.3 2.3 2.1 1.3 G.R.» LP. 3 G.R. ! LP." 1.2 6.2 20.5 20.6 22.9 23.0 24.1 15.6 16.3 19.3 19.8 21.3 20.2 1.2 34.6 40.0 8.8 4.7 4.8 2.6 1.0 1.3 2.3 2.1 1.3 6.5 22.4 24.5 33.4 38.1 42.5 25.3 26.7 32.4 36.5 40.8 38.0 — 0.8 0.9 0.6 — — — — — — — 3.5 229.8 104.7 367.1 Source : For workers recruited in groups, statistics published by the Ministry of Labour and National Service; and for workers under individual employment permits and for their dependants, statistics compiled by the Home Office. Since 1952 the Home Office statistics also cover workers recruited collectively and their dependants. The number of workers admitted under individual permits during these years has therefore been obtained by making the necessary adjustments in the latter figures. 1 Mainly from Switzerland (49.5), France (38.6), the Netherlands (26.5), Austria (20.5) and Den2 3 mark (18.8). Group recruitment. Individual permits. * Does not include persons of doubtful nationality. Poles and displaced persons to various overseas countries and partly in the fact that a large proportion of the immigrants admitted under individual employment permits remain in the United Kingdom for only a short time. The figures for Irish immigration can be obtained from two sources: the statistics compiled by the Ministry of Labour and National Service, covering Irish workers recruited under its responsibility, and the Board of Trade statistics, which show the annual balance of arrivals and departures by sea and air between Ireland and Great Britain. The first of these series covers too small a proportion of total movements to be worth reproducing. The second gives what may be regarded as a plausible account of net movements, although it does not allow for overland migration between the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland. According to this series net Irish immigration to Great Britain involved some 320,000 people from 1946 to 1957. The details are given in table 47. 142 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 47. UNITED KINGDOM: ARRIVALS FROM AND DEPARTURES TO THE REPUBLIC OF IRELAND, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . Arrivals Departures Net immigration 431 490 625 730 747 781 827 799 821 888 971 991 426 472 603 714 735 764 797 771 788 844 929 940 5 18 22 16 12 17 30 28 33 44 42 51 9,101 8,783 318 Source : Passenger movement and migration from and to the United Kingdom, published yearly in the Board of Trade Journal (London, Board of Trade). The figures show also that Irish immigrants were much more numerous in the second half of the period than in the first. No conclusion can be reached, however, regarding the relative importance of permanent and temporary movements, particularly seasonal ones. To sum up, net immigration to the United Kingdom from other European countries from 1946 to 1957 would seem to have considerably exceeded the 600,000 mark. There were, of course, ups and downs: while in the immediate post-war years the number of immigrants was very high, consisting chiefly of nationals of eastern European countries, it subsequently fell a great deal. At the same time, the proportion of immigrants from the Continent fell off as compared with that of Irish immigrants, which increased almost continuously from 1950 to 1957. Since 1953, however, immigration from the Continent has increased again, with the result that the total net immigration balance has risen rapidly over the last few years. BELGIUM Only from 1948 onwards do post-war Belgian migration statistics include a breakdown by country of origin and of destination. Details of the movement of foreign nationals between Belgium and the rest of Europe by year and by country from 1948 to 1957 are given in table 48. 143 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS Ii 1 fi II co tu 4 D O U z < « ! f» H O S ood < «n g ' S3 CO * -C Z -í < o z o oí o II 1 O 1- ¥ P ¥ i ! ¥ o -J « ON m (N q^N^DO;0^;0\oon <N ^ ' Ö (N en —' m' — OÍ ON" y i <o TJ- n n f<î m' TJ- <o h-' !• a H n ONCioocnr^^qi--<N«Tj(N \o Tf - ^ - ^ ir> v i oo r i \o ID 0O oá ¡=> tu oí tu O m T Í d n ^ i r i -¡ O Ò « en ri vi O o> ostsooooooppOOoo r i r i -H" ^-* ^ r i r i r i r i -H' en r- ^o r^ r ï o\ ^o w^ ON ^ Fen rs r i r î n r i f*î M' r> ffi m ri en ^ *-¡ r i ON v-¡ p o> ^q ON \O m* vî ^-' Ö r i r i Ö ON oo oo 00 ri 0\i-* O N - ^ ^ O f ^ ^ O O O O O O GÔON^OodoÔTtONrioNo ^ riN-H (N •— r i oo h V Î r j r^ \ o q q --; « H ri r i r i ri ^ r i ri ri ri r i o r^ n vo 0\ ^ o> 0 \ ^ oo N r^ r i i-i « r i r i r i en r i en in oo" ri n d en p en oo y-t¡ p os ON r^ (N o> ON v i en en en r i r i r i en r i oo i— r J p r-; v-j Tt oo O ON ooTfTrin-^^-^Tt«^«^ oo oo en •n 03 _ O 03 < H s >• oo ON © — (N m TJ- V I \ o rTt-Tj-v»invjvìv>v>viin ONO\ONO\ONONONO\ONO\ 144 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Between 1948 and 1957 total gross immigration to Belgium from other European countries involved over 420,000 persons. However, movements in the reverse direction were also considerable and left a net immigration balance of only about 185,000 persons. Over half the immigrants (51.7 per cent.) came from Italy, and Italians also accounted for nearly three-fifths (57.3 per cent.) of the total net immigration. The other major currents originated in France, Germany and the Netherlands. Immigration of refugees from eastern Europe was still sizeable in 1948 but fell to a very low level thereafter. A current of Greek immigration became apparent after 1955 and a current of Spanish immigration has become manifest even more recently. For the years 1946 and 1947 only Italian and I.R.O. statistics are available. The former set total net emigration to Belgium over the two years at 45,000 persons \ and the latter disclose that some 16,000 displaced persons were resettled by the I.R.O. in Belgium in the second half of 1947.2 European migration to Belgium since 1946 has been characterised by marked ups and downs. It first showed a rise in the immediate post-war years, reaching a peak in 1947-48. Subsequent highs occurred again on two occasions, in 1951-52 and in 1955-56. Between these three peaks there were two troughs in 1949-50 and 1953-54 respectively, the former being much lower than the latter. The interpretation of Belgian statistics, however, is rendered very difficult by the fact that they probably include a very large number of temporary, and in some cases non-migratory, movements. This helps to explain the rather large difference between the gross and net immigration figures ; another reason is the instability of foreign labour (particularly Italians) recruited for work in mines. A comparison of the results of the census taken on 31 December 1947 and of the count of aliens made on 1 November 1954 even suggests that the records of departures are probably defective and that net immigration of aliens to Belgium from the rest of Europe was actually much lower than the figure given by the migration statistics. Such a comparison discloses an increase of only about 12,000 persons in the foreign population 3 and a fall in the numbers of all the major nationalities other than Italians. 4 In the case of the latter, 1 Notiziario dell'emigrazione (Rome, Ministero degli Affari Esteri), Ninth Year, No. 5, May 1955, p. 584. 2 I.R.O.: Statistical Report (Geneva, 1951). 8 Even if allowance is made for the fact that movements of aliens to and from other continents showed a net emigration surplus of some 20,000 during the same period, this gives a net European immigration figure of only 32,000—still far removed from the 105,000 given by the migration statistics. 4 Annuaire statistique de la Belgique et du Congo belge (Brussels, Ministère des Affaires économiques, Institut national de statistique), Vol. 78, 1957, p. 42. 145 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS the Italian statistics show an even larger figure for net emigration to Belgium from 1948 to 1957 than the Belgian statistics.1 FRANCE The French immigration statistics relate exclusively to workers brought into the country by the National Immigration Office as either permanent or seasonal workers under the statutory monopoly in regard to recruitment conferred on that body, and to dependants of permanent workers who accompany or join them in accordance with official procedure. These statistics are reproduced in tables 49 and 50. In addition to permanent and seasonal movements there were large frontier movements from Belgium which involved an average of 40,000 to 50,000 people during the period under review.2 Permanent gross immigration for the years 1946-57 as a whole therefore amounted to over 600,000 people. In addition, there were a number of German war prisoners who, after their release, were kept on in France as free workers; of these some 40,000 chose to remain permanently when their contracts expired and should be added to the 1947 1 The detailed figures are as follows : Immigration to Belgium Emigration from Belgium Year 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 1 Belgian figures Italian figures 1 46.4 5.3 4.2 33.3 22.4 8.8 3.3 17.1 10.4 10.6 13.1 15.1 11.2 10.9 12.5 12.0 10.9 9.6 8.9 8.6 16.0 10.4 4.0 9.4 3.3 0.6 0.1 1.2 1.2 1.0 161.8 112.9 47.3 Belgian figures Italian figures 48.9 9.1 6.9 38.1 28.6 14.3 9.5 22.8 19.8 20.8 218.9 l Figures from Notiziario dell'emigrazione, op. cit. The discrepancies between the two series are very marked, the figure for net immigration to Belgium being higher by about 10,000 according to the Italian statistics. They are due to differences in the definition of emigration and immigration in the two countries. However, the number of emigrants returning to Italy as given by the Italian statistics is probably too low. 2 According to information collected in Belgium (and published in the Annuaire statistique de la Belgique et du Congo belge) the position as regards the number of frontier workers employed in France developed as follows (in thousands): On On On On 30 April 1946 31 March 1948 15 May 1952 15 October 1955 42.1 54.9 42.7 48.4 146 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 49. FRANCE : PERMANENT IMMIGRATION OF WORKERS AND THEIR FAMILIES, BY NATIONALITY, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 3 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1°54 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 1 MiscelSpaniards Displaced persons 1 laneous * Germans Italians 3.7 21.8 16.4 2.8 1.6 1.5 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.7 1.0 28.0 53.1 38.7 47.9 11.2 19.3 32.5 14.3 11.2 17.7 57.4 87.1 0.8 1.6 2.6 2.1 2.6 9.4 24.5 418.4 47.0 51.1 1.3 1.7 0.3 —. — 1.4 3.5 3.6] 1.9 3.8 4.3 3.4 2.1 2.2 2.8 3.9 8.0 7.4 17.5 19.2 1.5 0.2 0.2 0.3 — — — — 46.3 41.1 Total 30.7 69.5 81.9 85.5 19.2 26.2 39.2 20.0 16.2 23.6 71.3 120.5 603.9 8 Mainly from Poland and Hungary. Including Spanish workers for 1949-50 and dependants of Spanish workers for 1947-52. The other nationalities with the3 largest representation were thePortuguese (about 10,000, mostly in 1956-57) and the Moroccans. Second half. TABLE 50. FRANCE: SEASONAL IMMIGRATION, BY COUNTRY OF ORIGIN, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Belgians Italians 10.9 17.5 20.2 15.9 11.1 12.4 15.5 13.2 12.0 9.6 9.6 8.5 0.7 2.0 1.6 4.1 4.8 13.3 18.3 19.5 16.7 22.8 30.2 33.4 Spaniards — — — — — — — 1.1 2.9 8.9 15.1 Total 11.5 19.4 21.8 19.9 15.9 25.7 33.8 32.7 29.9 35.3 48.7 57.1 immigration figure. Thus the actual total came to something like 650,000 persons, of whom approximately two-thirds came from Italy, 14 per cent, (prisoners of war and official immigrants) from Germany, 7 per cent, from eastern Europe (displaced persons in 1948-50) and another 7 per cent, from Spain, mostly over the last few years. The official figures, however, do not cover all the recent immigration. They exclude not only self-employed workers and their families, whose entry into France is not supervised by the National Immigration Office, and workers' families which did not make use of the facilities provided 147 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS by the Office, but also illegal immigration in the first few months of 1946, the refugees who were given asylum, and all the aliens who settled in France as ordinary residents. In view of all these omissions from the statistics, total European immigration to France for the years 1946-57 may be reasonably estimated at not less than 700,000 people, of whom about one-half entered the country during the four-year period extending from 1946 to 1949. After the summer of 1949 there was a sharp drop, and no marked rise occurred until 1956, the peak for the whole period being reached in 1957. There is unfortunately no information from French sources concerning persons who, having originally entered as permanent immigrants, subsequently re-emigrated. However, by comparing the census returns of 10 March 1946 and 10 May 1954, an attempt can be made to estimate roughly the net balance of immigration from the rest of Europe between the two dates. The balance does not seem to have exceeded 250,000, as compared with a gross immigration figure probably well in excess of 450,00o.1 The explanation lies in the fact that many immigrants returned to their countries of origin. This is true chiefly of Germans, but also of Italians.2 Moreover, some 70,000 Poles and Yugoslavs who had immigrated before the war returned to their homelands in 1947-48, and many refugees emigrated overseas. In view of the movements which have occurred since May 1954, the net European immigration figure for the entire period probably lies somewhere between 400,000 and 450,000. x In 1946 the census return for the foreign population of European origin in France was 1,610,000 persons. The figure was only 1,455,000 in 1954, so that there had been a fall of about 150,000. In the meantime about 350,000 foreigners of European origin acquired French nationality while some 50,000 foreigners, most of whom were probably of European origin, emigrated to countries outside Europe. The net movement between France and the other European countries would therefore seem to have involved about 250,000 people. The two census returns on which this calculation is based are not, however, strictly comparable; nor has the natural increase— admittedly not considerable—been taken into account. 2 The Italian statistics for 1946-57 show the following movements to and from France (in thousands): Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Emigration Immigration 28.1 50.0 38.7 49.0 13.3 21.8 0.1 8.9 1.6 2.4 1.7 3.4 Year 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Emigration Immigration 35.5 17.2 13.1 17.9 57.5 87.1 4.2 4.4 4.7 0.9 2.6 13.8 The Italian emigration statistics agree roughly with the French immigration data, although they show a somewhat higher gross emigration figure (about 430,000). As regards net emigration, it totalled 380,000 according to the Italian statistics. This figure seems excessive, owing no doubt to an under-estimation of the number of returns. 148 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 As for seasonal movements, they increased greatly during the second half of the period, when they were more than twice as numerous as they had been in the first half. This increase was accompanied by a gradual substitution of Italians for Belgians. Spaniards also began to enter in large numbers from 1956 onwards. SWITZERLAND The statistics published by the Swiss Government do not really permit of a complete analysis of recent immigration since there are only two sources, namely statistics of residence permits issued to foreign workers for the first time and the count of foreigners subject to employment restrictions which is carried out in February each year. These two series are reproduced in tables 51 and 52. These statistics relate only to workers, who constituted an overwhelming majority, though not the totality, of the immigrants. Subject to this reservation, they are a source of useful information. The first series gives gross immigration figures, broken down both by types of immigration and by major nationalities. Permanent immigraTABLE 51 : SWITZERLAND : RESIDENCE PERMITS ISSUED FOR THE FIRST TIME TO FOREIGNERS AUTHORISED TO TAKE UP EMPLOYMENT, BY TYPE OF PERMIT AND NATIONALITY, 1946-57 (In thousands) Nationality 1 Type of permit Permanent Seasonal workers workers 2 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . Frontier workers * Total Austrian French German Italian 6.3 39.4 5.7 27.6 31.6 62.9 66.5 66.7 73.0 87.3 104.2 119.2 34.3 95.6 107.7 47.4 31.6 50.0 63.5 72.0 81.1 98.4 123.8 136.3 8.0 14.5 16.0 11.0 12.0 23.9 19.8 23.6 27.5 35.1 41.4 42.7 48.6 149.5 129.4 86.1 75.2 136.8 149.8 162.3 181.6 220.9 269.4 298.3 2.7 9.5 9.6 11.6 20.1 21.7 25.5 26.7 24.0 22.8 22.4 8.5 9.8 8.2 5.0 6.1 5.8 6.6 6.2 7.1 7.3 7.0 5.9 8.5 8.2 10.1 25.6 28.0 32.9 40.1 49.4 57.4 59.2 126.6 95.3 55.9 46.0 82.1 91.1 93.8 105.1 135.9 176.3 204.0 690.4 941.7 275.5 1,907.8 196.6 77.6 325.3 1,212.1 Source: Annuaire statistique de la Suisse (Berne, Bureau fédéral de statistique) and I.L.O. information. 1 a Main nationalities only. The figures for the years 1946-48 also include permits for longer periods issued to agricultural workers, domestic servants and the lower grades of personnel in the hotel and catering trades. 149 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 52. SWITZERLAND : FOREIGN WORKERS SUBJECT TO EMPLOYMENT RESTRICTIONS, BY NATIONALITY, 1949-58 > (In thousands) Nationality Austrian French German Italian Other Total . . . Frontier workers incl. in above figures . 1957 1949' 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 — 11.8 6.7 12.9 54.0 4.7 15.7 6.3 15.6 53.6 4.4 22.4 6.9 28.1 70.2 4.8 24.7 6.2 32.4 71.4 4.7 28.9 6.5 38.6 71.3 4.7 30.9 7.0 45.3 77.9 5.1 30.4 31.1 31.0 8.6 7.7 8.5 56.0 64.2 71.5 94.8 126.1 142.2 5.7 7.1 8.3 106.1 90.1 95.4 11.6 8.5 10.0 1958 132.3 139.4 150.0 166.2 194.6 237.0 261.6 16.6 15.9 18.5 22.8 28.5 32.9 Source : Annuaire statistique de la Suisse, op. cit. 1 Position in February each year. ' Breakdown by nationality not available. tion, which provided some 690,000 workers over the whole period, rose steadily from 1949 onwards and had increased fourfold by 1957. Seasonal immigration also increased considerably after that date since the number of people involved was three times as large in 1957 as it had been in 1949, while frontier movements increased roughly to the same extent. However, previous to 1949, immigration had already reached a 1947-48 peak in Switzerland as elsewhere. The subsequent decline extended into 1950 but was followed thereafter by a rapid and almost continuous rise. Tables 51 and 52 also bring out the very great preponderance of Italians among the immigrants. However, the number of Austrians and Germans increased greatly in the second half of the period, at any rate among non-seasonal immigrants, since Italy continued to supply almost all seasonal workers. Immigration of labour to Switzerland in the post-war period was therefore considerable; yet—and even though there were also other, minor immigration currents—the net immigration figure for aliens of European origin does not seem to have exceeded 250,000 for the whole of the 1946-57 period.1 This figure, of course, includes neither frontier nor seasonal workers. The reason is that even foreigners admitted as permanent immigrants, particularly Italian workers, are very unstable, owing to the types of occupations in which they are employed and the high proportion of women workers. 1 From 1941 to 1957 the foreign population, though reduced by some 55,000 as a result of naturalisations, showed a net increase of some 200,000 persons, 135,000 of them since 1950. The balance of the increase seems to have been largely, if not wholly, due to immigration between 1946 and 1950. 36.4 150 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 OTHER COUNTRIES By comparison with those discussed above, other migratory movements within Europe were much smaller. Western Germany only began to attract immigrants in substantial numbers, particularly from Italy and from Austria, in 1956. Until then immigration had been confined to a relatively small inflow from Austria, consisting largely of persons of German ethnic origin who chose to settle permanently in Germany. The Netherlands were another minor centre of attraction, particularly over the last few years when the numbers of foreign workers employed rose rapidly. This increase was due partly to permanent immigration from Belgium, Germany and Italy and partly to the emergence of frontier movements from the first two countries. Movements involving quite large numbers also occurred in the form of frontier, permanent and, above all, seasonal migration between Belgium, Germany and mainly Italy on the one hand and Luxembourg on the other. These movements have also increased considerably over the last few years. In northern Europe Norway has attracted Danes and Denmark has attracted Germans, especially frontier workers. In eastern Europe Czechoslovakia brought in about 10,000 Bulgarians in the immediate post-war years, as well as a small number of Rumanians and Italians. These movements ceased in 1948, and by now most of the immigrants seem to have returned to their own countries. Bulgarian immigration began again in 1956 on a temporary basis and on quite a small scale. The other movements affecting eastern European countries involved highly skilled workers from other countries in the area, or even (at least as regards Poland, and only in very recent years) from western Europe. These movements have always been of a temporary character and numerically unimportant. CONCLUSIONS A number of conclusions emerge from this rapid survey. The first is that most continental migration in Europe involved movements over short distances between neighbouring countries and even, in many cases (as is shown by the number of frontier movements and as would, no doubt, be demonstrated by a detailed study of the location of emigration and immigration centres), movements between contiguous areas in neighbouring countries. Of all the major emigration movements only that from Italy and, for a few years, that from Germany, covered a relatively extensive area and were not altogether regional. Moreover, the movements over short distances were often of a short-term character: CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 151 daily or weekly movements, movements over a frontier, seasonal movements or movements which, though permanent under official terminology, were still of short duration since in most cases net immigration figures were low. This latter trait constitutes one of the major differences between intra-European movements and European emigration overseas. The statistics also reveal that, apart from Italy, the southern European countries were relatively untouched by continental migration currents over the last 12 years (although the position in this regard has tended to alter recently). If it is borne in mind, moreover, that a clear majority of Italian emigrants to other European countries came from the northern part of Italy, it may be concluded that continental migration in Europe over this period affected mainly the more industrialised parts of the Continent and their immediate vicinity. The Americas Most of the migration currents between American countries converged on the United States. Little information is available concerning the movements that took place among Latin American countries but it seems that none of them were on a comparable scale. UNITED STATES Immigration For the years 1946-57 as a whole, permanent immigrants to the United States from the rest of the American Continent numbered about 880,000. Movements of foreign residents in the reverse direction over the same period involved little more than 95,000 persons, which leaves a net immigration figure of about 785,000. Details of these movements by countries of origin and of destination are given in table 53. Most of the immigrants came from Canada, which accounted for 43.7 per cent, of the total. A similar proportion came from Latin America as a whole (Mexico, Central America and South America), and Mexico alone accounted for 30.1 per cent. By and large, it would appear that the number of immigrants from other parts of the American Continent increased greatly during the period under review and that their proportion in the total number rose steadily. Over the whole period the proportion was about one-third (32.7 per cent.), but it has always exceeded 40 per cent, since 1952 and reached about 152 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 53. UNITED STATES: MIGRATION TO AND FROM THE REST OF THE AMERICAN CONTINENT \ 1946-57 (In thousands) Canada South America Miscellaneous * Total Year Immigration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23.9 24.4 25.4 23.3 23.3 27.3 37.8 35.8 32.9 37.2 44.1 50.1 0.9 0.9 1.1 1.8 2.9 2.9 2.4 1.9 2.8 2.6 3.3 3.1 7.9 7.6 8.5 7.6 6.2 6.9 11.8 23.3 39.3 52.1 62.2 32.6 1.0 1.0 0.8 1.2 1.2 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.4 0.3 0.5 0.5 3.2 3.0 3.0 3.2 3.4 4.0 5.1 6.2 7.0 8.5 9.8 12.7 0.9 1.5 2.4 2.7 3.0 2.3 2.0 2.5 3.8 1.9 2.2 1.4 10.3 10.9 10.0 8.5 8.4 8.1 11.5 11.2 13.9 20.8 25.5 24.2 2.5 1.6 3.0 4.4 4.0 3.1 2.8 3.3 3.7 1.6 1.4 0.8 45.3 45.9 46.3 42.7 41.2 46.2 66.2 76.5 93.1 118.6 141.6 119.6 5.3 5.0 7.3 10.2 11.1 9.3 8.2 8.6 11.7 6.3 7.4 5.8 Total . 385.5 26.6 265.9 10.9 69.1 26.7 163.3 32.1 883.8 96.2 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1 Mexico ImEmigra- migration tion ImEmigra- migration tion Immigrants and foreign residents leaving for good. ImEmigra- migration tion ImEmigra- migration tion Emigration ' Chiefly the West Indies and Central America. 45 per cent, in 1957.1 This development was less a result of immigration from Canada (although this has been rising markedly for some years) than of movements from Latin America, particularly Mexico and the West Indies. Yet, after rising steadily since 1951, the number of immigrants from Mexico fell appreciably in 1957. In any case the real volume of continental immigration to the United States was in all likelihood a good deal greater than is suggested by the figures in table 53, since for the period as a whole the statistics of the United States Immigration and Naturalization Service include some 90,000 immigrants of unspecified origin, the majority of them probably from other American countries.2 Finally, it should be noted that net immigration from the rest of the American Continent is actually a matter of some uncertainty, since United States statistics cover only foreign residents who leave the country for good, and not departures of persons who have acquired United States citizenship. This observation would appear to apply chiefly to re-emigration to Canada, where some 60,000 Canadians 1 For the total immigration figures, see Chapter VI. The immigrants in question are persons who first enter the United States under visas other than immigration visas and obtain an immigration visa at a later date. Such cases seem to be more common among nationals of non-quota countries than among others. 2 153 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS returning from the United States were counted between 1946 and 1957 (as compared with some 27,000 departures recorded by the United States Immigration and Naturalization Service), while from 1946 to 1950 there were over 7,000 returns from the United States of persons previously admitted to Canada as immigrants.1 In other words net immigration from Canada was probably lower by almost 50,000 than the figure shown by the statistics of the United States Immigration and Naturalization Service. On the basis of available information, it is impossible to say whether net immigration from other American countries was overestimated to the same extent. In addition to permanent immigrants the United States have, since 1946, attracted a considerable number of seasonal immigrants, mainly from Mexico. Not all of these enter the country legally, so that only partial records are available. The official figures by year and country of origin are reproduced in table 54. This table shows the importance of regular seasonal immigration from Mexico and the large increase in such immigration over recent years. Unfortunately, it does not give a complete picture of Mexican seasonal immigration as a whole, most of which was illegal until 1950. Even now, illegal entries have not ceased altogether, although they have been considerably reduced by stricter supervision and by the entry into force of a new recruitment agreement concluded with the Mexican Government in August 1951. Statistics concerning the employment of seasonal labour are equally unenlightening since they cover only workers whose papers were in order. Little, therefore, can be added concerning this problem. Emigration Conversely with the movements just described, there was an emigration of United States nationals towards Canada and Central and South America, with regard to which available statistics provide only very inadequate information. 1 The number of annual returns (in thousands) was as follows: Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canadian citizens Immigrants 4.6 7.0 4.6 4.0 3.4 3.6 0.9 2.8 1.7 1.3 0.7 — Year 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canadian citizens Immigrants 4.7 5.3 5.6 5.1 5.9 6.6 — — — — — 154 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 54. UNITED STATES : IMMIGRANT FARM WORKERS ADMITTED INTO THE COUNTRY, BY COUNTRY OF ORIGIN, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Canada 4.1 5.2 6.2 7.0 6.7 6.7 7.3 British West Indies Mexico 9.0 7.9 7.7 4.7 6.6 7.6 8.2 32.0 19.6 35.3 19.6 66.1 190.7 197.1 201.4 309.0 398.6 445.2 436.0 Miscellaneous Total 0.4 0.7 201.7 210.2 215.3 320.7 412.0 459.8 452.2 Source: For 1946-50, Eleanor M. HADLEY: " A Critical Analysis of the Wetback Problem ", in Law and Contemporary Problems (Durham, N.C., Duke University School of Law), Vol. XXI, No. 2, Spring 1956, pp. 351-352; and, for 1951-57, Organisation for European Economic Co-operation: Annual Report on the Manpower Situation in 1957 : United States, Document MO (58)7/30 (Paris, 21 July 1958 (mimeographed)). According to a Canadian source immigrants from the United States, an overwhelming majority of whom were United States citizens, numbered about 110,000 over the period as a whole. Details of these movements by year are given in table 55. This was partly offset by a reverse flow of about 40,000 United States citizens between 1946 and 1955.1 TABLE 55. CANADA : IMMIGRATION FROM THE UNITED STATES, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 Number of immigrants 9.6 9.4 7.4 7.8 7.8 7.8 9.3 Year Number of immigrants 9.4 10.1 10.4 9.8 11.0 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 109.8 1 See Canada Yearbook (Ottawa, Dominion Bureau of Statistics), 1956 and 1957. The exact figures (in thousands) were as follows, by years ending 30 June: 1945-46 1947 . 1948 . 1949 . 1950 . 6.8 5.0 4.9 5.8 3.9 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 4.3 4.0 2.8 2.1 2.3 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 155 Movements towards Latin American countries can be measured only for the few countries which compile migration statistics in the strict sense. Those to Argentina, Uruguay and even Brazil (about 10,000 United States citizens between 1946 and 1956) were apparently negligible; on the other hand there were many migrants to Venezuela, as may be seen from table 56. TABLE 56. UNITED STATES : MOVEMENTS OF UNITED STATES CITIZENS TO AND FROM VENEZUELA, 1950-561 (In thousands) Immigration Year 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 Total . . . Emigration 13.3 13.3 15.8 16.5 16.9 18.9 23.0 15.9 13.0 15.0 16.0 16.7 17.8 21.9 117.6 116.4 1 Includes United States citizens registered on arrival or departure as " immigrants *', " residents " and " transients ". The table shows that movements in the reverse direction were almost as numerous, so that from 1950 to 1956 at any rate the net immigration balance was negligible. This is because movements of United States citizens to Venezuela are generally short-term ones ; Venezuelan statistics in any case include many temporary movements in the statistical sense of the term. Movements of United States citizens to other Latin American countries were no doubt of a similar character but the only available information concerning them consists as a rule of statistics of travellers, which give no indication of the number of actual migrants. What they do indicate is that in all cases arrivals and departures of United States citizens have balanced out over comparatively few years. Mexico compiles migration statistics which show that between 1946 and 1953 some 9,000 United States citizens immigrated into that country and that almost as high a number re-emigrated.1 LATIN AMERICA Analysis of migratory movements within Latin America is hampered by the usual statistical difficulties. Only in Argentina does there appear 1 Anuario Estadístico de los Estados Unidos Mexicanos (Mexico City, Secretaría de Economía, Dirección General de Estadística), 1954. 156 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 57. ARGENTINA: NET IMMIGRATION OF NATIONALS OF OTHER SOUTH AMERICAN COUNTRIES, BY NATIONALITY, 1946-57 (In thousands) Brazilians Year Para- Uruguayans Miscellaneous Total . . . . . . . . . . . 0.4 0.1 0.4 0.1 1.6 0.8 0.8 1.7 1.7 26.5 -1.6 2.7 1.8 0.5 0.9 0.8 1.6 3.6 3.1 0.1 1.1 -0.2 1.4 1.0 0.7 2.6 2.3 2.7 5.4 6.4 1.6 3.3 6.8 6.1 8.7 4.0 0.6 3.0 6.4 4.2 6.9 9.5 10.0 7.1 7.5 9.6 25.5 22.7 -10.1 -6.4 -11.6 -2.0 12.3 7.6 -8.9 -1.0 -1.1 -3.9 1.7 12.1 0.4 0.3 0.7 0.1 0.9 2.5 1.4 0.7 0.7 — — — -6.1 0.1 -0.9 6.0 28.8 30.5 7.9 11.8 16.7 38.1 35.7 42.5 Total 35.2 15.7 50.6 113.0 -11.3 7.7 211.1 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . Source: For 1946-54, Dirección Nacional de Estadística y Censos: Informe Demográfica de la República Argentina 1944-1954 (Buenos Aires, 1956); and, for 1955-56, Boletín Mensual de Estadística (Buenos Aires, Dirección Nacional de Estadística y Censos), various issues. to have been a sizeable immigration surplus, as revealed by that country's statistics of travellers' arrivals and departures, most of the immigrants coming from Paraguay and Chile (table 57). However, quite apart from the reservations to which statistics based largely on records kept at land frontiers are necessarily subject, the figures give no idea of the extent of gross movements, which would seem to include many seasonal ones, particularly from Bolivia. As regards Venezuela most of the immigrants were Colombians, as may be seen from table 58. Thus about half the immigrants to Venezuela from other Latin American countries and 90 per cent, of the net movement between 1950 and 1957 came from Colombia. Moreover, total immigration from other parts of the American Continent may have been considerably greater than is shown by the figures in table 58, as some immigrants entering the country as tourists probably settled there subsequently. For the other Latin American countries the statistics available— whether migration statistics in the strict sense or statistics of arrivals and departures of travellers—suggest that there were no major movements among them, or at any rate none of a permanent character. On the whole, therefore, Latin America was less affected by continental migration than by European immigration.1 1 See below, Chapter VI. 157 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 58. VENEZUELA: MIGRATION BY NATIONALS OF OTHER LATIN AMERICAN COUNTRIES, BY NATIONALITY, 1950-57 (In thousands) Immigration Colombians 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Tota il . . . . Emigration Others Total Colombians Others Total 6.2 7.7 9.9 5.5 3.7 3.6 3.5 4.8 5.5 4.8 5.1 5.9 7.3 8.1 9.6 5.7 11.7 12.5 15.0 11.4 11.0 11.7 13.1 10.5 4.2 4.4 3.7 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.6 1.6 5.5 4.5 4.8 5.2 6.1 7.0 7.8 9.0 9.7 8.9 8.5 6.9 7.7 8.4 9.4 10.6 44.9 52.0 96.9 20.3 49.7 70.0 Africa In Africa, by contrast, there have been very extensive movements of indigenous workers from one territory to another, at least in the part lying south of the Sahara. These were helped by the basically unstable character of African labour. Unfortunately the statistics concerning such movements are most unsatisfactory, owing to the inadequacy of the checks on which they are based. As a rule, reliance has to be placed on figures relating to the crossing of frontiers, or more commonly on counts of foreign workers. Such movements have drawn a complicated pattern of cross-currents, since although some territories were exclusivelye migration or immigration centres, many were both at the same time. For purposes of analysis, three major geographical areas can be distinguished : west Africa, east Africa and southern Africa. In west Africa the main centre of attraction for African labour was Ghana (formerly the British territory of the Gold Coast). At the time of the 1948 census the resident population of that territory included 175,000 people born abroad, and the annual number of arrivals rose from 108,000 persons in 1938 to 392,000 in 1953. The immigrants, who generally stayed in the country for only a short time, came from the neighbouring French territories of the Upper Volta, the Ivory Coast and Togoland, and from Nigeria. In 1954 between 300,000 and 400,000 immigrants from the Upper Volta, the Ivory Coast and Togoland were employed in Ghana and accounted for 40 per cent, of the total employed 158 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 labour force. Nigeria also attracted workers from French West Africa and Gambia attracted workers from Senegal and Portuguese Guinea. In east Africa the migration pattern covered the northern part of Mozambique, Tanganyika, the eastern part of the Belgian Congo and Ruanda-Urundi, Uganda, the southern Sudan and southern Kenya, Northern Rhodesia and Nyasaland. Most of the migratory flow was from the outlying parts of the region towards the centre, that is to say towards the two territories of Tanganyika and Uganda. In Tanganyika in 1957 there were almost 55,000 workers from neighbouring territories, mostly Ruanda-Urundi and Mozambique. Uganda attracted workers from Ruanda-Urundi and Tanganyika. In addition to these two major currents there were secondary movements towards the eastern part of the Belgian Congo and Kenya; the former received workers mainly from Ruanda-Urundi and the latter from Tanganyika. The greatest movements of labour over the last 12 years, however, occurred mainly in the southern part of the Continent, and specifically towards Northern Rhodesia, Southern Rhodesia and the Union of South Africa. Of these countries South Africa exerted its attraction over the widest area—extending as far north as Tanganyika—and Northern Rhodesia over the smallest. The Union of South Africa received a flow of migrants from all parts of southern Africa. Immigrants from Mozambique seem to have been by far the most numerous since, according to a Portuguese source, there were 165,000 workers from that territory working in the Union by the end of 1953. Other important contingents came from the British Protectorates of Basutoland, Bechuanaland and Swaziland, from Southern Rhodesia and from Nyasaland. Southern Rhodesia recruited its foreign labour in a more limited area, once again including Mozambique (from which over 155,000 workers were employed at the end of 1953 according to a Portuguese source), as well as Nyasaland (100,000 workers in 1954), Angola and Northern Rhodesia. Immigration to the latter territory was on a much smaller scale and came mainly from Nyasaland, Tanganyika and Angola. At the end of 1957 about 20,000 immigrants were employed in the main industries of Northern Rhodesia (8,500 from Nyasaland and 5,500 from Tanganyika). Finally, apart from the three major areas surveyed above, some mention must be made of the two-way movement between Angola and the Belgian Congo. On balance, immigration to the Congo seems to have been definitely greater. It should be noted that the few figures cited give only a pale reflection of the numbers actually involved in inter-territorial movements of 159 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS African labour in tropical Africa, first because there was an uninterrupted flow of comings and goings over territorial frontiers, and secondly because the workers were in some cases, though probably not very often, accompanied or joined by their families. Besides migration of indigenous peoples there was also some migration of Europeans from one territory to another, generally within the British Commonwealth. The most important of these movements by far was the emigration that occurred from the Union of South Africa to the territories that have since 1954 formed the Central African Federation, especially Southern Rhodesia. Table 59 gives an idea of the extent of this movement, based on South African statistics. The Union of South Africa was thus the source of a migratory flow to other parts of the Continent which, over the whole period, involved more than 100,000 people, of whom 96,000 went to the two Rhodesias; of these, about two-thirds went to Southern Rhodesia and one-third to Northern Rhodesia. The actual numbers involved may even have been somewhat higher than appears from table 59; this, at any rate, is what a comparison between the South African figures and Rhodesian data suggests.1 TABLE 59. UNION OF SOUTH AFRICA: MIGRATION OF EUROPEANS TO AND FROM THE REST OF THE AFRICAN CONTINENT, 1946-57 (In thousands) Rhodesias Other territories Total Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . Tota 1 1 1 Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 5.1 5.5 6.1 7.2 11.2 12.2 7.3 6.9 8.1 9.1 9.5 8.0 0.4 1.4 1.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 1.1 2.0 1.8 1.5 2.0 0.7 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.7 1.2 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.4 1.8 2.2 1.7 0.9 0.5 0.5 0.8 0.8 1.1 1.4 1.5 1.2 5.8 6.0 6.4 7.5 11.9 13.4 8.1 7.3 8.5 9.6 10.1 8.4 2.2 3.5 3.1 1.4 1.0 1.0 1.3 1.8 3.2 3.2 3.0 3.2 96.2 » 13.6 6.8 14.4 103.0 28.0 including 53.0 to Southern Rhodesia between 1946 and 1955. For 1946-53, migration from South Africa to Southern Rhodesia involved 44,000 people according to South African statistics, as compared with 53,000 according to the Southern Rhodesian figures. For 1955-57, the South African statistics show an emigration of some 27,000 persons to the Central African Federation whereas the statistics of the Federation give a figure of 32,000. 160 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Regarding migration in Africa north of the Sahara, no precise information is available. The only movements worthy of mention would appear to be those from Algeria to Morocco, which involved members of both the European and the Moslem population. Asia and Oceania While the lack of migration statistics in most Asian countries precludes any accurate assessment of continental migration in Asia over the last 12 years, such movements in most cases do appear to have been on a small, not to say insignificant, scale. India is the only one of the four former major emigration countries (the others being China, Japan and Korea) from which emigrants left for other Asian countries in any conspicuous numbers. Moreover, such statistics as exist cover only official movements by sea, i.e. those made in conformity with emigration regulations, so that it is impossible to ascertain the extent of others, if any. Details of the official movements by country are given in table 60. These movements—which were on a very small scale compared with what they had been in the past—were directed chiefly towards Ceylon until 1949, and thereafter towards Malaya, while migration to Burma TABLE 60. INDIA1: OFFICIAL MOVEMENTS TO AND RETURNS FROM OTHER ASIAN COUNTRIES, 1946-56 (In thousands) imigration Net Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Total . Returns Burma Ceylon Malaya laneous * — — — — — — — — 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.3 7.9 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.1 1.3 2.8 4.3 7.6 5.5 — — — — — — — — Total — 21.7 20.9 19.3 12.9 6.4 8.0 11.4 10.9 3.7 4.5 3.8 2.1 3.3 5.1 6.1 5.6 1.5 1.3 1.0 1.5 1.4 1.4 19.6 17.6 14.2 6.8 0.8 6.5 10.1 9.9 2.2 3.1 2.4 — 123.5 30.3 93.2 3.3 2.9 3.1 3.0 4.7 3.2 4.2 Source: Statistical Abstract, India (Central Statistical Organisation, Government of India), 1950, 1951-52, 1952-53, 1954-55 and 1956-57. 1 The figures include Pakistan until August 1947. * Mainly countries bordering on the Persian Gulf, and, to a lesser extent, Africa. 161 CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS was negligible. However, statistics of arriving and departing travellers published by Ceylon and the Federation of Malaya suggest that migration between India and those two countries was actually much greater than the Indian figures indicate. The statistics of passengers arriving in and departing from Ceylon, which relate mostly to Indians 1 , indicate that the number of Indian immigrants was higher, at any rate until 1949, than is disclosed by the Indian statistics, and also that from 1950 onwards there was a reversal in the traditional flow of migrants which is not revealed by the Indian figures. Both series show a decline in migration in both directions; moreover, there was a slight immigration surplus for Ceylon for the period as a whole. The Malayan statistics, unlike those of Ceylon, include a breakdown of the passenger totals by racial origin and reveal a net immigration of over 60,000 2 Indians and Pakistanis between 1947 and 1957. Emigration from Pakistan appears to have been confined chiefly to a few small-scale movements towards countries bordering on the Persian Gulf. There is very little information on movements from China. In the very first years of the period there seems to have been considerable migration of Chinese to Thailand3, although most of them probably 1 The balance of arrivals and departures (in thousands of persons) from 1946 to 1956 was as follows: 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 56.8 22.5 20.2 30.7 -20.4 -14.0 -16.3 -12.6 - 8.0 -23.0 -18.0 18.0 Total 2 Net passenger movements to Malaya (broken down by nationality and excluding movements between Malaya and Singapore) from 1947 to 1957 were as follows (thousands of persons) : Year 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . Miscellaneous (mainly Siamese) European Indians and Pakistanis -3.7 -2.4 -9.2 -1.4 -100 -5.5 -1.6 1.2 2.8 5.3 2.5 0.7 0.5 1.3 0.7 1.8 1.7 1.3 0.8 1.0 1.6 1.7 -8.4 -0.9 -0.6 7.4 6.3 13.0 19.3 -0.3 3.1 6.0 5.7 -0.3 0.1 2.2 5.8 1.2 1.8 1.9 1.9 3.4 3.5 -11.7 -2.7 -6.3 12.5 -1.9 10.4 20.8 3.6 8.8 16.3 13.4 -22.0 13.1 50.6 21.5 63.2 Chinese Total Source: Monthly Bulletin of the Federation of Malaya (Kuala Lumpur, Department of Statistics). 3 The figures for 1946 to 1949 (in thousands) are as follows according to the official statistics of Thailand: 1946 1947 79.1 67.9 1948 1949 14.7 5.5 162 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 were not new immigrants but former Chinese residents returning to the country after a temporary absence. In other countries, particularly Malaya and Viet-Nam, statistics of Chinese arrivals and departures also seem to include Chinese having previously established residence in those countries. Nor does it seem that there was any emigration from Korea or any large-scale Japanese emigration to other Asian countries during the period considered. The emigration figures published by Japan since 1950 are not broken down by country of destination, and since they cover emigration to other continents as well as to Asia they are of no use for the purposes of this analysis. Moreover, they seem to include among emigrants a large majority of travellers who are not in fact migrants. There are no statistics concerning migration within the Middle East. There seems to have been a considerable flow of migrants from Iran towards Iraq, Kuwait, Bahrein and Qatar and from Syria and Lebanon towards the same territories, mainly Kuwait. The only sizeable movements within Oceania were those between Australia and New Zealand. Figures concerning these movements have been published by both countries; they are reproduced in table 61. The table shows a net immigration surplus of a few thousand for New Zealand. The balance has been clearly in favour of New Zealand since 1952. TABLE 61. MIGRATION BETWEEN AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND, 1946-57 (In thousands) Australian figures Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 1 New Zealand figures 1 Emigration Immigration Immigration Emigration 3.0 2.8 1.7 2.0 2.0 2.3 3.9 4.5 3.9 4.5 3.8 5.0 2.1 2.4 2.7 3.2 3.8 3.1 2.2 1.8 2.6 2.9 2.9 2.5 1.7 1.5 1.3 2.5 2.8 3.3 5.1 4.8 3.5 3.5 4.0 5.2 1.7 1.8 2.7 3.0 3.5 2.8 1.9 2.2 2.7 3.0 2.6 2.1 39.4 32.3 39.1 30.0 For New Zealand, year beginning on 1 April and ending on 31 March in the following calendar year. CONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 163 Bibliographical References The source material for this chapter is included in the list of references given at the end of Chapter VI. CHAPTER VI INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS Intercontinental migration currents are, as a rule, easier to analyse than continental ones owing to the overwhelming predominance of long-term—i.e., in the official sense, permanent—movements which, to a large extent, eliminates the problem of confusion between shortterm and long-term movements so often associated with continental migration statistics. To be sure, even here the distinction between permanent migrants, temporary migrants and non-migrants is not always clearly drawn, and the statistics do not always provide a fully satisfactory basis for quantitative analysis; but this is true chiefly of non-European emigration and for countries where European immigration has been only on a small scale, and since the vast majority of intercontinental migrants between 1946 and 1957 were Europeans who went to settle in a few major immigration countries overseas or who returned to Europe after a more or less extended stay in other continents, the inadequacy of statistics for the remaining movements is not a serious drawback. European Emigration GENERAL Based on the figures published by the various emigration countries 1 , together with those compiled for the years 1947-52 by the International Refugee Organisation (excluding movements to Israel)2, the gross European emigration figure for the period from 1946 3 to 1957 would seem to have been about 6.6 million. The details are given in table 62. This over-all figure, which may be accepted as an initial estimate, calls for a fundamental observation. It is the sum of data arrived at on a different basis in each country and represents total movements recorded as emigration movements by the responsible departments. 1 For Austria, there are no statistics that can be used. I.C.E.M. data, which cover most of the emigrants after 1952, have been used to fill the gap. Similarly, I.R.O. statistics have been used to cover the 1947-51 period. 2 The I.R.O. figures also cover movements from certain non-European countries, especially in the Middle East, East Africa and the Far East, and include a total of about 20,000 people, mostly Europeans, who were involved in those movements. 3 Practically no information is available for 1945; in any case, there was very little migration during that year. 165 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS C0»rìVD<<teSCSJON^-00©CS0NON CSCS^HWOCS^TJ-ONCOONTj-rt^ c ori-soiO —nit'rCi K O W Tco t TJ-T-C r -' — T ji-i r > siooe s > e r- ^ (N • * il H nV'^O © o o M 1 - ^ 1—t 1 - ON Tí- O f i V 2 H O N ^ ^ • r t H m CS « y 2 ? 2 Ä ? ¡z o Ì a Ü vi •* 2 O Pi Ü UJ -J PQ < 2 Kn>o 0 0 1-H »-I SO O CO w i ^ n t inrs^f'H ON m oo • so X> V~i O O r H O ^ r - O O V ^ O SO 1 r^ r^ r»ri rs* eco" t-»* csì es* <co jS so N «fr »n 1 Tf T f OO \ 0 0 0 T i " P i i f ì M T f r- co »r> •W«t ri CONO«/-) voKifswinr-r-r-M 1 ON" ON »ri 1 CS CS r i CS O * © ' '"í" CS* »ri »ri 1 t—i »o c o v> in ON T—1 ;* 2 • •m o *ÜÍ • O-^-TtsoONTfNooN^Ornr-Tj-iri F H i n n i o n N O i n N f ì H o o w o N SO i-t TT T f «Ti CONO NO ro rJ- Oh-^^Ttm^onvo^Ti-r-t irìV-iv-iO'rir^oorS'— , ON>rì<N v «o co co rico cs »ri co CO OOiricoincoTj-r^oooocSON^O vorj-co>rìONTi->ncsvoTi-r--cscs »n co ,-H r^ «n Tt ^H ^> in ,-H OTftrìOCSco^-TfrOONON^O^- es»nNO»n»neseseScsOTj-coco ,_, CO CS ' CS © »n co CS^H Tf ro <N OCOW-IONTJ-'-HTJ-OOOOTÌ-NOOO ONr-Tt-ONCiTj-oocosociTfcn.—« «Ti m NO T t so 00 ^H co o r• so «o o co SO- HH " ^ ON I/O 1—1 1—1 rtONTj-N H(NVÌrt »n 1 es' o> ON es" © OÑ co* es' co 1 1-HTJ- TI- Tt m TJ1— 1 do'vo \0 cs ^H ^H ^H in *-* es ^D T— O so ON CS CO CO no ss Ë rt tn e« 5 >> ONOn cSTtcoocoinooooso co OÓrlfH I r O ^ r H O Ò h ' r t r H r t 1 ^H r- T - H 1—1 co CS CS O O ¡= § o • •o GÌ ti o x> U-i .2 ni SO OONCSONONONONiriCOCSWONO»rì ONTfroco^Ö^T^cSiricscs^o* CS so Tf i-i « CS >* • Austria Belgium Denmark Finland Federal Germar Greece Ireland . 1/3 -IfìTt Tfr c s ON y 2 co eS CSCOONSO'—©COCOON T3 Si 1 e Snain O Pi O ^ M T-i SO ON T f SO CS so* r-* so" | ^ M d r i v o h P ì ( S Q ' so es 1 en to es »ri TÌ m r - - h r t CS CO "fr ^H so MN\o t^noooO'-i«n^to\ON ö r^ «o 1 <n* r i OÑ (N r i r i r r ^H I N in »-H l o Tt m NO vo Netherlan Norway Portugal c O Pi D W ON ^o es i> ^ CS ^ H ^ 3 ON ,-« CS es' C Ss2 •s 11 u X/l >-> L. 5 CO cö H ctf O bfi O Vi C P 4> •s «J s > oí 1> 166 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Even on the assumption that there were no major gaps in these records, it may be asked how far these national figures relate to " permanent " European emigration in the internationally accepted sense of the term, since depending on the way in which each country's statistics are compiled they may either include travellers who are not permanent migrants in the United Nations sense or not include all permanent migrants. Without attempting to assess the value from this point of view of each of the national sources used, it may be noted that the I.R.O. statistics, while they undoubtedly relate to permanent migration, do not cover all movements of refugees from Europe, whereas they do include persons from other continents whom it was not possible to deduct from the annual totals ; that the West German statistics are the only ones that are in full conformity with the United Nations standard * ; and that the other countries all diverge more or less from that standard either in their rules or in their practice. The Portuguese statistics do not include emigration to the overseas provinces; the Spanish, Italian and Dutch statistics may include among emigrants travellers returning overseas after a stay of less than one year (i.e. persons who are not actually migrants) 2 ; the United Kingdom statistics do not take account of movements by air or of movements to Mediterranean countries and, in addition, although they are based on the criterion of residence for a year or more, they probably include among immigrants and subsequently among emigrants travellers who come to the United Kingdom for a long stay. The statistics of the secondary emigration countries are generally even less reliable.3 Most of them tend to underestimate actual movements rather than to overestimate them. Thus, on the one hand, table 62 contains several total 4 or partial 5 1 This applies to the statistics proper but not to the estimates for the 1946-52 period, which cover German nationals only. 2 In addition, the Italian statistics do not include aliens and the Spanish and Portuguese statistics do not include people emigrating by air. These gaps are in fact minor ones, since most of the alien emigrants from Italy were refugees included in the I.R.O. totals and since emigration from Spain and Portugal by air is of negligible proportions. The omission from the Spanish emigration statistics of movements to Africa, on the other hand, is more serious. 3 In Belgium, Denmark and Sweden the records seem to make no distinction between permanent migrants, temporary migrants and non-migrants; moreover, the system of registration probably does not work in a fully satisfactory manner. In Ireland the statistics cover only emigration by sea through Irish ports. In Finland and Greece the data are based on passport application figures and appear to be largely incomplete. 4 Lack of figures for France; and lack of figures for Belgium in 1946-47. 6 Absence of information on Portuguese emigration to the overseas provinces; on emigration from Austria, apart from movements recorded by the I.R.O. and the I.C.E.M.; on British emigration to Mediterranean countries; and on Greek emigration to Mediterranean countries in 1946 and 1947 as well as in 1954-55 (apart from the movements recorded by the I.C.E.M.). 167 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS omissions, while several series in the table include a number of temporary migrants and non-migrants. 1 On the whole, it seems that the figure for permanent emigration from Europe to other parts of the world, excluding Israel, should be a good deal higher than the total based on the available figures, and that it probably comes to about 7 million. Table 62 shows the relative size of the migratory flow from various countries. The United Kingdom leads by a considerable margin, followed by Italy : these two countries account for half the recorded emigration. Western Germany (including both refugees and German nationals), Spain, the Netherlands and Portugal come next in that order. The figures given in table 62 may be grouped by larger geographical regions; the results are shown in table 63. These proportions changed considerably over the period, as shown by table 64. Central Europe made a massive contribution to the emigration movement only for a few years when the I.R.O. camps emptied, whereas TABLE 63. EUROPEAN EMIGRATION BY REGION, 1946-57 Region Thousands of persons Percentages 2,744.7 41.5 North-western Europe (British Isles, Belgium, Netherlands, Scandinavian countries) Central Europe (Western Germany, Austria, Switzerland) 1 Southern Europe (Portugal, Spain, Italy, Malta, Greece) 1,373.8 20.8 2,493.7 37.7 Total . . . 6,612.2 100.0 1 Including refugees resettled by the I.R.O. TABLE 64. DISTRIBUTION OF EUROPEAN EMIGRATION BY MAJOR EUROPEAN REGION, BY TWO-YEAR PERIODS, 1946-57 (Percentages) Period 1946-47 1948-49 1950-51 1952-53 1954-55 1956-57 1 Particularly among aliens. Northwestern Europe Central Europe Southern Europe Total 70 37 34 46 39 42 21 33 30 13 11 17 9 30 36 41 50 41 100 100 100 100 100 100 168 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the proportion of emigrants from southern Europe rose steadily (at least until 1955). Table 62 highlights the link between the record figures for the years 1949-51 and the operations of the I.R.O. It also shows that the resumption of emigration after the war was slow in most countries other than the United Kingdom, and that it generally reached its peak around 1951-52. Since 1953 the level of European emigration has become stabilised at more than 500,000 persons a year. Calculations based on the statistics used for table 62 also give an approximate idea of the distribution of gross emigration by continent of destination (table 65) : they show that America received about 70 per cent, of the total and Oceania less than 20 per cent. The African share is, however, considerably underestimated because the statistics do not allow for French emigration or for emigration from Portugal to its overseas provinces. On the basis of the immigration statistics kept by a certain number of countries, it is possible to estimate roughly the numbers returning to Europe over the 12 years under review, and therefore the net emigration totals. The figures show that about 2 million immigrants from other continents were counted between 1946 and 1957 in nine of the main European emigration countries. An overwhelming majority of them were former emigrants returning to their countries of origin. The proportion of returns was probably very small in the case of the other major movements, particularly German emigrants and I.R.O. refugees, so that it seems reasonable to estimate total net emigration for 1946-57 at upwards of 5 million people. Further details of these various over-all figures will emerge from a more careful analysis of the statistics of emigration and major immigration countries. TABLE 65. DISTRIBUTION OF EUROPEAN EMIGRANTS BY CONTINENT OF DESTINATION, 1946-57 Continent Figures in millions 4.7 2.9 1.8 0.4 .0.3 1.2 America North South Africa Asia Oceania Total . . . 6.6 Percentages 71 44 27 6 5 18 100 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 169 Table 66 contains gross and net migration data based on the statistics of the nine emigration countries referred to above. The interpretation to be placed on these figures will be discussed at a later stage, when each country is dealt with separately. TABLE 66. GROSS A N D N E T E M I G R A T I O N F R O M N I N E E U R O P E A N EMIGRATION COUNTRIES, 1946-57 (In thousands) Gross emigration Country Belgium 1 Denmark Ireland Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden United Kingdom Immigration Net emigration . . . 107.4 65.2 61.6 1,412.2 564.9 318.8 569.0 54.2 1,841.9 51.2 32.8 12.0 312.3 440.2 43.3 161.9 24.1 890.8 56.2 32.4 49.6 1,099.9 124.7 275.5 407.1 30.2 951.1 Total 4,995.2 1,968.6 3,026.6 COUNTRIES OF ORIGIN Emigration from and returns to Europe are described hereunder by major continental divisions—north-western Europe, central Europe and southern Europe. North-western Europe The two major emigration countries in north-western Europe were the United Kingdom and the Netherlands; the other countries accounted for only minor movements. United Kingdom. According to Board of Trade statistics, emigration from the United Kingdom to continents other than Europe accounted for a total of 1,840,000 people between 1946 and 1957. Over the same period there were 890,000 immigrants to the United Kingdom from those continents, which leaves an emigration surplus of about 950,000. The composition of these totals by country of destination and origin and by year is given in table 67. It should be remembered that these figures do not cover movements affecting countries of the Mediterranean basin or movements by air. TABLE 67. UNITED KINGDOM : INTERCONTINENTAL EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION AND ORIGIN, 1946-57 1 (In thousands) Canada Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . British West Indies Emigration Immigration British West Africa Emigration Immigration British East Africa Emigration Emigration Immigration Immigration 52.5 23.3 36.0 22.8 15.1 33.9 44.4 44.0 40.6 27.8 43.4 61.1 9.1 7.9 6.9 7.6 7.0 5.1 7.6 6.9 9.5 10.6 7.9 8.8 2.4 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.6 1.8 1.4 2.4 3.3 2.4 3.1 3.8 3.8 4.7 9.9 11.9 10.5 6.1 5.8 3.5 2.7 3.1 4.3 3.8 2.7 2.9 2.8 1.9 1.8 1.6 2.1 1.8 1.6 2.1 2.3 2.6 4.1 3.9 4.2 3.2 2.5 2.1 2.1 1.7 1.7 2.5 4.2 2.5 2.6 2.7 1.9 1.3 1.1 1.1 444.9 95.0 18.1 56.2 31.6 17.8 25.6 19.9 Northern and Southern Rhodesia Emigration Union of South Africa s India and Pakistan " Malaya Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 3.9 2.8 5.2 6.8 4.5 3.3 3.4 5.0 5.3 1.1 1.5 1.7 1.9 3.4 2.0 1.3 1.2 1.3 11.9 26.4 32.6 11.5 6.6 7.1 8.7 6.6 6.0 5.0 4.9 5.6 8.9 4.5 4.7 5.5 6.0 4.7 4.2 4.3 4.9 3.9 3.7 3.4 10.9 10.4 4.0 4.8 4.8 5.3 5.2 5.2 4.4 3.4 3.1 2.3 22.2 24.7 20.4 11.3 11.9 11.7 10.8 9.9 10.7 8.5 7.3 4.6 5.3 5.6 7.4 8.0 8.1 7.3 5.1 5.1 6.3 4.5 5.2 6.6 7.0 7.0 7.6 4.8 4.5 6.3 40.1 15.4 132.9 58.7 63.8 154.0 58.1 53.4 'British nationals and aliens, solely by sea. "The figures for 1946 .1947 and 1948 also cover migration to and from Rhodesia. 8 And Ceylon for 1946-48. TABLE 67 (cont.). UNITED KINGDOM: INTERCONTINENTAL EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION AND ORIGIN, 1946-57 1 (In thousands) Australia New Zealand Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . Emigration Immigration Emigration 9.6 13.1 34.5 53.1 54.7 57.2 52.5 30.6 34.8 36.2 32.4 35.3 5.1 4.7 4.3 5.6 7.2 10.0 10.8 11.5 13.5 10.3 10.1 8.0 5.4 6.0 7.1 9.3 10.6 9.8 15.3 14.6 10.4 10.2 11.5 10.2 1.4 2.7 2.4 2.9 3.1 2.9 3.4 3.4 4.4 3.5 3.2 2.5 443.9 »n-~! 101.2 120.5 35.8 British nationals and aliens, solely by sea. Immigration Other Commonwealth countries a Emigration Commonwealth total United States Other foreign countries All foreign countries Over-all total Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 6.7 3.8 5.1 7.1 6.3 9.6 14.6 10.1 12.3 14.5 12.0 9.8 7.9 6.4 9.4 6.4 6.9 6.0 3.2 4.3 3.7 3.3 2.3 3.5 5.8 5.4 7.2 7.9 8.2 9.9 6.8 5.5 5.6 5.3 3.6 4.0 60.3 27.6 32.3 25.2 21.1 29.3 26.4 27.5 27.3 25.2 24.2 25.2 12.5 9.2 12.3 15.0 14.5 19.5 21.4 15.6 17.9 19.8 15.6 13.9 171.6 126.5 168.1 152.6 136.4 169.5 181.8 155.2 148.4 128.0 140.9 162.9 67.1 62.8 73.7 64.8 71.9 76.3 82.1 77.8 92.3 84.8 73.8 63.4 112.0 63.3 72.5 351.5 Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 20.7 19.8 21.6 4.2 6.2 5.8 6.3 5.8 6.6 5.6 4.3 3.7 7.4 9.1 22.7 4.6 6.5 6.4 6.5 6.6 8.3 6.7 6.4 4.7 111.0 98.9 135.8 127.3 115.3 140.2 155.4 127.7 121.1 102.9 116.7 137.6 54.5 53.6 61.4 49.9 57.4 56.8 60.7 62.2 74.4 65.0 58.2 49.5 52.4 21.2 22.9 18.8 14.2 23.2 23.2 23.2 23.6 21.9 21.9 21.7 110.7 95.9 1,490.2 706.2 288.2 186.6 1,841-9 890.8 ' For 1946-48 these figures cover the British West Indies ,British West and East Africa and Malaya. a o o H > S o 3 z 172 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Table 67 brings out the essential characteristics of British emigration in the post-war period, namely the large numbers involved; the regularity of the flow; the great preponderance of movements towards the Commonwealth, which accounted for four-fifths of the total; and the high proportion—about 50 per cent.—of movements in the reverse direction. A slightly more detailed analysis shows that in fact several different kinds of movements were involved, namely— (a) a large and steady flow of British nationals towards Englishspeaking countries in North America and the southern hemisphere; (b) a smaller and much less steady flow of British nationals towards other Commonwealth countries 1 and, to a lesser degree, towards the Middle East 2 and Latin America 3 ; (c) a movement of aliens 4 returning to their own countries after staying in the United Kingdom for more than one year, and of Europeans who had previously immigrated to the United Kingdom and who left to settle overseas; and (d) a comparatively small number of citizens of other Commonwealth countries who had come to the United Kingdom for more than one year and returned to their countries of origin. The immigrants may be divided into two groups. Most of them were persons having previously emigrated from the United Kingdom who returned to that country: in the case of certain Asian countries, especially India and Pakistan, arrivals were sufficiently numerous to produce an immigration surplus. The remainder were nationals of other Commonwealth B or foreign countries who came to the United Kingdom for more than one year. The United Kingdom figures for emigration to the main countries of destination—Canada, the United States, the Union of South Africa, Central Africa, Australia and New Zealand—may be compared with the figures for immigration from the United Kingdom recorded in those countries (table 68). Without attempting to explain all of the discrepancies between these two series of figures, a word of comment is called for at least as regards the more conspicuous ones. It would seem, for instance, that the failure of United Kingdom statistics to include movements by air 1 Mainly the British West Indies, British West, Central and East Africa, India and Pakistan, Ceylon, Malaya and Hong Kong. 2 Mainly Egypt. 3 About 15,000 over the period as a whole. 4 British statistics list 125,000 alien emigrants; over 70,000 are recorded as having gone to the United States. 6 In the second part of the period, they included a large number of immigrants from the British West Indies, India and Pakistan. 173 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 68. UNITED KINGDOM: EMIGRATION BY MAJOR COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1946-57 (COMPARISON BETWEEN THE UNITED KINGDOM FIGURES AND THOSE COMPILED BY IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES) (In thousands) Country Canada United States Union of South Africa Central African Federation Australia New Zealand Emigration figures ] 444.9 288.2 173.0 443.9 120.5 [ Immigration figures 518.1 273.2 105.0 x 90.6 430.8 2 126.6 1 Includes immigration to Southern Rhodesia in 1946-54 and to the Central African Federation 8 in 1955-57, but not immigration to Northern Rhodesia and Nyasaland in 1946-54. Period running from 1 April 1946 to 31 March 1958. is of little consequence as regards emigration to Australia and New Zealand, but that it leads to considerable underestimation of the number of emigrants to Canada, the United States 1 and Africa and that such underestimation increases as time goes on. Similarly, the figures given for immigration from the British West Indies, at any rate for the last few years, have been much lower than the facts would warrant. All in all, the number of emigrants for 1946-57 may have been underestimated in the Board of Trade statistics by as much as 150,000. If so, this would mean that total emigration for the whole period actually involved about 2 million people. Netherlands. According to the statistics of the Netherlands Central Statistical Bureau, overseas emigrants over the years 1946-57 numbered about 565,000 and overseas immigrants about 440,000. This left a net emigration surplus of about 125,000. Details by year and by countries of destination and origin are given in table 69. Like the British figures, those in this table cover several types of movements. Omitting aliens, some of whom no doubt were not permanent migrants, it seems that two major erriigration currents can be distinguished, namely a steady flow of emigrants to the United States, and above all to British Commonwealth countries peopled by Europeans— mainly Canada and Australia—which developed chiefly during the second half of the period; and a less steady flow of emigrants towards 1 Allowing for the fact that a large number of emigrants who left the United Kingdom for the United States were American citizens and as such were not listed as immigrants in the United States. TABLE 69. NETHERLANDS : INTERCONTINENTAL EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY CONTINENTS AND COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION AND ORIGIN, 1946-57 1 (In thousands) Africa Year Union of South Africa Total . . . 1 Miscellaneous Immigration Emigration Immigration — — — — 2.3 1.6 2.9 4.7 3.8 3.7 3.4 2.4 1.9 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 — 1.5 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.1 1.2 26.7 6.6 5.3 6.3 Emigration 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 America Netherlands nationals and aliens 0.7 0.8 1.1 1.2 — — — Total Emigration 0.8 2.9 4.2 3.0 2.3 3.7 5.8 5.0 4.9 4.9 4.2 . 3.4 45.2 Canada Immigration Emigration Immigration United States Emigration Surinam and Netherlands Antilles Total Miscellaneous Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 3.3 2.7 2.3 2.6 1.7 1.7 2.5 3.3 3.9 3.6 3.9 3.9 4.7 9.9 1.5 1.7 1.5 1.5 1.3 1.7 1.7 1.7 2.4 1.5 2.0 2.0 0.6 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.9 1.1 1.2 1.1 1.5 7.5 14.0 16.5 15.7 15.3 27.3 30.0 29.3 24.6 17.2 24.1 28.7 5.3 4.7 4.4 4.8 3.3 3.4 4.7 6.4 7.9 8.5 8.5 9.1 35.4 31.0 12.4 251.2 71.0 i.i 1.2 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 1.0 1.3 1.7 1.9 2.2 2.3 7.0 7.0 7.3 19.3 21.5 20.5 16.2 7.3 8.6 12.6 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.8 1.4 2.1 2.0 1.8 4.8 4.0 4.1 3.7 4.2 4.2 4.0 5.2 10.6 11.1 1.2 1.1 0.8 0.9 0.9 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.5 1.9 2.8 4.1 3.2 3.0 2.4 2.8 3.0 2.9 2.7 3.0 3.5 3.4 16.0 127.5 10.3 55.8 12.9 36.8 — Emigration Immigration TABLE 69 (coni.). NETHERLANDS: INTERCONTINENTAL EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY CONTINENTS AND COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION AND ORIGIN, 1946-57' (In thousands) Asia Oceania total Indonesia Year Total Miscellaneous Australia New Zealand Total Miscellaneous z Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration 5.3 23.4 29.0 23.2 9.6 8.8 8.9 6.3 5.6 4.5 5.2 4.5 69.2 22.0 17.6 16.5 56.1 30.4 16.2 14.2 17.4 24.1 18.4 17.0 0.6 1.2 1.2 1.8 1.0 1.9 2.3 2.5 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.6 2.1 0.5 0.6 0.5 0.4 1.1 1.6 2.3 1.1 1.3 1.4 1.7 5.9 24.6 30.2 24.9 10.7 10.6 11.2 8.8 7.0 6.0 6.8 6.1 71.4 22.5 18.2 17.0 56.6 31.4 17.8 16.5 18.6 25.3 19.8 18.6 0.1 0.3 1.4 — — — 1.6 9.7 11.1 16.3 8.5 10.8 13.9 11.6 7.4 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.5 0.9 1.1 1.4 2.1 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.7 2.9 5.1 2.6 1.0 1.2 1.5 1.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.0 0.0 1.3 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.2 1.8 1.7 2.0 0.0 0.7 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 1.9 2.0 1.4 1.7 0.1 0.3 1.3 1.8 10.4 14.0 21.4 11.1 13.0 16.9 14.8 10.8 1.4 0.7 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.6 1.0 3.2 3.7 3.9 4.3 14.3 41.9 52.12 45.4 38.6 55.6 68.4 54.2 49.6 45.0 50.9 48.9 79.2 29.0 22.83 22.8 60.9 35.7 24.2 25.2 31.3 39.5 34.4 34.3 134.3 319.1 18.4 14.6 152.7 333.7 91.5 10.1 16.3 1.4 8.0 7.9 115.9 19.5 564.9 440.2 Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 7> O O z 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total 1 . . . Netherlands nationals and aliens. * Not including 2,076 emigrants bound for an unknown destination. 8 Not including 2,063 immigrants of unknown origin. z H > r S o < m I Z H m ^1 176 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Netherlands overseas territories l and Indonesia. Over the 12 years, returns from the latter country, swollen by a number of Indonesians or Eurasians who came to settle in the Netherlands, even exceeded departures—so much so, in fact, that they accounted for about threequarters of the total immigration figure. A comparison of the Netherlands statistics with those of the main countries of destination (other than Indonesia and the Netherlands overseas territories) seems to confirm their accuracy (table 70). TABLE 70. NETHERLANDS: EMIGRATION BY MAJOR COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1948-57 (COMPARISON BETWEEN NETHERLANDS STATISTICS AND THOSE COMPILED BY IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES) (In thousands) Country Canada United States Australia Emigration figures Immigration figures 127.5 55.8 26.7 91.5 127.7 51.1 27.3 91.6 The only notable discrepancy concerns emigration to the United States, and is due to the exclusion of movements of American citizens, whether of Dutch origin or not, from the United States statistics. Secondary Emigration Countries. There was no great flow of emigrants from the rest of north-western Europe, at any rate in absolute terms. According to their statistics, the four Scandinavian countries— Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden—together accounted for only about 210,000 emigrants, of whom about half went to the United States and most of the remainder to Canada. These statistics, however, especially those of Denmark and Sweden, are not altogether reliable, and, if compared with United States and Canadian figures, yield rather disconcerting results.2 In these circumstances, the figure of 210,000 can be regarded only as a very rough estimate. In any case, there were considerable movements in the reverse direction, at least towards Denmark and Sweden. There were also some 60,000 emigrants from Ireland, of whom nearly two-thirds went to the United States, and most of the remainder to 1 Surinam, Netherlands Antilles and Netherlands New Guinea. This is due at least partly to the inclusion of American citizens in the Danish and Swedish figures. 2 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 177 Canada or Australia. However, the Irish statistics, which include neither movements by air nor movements through British ports, seem to have underestimated the number of Irish overseas emigrants by at least 25 per cent. Between 1948 and 1957 nearly 110,000 emigrants left Belgium for overseas destinations ; only a little more than three-fifths of them were Belgians. Movements in the reverse direction involved over 50,000 people, which leaves an emigration surplus of about 55,000. Nearly 40 per cent, of the emigrants went to the Belgian Congo, from which about 50 per cent, of the immigrants came, mostly Belgian citizens returning to Belgium. The other emigrants went mainly to Canada (22 per cent.) and the United States (19 per cent.). If the figures for the years 1946 and 1947 are included, total gross emigration must have considerably exceeded 120,000. As regards emigration from France, no French figures are available. An estimate can, however, be made for the years 1946-57 on the basis of the statistics kept by the main overseas immigration countries. According to this estimate, there were probably about 155,000 emigrants from France, including a little over 100,000 French nationals, most of whom went to the United States (40 per cent.) and Canada (25 per cent.). This estimate, however, covers only emigration to American countries and to Commonwealth countries in the southern hemisphere. It does not include emigration to French overseas territories, to the former protectorates of Morocco and Tunisia and to the former associated states of Indo-China, with regard to which no direct data are available. On the basis of information bearing indirectly on the subject, however, such movements seem to have been considerable, since between the 1946 census and that of 1951 the French population of European origin in all overseas territories rose from 93,000 to 157,000 people—an increase of 64.0001—while between 1947 and 1951 the number of French-born persons in Morocco rose from 98,000 to 114,000.2 It is, of course, not possible to derive from these figures any indication concerning the volume of gross emigration from France towards all the overseas countries that used to be, or still are, under French sovereignty, but it is probable that this considerably exceeded the emigration of French 1 See Bulletin mensuel de la statistique d'outre-mer (Paris, Ministère des Affaires économiques etfinancières,Institut national de la statistique et des études économiques), Supplément série études No. 33 : Le recensement de la population non originaire des territoires d'outre-mer en 1951 (mimeographed). 2 See Gouvernement chérifien, Secrétariat général du Protectorat, Service des statistiques : Dénombrement général de la population de la zone française de l'Empire chérifien, effectué le 1er mars 1947 (mimeographed); and Gouvernement chérifien, Service central des statistiques: Recensement général de la population en 1951-1952 (Rabat, 1954). 178 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 nationals to other parts of the world, and that the bounds of probability would not be exceeded if total gross emigration from France over the whole period were estimated at about 400,000. There were, however, numerous returns from Indo-China and from Egypt, Tunisia and Morocco. Between 1955 and 1957, 90,000 French people seem to have left Tunisia and 75,000 Morocco. Central Europe The movement with regard to which there is the greatest uncertainty and confusion is that from central Europe. This can be reduced to two major currents, namely a movement of German, Austrian and Swiss nationals from their own countries ; and a movement of eastern European refugees who started out from central European countries where they had been provisionally residing. There are four sources of emigration statistics for these movements as a whole; the German statistics, which cover the emigration of German nationals and aliens from the Federal Republic since 1953; the I.R.O. statistics, which cover all movements of eastern European refugees from Germany and Austria under the auspices ofthat organisation; the I.C.E.M. statistics concerning the emigration of German and Austrian nationals and of aliens from Germany and Austria since 1952; and statistics of the emigration of Swiss nationals and aliens from Switzerland. These statistics, even if supplemented by the official estimates of the Federal Statistical Office for the emigration of German nationals over the years 1946-52, do not by any means cover all the emigration from Western Germany, Austria and Switzerland : for example, only those of the countries of destination give the last place of permanent residence and the nationality of the immigrants. Thus only these data can fill the sizeable gaps in those published by the countries of origin. Federal Republic of Germany. Not only did many German nationals emigrate from Western Germany: there was also a tremendous flow of refugees who originally came from central and eastern Europe. According to federal German statistics, the German emigrants— either German nationals by birth or refugees of German ethnic origin 1— numbered about 485,000 over the period as a whole. Table 71 gives details by year and country of destination. 1 Together with aliens, most of whom were refugees, over the years 1953-57. 179 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 71. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: GERMAN OVERSEAS EMIGRATION, BY COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1946-571 (In thousands) Year 1945 \ 1946 2 1947 7 1948 2l 1949 2 r 1950 4 1951 2 ] 1952 2 / 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total2 Canada United States Miscellaneous American countries Union of South Africa Australia Miscellaneous Total / 59.3 105.0 15.0 6.6 13.8 2.3 . . . . . 32.2 25.4 15.6 22.3 22.2 15.4 17.9 23.1 35.6 22.1 2.7 1.9 0.9 0.7 0.5 1.5 1.1 0.7 0.6 0.5 7.9 14.1 6.6 6.3 4.6 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.3 3.0 8.0 \ 9.0 ) 12.0 \ 15.0 J 35.0 61.0 \ 59.0 59.8 60.6 47.0 66.7 50.2 . . . 177.0 219.1 21.7 11.0 53.3 3.2 485.3 • • • . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 The figures in this table comprise the estimates of the Federal Statistical Office for the emigration of German nationals between 1945 and 1952 and the official emigration figures for the years 1953-57, including aliens, who numbered about 25,000 over those five years. a Estimated figures. See Wirtschaft und Statistik, op. cit., Sixth Year, No. 6, June 1954, p. 276. Forty-five per cent, of these emigrants went to the United States, 36 per cent, to Canada and 11 per cent, to Australia. A comparison of the German figures with those of the main countries of destination reveals that the number of emigrating German nationals was considerably underestimated, to the extent of at least 70,000 persons.1 As for the refugees from eastern Europe and others of non-German stock who left Germany, most of them emigrated under the auspices of the I.R.O. That organisation's statistics for the years 1947-51 list a total of some 530,000 persons 2 as having emigrated overseas from Germany. Their distribution by country of destination is given in table 72. Another 35,000-odd foreign refugees left Germany after the beginning of 1952, but most of them are included in the emigration statistics of the Federal Republic. Here again, the statistics of the countries of destination seem to show that higher numbers were involved, probably because the I.R.O. did not control all refugee movements from central 1 This underestimation, however, relates almost exclusively to the early post-war years. 2 Excluding movements to Israel. 180 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 72. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: NON-GERMAN REFUGEES EMIGRATING OVERSEAS, BY COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1947-51 Country Canada United States Brazil Venezuela Other Latin American countries Australia Other . . Total . . . Figures in thousands Percentages 83.4 273.5 16.7 8.1 10.0 134.2 4.6 15.7 51.5 3.1 1.6 1.9 25.3 0.9 530.7 100.0 and eastern Europe. The correct figure seems to be about 600,000, of whom 530,000 were recorded by the I.R.O. and 25,000 by the Federal Statistical Office. Thus the total number of overseas emigrants from Germany over the period as a whole seems to have considerably exceeded 1 million, of whom less than 45 per cent, were Germans and over 55 per cent, foreign refugees. Most of these emigrants went to North America, which took in four-fifths altogether. Very few emigrants returned to Germany. Austria and Switzerland. Very few Austrians emigrated overseas from their own country: for the period as a whole they can be estimated at about 105,00o.1 However, Austria was the starting point for a much larger movement of foreign refugees, of whom some, totalling about 95,000, were moved by the I.R.O. between 1947 and 1951 and others, totalling about 110,000, left under the auspices of I.C.E.M. between 1952 and 1957.2 Over the period as a whole, overseas emigration from Austria seems to have involved a total of some 310,000 people, of whom three-fifths apparently went to North America. 1 Including a proportion, quite high towards the end of the period, of refugees of German ethnic origin who acquired Austrian nationality in the meantime, so that the figure for the emigration of Austrians in a stricter sense was even lower than that given above. 2 It is true that the I.C.E.M. figures for 1956-57 include a large majority of Hungarian refugees who stayed in Austria for less than one year and who were not really, for statistical purposes, emigrants from Austria. 181 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS TABLE 73. REFUGEES RESETTLED BY THE I.R.O. IN COUNTRIES OUTSIDE EUROPE (EXCLUDING ISRAEL), BY NATIONALITY AND COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1947-51 (In thousands) Nationality Canada United States Baits Hungarians . . . Poles Russians and Ukrainians . . Czechoslovaks . . Yugoslavs . . . . Miscellaneous and not stated . . . 21.3 7.5 47.0 77.5 16.7 110.6 1.7 2.0 2.8 1.4 3.1 7.8 1.4 3.1 6.6 35.7 13.3 60.3 2.0 2.2 5.7 141.1 47.9 240.8 23.2 5.9 9.8 60.7 8.1 17.2 2.7 0.8 2.0 6.4 1.5 2.6 4.4 0.6 10.1 25.2 9.9 23.4 5.6 1.4 3.8 128.2 28.2 68.9 8.8 38.1 5.2 6.1 6.5 14.4 12.0 91.1 Total . . . 123.5 328.9 17.3 28.8 32.7 182.1 33.0 746.2 Venezuela Brazil Argentina Australia Miscellaneous Total On the other hand, most of the few emigrants from Switzerland— about 30,000 persons1—were Swiss nationals. As in the cases of Germany and Austria, North America was by far the main area of destination. The estimates used in the cases of Germany and Austria, however, are not altogether reliable. The statistics of the overseas immigration countries themselves are not always broken down by country of origin and by nationality, and where such breakdowns are made, as in Canada and Australia, refugees from Germany or Austria are often listed as coming from their country of origin and not from that of last permanent residence. As a result there is some uncertainty as to the breakdown of such refugee movements by country of actual departure. It does seem, at any rate, that few of them 2 emigrated overseas without first staying for over a year in central or western Europe. Nor is a breakdown by nationality available for refugees leaving Germany and Austria. The only breakdown that can be given is that for movements under I.R.O. supervision to overseas countries other than Israel from 1947 tò 1951. This is given in table 73. Southern Europe Most of the emigrants from southern Europe came from Italy, but Spain and Portugal also accounted for large numbers. 1 According to Swiss statistics at any rate; but they too seem to underestimate the number of emigrants considerably. 2 Other than the Hungarian refugees in 1956-57. 182 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 in I d <N Ü m m lu lì 1 iti 3 il ! Ì5! 1 âl III 111 ] I in i 1« ill U in in ! ¡j ill M | ill J >• u-i O ci 5 d « ' rt —¡ d Ò « t n c i c i CS —¡ ^ N N / O »O T t M oo T t f i q w^ ^•^(NVOOOONTtoOC^CÏrO vo ci oo' rn oo ci C< t-; oo O ~ TT • * «S od m" c i c i c i « d »n (-•' m o © m CJ m »n •— ov vo oo -st OO d c i d ci ò d » ' " • " ' H r i ci p rn o©©ov«nu-}coovpr-;vo p ö Ö ci Ö rn r»' vo c i r~ r-^ *ri e-' p VO d o o ^ f ^ v i ^ í ' v o o í ' - r i ci VO VO p ~-<mi/ >^<Nr^r^av©'ncn Ö c i oô w-j r-' ci Ö rn" c i o\ c i - - " " N N N N M tri 1 O O Ö Ö Ö O ö d ö ö Ö *•* c i c i c i c i >-* ^ ö d - cñ --"* oo fi VI d C4 VO o - ^ -^ « c i c i ~ ' i/S c i c i c i c i VO vi CJ v o - h C i O N O f n o \ i n o CI o - ^ ^ f y d o N c K r - ' - * c i oo vd VO d t n ^ h v ì M o ò a i ^ ^ ^ - ci ON 00 r^'*i-vqrn»nvO'sj-mavmr~ ©r^avoooòv-icn-Hrnoód OS VO ci VO r i oo r i r- ^ i n r- t>; \D y ; o d r n - ' t f - r n ^ - r n c i c i c i r n ' n VO ci ^ i n h v ì O N V ì q r i O ^ ; 00 C) VO oó o M M « ^- -- rtoi n n CJ O w - H M M i n v i « M n 1 d o © © d o d o — « ci CI . VO ©^l-p~'OC-;vO'^-rn© O r i 'O (*• - - oô c i r n o í oó N - (S N - H N vor~ooo\o — cjm^-mvo 0>OSC^O>0>0>0\0\CAO>0\ rn 5O 183 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS Italy. According to the statistics of the Central Statistical Institute, overseas emigration from Italy (both across the oceans and across the Mediterranean) over the years 1946-57 totalled 1,410,000 persons. During the same period immigrants from other continents totalled 310,000, leaving an emigration surplus of some 1.1 million persons. The distribution of these movements by year and by countries of destination and origin is given in table 74. The table shows how strong and steady was the flow of Italian emigrants from 1948 onwards—the years 1953 and 1957 being the only ones in which the numbers fell off appreciably—and the relatively small proportion of returns. It also shows that most of the emigrants—about 57 per cent.—went to Latin America, 27 per cent, to North America and 12 per cent, to Australia. Emigration to Canada, Venezuela and Australia reached appreciable proportions chiefly in the second half of the period, when the increase made up for the decline in emigration to Argentina. Emigration to countries in the Mediterranean Basin was on a small scale and did not balance the number of returns from those countries. A comparison of the Italian emigration statistics and of those for immigrants from Italy compiled by the main countries of destination will generally bear out the Italian figures (table 75). TABLE 75. ITALY: EMIGRATION BY MAJOR COUNTRY OF DESTINATION, 1946-57 (COMPARISON BETWEEN ITALIAN STATISTICS AND THOSE PUBLISHED BY IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES) (In thousands) Country Canada United States Brazil Argentina Australia Emigration figures Immigration figures 173.6 208.2 99.6 462.6 171.0 186.2 195.4 97.1 494.9 185.1 The discrepancies amount to less than 10 per cent. As regards Canada, the United States and Australia they can be partly explained by the non-inclusion in Italian statistics of the movements of I.R.O. refugees from Italy, who totalled 55,000. The refugees went to the following countries (figures in thousands) : Canada 7.8 Argentina 13.4 United States 10.6 Australia 14.1 Brazil 1.8 Miscellaneous 12.3 184 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 a il _H d .J. g vs CM Os r~ vi IN o , Os SO so Vi OO SO SO TT CSI VI so SO SO OS _ l Os OS OO on r~ CM CS OS „M so Ö h as .i s "4 1-a I as £ fi • s n f a il "T * * ä S! •ÏS « •A S 3 lì r- vi o r» 00 so Os OS CM ö O o o Vi Vi O .s II CM en O ë-a egä 2 , n II M •A S Sa E aS r •a •*Os <N vi oo OS © O ci o ,s « O _^Os -^ -*Os o o -^CM • * SO CM ci Vi CI m —" — H ci oo vi os - H o o ^H t~ f*1 Os CM Os m ~*Ci n o ci Csl 00 Vi rf oo so c~ ci m rt- ^ " ~*~'^ <N • * • * so rf Vi oo -H Ci p~ CM Tf vi t- Tj- 00 so ci Vi rO O <N Vi CM r~ r~ CÍ SO so es o o oo Os r~ SO Ci V» oo r~ ts os V> rs| <N <N CM IN ^ H ^ H (N CM <N r*1 O O Os SO Vi o v> VI TT ^ t— CM CM ci rr SO VI IN IN r- oo _w (N CM <N r*i r~ Os CM so <-* o VI r- r- CM • * so 00 O H 00 00 CO ™ oo n rt 00 00 VI Vi vi vi so Vi C-4 OS CM CM <N Ci Tt «ri O OS oo 1— m rl- CM Vi so • * *-*m p~ IN CM — ^—^ • * -^ '—i N. S ?" < — CM •^ CM CM en vi t- CM ci O O O o ~*^ ^ I-I 03 so r~ r— 00 CM 00 SO _ H 00 _ H Os oo <N CM CM M •A S CM o o o *s u p- 00 00 Os vi Ci O o o o n a J3 r~ o M CM o o o , a ¡3 m e-S ¿1 Î _ O 00 m O Vi TT Os M Ci O Os CS Tf vi SO SO V» »o SO VJ SO O o ci OS Os Ci O Os O ™ H en Ti- ci Cs| vi vi Tt- ri- so so 1 ™H —^ ' oo os' e-i OS "^ tOs' CM S < a o H * o so r- so p~ oo Os IN ci ri- Vi Tt TÍ- Tf Tf Vi vi Vi vi vi Vi vi VI os OS OS Os Os OS Os OS Os Os Os Os INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 185 As regards Argentina the explanation lies in the fact that there were Italian immigrants to that country from countries other than Italy. On the other hand, the figures for returns probably fall somewhat short of the actual totals. Spain. According to the statistics of the General Directorate of Labour there were about 570,000 overseas emigrants from Spain and about 160,000 overseas immigrants between 1946 and 1957. The net emigration figure was therefore about 410,000. Details of these movements by countries of destination and origin and by year are given in table 76. The table shows that emigration from Spain grew slowly after the war, remaining from 1950 onward at a fairly stable level of about 60,000 a year. The emigrants went almost exclusively to Latin American countries, especially Argentina until 1953 and Venezuela thereafter. The former country attracted 42 per cent, of their total number and the second 27 per cent., so that together they accounted for about 70 per cent. The accuracy of the Spanish statistics is largely borne out by a comparison with those of Argentina and Brazil. The Argentine figure, at 230,000, is slightly lower than the Spanish one, owing no doubt in part to the exclusion of Argentine nationals covered by the Spanish emigration data. Brazilian statistics on the other hand, set Spanish immigration at 83,700—a figure slightly higher than the 81,300 recorded in Spain. The difference is probably due to movements of Spaniards from countries other than Spain, particularly other countries in Latin America. Portugal. According to the statistics of the National Statistics Institute, overseas emigrants from Portugal between 1946 and 1957 numbered nearly 320,000, and overseas immigrants 43,000, leaving an emigration surplus of some 275,000. Details of these movements are given in table 77. As in the case of Spain, emigration from Portugal was particularly extensive in the second half of the period. Portuguese emigrants also went almost exclusively to Latin America, Brazil alone receiving threequarters of the total. There was, however, an appreciable movement to the United States and, in the last few years, to Canada. Returns were apparently few but they have probably been underestimated in the Portuguese statistics, especially in recent years. For the years 1946 to 1957, Brazilian statistics show an immigration of 232,000 Portuguese nationals, which confirms the Portuguese figure of 239,700 for the same period. Most of the discrepancy relates to oo TABLE 77. PORTUGAL : OVERSEAS EMIGRATION A N D I M M I G R A T I O N 1946-57* 1 BY COUNTRIES O F DESTINATION A N D ORIGIN, (In thousands) United States Argentina Venezuela Brazil Miscellaneous 3 Total Year Emigration 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . . Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration 0.2 0.4 0.6 1.5 0.9 0.7 0.6 1.5 1.9 1.3 1.5 1.6 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 — — 7.0 10.9 8.8 12.0 14.1 28.1 41.5 32.2 29.9 18.5 16.8 19.9 3.9 6.3 8.0 6.0 2.5 0.7 0.6 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.9 1.0 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.5 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.9 0.8 1.1 1.9 2.0 1.5 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.8 3.1 1.4 1.7 3.5 5.5 5.7 3.8 4.3 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.7 1.4 1.5 1.5 1.4 1.5 1.4 2.3 2.6 3.5 5.7 0.8 0.5 0.6 0.9 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.1 8.3 12.8 12.3 16.8 21.6 33.6 46.8 39.3 40.4 28.7 26.1 32.1 5.1 7.3 9.6 7.9 3.6 1.4 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.5 1.6 12.7 2.0 11.6 1.9 239.7 32.5 30.6 2.4 24.2 4.5 318.8 43.3 — 1 Returning emigrants. * Migration of Portuguese nationals and aliens by sea. • Mainly the Netherlands Antilles and Surinam, the Union of South Africa and Canada (especially in 1956-57). Thefiguresinclude emigration to France in 1946-48 and to the rest of Europe until 1954. 7> Z > a o z > o n > a o z LU 187 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS two years—1948 and 1949—and is probably due to the fact that at that time quite a large number of emigrants went back to Brazil after a temporary return to Portugal and were not once again recorded as immigrants on arrival. However, the Portuguese emigration statistics are incomplete in that they do not cover the very large movement to the Portuguese overseas provinces, mainly Angola and Mozambique, which took place during the period under review. Statistics of passenger traffic between Portugal and the overseas provinces from 1946 to 1957 show a net movement of nearly 120,000 persons, including some 80,000 to Angola and 35,000 to Mozambique. 1 Taking these figures into account, net overseas emigration from Portugal seems to have totalled about 400,000 persons. Malta. Emigration from Malta, though numerically slight, was very large in relation to the total population figure—the proportion being, in fact, considerably higher than in any other country. There were about 50,000 emigrants from Malta to destinations outside Europe. Most of these —over 70 per cent.—went to Australia, the rest being about equally distributed between Canada and the United States. The number of returns was negligible. The detailed figures are given in table 78. As may be seen from the table, there were considerable year-to-year variations, with two peaks in 1950-51 and 1954-55. Greece. As regards Greece, a comparison of that country's statistics with those of the main immigration countries suggests that they fall somewhat short of the actual figures. However that may be, Greek emigration from 1946 to 1957 can be estimated at about 150,000, and the figure 1 The detailedfigures(in thousands) were as follows : Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . Angola Mozambique 1.5 4.5 2.9 4.4 7.0 7.6 10.1 8.4 8.8 9.2 8.6 6.7 1.4 3.1 2.0 3.2 2.8 3.1 3.3 2.7 2.6 3.1 5.0 3.9 79.9 36.2 Miscellaneous 1.2 0.2 —. 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 — — 0.3 0.5 2.5 Total 2.9 8.8 5.1 7.6 10.0 10.9 13.8 11.4 11.5 12.8 13.5 10.4 118.6 188 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 78. MALTA : ANNUAL OVERSEAS EMIGRATION, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . To Australia To other countries Total 0.1 0.4 0.9 3.6 5.6 4.0 2.1 1.4 8.5 6.4 2.7 1.3 0.3 0.5 1.4 0.7 1.9 2.4 2.0 1.4 1.3 0.7 0.6 1.0 0.4 0.9 2.3 4.3 7.5 6.4 4.1 2.8 9.8 7.1 3.3 2.3 37.0 14.2 51.2 for the last four years at about 60 per cent, of this total. The number of emigrants was 20,000 in 1954 and 27,000 in 1956. In 1957 there was a considerable decline. According to the Greek statistics, as well as those of the major immigration countries, most Greek emigrants went to Australia (33 per cent.), the United States (30 per cent.) and Canada (17 per cent.). Apart from these three main currents, the only sizeable flow was to Brazil (about 7 per cent.). COUNTRIES OF DESTINATION Most of the European emigrants went to North America, Latin America and Commonwealth countries in the southern hemisphere. The rest of Africa and Asia attracted a much smaller proportion. United States and Canada Between 1946 and 1957 the United States and Canada together received over 3 million immigrants from Europe, or 45 per cent, of the European emigration recorded during this period. United States. According to the statistics of the Immigration and Naturalization Service, between 1946 and 1957 immigrants from Europe numbered 1,570,000, and some 135,000 alien residents emigrated to Europe. Net immigration from Europe therefore amounted to about 1,435,000 persons. A breakdown of these figures by year and by countries of origin and destination is given in table 79. These statistics, however, call for two 189 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS làl h If m m m m m lu n il ' !« lâl li ïâ! lâl l Ml o z^¿O oí" > <n NO O •o > r- o\ o ON c i (N 00 ^ (S o »n >»• *N «N v i NO Vi © ^ CN VI „ Cl NO O NO ON VI -* 5" t^ *N «N Vi ÔT NO oo «N O »O "Vi «N O O r- •** Ci Ci CO r~ CN r- Vi Vi O CI Ü2 C l ^ Tt ON CN (N NO ON C I CN Cl 00 O 00 ON O Cl Vi 00 v i c i O (M NO r^ ON r- ON wm( N Ci c i CN Cl Cl Cl CN CI ^t Cl c i _ "" "* — Cl ON Cl ON NO t^ ^t o t^ Vi r^ (N Cl • * Ci o c i Cl <N Vi NO OO c i NO OO 00 Vi Ci 00 NO r^ O Vi c i Cl Ci CN CN c i Ci Cl (S ~" Vi Ci 1/1 (S (S NO NO CN 00 t> Tf 00 <N O (S O iN m m (S r~~ r^ r^ oï <N NO c i • * "•* Cl Ci • * Vi t^ Vi Vi Cl CN O O o O o O O o o O O V i M o co o o 00 c i Cl ON c i Cl CI Ci Ci O <<t Vi Ci <s _- ° ON ON Vi 2 NO • * CI Ci 2 (S q Cl vi t - O NO ^ NO r- Cl CN CN \o Ci v i '- <* Cl CN CN r-; ON ON 00 r^ NO t - -* = m o O o O co vi NO <s es ON CN O O Vi 00 00 ON Vi Cl Ci Cl Cl NO O o i Vi Ci Vi tr, Tf v i O O © O O ¡Il c i NO O M Vi O ON il làl <N CN • * o ON NO d ci "* es c i «S C l d d d .¿ Vi Ci Ci O o O -* O Cl © Vi ci ri ci ci •"» "" *" -* O o * • " ^ (N r- NO oo Vi Cl 00 o ~ Vi 00 r-; r-; lâl O oo wmr* * - i O NO ON • * ON NO Vi •*r Vi Tt O T Í lâl O _ _ — ,_ _^^ o O O o o O o (S O NO •* NO 00 r- v i -* [^ <N (S - (S v i CI 00 ON ON ON o Vi ON Vi ON Tf CN O SO O Ci "* S CN O Vi lâl o Cl co M • * Vi ON O ON __— "" "" "~ "* ^ = _^ CN c i "* 00 ON ON O Ci Ci vï NO O ON d r- t ^ vo o O O v i CN CN _M co* co v i CN vî m 00 Cl Ci <N |âl Cl VI NO o 1 lâl Os IN o >• "n O c i •§ «N Cl lâl 1 - fN oo ì s £fe 0 NCi 0\ <vi lâl lu O Ci C l Cl —s S g 0\ ^O Ci C? Ci Cl NO CN o Ci Cl Vi Vi <* ^ •^ao ON Cl NO O O • * ON 00 cN ^t • * NO VI S Ci (N CS _ O O o O "" d O "* Ci NO Cl 00 NO CN ON CI NO ON O CN 00 " • NO d CN ^ ~*n "" Vi ~" <s r» o Cl CN V) Cl ON ON V i v i ON Vi ON VI ON NO Vi ON NO Vi "c5 o H II 190 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 observations. One is that they include a relatively large number of persons whose countries of origin are not specified 1, some of them immigrants from Europe. The other relates to departures and returns of persons previously admitted as immigrants: of these, only foreign residents other than naturalised aliens are counted as emigrants, and this necessarily leads to an underestimation of the number of returns to Europe. On the other hand, foreign residents who are registered as emigrants because they are leaving the United States for more than one year do not have to obtain a new immigration visa if they come back within two years. As a result, the figure for net immigration from Europe is not wholly reliable. According to the figures in table 79, immigration from Europe first reached a peak in 1949-51, during which period the United States admitted considerable numbers of refugees from central and eastern Europe. The proportion of Europeans in the total number of immigrants, which amounted to a little less than 60 per cent, for the 1946-57 period as a whole, was accordingly much higher during those three years. Towards the end of the period, there was another peak year in 1956 owing to the admission of further sizeable numbers of refugees under the Refugee Relief Act. This massive refugee influx was reflected in the tremendous proportion—nearly 50 per cent.—of immigrants recorded as coming from Germany, Austria and eastern Europe during the period under review (table 80). Thus, the largest group of immigrants—over 30 per cent.—consisted of refugees from eastern Europe. Next in numerical order came immigrants born in Germany (over 20 per cent.) who included a conTABLE 80. UNITED STATES: EUROPEAN IMMIGRATION FROM 1 JULY 1945 TO 30 JUNE 1957, BY COUNTRY OF BIRTH Countries Figures in thousands Eastern Europe 1 Germany United Kingdom and Ireland . . . . Italy Rest of Europe Total . . . 506.5 2 344.9 3 345.2 187.5 322.7 1,682.1 Percentages 30.1 20.5 19.0 11.2 19.2 100.0 1 Baltic States, Poland, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Yugoslavia, Bulgaria, Rumania and the U.S.S.R. • Including 183,000 born in Poland, 50,700 born in the U.S.S.R., and 44,300 born in Yugoslavia. * 254.6 for the United Kingdom and 65.6 for Ireland. 1 Over 90,000 for the period as a whole, consisting mostly of aliens who entered the United States as non-immigrants and subsequently obtained immigration visas. 191 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS siderable proportion of refugees, and immigrants born in the British Isles (19 per cent.). Immigrants from the rest of Europe only accounted for a little over 30 per cent, of the total; more than one-third of them were Italians. Canada. According to statistics compiled by the Canadian Department of Citizenship and Immigration, European immigration to Canada between 1946 and 1957 exceeded 1,465,000, accounting for about 90 per cent, of the total—a much higher proportion than in the United States. The details are given in table 81. Over one-third of the immigrants—35 per cent., to be exact—came from the United Kingdom, 14 per cent, from eastern Europe, about 14 per cent, from Germany, 13 per cent, from Italy and 9 per cent, from the Netherlands. Most of the remainder came from various countries in north-western Europe, mainly France, the Scandinavian countries, Belgium and Ireland. The number of immigrants from eastern Europe has probably been slightly underestimated in the Canadian statistics, which recorded some of them as having come from Germany, Austria or unknown places. Table 81 also shows that since 1946 European immigration to Canada has undergone marked fluctuations. Its volume was relatively slight TABLE 81. CANADA : EUROPEAN IMMIGRATION, BY C O U N T R Y O F ORIGIN, 1946-57 (In thousands) Austria France Western Germany Italy Netherlands United Kingdom Eastern Europe Other European coun-1 tries Total European countries (Over-all total) 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 0.1 0.0 0.6 0.8 0.6 4.3 3.9 6.8 6.0 2.9 4.3 5.7 0.4 0.5 1.3 1.2 1.4 8.3 5.4 4.0 3.7 2.9 3.8 5.9 0.5 0.3 2.5 2.9 3.8 29.2 25.7 34.2 28.5 17.6 26.1 28.4 0.0 0.1 3.2 7.7 9.0 23.4 20.7 23.7 23.8 19.1 27.9 27.7 0.2 3.2 7.0 6.8 7.2 19.3 21.1 20.3 16.2 6.8 7.8 11.9 50.5 35.6 42.7 20.8 12.7 31.7 45.3 46.8 43.4 29.4 50.4 109.0 0.6 7.8 49.3 38.0 21.3 37.1 7.1 0.7 0.6 0.7 4.8 33.5 3.8 2.3 5.6 5.3 15.9 25.9 15.6 13.1 13.5 11.3 20.4 35.3 56.1 49.7 112.2 83.6 61.9 179.1 144.6 149.9 135.6 90.7 145.5 257.4 (71.7) (64.1) (125.4) (95.2) (73.9) (194.4) (164.5) (168.9) (154.2) (109.9) (164.9) (282.2) Total 36.1 38.7 199.7 186.2 127.7 518.1 Year 201.6 2 158.0 3 1,466.4 (1,669.3) 2 including persons whose place of origin was not stated. Including Poland (81,400) ; Hungary (46,100) ; the U.S.S.R., including the Baltic States (42,700) ; and Yugoslavia (16,500). »Including Belgium (26,700) : Greece (25,200) ; Denmark (24,900) ; and Ireland (17,700). 192 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 until 1950 (except in 1948) and has been much more considerable since 1951, except for a marked decline in 1955. In 1957 it reached the record figure of a quarter of a million. Since the Canadian authorities do not keep emigration records, it is impossible to calculate net immigration from Europe directly. Returns to Italy and the Netherlands were probably few, and to central and eastern Europe negligible. The total number of emigrants to Europe is unlikely to have exceeded 150,000, with two-thirds going to the United Kingdom. All told, movements to and from Europe over the whole period resulted in an immigration surplus which may be estimated at 1.3 million. Latin America European immigration to Latin America, though substantially less numerous than to North America, came close to 2 million; the main countries involved were Argentina, Brazil and Venezuela. Argentina. According to the National Directorate of Statistics and of the Census, some 840,000 nationals of European countries were admitted to the country as immigrants between 1946 and 1957. They accounted for about 95 per cent, of the total immigration figure. During the same period, over 225,000 Europeans went back to Europe, leaving a net European immigration figure of about 610,000. Details of these movements by nationality and by year are given in table 82. These figures call for several remarks. First, they cover only emigrants by sea; moreover, they assume a correlation between immigration and the class in which a passenger is travelling. Thirdly, they cover aliens only. On balance, it seems that both immigration and emigration are somewhat overestimated. A new statistical series, which has been published for only a few years and covers all persons coming into the country with the intention of settling there, seems to bear out these reservations: for 1946-57, it discloses an immigration of very little more than 750,000 nationals of European countries. Data derived from both series are reproduced side by side in table 83. Both sources show that the huge majority—three-fifths—of all European immigrants over the period considered were Italians. Spaniards followed, accounting for more than a quarter. Altogether, an overwhelming proportion—about 90 per cent.—of the European immigrants to Argentina came from southern Europe. Moreover, the ordinary immigration statistics, even though they overestimate both emigration and immigration, seem to give a fairly accurate idea of the net European immigration figure. 193 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS s •¿•2 r^S w S à o -^N - v »O ON T* oo =§ ? è o if III fi* -^ M•<»• "X - V O <*> ~^, - N - N " O o-> O N rx K I N <N *o r-^ »o <*) • - i "-^ s ^n —O •^ •c> *-i —v oo "0 No o o ~-i oo " 1 fN-l ~-1 ~"1 • ~ 1 ro, «N ^ „ l~- r^ Ti- r^ ,-H ci oo s <N o ON ci _ -^ —N -^ "1 •fl- ^ i ON >*> * n IN -^ -> »NI -^>— s -^ °n rx •n s ON .^ —s ON O rs rs —v l\ • * ON NO *o tx ^-« —s IN <n « N rs • O NO x - i •»1 • * 00 >/1 r N C l O N O N i r i « CS rs rs rs I S > -—^ W lâl ts Tt ÖS Ü 1 >< 00 ON NO • * NO O N NO rs rs rs " H ci ~« ON ci Cl VI 00 Tf ^H ci CI ci O »-^ Tf oo O Tt- NO r^ *-* t-~ ^ •* rs o O rs Cl Cl O Cl Cl rs Cl • * rs o u-i NO rs' O IS rs' rs ci ^ H 1S r~ oo l~ O U-N O o ~H rs rS tS Jil NO r-_ 00 00 r - 1/1 c o rs NO Tf lâl 1 rs lâl 1d lâl o TJ- CS « ^ o o ON ts 1^ CS oo — o TI- CS CS I S ci 00 rs r^ f» ci rt «1 • * H-N r s fO ro NO »/i © d t— f S e n »ri • * r^ C l rs r- oo 0 0 r~ r-~ C l ON r s U*l NO M - S 111 TT lâl Vi o »-< (S r^ rs o o O —i rs l-H m ^ ^ NO s a |y .= § lMè» - 3 ¡ lu Iti s 1 , PI i >< ON ON Cl O ON m Tf rS TI- NO Cl r~ oo Cl oo t-; d NO NO NO O TI- TJ- o Cl rs Tf VI OO w-1 «n OO O N NO Tt • * NO OS ^^ ^ H >n O »TN rs rs NO m o o O O o o O ON NO d d d lâl S ITN u-i ^_ O l rs rs rs ^H ^H O O O o O O O a ,—1 ON ci lâl Ö ^-i J£ 00 ci ^^ „s ss ^ "O ^ H •3 2 H IN O ^H O es T j o o ^ o NO 0 0 T-4 í—1 o o ON Tt O Tf ^^ es rs rs rs t ~ C l o o O o o o o O O O o o Tt Tt ci Cl (S NO C l f i Cl o IN r~ Ci O C l rs rs rs • * • * o o O O o o o 00 ON r- tn O ,_ o IN Tf oo NO oo Tf Tf r~ Tl«^i u-i rs r^ 00 ON NO • M o 00 rs •* 1-1 ooH rs ^ NO Cl NO ^H NO Tt — ' ' r^ O oo OO OO m Vi oo o t - ON 00 ON ON t— •o co NO O N rs C l Tt t~ NO oo o T—1 " V Ì es I I 1 o t- ^^ e s 1 o 1 ci O O O ON • * ^ rt rs ts ON Tf Vi Cl rs OO rs —i r S CS rs rs ^ NO Cl w-i r^ —" ^ ^Cl Cl rs ^* *~* ON Tf T)- O rs Cl d rs "ci ^_ NO r^ oo ON CN| C l O Tt- TÍ- T t T j - W-N Wï W l W l ON OS O N ON O N ON O N O N MVI ON v i NO r^ w-i *ri V~i O N ON O N O H 194 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 83. ARGENTINA: COMPARISON BETWEEN STATISTICS OF PASSENGER ARRIVALS BY SEA (SECOND AND THIRD CLASS) AND NUMBER OF IMMIGRANTS INTENDING TO SETTLE, 1946-57 Second and third class passengers Immigrants intending to settle Nationality Italians Miscellaneous Total . . . Figures in thousands Percentages Figures in thousands Percentages 494.9 231.5 112.3 59.0 27.6 13.4 453.0 207.5 94.3 60.0 27.5 12.5 838.7 100.0 754.7 100.0 Table 82 shows that immigration fluctuated appreciably over the period under review, reaching a peak between 1948 and 1951 and falling off rather sharply thereafter. Brazil. According to the statistics of the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics, nationals of European countries who immigrated to Brazil over the 1946-57 period numbered about 500,000 and accounted for about 90 per cent, of the total immigration figure. A breakdown by nationality and by year is given in table 84. TABLE 84. BRAZIL: IMMIGRATION FROM EUROPE 1 , BY NATIONALITY, 1946-57 (In thousands) Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . Tota 1 1 Portuguese Spaniards Total Miscel- European laneous * immigration (Over-all total) 0.2 0.6 2.3 2.1 2.7 2.9 2.4 2.3 2.0 1.1 0.8 1.0 1.1 3.3 4.4 6.4 7.3 8.3 15.2 15.5 13.4 8.9 6.1 7.2 6.3 8.9 2.8 6.8 14.7 28.7 42.8 33.7 30.1 21.3 16.8 19.5 0.2 0.7 1.0 2.2 3.8 9.6 14.9 13.7 11.3 10.7 7.9 7.7 3.9 3.8 8.9 4.3 4.6 9.2 7.7 9.3 7.2 4.3 3.0 6.5 11.7 17.2 19.4 21.7 33.1 58.7 82.9 74.5 64.0 46.3 34.6 41.8 (13.0) (18.8) (21.6) (23.8) (35.5) (62.6) (88.1) (80.2) (72.2) (55.2) (44.8) (53.6) 20.0 97.1 232.4 83.7 72.6 3 506.0 (569.5) Nationals of European countries. 10 500 Greeks. * Including Russians and stateless persons. * Including INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 195 Permanent immigration in the official sense of the term may have been somewhat underestimated owing to the fact that the Brazilian statistics cover only immigrants entering the country for the first time. It does not seem, however, from a comparison with the statistics of the countries from which the vast majority of the immigrants came, that the underestimation is a substantial one. Table 84 shows that about 85 per cent, of the European immigrants were nationals of southern European countries and that the Portuguese alone accounted for 46 per cent, of the total number of European immigrants. The Italians accounted for 19 per cent, and the Spaniards for about 17 per cent. Unlike in Argentina, immigration was comparatively slight prior to 1950. The subsequent movement reached its peak between 1952 and 1953 and has since fallen considerably. As there are no emigration statistics, no exact figures can be given for net European immigration. Based on the figures of the main countries of origin, it may be estimated at somewhere between 400,000 and 420,000 for the period as a whole. Venezuela. In Venezuela immigration and emigration statistics have been published by the Director-General of Statistics and of the Census only since 1950. According to these statistics, about 490,000 nationals of European countries emigrated to Venezuela between 1950 and 1957; meanwhile, about 235,000 emigrated, leaving a balance of about 255,000, or nearly 85 per cent, of the total net immigration figure. Details are given in table 85. The two salient features of this movement are, first, its particularly large scale over the last few years, and, secondly, the great preponderance of nationals of southern European countries, who account for about 80 per cent, of the gross immigration and almost the whole of the net immigration figure. For the years 1946-49, the number of immigrants can be ascertained only from the statistics of the main countries of departure, which give a total of about 45,000 immigrants, including 24,000 from Italy, most of the others (over 13,000) being displaced persons resettled by the I.R.O. This would bring total European immigration between 1946 and 1957 to more than 500,000. However, the data in table 85 were obtained by adding the figures for three of the categories of travellers distinguished by Venezuelan statistics according to the type of residence permit held—immigrants, residents and " transients ", i.e. travellers admitted to the country for one year's residence. Of the latter, quite a large number actually stay TABLE 85. VENEZUELA : MIGRATION FROM AND TO EUROPE, BY NATIONALITY, 1950-57 * (In thousands) Ital ans 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 1 Portuguese Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration 16.6 14.1 19.9 28.1 25.0 33.4 26.7 24.5 4.7 7.2 7.9 10.3 12.4 15.7 17.7 18.4 5.1 2.2 1.7 5.3 7.5 7.8 5.3 6.0 0.9 1.1 1.1 1.0 1.2 1.9 2.5 2.6 188.4 94.5 40.8 12.3 Spaniards Miscellaneous Total movements by Europeans Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration 12.1 12.4 11.5 16.2 24.0 32.5 32.2 34.3 2.5 3.4 4.8 5.4 6.1 8.3 10.1 12.4 10.0 9.0 8.3 8.9 9.9 10.5 12.7 14.0 7.5 7.1 7.9 8.4 9.0 10.1 11.4 12.2 43.8 37.7 41.4 58.5 66.4 84.2 76.9 78.8 175.1 53.1 83.5 73.2 487.8 The figures apply to nationals of European countries classified either as immigrants, residents or transients. (Over-al total) Immigration Emigration 15.6 18.8 21.7 25.1 28.7 36.0 41.7 45.7 (69.5) (64.2) (73.3) (87.9) (96.6) (118.1) (116.5) (127.3) (41.6) (41.1) (45.7) (48.5) (53.8) (63.2) (74.5) (83.7) 233.2 (753.4) (452.1) 197 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS for less than a year and should really be excluded from permanent immigration statistics. This probably accounts for the large discrepancies which a comparison of Venezuelan immigration figures with the statistics of European emigration countries discloses. A possible further explanation lies in the arrival of European immigrants, especially Italians, Spaniards and Portuguese, from other Latin American countries. By and large, gross permanent immigration from Europe from 1946 to 1957 probably fell somewhat short of 450,000; over three-quarters of the total figure should be credited to the years 1951-57. The net figure may be put at a little over 300,000, the great majority of the immigrants being Italians and Spaniards. Thus, immigration from Europe, which was on a relatively small scale in the first few years of the period, increased considerably from 1950 onward, reaching its peak in 1955-57. The great majority of the immigrants—about 85 per cent, according to the Venezuelan statistics— came from southern Europe. Other Countries. On the whole the information available for other Latin American countries is much less satisfactory. It does, nevertheless, give a general idea of the size of European immigration to these countries. In Central America such immigration was slight and generally offset by roughly equivalent movements in the reverse direction.1 Mexico does not seem TABLE 86. URUGUAY : EUROPEAN IMMIGRATION, BY NATIONALITY, 1948-56 (In thousands) Year 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 Total 1 . . . Spaniards Italians Miscellaneous Total 1.1 1.8 2.9 4.0 3.8 3.8 3.9 5.6 4.4 1.6 2.9 2.5 2.2 1.9 2.1 2.1 3.3 1.8 1.2 0.7 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 3.9 5.4 5.9 7.1 6.5 6.4 6.5 9.4 6.6 31.3 20.5 5.9 1 57.7 Including 1,300 non-Europeans. 1 In Cuba, for example, migration to and from Spain over a period of ten years left an immigration surplus of only a few thousand people. 198 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 to have received more than about 15,000 European immigrants over the whole period. European immigration was also very slight in the Pacific seaboard States of South America—about 20,000 in Chile and less than 10,000 in Colombia. Apart from the three major immigration countries already referred to, only Uruguay received a sizeable number of European immigrants—some 60,000 between 1948 and 1956—over half of them Spaniards and over one-third Italians (table 86). Africa The main African immigration country was the Union of South Africa, which between 1946 and 1957 received over 175,000 immigrants from Europe. This figure represents over 80 per cent, of all immigrants of European stock. Movements in the reverse direction totalled some 21,000 and left a net European immigration balance of about 155,000. Details of these movements by country of origin and destination and by year are given in table 87. Three-fifths of the immigrants (i.e. 105,000) came from the United Kingdom, 27,000 from the Netherlands, 16,000 from Western Germany and 13,000 from Italy. The only notable emigration movement was to the United Kingdom, which accounted for about 18,000 people out of a total of 21,000. Over the years 1946-57 the countries that now form the Central African Federation—Nyasaland, Northern Rhodesia and, principally, Southern Rhodesia—also received European immigrants in large numbers. By the end of October 1954 Southern Rhodesia alone had received some 40,000 immigrants from the United Kingdom and between 2,000 and 3,000 from other European countries.1 In 1955-57 the three territories of the Federation received over 30,000 immigrants from Europe, almost nine-tenths of them from the United Kingdom2, the figure for the entire period being 90,000, if not more. An overwhelming majority of the immigrants were British. The proportion of returns does not seem to have exceeded one-quarter. 1 Economic and Statistical Bulletin of Southern Rhodesia (Central African Statistical Office), Vol. XXI, No. 24, 21 Mar. 1954. 2 The detailed figures (in thousands) were as follows : Year 1955 1956 1957 United Kingdom Rest of Europe Total for Europe (Over-all total) 6.4 9.6 10.3 1.2 2.0 2.0 7.6 11.6 12.3 (19.6) (25.6) (23.7) TABLE 87. UNION OF SOUTH AFRICA: MIGRATION FROM AND TO EUROPE, BY COUNTRIES OF ORIGIN AND DESTINATION, 1946-57 (In thousands) Western Germany Italy Year Immigration Emigration Immigration Netherlands Emigration Immigration Emigration United Kingdom Immigration Emigration Miscellaneous Immigration Emigration Total for Europe Immigration Emigration (Over-all total) Immigration Emigration z O o Z 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total . . . 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.9 2.3 2.4 2.8 2.1 1.9 1.6 1.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.9 1.7 0.7 0.7 1.2 0.9 0.9 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 1.0 2.8 1.3 2.2 2.6 4.5 3.5 3.3 2.9 1.8 1.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 7.5 20.6 25.5 9.7 5.1 6.0 6.9 5.4 4.6 4.4 4.5 4.7 2.4 1.4 0.7 1.1 1.9 1.3 1.0 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.5 1.2 0.3 1.1 0.9 0.9 1.2 1.5 1.6 1.3 1.2 1.4 1.6 2.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 8.1 23.6 30.8 12.5 11.1 13.4 16.4 13.8 12.5 12.2 11.2 10.7 2.6 1.6 0.8 1.2 2.1 1.4 1.2 1.9 2.0 2.3 2.1 1.8 (11.3) (28.8) (35.6) (14.8) (12.8) (15.2) (18.5) (16.3) (16.2) (16.4) (14.9) (14.6) (9.0) (7.9) (7.5) (9.2) (14.6) (15.4) (9.8) (10.2) (¡1.3) (12.5) (¡2.9) (10.9) 16.1 0.4 12.7 0.3 27.3 1.2 104.9 17.6 15.4 1.3 176.4 20.9 (215.4) (131.2) Z m Z > r S o S m Z H 200 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 There was also considerable European immigration to British East Africa, particularly Kenya, where some 50,000 European immigrants, mostly from Europe (or more precisely from the United Kingdom), were recorded between 1946 and 1956.1 Over the years 1954-56 alone, the number of immigrants from Europe exceeded 16,000. In Tanganyika the number of new immigrants of European stock considerably exceeded 35,000 between 1946 and 1957. Here again a large proportion came from the United Kingdom.2 The figures for Uganda are almost as high. Immigration from Europe was also heavy in other African territories under European administration. According to Portuguese figures already cited3, net immigration from Portugal to Angola came to about 80,000 and from Portugal to Mozambique to more than 35,000 between 1946 and 1957. There is less information on French immigration to the French territories in Africa, which seems to have left a surplus of some 60,000 people 4, half of them in the territories of French West Africa alone, between the 1946 and 1951 censuses. Both in the Portuguese and in the French territories immigration other than from the mother country appears to have been comparatively unimportant. The same may be said of the Belgian Congo, which between 1948 and 1956 received some 40,000 emigrants from Belgium, mostly Belgians, while returns to Belgium were almost half as numerous. In British West Africa, between 1949 and 1957, over 25,000 immigrants arrived from the United Kingdom; this figure, however, was very nearly offset by a movement of about 20,000 persons in the reverse direction. On the other hand, owing to the non-inclusion of movements by air, movements in both directions have probably been underestimated to quite a considerable extent. In Morocco and Tunisia the predominance of French immigrants does not seem to have been as marked as in the French Overseas Territories: since 1946 a number of Spanish and Portuguese nationals have settled in the first of these countries and Italians in the second. Although French immigration to Morocco remained considerable until 1955, the large number of people who returned to France after that date makes it doubtful that arrivals actually exceeded departures over the period as a whole. In Tunisia, there was quite definitely a positive French emigration balance. 1 See Colony and Protectorate of Kenya : Statistical Abstract (Nairobi, Government Printer), 1955 and 1956. 2 Statistical Abstract of Tanganyika (Nairobi, East African Statistical Department), 1938-51 and 1956. 3 See above, p. 187. 4 See Bulletin mensuel de statistique d'outre-mer, op. cit. ; and Population (Paris, Institut national d'études démographiques), No. 3, July-Sep. 1954, pp. 532-533. INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 201 In Egypt European immigration was of a highly international character and included French, British, Italian and Greek nationals. Here also, there was a turning of the tide in 1956 and 1957, when many people returned not only to the United Kingdom and France but also to Italy. Asia The only Asian countries to receive immigrants from Europe in any appreciable numbers were the former colonies of the United Kingdom, France and the Netherlands. While there is no statistical information from either French or local sources concerning French movements to and from the countries of the former Indo-Chinese Union, there can be no doubt that emigration from that area substantially exceeded immigration towards it. A similar trend for India, Pakistan, Ceylon and Indonesia is revealed by the British statistics and, even more so, by those of the Netherlands. Actually, European immigration to these countries had always been of a more or less temporary nature, and the political events of the past decade merely amplified the traditional flow of Europebound returns. In addition to European repatriations, a sizeable number of persons of Asian origin emigrated from these areas to the former administering countries.1 Australia and New Zealand Between 1946 and 1957 Oceania was a major pole of attraction for European emigrants—the most important, in fact, after the American Continent. Altogether, it received about 1.25 million immigrants, the great majority of whom settled in Australia. Australia. From 1946 to 1957, according to the Commonwealth Bureau of Census and Statistics, Australia received 1,090,000 immigrants from Europe, representing over 85 per cent, of the total immigration figure. Emigration to Europe for the same period involved about 180,000 persons, leaving a surplus of over 900,000. Details of these movements by year and by country of origin and destination are given in table 88. Immigration from the United Kingdom was by far the largest (about 40 per cent.) but so was emigration to that country. Immigrants from Western Germany (17 per cent.) and from Austria were chiefly refugees 1 See above, pp. 172 and 176. 202 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 ü Î I il I if a if Ü H 1 Î i il i il il W * J 1il il 1 il il I il il lì il il il ! î "~N—"\~N " N —N - V —N —s —V "~*\ "~V -^\ C2. s * _ > — " — - > •**, ^ •*-, s ^ . - ^ , - ^ ^ -*< o s " n o o o \ o \ f i H o o o o \ o \ H oo \ o r-' os r i c i od o í ~ © —' r i — „- — — r ^ r ^ r ^ r ^ o ONO>cnooowi'— OS O r ^ p - ^ - o o fi oo oo o • o i n \ q \ o ^ D \ o \ q r n N M ^ o r | tri CI O ri TJ-" - ' r i ò \ o T f v i co ^ o\^' ^H* -Î oó f ^ - ^ n Tt ^ oo oó \ o "n T f ri - - n r i r - ' c J i o c o t o i o V Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ó vi oo Ö —* —" (^—-Tt-HVOr^oOtN-^^OOON d o d « oí r i r i oí n - H ' r>" - r j ^ T t ^ « n \ o v j v ì w v ì O ò d d d o o « ri ri ri n ^ © r o v o o ^ o ^ - o r - O N u - i o r i © © r i c ì v o o s O N T ^ i o r ^ o o o ó O O « - ; — « r « ^ N r l n CT\ oo t oo r j ^ n T i ; 0 \ q o o r v r > T f O M n o -H" J - ' « ' r i <-' r i o \ d d \o 00 Ó Ö Ö ÖÖ Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö Ö O n - © © © —'f^irj-ior-'—« ö ö ö ö d d d ö ö ö ö —* y-» — ' t n o o m o O ( * ì - ^ O N r « ^ o o Ó ^ o í r i r ^ ^ o o o o f ^ o Ñ v d » o i n v^ *—• —i O O O O O O O O O - " oo — <N ö ö ö ö ö ö ö ö ö ö d ö © 0 - ^ - - 0 \ p ^ o o o o T í ; \ o p r j r ¡ d o d MÍ ^ ri d d « vi ^ ^' v o r - o o o s O — N M T } - i r \ û r 0 \ 0 > 0 > 0 \ O N O \ 0 \ 0 \ O N O \ 0 \ 0 \ ri 'S o H 203 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS of non-German stock moved under I.R.O. auspices. A breakdown of the movement by nationality gives an idea of the number of immigrants who came indirectly from eastern Europe through Western Germany, Austria and Italy: there were nearly 200,000 between 1 October 1945 and 30 September 1957 (as compared with not more than 70,000 German and Austrian immigrants during the same period).1 Immigration from southern Europe (Italy, Greece and Malta) was on an even greater scale, especially in the second half of the period; the total figure considerably exceeded 250,000. Italy alone accounted for 17 per cent, of the immigration from Europe. Finally the diversity of recent immigration was brought to its present pitch by the growth of immigration from the Netherlands from 1950 onwards. Immigration had been slow to increase in the initial post-war years, but rose suddenly in 1949-50, when the vast majority of I.R.O. displaced persons were admitted; it never reached the same level again thereafter, remaining more or less stable from 1951 to 1957, except for a marked drop in 1953. TABLE 89. NEW ZEALAND: MIGRATION FROM AND TO EUROPE, 1946-57 1 (In thousands) Netherlands United Kingdom Miscellaneous Total for Europe (Over-all total) Year Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration Immigration Emigration . . . . . . . . . . . 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.7 3.5 5.2 1.7 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.1 4.9 6.3 7.1 10.1 9.6 11.4 14.9 14.6 10.3 12.0 12.1 13.2 1.8 1.9 1.9 2.3 2.7 2.9 2.7 3.0 4.1 4.0 3.6 3.1 0.2 0.2 0.6 1.6 1.6 3.4 0.9 0.7 0.7 0.6 1.7 1.6 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 5.1 6.6 7.8 11.9 11.9 18.4 21.0 17.0 12.2 13.7 15.0 16.4 1.9 2.2 2.0 2.4 2.8 2.9 2.8 3.2 4.3 4.3 4.0 3.4 (8.1) (9.6) (U.4) (17.7) (18.2) (24.9) (29.0) (24.9) (19.5) (20.9) (23.0) (26.3) (6.1) (5.8) (6.7) (6.9) (7.8) (7.3) (6.3) (7.0) (9.0) (9.4) (9.2) (8.1) Total 16.6 0.6 126.6 34.1 13.8 1.6 157.0 36.2 (233.4) (89.6) 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1 . . . . Years running from 1 April to 31 March. 1 See Statistical Bulletin (Canberra, Department of Immigration), No. 25, Jan. 1958, p. 9. Poles were the most numerous (over 70,000), followed by Baits (over 35,000), Yugoslavs (nearly 30,000) and Hungarians (25,000). German immigrants numbered about 55,000. 204 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 New Zealand. The picture of European immigration to New Zealand is very different. According to the Department of Statistics over 155,000 immigrants from Europe, representing a little over two-thirds of the total number of immigrants, were counted between 1 April 1946 and 31 March 1958. This immigration was offset by the emigration to Europe of over 35,000 people, which left a surplus of some 120,000. There was a heavy preponderance of immigrants from the United Kingdom—over 125,000 people, representing about 80 per cent, of the total. Details of these figures by countries of origin and destination and by year are given in table 89. Of the other movements, the only one that involved considerable numbers was immigration from the Netherlands—about 17,000 people, representing over 10 per cent, of the total. The only considerable emigration movement was towards the United Kingdom, involving about 35,000 people. CONCLUSION On the basis of the foregoing statistical survey the number of permanent emigrants from Europe to other continents over the years 1946-57 would appear to have reached, if not exceeded, 7.5 million, including about 5 million to the Americas, 1.2 million to Oceania, 0.8 million to Africa and 0.5 million to Asia. It would also seem that movements in the reverse direction left an emigration surplus of about 5.5 million. The statistics of immigration countries tend to confirm the view that the figures compiled by the emigration countries are probably too low. The statistics also show that permanent European overseas migration figures cover movements of two different types : migration for long-term residence or permanent settlement in countries with a European population and culture, and migration to countries where European settlement so far has been essentially on a non-permanent basis. In the former case net emigration figures are high, whereas in the latter they are low and sometimes even negative, under the influence of certain temporary political factors. The great majority of movements to America and Oceania were of the former type, whereas those to Asia were of the latter. Migration to Africa included movements of both types, although long-term ones tended to predominate, not only in the extreme north and south, but in a very large part of the entire southern half of the Continent. INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS 205 Long-term movements may be divided into two major currents, flowing respectively from north-western and central Europe to Englishspeaking countries in other parts of the world and from southern Europe to Latin America. There was, however, cutting across these two main currents, quite a considerable flow of Italian, Maltese and Greek migrants to North America and Australia. Other movements were of lesser importance. Short-term movements took place chiefly between colonial powers and their present or former possessions overseas. Between Europe and Africa such movements expanded, whereas between Europe and Asia they became fewer owing to post-war political changes. Another difference between long and short-term movements was that the former, by and large, involved workers in all grades of employment, whereas the latter consisted almost wholly of highly skilled workers. In other words, long-term movements were generally mass movements; shortterm migration, on the other hand, involved mainly supervisory personnel and skilled labour. 1 Other Intercontinental Movements Other intercontinental movements were of very minor importance. Most of the migrants went to Europe, an overwhelming majority of them former emigrants returning to their countries of origin. These movements have been described in the previous sections. However, a few small movements to Europe and to other continents involved nonEuropeans. There were no movements of any importance from Africa except a few from British and French non-metropolitan territories to the respective mother countries, and a flow of Tunisians and Moroccans, together with much larger numbers of Algerians, to France. The American Continent, on the other hand, was the starting point for two substantially larger, and vastly differing, movements: a flow of migrants from the British West Indies to the United Kingdom, and a series of comparatively short-term movements of United States nationals to various parts of the world. The former seems to have been only partially recorded in British migration statistics, which set gross immigration to the United Kingdom from the British West Indies between 1949 and 1957 at some 55,000 and net immigration at about 40,000.2 According 1 See below, Chapter X. The Board of Trade statistics do not include movements by air; they count as immigrants only persons who state their intention of residing in the United Kingdom for a year or more; in addition, these statistics do not distinguish between the movement of British subjects of European and non-European stock. 2 206 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 to some estimates, the movement (which has grown considerably since 1953) has widely exceeded these figures and the numbers involved are perhaps twice as high. 1 Emigration of United States citizens is a subject on which no American figures and few foreign ones are available : it seems that the emigrants were widely dispersed throughout the world, mainly in western Europe and the Far East,, and there especially in Japan and the Philippines. Emigration from Asia was on a limited scale. From the Middle East, especially Syria and—above all—Lebanon2, there was a fairly large flow of emigrants (although it is very difficult to give an exact figure), mainly to Latin America and also to Africa and even Australia. Brazil received some 20,000 immigrants from the Middle East, Venezuela over 7,000 and Argentina about 4,000 between 1946 and 1957. Very little is known about movements to the various parts of Africa. From India and Pakistan there was a considerable flow of emigrants to the United Kingdom, which British migration statistics do not differentiate from returns of United Kingdom citizens to Europe. Europeanpopulated Commonwealth countries, on the other hand, received very few immigrants from either country. The other pole of attraction for Indian and Pakistani emigrants was British East Africa: some 50,000 non-European immigrants from India, Pakistan and Goa are recorded as having entered Kenya and some 20,000 Tanganyika since 1946; the vast majority came from India. From the Far East emigration to continents other than Asia was very slight (table 90). Apart from European refugees leaving the Philippines, Shanghai and Hong Kong, the biggest movement was from Japan, which some 50,000 persons left for America, the overwhelming majority of them during the last few years of the period. Between 1946 and 1957, over 30,000 Japanese were admitted to the United States (mostly as non-quota immigrants) 3 , over 20,000 to Brazil and about 4,000 to Argentina. Filipinos and Chinese also benefited, though to a lesser degree, from non-quota immigration opportunities offered by United States legislation, and the Chinese similarly benefited from Canadian provisions concerning the reuniting of family groups. Australia, for its part, received some 10,000 immigrants from China and 7,000 from Indonesia, the vast majority being of European stock. 1 See " Post-War Migration of West Indians to Great Britain ", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LXXIV, No. 2, Aug. 1956, pp. 193-209. 2 For 1952-56, Lebanon reports the following emigration figures without specifying the countries of destination: 1952 2,700 1954 4,000 1953 3,300 1955 4,600 1956 3,300 3 Practically all of them were spouses or children of United States citizens. INTERCONTINENTAL 207 MOVEMENTS TABLE 90. MIGRATION FROM FAR EASTERN COUNTRIES TO THE FOUR MAJOR IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES IN THE AMERICAS AND TO AUSTRALIA, 1946-57 (In thousands) Country of destination Canada United States Brazil 3 Argentina Australia ". China » Japan 16.9 21.4 1.5 0.9 10.4 0.6 31.9 20.5 4.0 2.4 Indonesia Philippines 2 0.5 17.4 6.7 1.2 1 The figures for immigration from China to Canada, the United States and Australia do not include immigrants from Hong Kong. On the other hand, they do include a number of European refugees, particularly in the case of the United States. The I.R.O. gives a figure of 6,500 people (of whom 4,800 went to the United States) for migration from Shanghai to the three countries in question. * The figure for immigration from the3 Philippines to the United States includes 1,700 refugees who were resettled in the United States. Immigrants of Chinese and Japanese nationality. Bibliographical References Apart from data published by the various international organisations, the following list of references (covering both Chapters V and VI) includes only official publications containing the migration statistics of the main emigration and immigration countries. For other countries, the sources are mentioned in the text itself. Use has also been made of data communicated directly to the I.L.O. International Sources JOINT STATISTICAL PROJECT ON EUROPEAN MIGRATION (I.C.E.M.-I.L.O.- O.E.E.C.-U.N.) : A Decade of Post- World War II European 1946-1955. UNITED NATIONS: Demographic Migration, Yearbook. INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: Year Book of Labour Statistics ; ana Industry and Labour (fortnightly). INTERNATIONAL REFUGEE ORGANISATION: Statistical Report, with summaries covering the 54 months of its operations (Geneva, undated graphed)). (mimeo- INTERGOVERNMENTAL COMMITTEE FOR EUROPEAN MIGRATION: Annual Statistical Report. National Sources Argentina. DIRECCIÓN NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA Y CENSOS: Informe demográfico de la República Argentina (1956); and Síntesis estadística mensual de la República Argentina (since 1956 Boletín mensual de estadística). Australia. COMMONWEALTH BUREAU OF CENSUS AND STATISTICS: The Official Yearbook of the Commonwealth of Australia ; and Australian Demographic Review. DEPARTMENT OF IMMIGRATION: Statistical Bulletin. 208 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Belgium. INSTITUT NATIONAL DE STATISTIQUE: Annuaire statistique de la Belgique et du Congo belge ; and Bulletin mensuel de statistique. Brazil. INSTITUTO BRASILEIRO DE GEOGRAFIA E ESTATÍSTICA: Anuario estatistico do Brasil ; and Boletim estatistico (quarterly). Canada. DOMINION BUREAU OF STATISTICS: Canada Yearbook. MINISTRY OF CITIZENSHIP AND IMMIGRATION: Annual Reports; and Quarterly Immigration Bulletin. Central African Federation. CENTRAL STATISTICAL OFFICE : Economic and Statistical Bulletin of the Federa- tion of Rhodesia and Nyasaland ; and Monthly Digest of Statistics. Denmark. STATISTICAL DEPARTMENT: Statistical Yearbook. Federal Republic of Germany. STATISTISCHES BUNDESAMT: Wirtschaft und Statistik, monthly (from 1954 on); and Statistische Berichte, Arb. Nr. VIII/26. Finland. CENTRAL STATISTICAL OFFICE: Statistical Yearbook of Finland. France. MINISTÈRE DU TRAVAIL ET DE LA SÉCURITÉ SOCIALE: Travailleurs étrangers en France. INSTITUT NATIONAL D'ÉTUDES DÉMOGRAPHIQUES: Population (quarterly). Greece. NATIONAL STATISTICAL SERVICE OF GREECE: Monthly Statistical Bulletin; and Statistical Yearbook of Greece. Ireland. CENTRAL STATISTICS OFFICE: Irish Trade Journal and Statistical (quarterly). Bulletin Italy. ISTITUTO CENTRALE DI STATISTICA: Annuario statistico italiano ; and Annuario statistico dell'emigrazione (1955). MINISTERO DEGLI AFFARI ESTERI, DIREZIONE GENERALE DELL'EMIGRAZIONE: Notiziario dell'emigrazione (June 1955); and Relazione italiana nel 1955, 1956 e 1957. sull'emigrazione Malta. DEPARTMENT OF EMIGRATION: Report on Emigration from Malta (since 1956 Report of the Department of Emigration, Labour and Social Welfare). MALTA CENTRAL OFFICE OF STATISTICS: Statistical Islands. Abstract of the Maltese 209 INTERCONTINENTAL MOVEMENTS Netherlands. CENTRAAL BUREAU VOOR DE STATISTIEK: Statistiek van de btiitenlandse Migrâtie. New Zealand. CENSUS AND STATISTICS DEPARTMENT (since changed to DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS): New Zealand Official Yearbook ; and Monthly Abstract of Statistics. Norway. CENTRAL BUREAU OF STATISTICS OF NORWAY: Statistical Yearbook of Norway. Portugal. INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA: Anuario demográfico. Spain. DIRECCIÓN GENERAL DE TRABAJO : Estadísticas de migraciones (published since 1954 in the Revista de Trabajo) (monthly). Sweden. CENTRAL BUREAU OF STATISTICS: Statistical Abstract of Sweden. Switzerland. BUREAU FÉDÉRAL DE STATISTIQUE: Annuaire statistique de la Suisse. DÉPARTEMENT FÉDÉRAL DE L'ÉCONOMIE PUBLIQUE: La vie économique (monthly). Union of South Africa. BUREAU OF CENSUS AND STATISTICS: Monthly Bulletin of Statistics. United Kingdom. CENTRAL STATISTICAL OFFICE: Annual Abstract of Statistics. BOARD OF TRADE : Board of Trade Journal (weekly), including annual supplement containing migration statistics. HOME OFFICE: Statistics of Foreigners Entering and Leaving the United Kingdom. MINISTRY OF LABOUR AND NATIONAL SERVICE: Annual reports. United States. U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, BUREAU OF THE CENSUS: Statistical Abstract of the United States. IMMIGRATION AND NATURALIZATION SERVICE: Annual reports. Uruguay. DIRECCIÓN GENERAL DE MIGRACIÓN: La inmigración en los últimos veinte anos (1955). Venezuela. DIRECCIÓN GENERAL DE ESTADÍSTICA Y CENSOS NACIONALES : Anuario Estadístico de Venezuela ; and Boletín mensual de Estadística. SECTION B ECONOMIC MIGRATION FACTORS The migratory currents described in the previous section, however diverse in appearance, have one essential feature in common: all are voluntary—albeit more or less spontaneous—movements of workers in search of better rewards for their labour and better living conditions for themselves and their families. They are thus linked directly with international disparities in level and tempo of economic development, and any attempt at explaining them will inevitably lead to the heart of this fundamental problem. However, no straightforward economic explanation-r-even if duly qualified by certain psychological considerations—can by itself account for the economic migration phenomena of today. International movements of labour are no longer, as they once were, the mere reflection of supply and demand on a competitive market, but are conditioned to a large extent by state intervention in a number of forms. Thus, while the same economic and psychological forces are still at work, they no longer operate unchecked but are shaped by political factors which include both restrictive laws and regulations and public policies deliberately aimed at promoting and planning such movements. The former are reviewed briefly in Chapter VII; the latter are discussed in Chapter IX. In either case, developments having occurred since 1957 have naturally been left out of account. * * * CHAPTER VII LAWS AND REGULATIONS In those parts of the world which are still governed—theoretically at least—by a market economy, men are far less free than formerly to travel from one country to another in search of a better-paid job or, for that matter (if unemployed), any job at all. Political and economic reasons have led all countries, including those which remain most attached to principles of economic freedom, to place strict controls on migratory movements with a view to preventing those which they consider undesirable: in this field as in many others, laissez-faire has been abandoned in favour of more or less stringent regulatory practices. Such restrictions—which over the past 12 years have given few, if any, signs of relaxation—are concerned far less with emigration, which is generally unopposed, except in a very few cases, than with immigration, which nearly everywhere has given rise to defensive measures.1 The main preoccupation, due largely to the influence of trade unions, is generally to protect local living standards and employment levels against large-scale immigration, or immigration badly suited to local needs. Often, too, there is a fear that admission of groups with racial or cultural characteristics too different from those of the local population will raise difficult problems of integration. Emigration laws and regulations, the restrictive effect of which is usually slight, will be considered briefly ; on the other hand, those dealing with immigration, which are far more important for the purposes of this study, merit detailed discussion and will be dealt with more comprehensively. Emigration Laws Freedom to emigrate is recognised by most national laws and regulations and in some countries is even laid down in the national Constitution.2 In most countries, even the provision requiring male emigrants 1 This situation is reflected in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights adopted by the United Nations General Assembly on 10 December 1948, Article 13 (2) of which mentions the right to emigrate but not that to immigrate. 2 Article 35, paragraph 3, of the Italian Constitution of 1947 specifies that the Republic recognises the right to emigrate, subject to obligations laid down by law in the general interest, and protects Italian workers abroad. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 213 to have first fulfilled their military obligations has been dropped. However, there are some exceptions. A Syrian law, for example, prohibits the emigration of Syrian nationals other than those covered by special provisions. However, such a blanket prohibition is exceptional. Usually the provisions apply only to limited categories of persons, whom it is particularly desired to protect against possible exploitation abroad or whose departure might be economically undesirable. An Indian Act of 1922, amended in 1938, which authorised the Government to prohibit emigration of certain categories of workers either in general or to specified countries, was inspired by preoccupations of the former type. It virtually precludes all unskilled workers from emigrating and provides for the effective enforcement of this prohibition. Similar legislation is in force in Pakistan; however, it has been used to control emigration rather than prevent it altogether. On the other hand, the emigration laws which have been applied in Ceylon since 1948 are dictated primarily by the latter type of preoccupation : they prohibit emigration for employment of any person whose recruitment has not been approved by the Government. Similar regulations govern the emigration of indigenous workers in African territories south of the Sahara. They place severe controls on recruitment so as to prevent large-scale departures from disrupting the tribal economy, and they specify that the workers recruited must return to their places of origin on expiry of their contract. However, while emigration in most countries is not seriously limited by statute, administrations have more or less effective means of opposing the departure of a given category of persons or emigration to a given country if they so desire. One possibility is to refuse to issue the necessary travel documents; this is particularly easy in countries such as Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain where emigrants must have special passports or passports bearing special visas. In Italy the prospective emigrant, in order to obtain a passport, must produce either the letter summoning him to the immigration country or the employment contract from that country; the bona fide character of such documents must be certified by the local Italian consular authorities. In the case of organised migratory movements, in which the Government is a responsible party, the authorities must further ascertain that the living and working conditions offered to the emigrant are satisfactory. Thus, the Government will not permit workers to emigrate to Latin America for wages below a certain level, and in 1955 it placed a temporary embargo on emigration of workers for employment in Belgian coal mines. In the same way— albeit for different reasons—the Spanish authorities refused for several years following the war to issue the papers which would have permitted 214 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 resumption of traditional emigration currents to France. Used on a very large scale, this purely administrative device could, even in the absence of a statutory prohibition, bring emigration to a standstill; this is virtually what has happened in the eastern European countries and the Soviet Union. Of course, there are other ways in which governments can exert a substantial influence on migration currents, e.g. by refraining from promoting emigration x or by encouraging emigration to certain countries. Under present conditions failure to intervene actively almost inevitably has the same effect as a deliberately restrictive policy. On the other hand, it may be doubted whether provisions adopted long ago by nearly all emigration countries to protect their nationals against deceitful propaganda and to ensure decent travelling conditions for them may be considered as restrictive measures. Such provisions are purely protective in intent, and their restrictive effect, if any, is probably negligible nowadays. Immigration Laws Far more important are the restrictive effects of laws and regulations dealing with immigration, the dual aim of which, as stated above, is essentially to prevent—(a) a deterioration in the employment situation and a weakening of the workers' bargaining position vis-à-vis the employers; and (b) altering national cultural characteristics. An attempt is made below to describe by broad regions the various laws and administrative practices designed to achieve this twofold protective aim. Other provisions relating to age, state of health or morality are less important for the purposes of this study and may be left out of account. WESTERN EUROPE Economic—or perhaps one should say occupational—regulation of immigration is most systematic and at the same time most severe in western Europe, where laws and regulations generally reflect the trade union philosophy that immigration must be resorted to only to fill jobs that cannot be filled by nationals of the country or foreign workers already established there. This amounts practically to restricting immigration to those occupations in which the demand for labour exceeds the domestic labour supply. Such laws, moreover, prohibit foreigners from moving out of a restricted group of occupations for a specified period of time. Once 1 See below, Chapter IX. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 215 this period has elapsed, they are eligible for the various agricultural, industrial and service occupations (either as employees or on their own account), with the sole exception of those from which foreigners are in any case barred by statute, i.e. the civil service and, in most cases, the professions. Practical application of the principles laid down by law is ensured through the procedure governing the granting and renewal of employment permits by the competent authorities, which in most cases are the labour departments. These permits, which foreigners must have in order to engage in the occupations open to them, are generally issued only after the employer has notified the authorities of the needs which he is unable to fill by recruitment within the country, and the latter, having satisfied themselves that such needs cannot in fact be met from the domestic employment market, authorise the employer to recruit abroad. Often, the authorities have the further duty of ascertaining that the candidates have the physical and vocational qualifications for the job. Permits are granted for a limited period, usually not exceeding one year, owing to the possibility of a subsequent change in employment market conditions; and they are renewed for an equal or longer period only if such conditions remain favourable. Thus, the function of immigration is confined to meeting certain well-defined needs, while at the same time protecting the local employment market from undue pressure likely to cause unemployment, to depress wages or to reduce job opportunities for nationals of the country in their chosen fields. The extent of this protection, however, is usually limited by provisions for the gradual extension of the rights of foreign workers as regards access to employment, ultimately placing them, theoretically at least, on a par with nationals of the country.1 Actually, the fact that this process takes several years, coupled with various sociological factors, tends more or less to perpetuate the inferior status of foreign workers, with the result that the protective purpose of restrictive employment policies is fully achieved. In some countries, however, the law makes an exception in favour of the nationals of certain countries by placing them from the outset on exactly the same footing as the local citizenry. This is done either by waiving the employment permit requirement altogether or by granting 1 The regulations and practice vary considerably from one country to another. In France the immigrant must, in principle, wait 14 years before he can receive an employment permit valid for all types of paid employment. In the United Kingdom, he normally qualifies after four years for removal of restrictions on his freedom as regards choice of employment. In Belgium, permits valid for all occupations are granted only to foreigners having resided continuously in the country for ten years ; for British, French, Italian and Swiss nationals, and for foreigners married to Belgian women, the period is only five years. 216 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 permits automatically. Such a privilege is enjoyed by Spanish workers in Portugal and, reciprocally, by Portuguese nationals in Spain ; by citizens of Commonwealth countries and Ireland in the United Kingdom, and by citizens of the United Kingdom in Ireland; by Austrians in the Federal Republic of Germany; by nationals of Belgium, Luxembourg and the Netherlands in each of the other two c o u n t r i e s 1 ; and by nationals of Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden in each of the other three countries. 2 Moreover, in several countries, e.g. Belgium and France, political refugees are entitled to preferential treatment. Other exceptions to the laws generally applicable are the result of decisions taken by various European regional organisations. Article 69 of the treaty of 18 April 1951 establishing the European Coal and Steel Community lays down the principle of free circulation between member States 3 of workers with " recognised qualifications for positions in such [i.e. the coal and steel] industries ". A set of admission regulations —fairly restrictive, admittedly—issued under this Article came into force on 1 September 1957. Moreover, a decision taken by the Council of the Organisation for European Economic Co-operation on 30 October 1953 (since amended several times, most recently on 7 December 1956) provides for a certain relaxation of the general rules governing the issue and renewal of employment permits in the case of nationals of the member States. 4 Finally, Article 48 of the treaty of 25 March 1957 establishing the European Economic Community, provides for " free movement " of wage-earning and salaried employees between the six countries 5 , to be achieved " on the expiry of the transitional period at the latest ". However, apart from these exceptions (of which the last-named is not yet in operation), the conditions placed on the employment of immigrants in western European countries have the effect not only of 1 The treaty of 7 June 1956 establishing a common employment market between the Benelux countries, which has not yet come into force, merely sanctions a longstanding practice whereby movement between the three countries was in effect free, permits being granted almost automatically; they have since been abolished by an interim agreement dated 20 March 1957. 2 Prior to the conclusion of the four-power agreement of 2 July 1954 establishing a common employment market, Sweden had already granted this privilege to nationals of the other three countries in 1943, and Denmark to Swedish nationals in 1947. 3 Belgium, France, the Federal Republic of Germany, Italy, Luxembourg and the Netherlands. 4 Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, the Federal Republic of Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom, but not Portugal and Turkey, which were not parties to the decision. On 16 March 1957, the O.E.E.C. further adopted a series of recommendations which represent a new step towards liberalisation but have no binding effect. 6 The members of the European Coal and Steel Community, except that the French departments of Algeria and the French overseas departments are excluded—at least for the time being—from the scope of the treaty. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 217 reducing immigration to the economically indispensable minimum but of preventing immigrants from competing on equal terms with nationals of the country and relegating them to an inferior position for a more or less extended period following their admission. No doubt western Europe has several regional " open " employment markets, but the European employment market as a whole still bristles with barriers which leave very little scope for the free play of supply and demand. In most cases, moreover, the law permits the immediate families of workers having obtained an employment permit to accompany or join them. However, these provisions sometimes include clauses concerning housing which, temporarily at least, delay the reuniting of households. Moreover, members of the worker's family who wish to work must fulfil the usual requirements for admission of foreigners to employment, and in so doing they are entitled to no advantages other than those established by laws relaxing employment restrictions after a prescribed period of residence (in the event that they have resided in the country that long before applying for an employment permit). On the other hand, nowhere in western Europe are there any employment restrictions based on nationality; but cases of unequal treatment resulting from the granting of positive advantages to certain nationalities under domestic law or international treaty provisions are frequent. Laws exempting nationals of certain countries from the possession of an employment permit have already been mentioned. In addition, various international agreements, for example bilateral or multilateral social security agreements, mutual co-operation arrangements between national employment services and, above all, bilateral recruiting agreements, have the effect of providing special advantages for nationals of the parties thereto. For instance, since the war Italy has concluded recruiting agreements with nearly all western European countries faced with a labour shortage, thus enabling its nationals to benefit by this situation more fully than they could otherwise have done. 1 UNITED STATES AND CANADA In the English-speaking countries of North America, i.e. the United States and Canada, immigration laws fulfil a dual protective purpose. The power of attraction of both of these countries is such that they have found it necessary to protect themselves against the economic threat posed by excessive immigration, while at the same time guarding against a massive influx of alien elements likely to alter national cultural 1 See below, Chapter IX. 218 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 characteristics. Their laws and administrative practices accordingly reflect a combination of both of these preoccupations and are, as a result, fairly complex in character. The problem, however, is not exactly the same in the two countries. In the United States, which is no longer in need of large-scale immigration, but nevertheless remains a major pole of attraction, it is mainly to keep admissions within bounds, so as to avoid disrupting the employment market and, above all, altering existing cultural patterns. In Canada, on the other hand, where there is still a great need for immigration, the intake must be regulated in the light of changing economic needs while at the same time attempting to strike a reasonable balance between economic and cultural considerations. As a result, Canadian laws and regulations are usually more flexible. United States The basic trait of United States immigration laws is the distinction which they establish between nationals of other countries in the western hemisphere 1 , who are admitted without restriction, and other persons, for whom annual quotas are fixed. Another distinctive feature is the method of fixing the quotas, which results in widely varying treatment for the different nationalities. Based as it is on the ethnic composition of the population of the continental United States in 1920 2, its effect is to reduce immigration from continents other than Europe to an insignificant level 3 and to keep continental European immigration (particularly from eastern and southern Europe) within strict limits.4 Moreover, visas both for quota and non-quota immigrants are granted only after the responsible authorities have satisfied themselves that the immigrant is not likely to become a public charge. Those who cannot show that they have sufficient resources must name a sponsor. Byway of exception, the law permits the entry of certain persons on a non-quota basis ; the most important exception of this kind concerns spouses and underage children of United States citizens. 1 Meaning persons born in another independent American country. Under the 1924 immigration and naturalisation laws (which only came into force in 1928) and those of 1952, the provisions of which are nearly identical in this respect, every country or territory under mandate or trusteeship is assigned a quota which bears the same proportion to 150,000 as the number of inhabitants of the continental United States born in the country or territory in question bore to the total population in 1920, provided that in no case shall the quota for any country or territory be less than 100. 3 The quota is actually 100 for most non-European countries. In addition, only persons eligible for naturalisation may be admitted as immigrants, and prior to 1952 the law barred most Asiatic races from naturalisation. 4 For example, the quota for Italy is 5,645, whereas that for Germany is 25,814 and that for the United Kingdom 65,361—a figure so high that it is never filled. 2 LAWS AND REGULATIONS 219 Before 1952 only numerical restrictions were applied; their purpose was to prevent immigration from rising once again to the enormous figures which it had reached at the turn of the century. By 1952, however, the view that the existing system of quota restrictions was no longer sufficient had gained considerable ground and the result was the passing of a new immigration law, the McCarran-Walter Act, which provides that persons wishing to immigrate to the United States, on either a quota or non-quota basis and whether for employment in skilled or in unskilled occupations, may be refused immigration visas if the Secretary of Labor considers that there are already enough persons in the country who are qualified for the work in question and that admission of foreign workers might have unfavourable repercussions on wages and working conditions in such occupations. In spite of its general character, this provision appears to be aimed primarily at nationals of countries in the western hemisphere and the unrestricted right of admission which they now enjoy.1 The new Act further provides that up to 50 per cent, of the visas granted to quota immigrants must be reserved on a preferential basis for candidates with special occupational qualifications. This provision reflects qualitative preoccupations of a type not found in earlier laws2, which had been concerned merely (since 1882) with health and morality. Nevertheless, United States laws by and large still do not assign any well-defined economic function to immigration. The only purpose behind the present method of apportioning quota immigration visas among workers and non-workers is to permit, so far as possible, the reuniting of families.3 Moreover, apart from the new provisions introduced by the 1952 Act, of which one has not yet been used and the other has had very little practical effect, no restrictions of an occupational nature are placed on the admission of workers. Finally, all immigrants, once they have been admitted and whether or not they originally declared their intention of taking up gainful employment, are eligible for all occupations with the exception of the civil service and certain occupations, usually of a professional nature, which are reserved by state laws for United States citizens or persons having resided in the country for a certain number of years; otherwise, there is no legal provision to prevent 1 The 1952 Act further empowers the President to oppose the entry of such foreigners or categories of foreigners for as long as he sees fit, should such entry, in his view, be contrary to the interests of the United States. 2 Although the 1924 Act established a priority in favour of agricultural workers, within certain limits. 3 The 1924 and the 1952 Acts contain similar provisions, i.e. they establish a certain priority in favour of the spouses and children of foreigners previously admitted and also of more distant relatives (ascendants and collaterals) of United States citizens. 220 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 foreigners from competing on equal terms with nationals of the country either in wage-earning or salaried employment or in most independent occupations. Statutory restrictions on immigration from continental Europe have, on two occasions, been modified by emergency legislation which temporarily expanded immigration opportunities for nationals of certain countries, for whom emigration had become a pressing need. The Displaced Persons Act of 1948 authorised the entry of 400,000 refugees from central and eastern Europe through anticipated utilisation of the quotas allotted to their respective countries of birth 1 , and the Refugee Relief Act of 1953 authorised issuance from 7 August 1953 to 31 December 1956, on a non-quota basis, of 209,000 immigration visas, mostly for refugees of German, Italian, Greek and Dutch extraction, and to some extent, for refugees of different nationalities, as well as for close relatives of Italian, Greek and Dutch nationals already established in the United States. Furthermore, a 1954 amendment permitted persons in the lastnamed category to take advantage of an unfulfilled demand for visas originally intended for refugees of the same national origins. These exceptional provisions substantially mitigated the strictness of standing immigration laws with respect to immigration from continental Europe. However, having been adopted for humanitarian rather than economic reasons, they merely confirm the more or less gratuitous character of established United States immigration policy. The economic development of the country no longer requires a large influx of immigrants —permanent immigrants, that is, since there is still a shortage of seasonal labour which is met by special provisions not included in the general immigration laws—and, on the whole, a tradition of hospitality, far more than need, is the reason why the United States goes on admitting any immigrants at all, the major purpose of statutory restrictions being to ensure that this concession of the economic to the political is not extended to the point where socially undesirable consequences may result. This is true of the general laws, in which the extent of the concession varies from one case to another, depending on considerations of political or cultural kinship, and to an even greater extent of the emergency laws of 1948 and 1953, which were inspired by purely humanitarian considerations. Canada Canada faces an entirely different problem, and its immigration laws are far more flexible than those of the United States. Not only are there no numerical restrictions but the Government and, subject to the 1 The actual number of immigrants under this Act was slightly less than 394,000- LAWS AND REGULATIONS 221 administrative regulations which it lays down, the responsible executive agencies, enjoy broad discretionary powers. The first duty of the Executive is to regulate the volume and composition of the migratory influx in keeping with the needs and possibilities of the economy. Thus its powers far exceed those of European administrations. Under this system visas are issued not on the basis of notified job vacancies but of needs estimated in the light of more or less approximate economic forecasts. Since any decision to admit a worker automatically extends to members of his immediate family 1 , the administration, in issuing visas, must take account not only of probable employment trends but also, in the case of workers with families, of the availability of housing. Subject to these economic considerations, the administration selects immigrants on the basis of their occupational qualifications. At the same time, however, it applies a policy of integration which necessarily, to some extent, involves differences in treatment as between the various nationalities. Based on the cardinal principle contained in the Immigration Act, that immigration to Canada is not a right but a privilege, the Government has issued regulations establishing specific rules which are more or less liberal from one case to another. These regulations have been modified several times. The version issued on 24 May 1956 contains more precise standards than any of its predecessors and substantially reduces the discretionary powers hitherto enjoyed by the administration. Under the most recent regulations the blanket prohibition formerly placed on the admission of Asiatics—with the exception of close relatives of Canadian citizens and a small annual quota of Indian, Pakistani and Cingalese nationals—has been lifted. The regulations merely lay down varying requirements, which are more or less easy to fulfil, for the different nationalities. For instance, British subjects born or naturalised in the United Kingdom, Australia, New Zealand or the Union of South Africa, citizens of the Republic of Ireland, French citizens born or naturalised in France or in the Islands of St. Pierre and Miquelon, and United States citizens may be admitted on the sole condition that they have the means of supporting themselves until they can find a job. Immigration for such persons is virtually free, except that the visa can always be refused in individual cases. The provisions concerning naturalborn or naturalised citizens of other western European countries 2 and refugees from any part of Europe are somewhat more stringent. Such. persons must either—(a) undertake to accept employment found for them 1 Except where objected to on grounds of health or morality. Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Federal Republic of Germany, Greece, Iceland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and Switzerland. 2 222 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 by the Canadian authorities or to take up employment only with the approval of the latter; or (b) be relatives x of a Canadian citizen or a person legally admitted into the country. Other categories of immigrants may be admitted only if they have family ties with a Canadian citizen or a person admitted for residence in Canada, the definition of such ties being broader in the case of citizens of certain middle-eastern countries 2 and of all European and American countries.3 The present provisions restricting the admission of certain classes of immigrants have superseded earlier ones which were far less specific. The law further provides that a visa may always be refused where a special investigation reveals that either the applicant personally or his country of origin have cultural characteristics which make his admission undesirable. Thus, whilst the regulations are more specific than formerly, the continued absence of any numerical limitation, combined with the principle that no one has an automatic right of admission to Canada and that the authorities may reject visa applications at will, gives the latter the necessary freedom to adjust their policy to circumstances obtaining at any given time, striking a balance between economic needs and cultural preferences. Finally, regarding the access of foreigners to employment, the laws of Canada are as liberal as those of the United States. Subject to the usual exceptions, i.e. the civil service and some of the professions, immigrants from the time of their arrival are placed on the same legal footing as Canadian citizens and may engage in any occupation, whether as employees or for their own account. However, a person having received government financial assistance for the purpose of migration may be required to work at his stated occupation for a year, or at least until such time as he has reimbursed his advance; but the Government does not always exercise this prerogative, and freedom with respect to choice of employment remains the keynote, not only for the workers, but for members of their families as well. LATIN AMERICA Latin American laws also reflect a dual preoccupation : to ensure so far as possible that immigration will serve the needs of the economy and, either implicitly or explicitly, to preserve national cultural characteristics. 1 Broadly defined to include spouses, children, parents, grandparents, brothers and sisters and the spouses and children of such persons. Regulations require, however, that any Canadian citizen or person previously admitted to Canada making an application for admission on behalf of a member of his family should be able to support him. 2 Egypt, Israel, Lebanon and Turkey. 3 The definition in the case of the favoured countries is the same as for citizens of the 15 western European countries mentioned earlier. For the others, it covers only spouses, under-age children and aged parents of Canadian citizens. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 223 Generally speaking, the regulations (so far, at least, as their purely occupational aspect is concerned) are broad and liberal. Their purpose is not, as in western Europe, to ensure that immigration is restricted to workers for whom there is a real, well-defined economic need, but rather to provide an outlet for all persons drawn to the country by the free play of market forces and able to perform a socially useful function. In Brazil, Chile and Uruguay, for example, the only condition laid down is that the immigrant's proposed occupation must be a lawful one and that it will adequately support him. In other countries, such as Argentina and Venezuela, a greater effort has been made to adjust immigration to what the economy can absorb: the laws require an applicant for an immigration permit either to have sufficient capital to set up his own business or to be in possession of an employment contract signed by a local employer. However, unlike in Europe, there is no basic provision which curtails the right of employers to hire foreign workers by subordinating it to conditions on the domestic employment market. Most of the laws also contain safeguards designed to prevent immigrants without means of support from entering the country and subsequently becoming public charges. In Brazil the law lays down two additional restrictions. First, it establishes quotas whereby the annual number of immigrants of any given nationality may not exceed 2 per cent, of the total number of nationals of the country concerned having immigrated to Brazil between 1 January 1884 and 31 December 1933 1 ; it further provides that 80 per cent, of the immigrants admitted under the quota system must in principle be farm or rural industry workers. In Argentina a decree of 1952 placed severe restrictions on the issuance of immigration visas for the Buenos Aires area and limited the automatic granting of visas for settlement in other regions to agricultural and other rural workers.2 Otherwise, occupational selection is not a major objective of Latin American immigration laws, although it is being promoted indirectly by organised immigration programmes aimed at meeting a particularly critical demand for certain classes of workers. Such schemes, under which workers receive special advantages, have been launched in Brazil and Venezuela, and also in Argentina, where a bilateral organised immigration plan was set up under various agreements concluded with Italy. 1 The Brazilian quota system, however, is much more flexible than that of the United States. The administration may increase the quota of any given nationality to 3,000, authorise carrying over the unused proportion of a quota from one year to another and even transfer an unused portion to another nationality. However, the beneficiaries of any such transfer must be agricultural workers. Moreover, the quota system applies only to spontaneous immigration and not to organised movements sponsored by the Government. 2 This decree was abrogated in 1956. 224 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 As for immigration restrictions based on national origin they are to be found in the laws of many, though not all, Latin American countries. No such restrictions, for instance, exist in Argentina, Chile and Paraguay. Where they do exist they are aimed solely at excluding coloured people and particularly Asiatics; in Venezuela, for instance, the law provides that non-whites may not be admitted as immigrants, and a Uruguayan statute achieves more or less the same purpose by excluding Africans and Asiatics. As a rule, nationals of European and American countries are not subject to immigration restrictions. In Brazil, where no nationality is excluded in principle, the effect of the quota system is to create wide disparities of treatment in practice. However, as already mentioned, specific provisions are far from rigid and leave considerable scope for discretionary action. Generally speaking, whether or not the law contains specific provisions, administrations usually enjoy considerable freedom to oppose the entry of persons whom they regard as culturally undesirable. The statutory safeguards established for this purpose may refer explicitly to race or nationality 1 or, e.g. in Argentina, to education.2 Moreover, bilateral agreements and organised migration programmes negotiated with certain emigration countries constitute an effective practical means of promoting immigration from those countries.3 Finally, continental and overseas migratory movements are often governed by different provisions, the more favourable ones applying to the former.4 Legislative provisions relating to the access of foreigners to various occupations vary substantially from one country to another and are on the whole less liberal than in North America. Restrictive provisions are by no means confined to the professions and the civil service. In Brazil, for example, some wage-earning and salaried jobs are reserved for Brazilian nationals, and in both Brazil and Venezuela the law requires a minimum proportion of jobs in industrial and commercial undertakings (two-thirds in Brazil and three-fourths in Venezuela) to be reserved for nationals of the country. Moreover, in the case of organised migration, particularly where special facilities such as free transport are provided, 1 For instance, Colombian legislation leaves the administration free to oppose on various grounds, and in particular that of racial origin, the entry of persons to whom the granting of Colombian citizenship is considered undesirable; in Brazil the law gives the Government the power of veto, on economic or social grounds, over the entry of persons of a given race or origin ; and in Mexico the law requires the administration to take account, when admitting immigrants, of their capacity of assimilation. 2 Argentine law requires that immigrants be able to read. 3 For instance, the 1948 Immigration Agreement between Argentina and Italy provides for the free transport of Italian immigrants selected under the scheme. * In Brazil and Argentina, for instance, the law makes it easier for nationals of neighbouring countries to immigrate and accede to employment. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 225 workers must undertake to remain for a specified period in the occupation for which they were recruited. In Brazil even spontaneous immigrants admitted under the quota system for work in agriculture and other rural occupations remain subject to this obligation for four years. Finally, the law usually entitles the immigrant to come with, or at any time be joined by, his immediate family. In certain cases—particularly in the case of organised migration—financial facilities are granted workers for the transport of their spouses and children. In no country, moreover, are any restrictions placed on the eventual employment of persons admitted as dependants. AFRICA The two aspects of African migration—movements of indigenous workers from one African country or territory to another, on the one hand, and inter-continental immigration on the other—are dealt with by entirely distinct provisions. As regards the former, the problem in Africa is the reverse of what it is elsewhere : there is a shortage of indigenous labour, and the chief danger against which the various territories have to protect themselves is depletion of their manpower resources. As a result, such statutory restrictions as exist concern emigration rather than immigration, and a number of territories have concluded agreements aimed at harmonising their emigration policies. Immigration laws, on the other hand, are dictated by other preoccupations. Their aim is, first, to establish police and health controls over the immigrants and, secondly, to guide the immigration flow so as to prevent workers from leaving the areas where they are needed and succumbing to the lure of the cities, where there is often a labour surplus. The Union of South Africa, for instance, has adopted a series of fairly strict provisions applicable for the most part both to workers recruited in the Union territory and to immigrants from the outside. The establishment of the so-called native labour bureaux in 1952 represents a further step towards closer supervision over migrant labour movements. The laws also contain various provisions for the protection of migrant workers. Immigration from other continents is governed by entirely different rules, the primary purpose of which is to prevent the entry of persons whose activities might prejudice the interests of the local populations or simply not make a positive contribution to local economic development. The means of achieving this purpose are much the same everywhere, immigration permits being granted only to persons intending to 226 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 set up their own business and having the necessary funds to do so and to workers in possession of an employment contract signed by an individual employer or company; as a rule, the proposed occupation must in addition be a useful one, and one that cannot be carried on by a local inhabitant. Most laws do not contain any discriminatory provisions based on nationality. However, in non-metropolitan territories the unrestricted right of entry enjoyed by nationals of the mother country in effect places considerable limitations on immigration opportunities for foreigners, particularly where coupled (as, for example, in the Portuguese overseas provinces) with administrative policies deliberately aimed at restricting foreign immigration. It may be added that, for reasons both political and economic, Asian immigration is usually not encouraged. Furthermore, statutory restrictions are usually placed on the free access of foreigners to employment. This may be done either by barring them outright from certain occupations or by placing numerical limits on their employment. In addition, immigrants are often required to deposit the amount required for their repatriation in the event that they become unable to work. In this over-all review, special mention must be made of the laws of the Union of South Africa 1 , which are based on preoccupations of a particular kind. The existence of two communities, one of European and the other of African—and, to some extent, Asian—origin, separated by a very real social barrier, has led to the adoption of regulations aimed not only at preserving the cultural characteristics and protecting the economic interests of the white population but also at preventing social debasement of European immigrants. The practical effect of all this has been to prohibit altogether the immigration of persons considered as incapable of being integrated into the white population —i.e. Asiatics—and to make European immigration conditional on the possession of an employment contract for a socially dignified and economically useful occupation. As a result, residence permits are granted only to persons who are engaged in certain occupations and who undertake to remain in those occupations for three years. By way of exception British subjects of European extraction who are citizens of the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia or New Zealand and citizens of the Republic of Ireland are exonerated from this requirement and are 1 The situation is somewhat similar in Southern Rhodesia, now part of the Central African Federation, where the law pursues a threefold objective: to encourage the immigration of European workers, to preserve the living standards of the white population, and to avoid hindering the occupational advancement of Africans. As in the Union of South Africa, admission of British subjects is unrestricted. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 227 admitted without restriction provided that they have sufficient means to support themselves and their families until they can find a job. Thus, elaborate legal standards regulate immigration of Europeans of non-British extraction and administrative practice in the matter is extremely cautious. WEST AND SOUTH-EAST ASIA In west and south-east Asia a trend towards immigration restrictions which began before the last war received a powerful impetus from post-war political changes. In these regions laws or regulations dealing either with immigration as such or with the employment of foreigners reflect a strong desire to reserve for nationals of the country all occupations which they are competent to perform, and sometimes (particularly in certain far-eastern countries) a political objective as well: that of preventing an increase in the size of certain foreign, e.g. Indian or Chinese, minorities. All of these laws, some of them quite recent \ are protectionist in intent.2 As a rule, foreigners wishing to settle in one of the countries concerned to engage in a gainful pursuit must first obtain a special permit, which is usually granted only if the proposed occupation is considered essential and cannot be carried on by a national of the country. The discretionary powers of the administration to grant or withhold such permits are virtually unlimited. In Syria, however, nationals of countries which are members of the Arab League are not treated as foreigners for immigration purposes. Although the effect of these various regulations is the same, i.e. to exclude foreigners from occupations for which nationals of the country are qualified, the specific provisions vary considerably from one country to another. In Lebanon permits are delivered only to skilled workers, and then only temporarily. In Syria they are granted to nationals of non-Arab countries only in the case of skilled workers or technicians and their validity is limited to one year, with the possibility of subsequent extension. In Iraq foreigners are excluded by law from many occupations ; however, these restrictions do not apply to occupations covered by agreements establishing concessions in favour of foreign companies. Apart from this, special authorisations may be granted by way of 1 The laws of Ceylon, for example, date from 1948 and 1955 and those of Burma from 1953. 2 Except in Israel. 228 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 exception for certain occupations in which special skills not available locally are required. In Ceylon, Burma and Malaya employers wishing to recruit workers outside the country must obtain permits which are granted if they can prove that suitable candidates cannot be found locally. Finally, in Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines, the national employment market is protected by the simpler device of a quota system. In Thailand the annual quota has been fixed since 1950 at 200 persons per nationality; in Indonesia the total quota is 8,000 persons, similarly divided among eight nationality groups.1 In the Philippines each nationality is assigned an annual quota of 50 persons. These quotas are filled by the responsible executive agencies on the basis of economic needs. In one form or another, the practical effect of these various regulations is to restrict admission to persons whose work is considered useful for the economic or cultural development of the country. These include experienced entrepreneurs with capital of their own, professional persons, managers, technicians and skilled or semi-skilled workers able to produce evidence of their qualifications and, in the case of employees, proof of the fact that they have been engaged either by the government, a company or a private individual. Unskilled workers—and, in some instances, craftsmen—are no longer admitted anywhere, in fact if not in law. Thus, while the new regulations in the countries of western Asia have not fundamentally altered the existing situation, the position is quite different in south-east Asia, and particularly in Ceylon, Burma, Thailand and Malaya, where a stop has been put to the massive immigration of Indians and Chinese on which these countries formerly relied for unskilled labour. AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND The immigration laws of Australia and New Zealand are similar in many respects to those of Canada. The problem itself is similar, if not identical. Essentially, it is one of reconciling a long-term need for largescale immigration with certain selective preoccupations, having regard to what is economically desirable at a given time as well as to preferences based on cultural affinity. The statutes, therefore, are extremely flexible in both countries, and responsibility for the admission of immigrants is largely in the hands of the Executive, i.e. the Minister of Immigration. Both in law and in fact British subjects of European stock are admitted freely to Australia and New Zealand provided (as in the case of all 1 Burma, Ceylon, India and Pakistan; China; Middle East; Commonwealth countries; Netherlands; the remainder of Europe; the United States; and the rest of the world. LAWS AND REGULATIONS 229 immigrants) that they have sufficient resources to support themselves until they can find a job. 1 The admission of other categories is usually a matter for decision by the executive agencies concerned. Such decisions, both as regards the number and the occupational distribution of the immigrants admitted, are based so far as possible on estimated manpower requirements. In other words, they are determined primarily by considerations of economic and manpower policy, and subsidiarily only by cultural preferences. Family considerations also enter into the picture, particularly in Australia, where the Government prefers to admit family units rather than isolated workers. In practice, since neither country can rely on spontaneous immigration to cover its needs, the process of selection largely takes the form of organised and assisted immigration programmes.2 This facilitates the solution of occupational and ethnic distribution problems. The laws of both Australia and New Zealand are very liberal as regards access of immigrants to employment : the only restrictions, by and large, concern the civil service 3 and some of the professions; these moreover, do not apply to British subjects. However, bilateral migration agreements between Australia, on the one hand, and Italy and Western Germany on the other provide that an immigrant whose passage has been financed by the two governments concerned shall be required to work at a government-approved job for at least two years. In New Zealand this statutory obligation applies to all assisted immigrants, including British subjects. Moreover, local provisions requiring the possession of a diploma for admission to certain skilled or professional occupations have a further restrictive effect. Immigrants enjoy full freedom to bring their families with them or to send for them later, on the sole condition that such persons do not fall within certain categories excluded by law on grounds of health, morality or security. Dependants have access to employment on the same terms as heads of families. Finally, the financial assistance granted to the head of the family to cover his travel expenses may be extended to the entire family group. * * * 1 This obligation does not as a rule apply to immigrants arriving under government-sponsored programmes. These are usually recruited in the light of known market requirements and can usually be placed in employment immediately upon arrival. 2 See below, Chapter IX. 3 Unnaturalised immigrants may nevertheless be employed on temporary government jobs. 230 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 These, in broad outline, are the various statutory provisions which now limit the freedom of labour to move from one country to another. With such freedom virtually confined to the few cases in which it is established by regional or other arrangements (e.g. those between the European-populated nations of the British Commonwealth), it may well be asked whether there is still such a thing as an international employment market, even among countries with a market economy. But restrictive regulations are, after all, no more than a reflection of natural pressures caused by distance, differences in living standards and, to some extent, cultural preferences. Moreover, while man-made restrictions may hinder or curtail certain movements, such movements nonetheless continue and are still determined largely by the traditional forces of supply and demand. Bibliographical References Analysis of the Immigration Laws and Regulations of Selected Countries, in two volumes (Vol. 1 : General Introduction, Selected Countries of Europe, Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Union of South Africa; Vol. 2: United States and Latin American Countries) (Geneva, 1954). INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: ORGANISATION FOR EUROPEAN ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION: Documents of the Manpower Committee (Restricted). X. LANNES: Immigration in France since 1945, Publication VIII, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhorf, 1953), Chapter II. A. OBLATH: "Italian Regulation of Emigration", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LVI, No. 4, Oct. 1947, pp. 408-425. " Inter-Territorial Migrations of Africans South of the Sahara ", ibid., Vol. LXXVI, No. 3, Sep. 1957, pp. 292-310. D. CORBETT: Canada's Immigration Policy (Toronto, University of Toronto Press, 1957), Chapter II. Law and Contemporary Problems (Durham, N.C., Duke University School of Law), Vol. XXI, No. 2, Spring 1956 (issue devoted to immigration problems). CHAPTER Vili THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY THROUGHOUT THE WORLD While today's economic migration movements, influenced as they are by public policies aimed both at controlling and promoting them, can hardly be viewed as a purely spontaneous phenomenon, they nevertheless depend largely on traditional market forces which in turn are conditioned by international disparities in level and tempo of economic development. In analysing migratory movements, it is therefore necessary to examine such economic disparities in so far as they exert a decisive influence on the employment market. This chapter reviews the 1946-57 period from this angle, describing first the origins and manifestations of the demand for labour which set recent migration trends in motion and, next, the manner in which the demand was met. Both mechanisms are, of course, interdependent: an abundant supply is of no use unless there is an actual demand, just as demand is ineffectual unless there is a supply to draw from. Although the two aspects have been dealt with separately for purposes of clarity, this interdependence should be constantly borne in mind. The Demand for Labour GENERAL The power of attraction of immigration countries depends to an even greater extent than formerly on the existence of a labour shortage on the domestic market. Such a shortage may be either general or restricted to a few occupations. It may also be either a permanent, structural phenomenon or a cyclical one. Finally, a labour shortage in some occupations may co-exist with a surplus in others and thus give rise to opposite migratory movements. The situation in immigration countries, therefore, is characterised by the failure of domestic manpower resources to keep pace with economic development and an expanding labour demand, usually because the number of young workers who join the labour force each year is too small, often because the existing labour force is not quick enough to 232 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 adjust to economic change, and sometimes for both of these reasons combined. Thus immigration phenomena can be explained only in terms of national employment market forces. Analysis of these forces is far from simple. Even where precise data concerning economic development, the labour force, immigration and employment trends are available—and they seldom are—the relationship between these closely interdependent factors is difficult to express in simple terms. Not even a long-term approach, concentrating on the deepseated phenomena underlying short-term economic fluctuations, can eliminate this difficulty entirely. Normally, heavy immigration might be expected to be a natural concomitant of rapid economic development accompanied by a slow increase in the labour force. However, this is often not the case in practice; moreover, the relationship, where it exists, is by no means a strict one. Rapid economic development may or may not create many new jobs : the extent to which it does so will depend on whether development emphasis is on the creation of new production facilities or the improvement of existing ones. Even where employment opportunities vastly outstrip the normal increase in the labour force or changes in the employment pattern result in a sudden rise in labour demand in the expanding sectors, immigration is not necessarily the only answer : there may be large labour reserves—e.g. women or farm workers—in the country itself, or high mobility within the existing labour force may help to remedy shortages.1 Conversely, insufficient labour mobility can result in shortages in countries with a rapidly increasing population. It may be added that the relationship between these two basic factors—economic development and the labour supply— is a reciprocal one, in that the abundance or scarcity of labour can be a guiding consideration in the determination of investment policy. Thus immigration, viewed solely as a source of additional manpower, and in so far as it is not related directly to a specific demand, is not only a result but also a factor of employment market forces. Moreover, considering the new needs created by the resulting population increase, it is clear that immigration on a sufficiently large scale constitutes in itself a basic factor of economic development. Thus, there are obvious limitations to any purely theoretical explanation of immigration. The problem, no doubt, would be simpler if the economic forces at work were not strongly influenced by public policy in an infinite variety of forms. The rate of capital formation and the investment pattern—particularly as regards the distribution of investment among labour-intensive and capital-intensive industries—are no 1 Resort to overtime can also increase the total amount of activity without any increase in the labour force. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 233 longer determined by private initiative alone. Furthermore, governments have the power to influence the size and structure of the labour force, particularly by promoting labour mobility; it is they who, by adopting certain policies regarding the employment of foreigners, determine both the function and the limits of immigration. Therefore, the economic, demographic and social factors conditioning immigration cannot be divorced from political considerations by which they are themselves partly determined. These various factors have led to a wide variety of situations, ranging from highly developed countries with a slowly increasing adult population, where the demand has been essentially for manual and comparatively unskilled workers, to the less developed countries subject to strong population pressures, where employment opportunities for foreigners have been almost exclusively at the more skilled levels of the occupational scale. The following is a description of the position in the various parts of the world, with an attempt at outlining the factors at work in each case. EUROPE Immigration in western Europe has been prompted largely by a labour shortage in heavy jobs which workers do not take up readily or which they leave as soon as other opportunities arise. Shortages of this nature, and sometimes very considerable ones, have occurred in Belgium, France, the United Kingdom, Sweden and Switzerland.1 These five countries are all characterised by an advanced state of industrialisation coupled with an extremely slow increase in the domestic labour force over the years under review.2 In these countries such shortages constitute a traditional, deep-rooted social phenomenon. The economic sectors in which most of these shortages occurred during the past few years were about the same everywhere. They included agriculture, mining, construction, metallurgy, domestic service and— though more sporadically—textiles. Most of the demand, moreover, was for unskilled workers. The relative size of the shortages, by industry, differed appreciably from one country to another, and in some the pattern underwent considerable change during the period considered. 1 The same applies to Luxembourg and, since 1955, to the Federal Republic of Germany. 2 The average annual percentage rates of increase from 1946 to 1955 were 0.12 for Belgium, 0.17 for France, 0.21 for the United Kingdom, 0.36 for Sweden and 0.41 for Switzerland (figures supplied by the United Nations). 234 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 In Belgium the demand for foreign labour was mainly, if not exclusively, for heavy work in mines and, to a lesser extent, metallurgy; at the same time there was a labour surplus in agriculture and textiles. In France the range of industries affected by the shortage was much more extensive, covering not only mines and metallurgy but agriculture, construction, domestic service and textiles as well ; in the latter industry the shortage resulted in heavy frontier movements of Belgian workers. The shortages were heaviest in agriculture (throughout the entire period), mining (during the early years) and construction (during the later ones). In Sweden the range of industries affected was also fairly wide and covered agriculture, domestic service, mining, metallurgy and textiles. This was also true in Switzerland where the heaviest demand was for farm workers, domestic servants, construction and metallurgical workers. In the United Kingdom shortages occurred in the same sectors, with a concentration in domestic service and metallurgy following the immediate post-war period. However, in the absence of precise data on the employment of Irish citizens and nationals of the non-European Commonwealth countries, to whom employment permit requirements do not apply, it is impossible to obtain a complete picture of the situation, particularly for recent years. This widespread shortage of labour in the less skilled manual jobs was due to a combination of factors which include the slow rate of increase of the labour force, owing to deep-seated population trends as well as to the low birth rate of the thirties; comparatively rapid economic development and expanding employment opportunities in the more attractive manufacturing and service occupations, both for young persons joining the labour force and for older workers willing to transfer to new jobs ; a comparatively high standard of general and vocational education, enabling all those wishing to take advantage of these opportunities to do so, and thereby accelerating the trend away from heavy labour; and immigration policies designed to relegate newly arrived foreigners to the least popular occupations and to reserve the benefit of expanding employment and resulting opportunities of occupational advancement for nationals of the country and resident foreigners. These various factors account both for the chronic character of the shortages and for the fact that they affect mainly, if not exclusively, the less skilled occupations. True, there have been a few cases in the very recent past where economic expansion outstripped the development of vocational training facilities, resulting in a shortage of skilled workers in the metallurgical, engineering and construction industries; but it has not been possible, by and large, to remedy these shortages through immigration. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 235 Thus, in five industrialised European countries vigorous economic expansion coupled with a virtually static labour force has created a chronic labour shortage.1 The extent of this shortage, however, has varied considerably during the period under review as a result of economic changes, both cyclical and structural. The cyclical influence is reflected in annual immigration statistics.2 In each of the five countries considered there have been successive waves of immigration, each coinciding with a period of particularly rapid expansion. The first of these—covering the period of return to a peacetime economy, from 1946 to 1948—came at a time when labour shortages were both frequent and severe, particularly in countries where the labour force had been decimated by the war; the second immigration wave (1951-52) and a third one (1955-57) were caused by two further upswings in the pace of economic expansion, the latter more marked than the former. Between these periods, the process of expansion was slower and the demand for foreign labour fell, sometimes very considerably. However, such cyclical fluctuations conceal deep-seated long-term trends. First of all, even though the labour force in immigration countries has increased very little since the war, and even though economic expansion during the same period has been both rapid and continuous, employment has expanded comparatively little, except during the immediate post-war boom and in very recent years. In so far as migration statistics and those published by national departments responsible for the control of foreign residents can be relied upon (unfortunately, accurate statistics concerning returns are seldom available) they suggest that, since 1949, and with the exception of Switzerland, the number of new jobs created in major immigration countries was appreciable only in periods of rapid economic expansion; during slowdowns it was practically nil, and the average for the entire period was quite low. There are several reasons for this. The first and most important is the considerable part played by technological progress, i.e. improved equipment and methods, in the economic expansion of these countries. The post-war productivity drive which governments promoted as a means of raising the workers' living standards, and which at the same time commended itself as a means of counteracting the rise in production costs 1 The need for immigration is not necessarily confined to countries enjoying full employment. There have actually been cases where it was necessary to bring in foreign workers in spite of unemployment at home, owing to the reluctance of the unemployed to take jobs in unpopular occupations suffering from a labour shortage or to move to other areas offering better job opportunities. Belgium is a case in point: labour shortages in the mining areas have long existed side by side with unemployment in other parts of the country. 2 See above, Chapter V. 236 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 brought on by labour's social gains, had a depressing effect on the employment level, particularly in those industries which had formerly suffered from a chronic labour shortage, such as agriculture, mining and construction. In these sectors rising production was not accompanied by anything like a corresponding increase in the labour force. Where technological progress did create new jobs, the demand was often for highly skilled workers who were just as scarce on the foreign as on the domestic employment market. Needless to say, these circumstances were hardly conducive to largescale immigration. A further factor, however, was the adoption of manpower policies deliberately aimed at maximising employment opportunities for nationals of the country through such devices as overtime work, mobilisation of all domestic labour reserves, including women, vocational guidance policies aimed at drawing young workers into expanding fields, accelerated retraining courses for adult workers, and the establishment of clearing machinery for the adjustment of labour supply and demand at the regional or national levels. In this way, the industrially advanced countries were able to meet a larger part of their manpower needs from the domestic market. France, in this respect, enjoyed a special advantage thanks to a steady influx of Algerian workers, from which most of the unskilled labour demand has been filled since 1949. Afinalfactor which helped to curtail international labour movements was the impact of immigration policies proper—policies aimed deliberately at keeping immigration at a bare minimum. While these policies were largely inspired by trade union fears that immigration might threaten productivity and rising real wages, housing shortages were a further reason for their adoption. These various factors explain why the immediate post-war period, when production had to be increased at all costs, was followed by a decline in immigration. Not only had the actual needs become less pressing 1, but governments tended to appraise them more critically. Among the eastern countries, only Czechoslovakia has attracted foreigners in any appreciable numbers, although it was by no means the only country to experience a labour shortage. Throughout eastern 1 The recent upturn in immigration in several countries during the past few years does not appear to have affected the validity of these conclusions : it can be explained as a normal phase in a long-term cyclical trend. Moreover, in France, where it was most marked, it was helped by various non-economic factors, e.g. the small number of young persons joining the labour force, the raising of the school-leaving age, the lengthening of the period of military service and the decline in Algerian immigration. If, however, the trend were to continue, it would tend to show that full employment policies have now borne fruit and that manpower reserves in immigration countries have declined substantially. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 237 Europe, manpower losses caused by the war and mass population movements, coupled with policies of industrial expansion, have put an end to underemployment and created instead a situation of overemployment characterised mainly by a shortage of skilled workers and, in some countries, e.g. Poland and Czechoslovakia, farm workers. Owing to its generalised character, the problem could not have been solved through migratory movements within the area. Such movements as did take place were purely temporary and confined to highly skilled workers ; they went mostly from Eastern Germany, Czechoslovakia and the Soviet Union to other countries, under mutual technical assistance projects.1 For political reasons the governments concerned were unfavourably inclined towards migration as a means of solving their manpower problems ; even if they had decided in favour of such a solution, it could not in any event have extended beyond the limits of eastern Europe. Only Czechoslovakia, prior to 1948 and again after 1956, brought in foreigners, usually farm workers recruited under short-term contracts; there was also a certain amount of frontier movement by Polish workers. UNITED STATES AND CANADA As already stated, the two main immigration countries during the post-war period, at least numerically speaking, were the United States and Canada. However, the part played by immigration in the national development process was quite different in these two countries : while it was secondary in the United States, it was essential in Canada where the proportion of immigrants to the entire population was much greater. United States In the United States immigration was a secondary factor in the expansion of the labour force, owing both to the legal restrictions placed on it and to the over-all trend of employment and economic development within the country. It seems quite clear that the restrictive laws governing overseas immigration have reduced the total figure to a far lower level than it might otherwise have reached. The recent development of immigration from Mexico and Central America does not appear to have offset the restrictive effects of the quota system applied to overseas immigration, even as modified by emergency legislation. 1 For the past few years some countries, particularly Poland, have received assistance from western European technicians. 238 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 However, the purpose of maintaining rigid limits on overseas immigration is not confined to the cultural preoccupations reflected in the quota system. The view is widely held in the United States that at the present stage of economic development further immigration might hinder the rise in productivity and personal income. In this respect, American opinion shares the views which have gained widespread favour in western Europe. These views may or may not be borne out by the fact that, without significant resort to immigration, the United States since the war was able to achieve a 40 per cent, increase in national income over a period of 12 years; but what this tremendous increase, compared with the relatively small (though in itself substantial) increase in the labour force, does show is this: that even in the world's most productive economy there was still room for considerable further progress. This progress has consisted in a steady improvement of equipment and methods and has had a restrictive effect on employment, obviating the need for immigration on a larger scale. Thus, owing to a marked change in the pattern of demand and a continuous effort to rationahse production methods, the process of development involved only a moderate rise in total employment: from 55.3 million to 65 million (i.e. 17 per cent.) between 1946 and 1957. A further result was a substantial alteration of the employment pattern : thanks to technological progress, the number of persons engaged in primary production underwent a marked decrease while new employment opportunities arose chiefly in the service industries which were naturally less influenced by the productivity drive. Finally, considerable changes occurred in the occupational distribution of the labour force, mainly through a fall in the number of unskilled workers. This fall was significant not only in absolute terms but even more so by comparison with other occupations, excepting farm work, in which there was also a decline. Thus the demand for foreign workers is far less than it used to be, both because employment increased at a comparatively slow rate, with the rise in labour productivity outstripping the increase in the labour force, and because the productivity rise, naturally enough, had its most telling effect on the less skilled occupations, resulting in a complete reversal of the traditional pattern whereby the United States economy absorbed a steady and massive flow of foreign labourers in response to a constant demand created by industrial expansion and the rise of earlier immigrants in the occupational scale. Only in agriculture is there still an acute labour shortage, owing to the exodus of workers—e.g. farm workers in the south and west—to more stable and better-paid jobs in the cities. Thus one result of the economic progress achieved over a 12-year period was to open vast new occupational vistas for THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 239 United States citizens, far more than to create additional jobs in occupations which formerly relied largely on immigrant labour. In the unskilled occupations the number of jobs actually decreased. In the case of more skilled jobs, both manual and non-manual, the national employment market had no difficulty in meeting the demand, owing to various factors, e.g. the fact that the natural rate of growth of the adult population was higher than in most western European countries.1 Another reason has been the remarkable mobility, both geographic and occupational, of American labour. Finally, recent development trends have created particularly favourable conditions for the expansion of female employment. Two further factors have helped to reduce the need for immigration. One is the influx of Puerto Rican workers in the eastern states. These have filled many of the jobs at the lower levels of the occupational scale, i.e. farm work and lower-grade urban occupations, which 30 years ago were still held mostly by European immigrants. The other factor is the immigration from Mexico in the southern and western states, which fully covers seasonal farm labour requirements in these areas. Thus, it appears, the United States no longer feels the need for massive immigration. This does not necessarily mean that the admission of more immigrants would have involved serious difficulties. Indeed, it is sometimes claimed that the present immigration figure, as fixed by law, is less than the economically optimum level and that the present rigid system makes no allowance for the adjustment of immigration to economic fluctuations. This is certainly true of European immigration, which is kept within artificial limits by quotas and emergency legislation. Even movement from other American countries increased steadily until 1956 and declined only in 1957; the sole exception was Puerto Rican immigration which closely reflected the economic recessions of 1949, 1954 and 1957. Canada The case of Canada is quite different : here the immigration flow has been much greater and has been dictated by economic necessity. Employment market trends over the past 12 years nevertheless have much in common with those in the United States. From 1946 to 1957 total employment rose by a little more than 20 per cent., as compared with a better than 50 per cent, increase in the national product. Therefore, rising productivity played an even greater part in economic development than it did in the United States. Moreover, the employment pattern, ^ h e average annual rate from 1946 to 1955 was 0.79 per cent. 240 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 much as in the United States, changed considerably, i.e. there was a marked decline in primary industry and a much higher rise in tertiary than in secondary industry. Only a few branches, e.g. mining and construction, failed to conform to this pattern. Thus the effect of vigorous industrial expansion was not so much to raise employment in manufacturing industries as to speed up the rate of agricultural modernisation and to support the expansion of service industries. It may be asked why, in these circumstances, Canada resorted to immigration on a much larger scale than the United States. The reasons are several. First, the employment level rose faster in Canada than in the United States. True, the domestic labour force also increased at a higher rate 1 , but this was to some extent onset by heavy and continuing emigration to the United States. For geographical reasons, moreover, employment in Canada is subject to marked seasonal fluctuations, and demand during the peak periods cannot be met, as elsewhere, by temporary immigration. Finally, account must be taken of a series of factors stemming from marked differences in the structure and main trends of development of the two economies. These require further analysis. A careful comparison of employment patterns and trends in the United States and Canada will vividly illustrate the gap separating an economy in which basic industries are still in the process of development and one which is almost overequipped. In Canada employment has expanded faster than in the United States in such basic non-agricultural sectors as mining, construction, durable goods, public utilities and transport. The result has been a substantially higher demand for male manual workers and a lesser expansion of female employment which, in spite of its recent development, is still at a lower level than in the United States. Public policy has reinforced these natural tendencies. Convinced of the need for a growing population to support an expanding economy, the Government has pinned its hopes on a process of mutual stimulation between industrialisation and immigration. Two further factors, apart from immigration, account for the exceptional pace of industrial expansion : a favourable financial position resulting from the liquidation during the war of much of the foreign debt, increased exports, improved terms of trade and the flow of capital from the United States ; and the existence of vast power and raw material resources which have attracted considerable investments.2 The authorities therefore decided 1 The average annual rate of increase from 1946 to 1955 was 1.28 per cent. The ratio of gross investment to gross national product has increased steadily since 1946: from about 16 per cent, it rose to 21 per cent, in 1949-51, between 23 and 24 per cent, in 1952-55 and 26 per cent, in 1956. During the same period the corresponding ratio in the United States remained in the vicinity of 15 per cent. 2 THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 241 to adopt—within prudent limits—a fairly generous immigration policy and to accept immigrants not on the basis of ascertained needs, as in Europe, but rather in the light of estimates assuming continued economic growth and a rising labour demand, bearing in mind also the continuous changes taking place in the structure of the labour force and the need for encouraging such mobility through the introduction of foreign labour. The wide range of needs found in a changing economy and the virtually unlimited right of entry enjoyed by certain nationalities 1 explain the comprehensive occupational distribution of immigrants over the past 12 years. Of course, the bulk of the immigrants (other than the British) are still employed in such sectors as agriculture (owing to the exodus of farm workers, which has actually tended to outstrip the progress of farm mechanisation), basic metallurgy, the metal trades, construction and domestic service ; but the traditional pattern, common to most of the more developed countries, whereby immigrants are relegated to the lower rungs of the occupational ladder is increasingly blurred and the number of immigrant workers who are assigned directly to skilled jobs appears to be rising. Throughout the period there was a close correlation between immigration and the rate of economic expansion. Both rose moderately from 1946 to 1950, and sharply thereafter. Even secondary variations in the tempo of economic development were, with a slight time lag, duplicated by fluctuations in the number of workers entering the country. Thus the first post-war surge of economic activity which followed the demobilisation of the armed forces and their integration into the civilian labour force, lasting through 1947 and the early part of 1948, brought on a significant rise in immigration, which in 1948 reached its first postwar peak. A subsequent cyclical economic slump lasting until the middle of 1950 and the sudden upturn which followed it were similarly reflected in the immigration figures, and the slight recession of 1954 as well as the ensuing phase of rapid economic expansion are mirrored by the 1955 drop in immigration, its sharp recovery in 1956 and the record number of admissions which capped it in 1957. LATIN AMERICA With the exception of Argentina, Uruguay, Venezuela and, to a lesser extent, Brazil, Latin America has received few immigrants since the war. In these countries, strong population pressures, combined with a generally low degree of industrial development, have created 1 See above, Chapter VII. 242 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 economic conditions diametrically opposite to those which normally attract immigrants in large numbers. The productivity of the domestic labour force is low and must be offset by the immigration of highly skilled workers, i.e. technicians, skilled operatives and farmers, able to make a positive contribution to economic development. However, in most cases inadequate capital formation and the lack of foreign investment*• have meant that only a small fraction of the employment potential in these occupations could be fulfilled. Thus, the kind of immigration most urgently needed for economic development has been reduced to small, not to say insignificant, proportions by the inadequacy of the development process itself. This vicious circle is common to most Latin American countries. Nevertheless, there has been immigration on a relatively large scale to the four Atlantic seaboard countries—Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay and Venezuela. The economies of these four countries, particularly Brazil, are by no means free from the weaknesses characteristic of Latin American economies. Over-all productivity has remained far lower than in the young English-speaking nations, and economic development is hampered by a dearth of capital equipment and vocational skills. Moreover, as elsewhere in Latin America, the population has increased rapidly 2, and this process has been accompanied by massive rural depopulation. Therefore, large-scale investments are required to raise both living standards and the employment level, and this entails difficulties of capital formation and utilisation. With regard to the former, the countries must still rely largely on imports and hence are at the mercy of fluctuations in their export trade; as for capital utilisation, population pressure compels a painful choice between investment for growth and investment for productivity. By and large, economic development has been accompanied by strong inflationary pressures, which (at least in Brazil, Uruguay and Argentina) have resulted in sudden and erratic price increases. The four Atlantic seaboard countries of South America have therefore, like all other Latin American countries since the war, been caught 1 The increase in American investment has been partly offset by large withdrawals of European capital. Altogether net foreign investments from 1946 to 1953 averaged 241 million dollars a year, clearly a very low figure. Moreover, such investments were most unevenly distributed and were largely concentrated on speculative ventures (mostly mines), working primarily for the export trade rather than on local industrial development or public works. See Inter-American Economic and Social Council: Foreign Investment in Latin America, Economic Research Series (Washington, D.C., 1955). 2 Except in Argentina where the natural increase of the labour force amounted to 1.5 per cent, per year on an average, as compared with 2.33 per cent, in Brazil and 2.36 per cent, in Venezuela. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 243 between the various pressures engendered by a growing population, urban development and social progress, which have occasionally threatened to cancel out the gains of agricultural and industrial progress by increasing the demand for consumer goods, housing and welfare services. This demand could only be met by an increase in production and it was for this reason that these countries resorted to immigration, hoping thereby to cover the essential needs of industry and also of agriculture, the development of which is hindered by the flight from the rural areas and bedevilled by chronically low productivity. Normally, immigration should have been confined to this function; however, it appears, in effect, to have often exceeded actual needs, owing to insufficiently selective admission policies. If the four countries were at all able to translate their manpower needs (which are common to all Latin American countries) into actual jobs, this was largely due to two factors: the existence of greater capital resources, accumulated during earlier stages of development, and better opportunities to increase them, thanks to a more favourable external financial position. The first-named factor (on which, it must be admitted, immigration policies have often banked too heavily) appears to have played a particularly important part in Argentina, and the latter in Venezuela. In Argentina the immigration flow was associated with an official policy of intensive industrialisation aimed at achieving economic independence as soon as possible. This policy was initiated at a time when the balance of payments was exceptionally favourable. Since then, however, and particularly after 1949, the situation deteriorated considerably. Dependent as it was to a large extent on the possibility of importing raw materials and capital goods—i.e., in the absence of sufficient foreign investment, on the national export trade—industrial expansion was hindered for many years by two major factors : the deterioration of the terms of trade and insufficient farm production, the latter due largely to a development policy which had the effect of discouraging agricultural expansion, and also, in 1952, to the consequences of a disastrous drought. As a result, conditions for immigration were favourable only during the immediate post-war years, when employment expanded rapidly. After that, immigration stagnated and then receded; the upward trend was not resumed until 1953. If it continued at all after 1950—which it did, though at a much slower pace than previously—this was because of an urgent demand for farm labour resulting from the large-scale movement of workers to better-paid jobs in the cities, and also to the fact that the Government persisted in its policy of industrial development, for which skilled workers were needed; but the process of industrial 244 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 expansion could not be kept up for lack of capital 1 , progress achieved in some areas was offset by slumps in others, and the result was a decrease in over-all productivity. However, beginning in 1954, agricultural recovery coupled with an improvement in the terms of trade improved the situation somewhat, though without resulting in resumption of immigration on anything like its former scale. In Venezuela, on the contrary, economic development was favoured by an abundance of capital resources. These consisted of foreign investments in the country's sub-soil—mostly petroleum—and in the proceeds of agricultural exports (at particularly favourable prices during the second part of the period) and, more important yet, exports of mineral wealth.2 Thus, unlike in Argentina, the investments required by expanding domestic demand were readily forthcoming and the result was a manufacturing and construction boom. Considerable amounts were also invested in agriculture, particularly through the grant of government credits for land settlement purposes. These factors account for the high rate of immigration and its continuous rise since 1951 : conditions were much more favourable than in Argentina, as evidenced by sharply rising productivity and relatively stable prices. Immigration conditions were also comparatively good in Uruguay, where a better balance has been maintained between industrial and agricultural development than in Argentina. In Brazil immigration reached sizeable proportions only during the second half of the period, owing to a slight acceleration in the pace of development. This was due to a turn for the better in the balance of, trade and to an increase in foreign investments. However, the inflow of fresh capital was not enough to influence productivity appreciably. In particular, immigration for land settlement developed on no more than a purely experimental scale. Thus, during the recent phase of development, the employment potential for skilled workers and experienced farmers in Brazil was fulfilled only to a slight extent. Moreover, many of the immigrants fell in neither category and could not make a useful contribution towards raising productivity. This, roughly, is the explanation which can be given for recent immigration trends in Latin America and of the seeming paradox constituted by large-scale immigration in countries already faced with strong internal population pressures as well as low productivity and underemployment. 1 Gross investment dropped from 21 per cent, of the gross national product in 1950 to 15 per cent, in 1953. 2 The percentage of gross investment to gross national product (29 per cent, in 1952) was higher in Venezuela than in any other Latin American country. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 245 AFRICA AND ASIA In Africa migration on a large scale has been a corollary of vigorous economic development fed, to a large extent, by a heavy flow of capital from Europe, particularly from metropolitan powers to their African territories. Fresh investments have helped to develop a cash economy, to stimulate the spread of wage-earning employment and urban development, and to increase the demand both for European industrial supervisors and for African labour—a demand which only immigration could fill. As a result, the entire Continent has been covered by a network of migratory cross-currents, both international—or rather inter-territorial— and intra-territorial, the former not always easily distinguishable from the latter. The economic changes which gave rise to these movements took place against a backdrop of uneven development, and their extent was not everywhere the same. As a result, immigration tended to cluster around a few privileged areas. In Africa south of the Sahara, a rough distinction can be made between two types of territories : those which have attracted only European immigration—usually the least developed—and those which have in addition attracted unskilled African labour for employment in agriculture, mines or industrial establishments. The French and Portuguese territories belong to the former group : here the emphasis has been on the development of transport and communication facilities, public utilities and administrative services rather than on manufacturing industries; as a result, the demand for indigenous labour has been comparatively slight and has usually been met locally. The second category includes the Union of South Africa, the Central African Federation, Ghana, and to a lesser extent British East Africa and the Belgian Congo, where agricultural and industrial development have been much more intensive and have created a demand for African skilled labour, which it has not been entirely possible to fill locally. These territories—and particularly the more developed ones—have therefore exerted a strong attraction on African labour in other areas, extending in some cases to territories faced themselves with a labour shortage. The two most important centres of immigration over the past 12 years have been the Union of South Africa and the Central African Federation. In the former, economic development has gone ahead swiftly, atrracting a large flow of African labourers from neighbouring territories, particularly in the mining areas, and sizeable European immigration as well. However, in spite of vacancies in the local labour force owing to emigration to Northern and Southern Rhodesia, European immigration was not as large as might have been expected at the be- 246 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 ginning of the period: the massive influx of 1947 and 1948 was followed by a regular, but much slighter movement. This was due to a tendency of the dividing line between the occupations traditionally reserved for Europeans and those normally performed by non-Europeans to recede slowly but surely in favour of the latter, leading the authorities, in 1949, to introduce a strictly selective immigration policy which accounts for the much lower figures of later years. However, while immigration during this period was satisfactory from the qualitative point of view, it appears that, in terms of numbers, it was insufficient to meet the demand for highly trained personnel and skilled workers created by a vigorously expanding economy. The labour shortage in such occupations therefore remained both persistent and acute, and was aggravated by competition from other immigration countries. In the territories which since 1954 have formed the Central African Federation, the rate of expansion was even greater than in the Union of South Africa, due to steadily rising exports, more favourable terms of trade and a considerable flow of foreign capital attracted by the natural wealth of the country, particularly its mining resources.1 The boom was accompanied by a strong immigration current, at least in the Rhodesias, where local African labour was thoroughly inadequate and where the crying need was for European personnel in all industries, both old and new. However, the difficulty of providing new housing and public utilities on the required scale compelled the authorities to put a curb on immigration—in spite of which the movement progressed almost continuously, reaching an extremely high figure in recent years. In Africa north of the Sahara, where there has been a severe and generalised problem of overpopulation, the sole function of immigration has been to provide supervisors for industry. The most important immigration country appears to have been Morocco, though in the absence of adequate information it is impossible to establish a clear-cut relationship between immigration and economic development in that country. An almost identical situation obtains in the Near East. Immigration here was slight and involved only European and North American supervisors. Often it was linked with the development of foreign undertakings, e.g. petroleum companies and engineering firms. However, the com1 The proportion of gross investment to gross national product reached the impressive figures of 44 per cent, in 1950, 55 per cent, in 1951 and 47 per cent, in 1952. Despite a subsequent decline (to 35 per cent, in 1953, 32 per cent, in 1954 and 34 per cent, in 1955) it has been consistently higher than in the Union of South Africa, where the corresponding figure over the past few years has remained close to 25 per cent. Foreign investment accounted, on an average, for more than one-fourth of the total from 1950 to 1954. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 247 panies located in the Persian Gulf area attracted workers from other countries in the area, e.g. Syria, Lebanon and even India and Pakistan. Finally, in south-east Asia, economic development has had the same difficulty in keeping up with population trends as in other areas. The situation in the traditional immigration countries (Ceylon, Burma, Thailand, Malaya, Viet-Nam, British Borneo and Indonesia) is no longer favourable to the immigration of Indian and Chinese labourers for work in mines and plantations. These currents, which were greatly reduced during the depression of the thirties stopped altogether after the Second World War. However, Burma and, above all, Malaya continued to attract substantial numbers of skilled workers from India prior to the entry into force of the new immigration laws.1 Korean and Japanese migration, which had consisted largely of movements within the former Japanese Empire, also ceased—or rather were reversed, assuming the form of massive repatriations. 2 Some south-east Asian countries, however, have in recent years imported a handful of Japanese technicians and skilled workers. Settlement schemes for Indians in British Borneo and Japanese in Cambodia have also been discussed recently but never advanced beyond this stage. On the whole, it is quite clear that the basic factors which at one time made for large-scale movements of labour in this part of the world have simply disappeared without being replaced. Nevertheless, some immigration of highly skilled European and North American personnel has continued in south-east Asia, and demand for foreign technicians remains strong in many countries—this in spite of political changes which have resulted in widespread replacement of foreign supervisory personnel by nationals of the countries concerned as well as in the withdrawal of foreign capital. AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND Australia and New Zealand, together with Canada, Venezuela and the two major south African immigration countries, complete the small group of European-peopled nations overseas where economic development has been so rapid, and has been guided in such a way, as to create a strong demand for immigrant labour. Both of these countries since the war have concentrated not on maximising individual income but rather on making investments calculated to ensure better use of existing resources and to remedy basic economic weaknesses brought to light by 1 2 See above, Chapter VII. See above, Chapter IV. 248 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the depression of the thirties. In carrying out this policy, they were greatly helped by a favourable external financial position. As in Canada, the emphasis has been both on the development of production facilities and on immigration, not only because industrialisation in countries with a comparatively slow population increase and without an industrial tradition is bound to create a labour demand which cannot be met satisfactorily in any other way, but on the theory that immigration per se constitutes a means of stimulating investment. Thus, immigration in these countries is part and parcel of a systematic policy of industrial expansion. This policy has resulted in an increased labour demand—a demand intensified by the failure of the employment level in primary industry to fall appreciably and by a snowballing effect whereby immigration itself has become a factor of economic development. It may be added that since the war trade unions and public opinion in both countries, which formerly tended to look upon immigration with some diffidence, have, in the light of successful experience, come around to a more favourable view. This has left the governments freer to regulate the migratory flow in keeping with the general interest as they saw it, while pursuing their efforts to promote investment, particularly in basic industries characterised by heavy outlays and low yields but essential to balanced industrial development. One final factor accounts for the heavy emigration both to Australia and to New Zealand. The general level of productivity in these countries has, for various structural reasons, and in particular the greater relative importance of agriculture, remained lower, and its progress over the past 12 years less marked, than in Canada. Thus, although the increase in gross national product was less, a comparatively larger labour force was needed to achieve it. All of these reasons account for the considerable proportions reached by immigration in both countries, particularly in Australia where a greater effort was made to encourage the movement of families. In that country the number of immigrants in some years was proportionately as high as it had been in the United States before the First World War. It actually exceeded original planning estimates, owing to new requirements created by cumulative processes of economic growth and, generally speaking, by a variety of factors which resulted in a higher rate of formation than had been foreseen at the beginning of the capital period.1 1 After an initial sharp rise (from 20 to 29 per cent.) between 1948 and 1951, the ratio of gross investment to gross national product, as in Canada, settled at about 25 per cent. In addition, Australia by the end of 1956 had received close to 318 million dollars in long-term loans from the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 249 As in Canada, and for the same reasons, opportunities for immigrants in Australia were many and varied. In agriculture, not only were the usual effects of the rural exodus keenly felt but the drop in employment resulting from the spread of modern farming methods was offset by an expansion in stock-raising which created a fresh demand for farm labour; as a result, total agricultural employment barely diminished at all. In tertiary industry—and particularly in commerce, transport and domestic service—there was also a sizeable demand for immigrant labour. However, it was in manufacturing, and at all levels of occupational skill, that the demand was heaviest. Moreover, statistics show that in Australia as in Canada, and for the same sociological reasons, a higher proportion of the British immigrants took up non-manual or skilled manual jobs than was the case for other nationalities. The trend of immigration figures, on the other hand, was quite different from that observed in Canada. For one thing, immigration was slow to pick up during the immediate post-war years owing to a dollar shortage which hindered economic development. The highest levels were reached in 1949 and 1950 when Australia made a special effort to take in a considerable number of I.R.O. refugees, even in excess of its immediate needs. There was a slight decline in 1951 and 1952 and a more serious one in 1953 owing to an economic slowdown in the second half of 1952 and the first half of 1953. However, beginning in 1954, the upward trend was resumed, and the same average level as in 1951 and 1952 was again reached in 1955, 1956 and 1957. The position in New Zealand was much the same as in Australia, though on a smaller scale. There was a similar increase in gross national product, and general employment also remained stationary in the primary sector while rising sharply in manufacturing. However, there were some differences. Industrialisation in New Zealand faced greater obstacles than in Australia and could not proceed as rapidly. The economy remained to a greater extent a rural one, industrial as well as over-all employment rose more slowly, and opportunities for immigrants were fewer—even though they occurred in much the same fields as in Australia. These essentially were agriculture which, as in Australia, suffered from a labour shortage, industry, where the heaviest demand was for metallurgical and construction workers, and most of the service occupations. The Labour Supply GENERAL An attempt has been made in the preceding section to explain the reasons for immigration currents and in particular why there has been 250 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 a comparatively heavy demand for immigrant labour in some countries. The phenomenon has been ascribed largely to a combination of objective circumstances peculiar to immigration countries. The reasons why workers emigrate in response to this demand are, on the other hand, far less simple to explain, owing in particular to certain psychological factors which largely elude objective analysis. This does not mean that the labour supply, as well as the demand, is not determined by economic factors: readiness to emigrate, after all, depends largely on whether or not the individual decides that it is in his interest to do so. In this respect population pressures, generally considered an essential emigration factor, are no doubt important in that wherever they exist people are readier to emigrate than elsewhere; and it is historically true that major migratory currents, past and present, have originated in countries suffering either momentarily or chronically from overpopulation, i.e. countries in which the labour supply exceeded the demand. But this is merely a contributory, not a decisive factor, even in the case of large-scale movements. Moreover, even where such a causal relationship exists, it is not necessarily a direct one. Many of the emigrants who leave an overpopulated country are neither unemployed nor even badly paid: they may simply consider that chances are better abroad, either immediately or in a more or less distant future. Conversely, it is not unusual for the unemployed to scorn emigration opportunities if they feel that the prospects are not good enough, particularly with the increasingly comprehensive and generous unemployment relief schemes found in many countries today. Therefore, the factors that lead people to emigrate are partly of a non-economic nature; as such, they cannot be explained in purely mechanistic terms, but must be viewed as the sum of all the complex motivations that condition individual behaviour. The meaning of this will be made clearer in the following pages. THE FACTORS OF EMIGRATION A person who goes abroad in search of a better job—whether he be unemployed, underemployed or fully employed (and adequately paid) in his own country—is guided essentially by self-interest: no worker will emigrate unless he has the certainty, or at least a reasonable hope, of improving his economic position. However, in analysing this element of self-interest, care must be taken to avoid oversimplification. Apart from the hope of immediate material gain, other features, some of a purely non-economic nature, may be involved. An emigrant faced with a choice of possible destinations THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 251 will not necessarily be guided solely by the prospect of greater material rewards. Therefore, while a constant correlation has been observed in recent years between migration and international disparities in the general level of earnings, this has not always been the decisive factor in determining the choice of individual emigrants. Besides, this correlation itself is not always easy to establish owing to the difficulties involved in any international comparison of real wages ; such difficulties arise at all levels of the occupational scale owing to considerable differences between wage systems in the various countries. If the law of supply and demand operated freely, it would be normal to expect a general correlation to exist between wage levels on the one hand and the spread—both geographical and occupational—of migration currents on the other. In many cases, this correlation is not clearly evident. Certain trends, however, are discernible. The United States, for instance, where earnings in all occupations are higher than anywhere else, has always been a quasi-universal pole of attraction. It is obvious, moreover, that problems of selection facing all immigration countries are easier to solve in those countries which are in a position to offer the highest wages. In this regard, Canada, where most of the demand for labour can be met from the high-wage countries of western Europe, has been in a far stronger position than the other European-populated Commonwealth countries, particularly Australia. Similarly, in western Europe the United Kingdom, Sweden and Switzerland are the only major immigration countries which have persistently attracted workers from countries with a comparatively high standard of living, e.g. Germany, while France's area of recruitment has long been confined to southern Europe. Again, in Latin America, where average wages are generally lower than in western Europe, southern Europe has filled the bulk of the labour demand, whereas western European—and to an even greater extent North American—immigration has been confined to the higher levels of the occupational scale. This process of stratification is even more pronounced in Africa where African, Asiatic and European immigration currents respectively have met demand at three different levels. These few examples show conclusively that there is a constant correlation between migratory currents and disparities in standards of living and that, moreover, there is an inverse relation between migration of skilled and supervisory personnel and mass movements, the former gravitating to the less developed areas and the latter (which may or may not cover all levels of the occupational scale but in any case always include the lower ones) towards the more advanced countries. Of course, real wages, in the present context, must be understood as covering all material benefits accruing from any gainful occupation, i.e. 252 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the net earnings of each family plus any social benefits, since such subsidiary payments as family allowances, rather than the wage itself, may in some cases provide the decisive inducement to emigrate. The wage itself must be understood not in the sense of an hourly rate, but of the amount earned over a longer period of time : therefore, in addition to the hourly wage rate, the number of hours worked per week and the degree of stability of the employment offered must also be considered. However, important though they may be, differences in real wages, even in this broad sense, cannot account wholly for the emigrant's choice. Other considerations can and—experience shows—often do, play a part. These include the availability of housing for the worker and his family (whether accompanying him or joining him later) and possible restrictions on the transfer of savings or family allowances to his family pending their arrival in the country of immigration or his own return to the country of origin (if he happens to be a temporary migrant). However, apart from, and possibly more important than, immediate economic interest, various psychological factors of a more complex nature also enter into the picture. From the point of view of the worker who is unemployed in his own country with no remedy in sight, emigration is an attractive possibility, far more because of the opportunity to escape from a demoralising situation and to make a fresh start than because of the immediate material advantage involved. Indeed, immigrants in general often seem less interested in immediate economic advantage than in long-term opportunity for themselves and their children and are not infrequently prepared to accept momentary sacrifices for the sake of living in a country offering better development prospects, greater job security, better opportunities for interoccupational transfer and easier access to propertied status. These long-range considerations appear to have played a particularly important part in the case of emigration from countries with a high level of employment and productivity (such as the United Kingdom and the Netherlands) towards countries such as Australia, where the element of immediate economic advantage would in many cases seem to have been insufficient to constitute by itself a decisive inducement. Generally speaking, it is rare for long-term migration, involving the entire future of individuals, not to be determined essentially by longterm prospects : there is a vast difference between the motives of persons who emigrate permanently and those of temporary emigrants whose main concern is usually to save as much money as fast as possible. In the latter case, immediate economic advantage is the overriding factor and differences in real wages from one country to another play a far more important role. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 253 Finally, emigration may be affected by non-economic factors. Political developments in a given country can create a more or less permanent feeling of insecurity or pessimism and thus set in motion or speed up a migration current. For example, in 1951-52 the Korean War appears to have stimulated European emigration, and the Suez crisis in 1956-57 had a similar effect on British emigration. The decision to emigrate overseas taken at one stage or another by the vast majority of eastern European refugees, was dictated not only by economic considerations but also by a yearning for security and often a desire to make a clean break with the past. Also, certain long-term migration currents have continued to reflect affinities based on a community of culture and custom: Portuguese emigrants feel more at home in Brazil, Spaniards in the Spanish-speaking countries of Latin America, and British people have a preference for Commonwealth countries with a European heritage, in spite of the ease with which they can gain admission to the United States. Italians consistently choose to emigrate to Latin America, Switzerland or France, where they presumably expect to have less difficulties of adjustment than elsewhere. Apart from the psychological disadvantages of too great and too sudden a change of environment, chances of a successful career for the immigrant are best in a country where conditions are similar to those to which he is accustomed. Indeed, cultural kinships appear to have played a greater part in this respect than geographical proximity: emigrants are by no means systematically inclined to prefer nearby countries to more distant ones. At this point, however, travel expenses come into the picture and it becomes difficult to distinguish exactly the purely psychological from the economic aspects. It does seem, at any rate, that short-term, unlike long-term movements tend to gravitate towards countries which are geographically closer. A final important factor is tradition. Permanent migratory currents create psychological and social bonds between nations, which immigrant colonies established in the various countries help to maintain. Not only can the prospect of finding compatriots abroad, possibly friends or relatives, constitute a psychological inducement for the would-be emigrant, but such colonies, wherever they exist, often provide very substantial material advantages for the newcomers. They may, for example, find them jobs, bring them into contact with prospective employers, advance all or part of their travel costs or even stand surety for the immigrants, where this is a legal requirement. This type of assistance has played a persistently important part over the past 12 years, in spite of the development of government-organised and assisted migration programmes. 1 1 See below, Chapter IX. 254 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 To sum up, it is clear that recent emigration currents have been conditioned largely by differences in levels of earnings, but that apart from this fundamental factor a number of extraneous circumstances of an economic and psychological nature have continued to play an important part; foremost among these are the self-perpetuating traditions just described. Further analysis will, however, disclose still other factors worthy of attention. Disparities in real wages over the past 12 years have by no means remained invariable. Each economy has its own tempo of development. The gap between wage levels in two countries may, at any given time, become wider or narrower; in some cases the tables may be turned entirely, and any such development will necessarily have an effect on migration between the two countries. Actually, no such dramatic reversal has taken place since the war; rather, the varying rates at which real wages rose in the various countries resulted in an increase rather than a decrease in existing disparities. There have, of course, been exceptions. For instance, real wages rose faster in Italy than in the Latin American countries, with the possible exception of Venezuela. This lessened the attraction which these countries formerly held for Italian emigrants, and in some occupations emigration ceased entirely. German emigration to countries such as Belgium and France suffered a similar fate. So far, comparatively little has been said of the relationship between emigration and overpopulation. This point merits closer attention, since it is undeniable that overpopulation—in the sense of a large labour surplus far in excess of employment possibilities—is an important factor of emigration, particularly as it is usually a structural phenomenon resulting from fairly constant population pressures. Overpopulation, however, where it exists, is only one aspect of a condition common to most underdeveloped economies, the symptoms of which are an abnormally high degree of underemployment, low over-all productivity and a low average wage level. Thus the problem merges with that of the correlation between emigration and wage levels, and between emigration and unemployment. The former has already been discussed extensively. However, it must be further pointed out that population pressures tending to aggravate an existing state of overpopulation act as a check on rising wages, at least in occupations suffering from a labour surplus; this in turn tends to accentuate the disparities which, as already pointed out, are the fundamental cause of migratory movements. The relationship between emigration and unemployment is a closely related problem in so far as underemployed workers earn wages below THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 255 the subsistence level while the totally unemployed receive allowances more or less pegged to the minimum subsistence figure. Continuing population pressure can only bring further pressure to bear on the the job supply, and this means still lower living standards, with all the psychological consequences which such an apparently hopeless situation entails. It is this fundamental unbalance between population and wealth, resulting in substandard productivity, underemployment and low living standards, which characterises most of the major emigration countries. This basic relationship, while it admits of exceptions and is at best only a partial explanation, is sufficiently borne out by the facts to serve as a useful working hypothesis in attempting to trace migratory movements back to their source in the various countries. Such an attempt has been made in the following pages, first for Europe and then for the rest of the world. OVERPOPULATION AND EMIGRATION IN EUROPE Although the situation in Europe varies from one country to another, a fundamental relationship appears to exist between overpopulation and emigration. In some countries, e.g. Western Germany, overpopulation has been a purely temporary phenomenon; in other areas, e.g. southern Europe and Ireland, it has been a structural one. Generally speaking, nearly all of the major emigration currents, both continental and intercontinental, have sprung from a situation of temporary or chronic underemployment. The only exceptions are the United Kingdom and the Netherlands, and even the latter country was at one time threatened with overpopulation; the fact that the threat did not materialise is probably in part the result of timely resort to emigration. The principal cause of overpopulation—or, if preferred, underemployment—in the various countries has been scarcity of capital. Broadly speaking, and allowing for certain features peculiar to individual countries, three different cases may be distinguished: that of Western Germany, a highly industrialised country with a relatively low rate of demographic increase, where overpopulation resulting from the partial destruction of the nation's capital assets, coupled with a massive migratory influx, was a purely accidental circumstance; that of the southern European countries, where by contrast overpopulation is a structural phenomenon as it is in all underdeveloped countries with a slow rate of capital formation combined with strong demographic pressures; and that of the Netherlands, where overpopulation was never more than a threat. 256 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 As regards Western Germany, the productivity and employment problems with which the post-1945 influx of refugees of all origins presented a war-ravaged economy have already been discussed at length.1 During this period the tremendous demand for jobs (which only eased gradually), coupled with economic disruption, compelled many workers, particularly refugees, to accept unsuitable employment. However, with the exception of non-German refugees, who were cared for first by U.N.R.R.A. and later by the I.R.O.—which subsequently resettled most of them—emigration from Germany never reached massive proportions. Of the movements that did occur, the most important, oddly enough, came at a time when the country was well on its way to economic recovery and employment market conditions were reverting to normal. These were the currents towards areas such as North America, Australia and Switzerland, which developed mostly during the latter part of the period reviewed. Another remarkable feature of West German emigration during this period was the small proportion of unemployed among the emigrants—even though the rate of emigration was higher among refugees than among West Germans, and higher also in the overpopulated Länder than in the others. All of this suggests that, while there was a connection between post-war German emigration and the critical economic conditions prevailing at the time (particularly the glut on the employment market), its timing was conditioned mainly by extraneous, and primarily political, factors: the ban placed on emigration by the Occupation authorities during the immediate post-war years; the reluctance of certain emigration countries, for some years after, to admit Germans; and the absence, prior to 1949, of a central government able to guide emigration policies. Thus, throughout the entire period of economic distress which Western Germany experienced after the war, its nationals had little or no possibility of emigration. By the time the situation had improved, particularly as regards overseas emigration, the inclination to emigrate was far less strong, even among the refugees who had lost all hope of ever returning to their former homes. Thus, while emigration to countries with higher living standards continued at a substantial level during the latter part of the period, it is increasingly difficult to explain this fact in purely economic terms now that the Federal Republic of Germany has become one of the most prosperous countries in western Europe. In Austria the link between emigration and the population surplus created by the refugee influx is more obvious : many of the emigrants were in fact workers directly affected by the surplus ; nevertheless, even 1 See above, Chapter I. THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 257 after full employment was restored, emigration continued for the same reasons as in Germany, albeit at a slower pace. Overpopulation in Germany and Austria has therefore been a purely accidental, temporary phenomenon. In southern Europe, on the other hand, it is a chronic problem with deep-rooted structural causes. Countries in this area are characterised by an essentially agricultural economy 1 , low productivity and a rapidly increasing labour force 2, and industry has not expanded rapidly enough to absorb the labour surplus resulting from the general population increase and the flight from the land. The result has been underemployment, both rural and urban, in a wide variety of forms. An attempt has been made to express the extent of underemployment in these countries by calculating how many workers could be withdrawn from the labour force without affecting national production. The figures arrived at, while of necessity approximate, are nonetheless impressive: 3 or 4 million for Italy (i.e. about twice the official unemployment figure), at least 2 million for Spain, and 1 million for Greece. They give an idea of the tremendous disproportion between human and capital resources which still exists in the peninsular countries of the Mediterranean—a disproportion which scarcity of investment during the past 12 years has tended to perpetuate and, in some cases, to aggravate. Thus, scarce jobs and low wages in southern Europe have developed a propensity to emigrate among large masses of workers and helped to create a tremendous manpower reservoir for immigration countries both in Europe and overseas. This, however, does not necessarily imply a direct correlation between population pressure in a given region and emigration from that region. Only in Italy do emigrants come, by and large, from those parts of the country where income per inhabitant is lowest: elsewhere, such a correlation is by no means the rule. This is because propensity to emigrate, strong as it is in the overpopulated countries of southern Europe, is to a greater extent than elsewhere held in check by the nature of foreign demand. Overpopulation resulting 1 The percentage of the actual population which is engaged in agriculture in each of the countries concerned, as given by recent census figures, is as follows: 40 per cent, in Italy (1951), 48.4 per cent, in Portugal (1950) and 48.8 per cent, in Spain (1950), as compared with 27.7 per cent, for France (1954), 23.2 per cent, for Western Germany (1950) and 19.3 per cent, for the Netherlands (1947). 2 The average natural rate of increase of the active age groups (i.e. men aged from 15 to 65 and women from 15 to 60) in the southern European countries over the past ten years appears to have been in the neighbourhood of 1.5, the figure for Italy being lower and that for Greece substantially higher. In the industrialised countries of north-western Europe (with the exception of the Netherlands) the rate has never exceeded, and has often been well below, 0.5 per cent. 258 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 from powerful demographic pressures has had its most telling effect in agriculture, where it has resulted in the accumulation of an unskilled labour surplus. By contrast, much of the demand in immigration countries, especially overseas, has been for semi-skilled or skilled workers. As a result, these countries, by and large, have provided fewer immigration opportunities for the surplus groups of workers than for the others, and emigration from southern Europe, particularly Italy, has by no means been consistently confined to unemployed, underemployed or even badly paid workers. Thus, study of the relationship between emigration and overpopulation in this area discloses a considerable gap, quantitatively and qualitatively speaking, between the potential labour supply and the actual demand. An analysis of the regional distribution of southern European emigration would no doubt, in addition, bring to light a number of factors of a social and psychological (rather than economic) nature, e.g. tradition and personal relations. It might also show that in some of the more underprivileged areas, where economic conditions would normally seem to favour emigration, persons actually wishing to emigrate simply could not afford to do so. This remark applies less to Italy, where emigration has been effectively organised by the authorities, than to other countries, e.g. Spain and Portugal. In these two countries, emigration has remained essentially a regional phenomenon affecting mainly the north Atlantic provinces in the former and the northern provinces in the latter—a fact which cannot be explained on purely economic grounds. In Greece the recent development of emigration must be credited to government action, and in particular to the assistance of the Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration which has provided badly needed facilities for the emigrants. Finally, the high level of Maltese emigration from 1948 to 1955 was essentially the result of public sponsorship. Thus, emigration from southern Europe over the past 12 years has been dictated almost exclusively by foreign labour demand and has followed its vicissitudes; but there was no economic change within the area itself such as might have affected overpopulation—and hence emigration—to any appreciable degree. In Italy, however, while unemployment and, with it, propensity to emigrate remained considerable throughout the entire period, economic progress, particularly in recent years, made possible the total absorption—and in some instances even created a shortage—of skilled workers and caused a substantial decrease in the surplus of semi-skilled labour. Since at the same time real wages rose considerably, the labour supply available to immigration countries has become increasingly confined to unskilled workers. Thus, an THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 259 improving employment situation in Italy has presented these countries with an increasingly difficult recruitment problem. The combination of overpopulation with underdevelopment has by no means, during the period considered, been confined to southern Europe. In eastern Europe, where present-day industrial development policies have basically altered the pre-war employment picture, rural underemployment has virtually disappeared : indeed, some countries have suffered from a farm labour shortage. However, population pressures remain strong and in some cases surpluses have developed. In Bulgaria, for instance, the Government recently resorted to the placing of unemployed agricultural workers in Czechoslovakia and the Soviet Union. Even north-west Europe has had localised overpopulation problems; these have been solved by internal rather than by international migration. Even so, such situations would seem to account, partly at least, for movements of Finnish workers to Sweden and for seasonal and frontier movements of Belgian workers into France. The outstanding example, however, is Ireland where the rate of emigration has been the highest in the world after Malta. This was due not only to the attraction of high-wage countries, both close and distant, but also to sluggish economic development at home, where the rural population surplus has outstripped the expansion of urban employment, thus perpetuating widespread structural unemployment. In the Netherlands, which over the past 12 years has been one of the major European emigration countries, the correlation between emigration and overpopulation has also been in evidence. However, owing to the advanced degree of industrialisation and the high level of employment, thanks to which the threat of overpopulation never really materialised, the problem in this country was quite different. True, the comparatively rapid rate of increase of the domestic labour force— about 1 per cent, per year, a particularly high figure for western Europe— and the reversal of the traditional migratory flow between the Netherlands and Indonesia subjected the economy to unusually heavy stress during the post-war period, thus further aggravating the effects of wartime destruction and loss of colonial income. At no time, however, did unemployment reach alarming proportions, even between 1950 and 1952 when trade difficulties put a damper on industrial development.1 Even the scarcity of farmland does not seem to have resulted in substantial rural underemployment, all surpluses having been rapidly absorbed by urban industry. These circumstances, coupled with a successful 1 From 29,000 in 1949 unemployment rose above 100,000 in 1952, falling again to a figure slightly in excess of 40,000 in 1955. Even when it was at its highest, however, no more than 3.5 per cent, of the entire labour force was affected. 260 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 policy of full employment through industrial expansion and development of exports, have prevented demographic pressures over the past 12 years from affecting employment to any considerable extent. How far this success could have been achieved without resort to emigration is, of course, difficult to say. Furthermore, the tightness of the employment market appears to have made it rather more difficult for workers, particularly young persons, to find really suitable jobs, while at the same time slowing down the rise in real wages. It did not, however, significantly increase propensity to emigrate. That emigration did in fact develop considerably during the latter part of the-period was due largely to the deliberate efforts of the Government to encourage it, thus relieving the economy of the further strain—particularly the need for heavier investment—which would have resulted from unchecked population growth. Another factor was the Government's desire to provide broader occupational horizons for the younger generations. A major objective of this policy was to create a regular emigration tradition, which would help to overcome employment difficulties caused by a rapidly expanding labour force. These efforts happened to coincide with the opening up of vast new employment opportunities overseas, particularly in Canada and Australia. As a result Dutch emigration after 1950 assumed a new complexion : traditional movements of supervisory personnel to Indonesia and the overseas territories were largely replaced by permanent emigration of manual workers to the European-peopled countries of the British Commonwealth. Remarkably enough, the continuous and rapid improvement of the economic situation from 1953 to 1957 did not reduce the emigration flow to any substantial extent. In the United Kingdom, on the other hand, recent emigration bears no discernible relation to overpopulation or demographic pressure. Immigration has not fallen far below emigration, and the natural increase in the domestic labour force since the war has been slower than in most countries : not only has unemployment during this period been non-existent, but there has been an almost constant labour shortage. In spite of balance-of-payments difficulties, real income per inhabitant has increased steadily and at a rate which compares quite favourably with that of other western European countries. Thus, there is no ready economic explanation for what is in fact one of the most important emigration currents in the world today. The explanation can only lie in the strong attraction still exerted by the United States and the Commonwealth countries, particularly those with a European population, where living conditions are better than in the United Kingdom and where employment prospects for British emigrants are particularly promising. This interpretation is borne out by the fact that British emigration THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 261 includes a higher proportion of skilled workers already enjoying a high standard of living at home than those of any other major European emigration country. Even so, neither Canada nor Australia nor New Zealand have received as many British immigrants as they would have liked to do. This is not to say that there is no correlation at all between recent British emigration and economic and social conditions in the United Kingdom since the war. The high rate of emigration from Scotland, for instance, seems due not only to deep-seated tradition but also to a state of relative underdevelopment by comparison with other areas in the United Kingdom. From a more general standpoint, the policy of austerity pursued during the immediate post-war years in order to achieve a lasting improvement in the balance of payments appears to have played a significant part. Apart from this, a constant underlying tendency—readily apparent at the first hint of a crisis—to take a dark view of the country's economic future may account to some extent for emigration fluctuations since 1950. The post-war tendency, general throughout western Europe, towards a levelling of earnings which has operated to the detriment of certain classes, e.g. non-manual workers, appears to have stimulated emigration by such workers. Finally, a part has doubtless been played by housing difficulties in large cities, particularly the London area, from which emigration has been considerable. However, in the absence of adequate statistical evidence, none of these factors can be anything but a matter of surmise. The policy of the Government has been to try to meet the need of Commonwealth countries for British immigrants so far as the demographic situation and economic interests of the United Kingdom allowed. The Government did not, however, engage in active promotion to the extent of adding much to the contribution already made by spontaneous factors towards the revival of traditional British overseas emigration currents. Other European oversea movements originated in countries with a comparatively static population and bear no relation to the local economic situation. These comparatively minor currents are due to the attraction of high living standards in North America and also to the economic, and sometimes cultural or political ties which some of these countries, e.g. France and Belgium, maintain outside Europe. OVERPOPULATION AND EMIGRATION OUTSIDE EUROPE Outside Europe, emigration currents have also varied considerably in cause and nature. Some, owing to the absence of legal restrictions or the physical impossibility of enforcing them, were a truer reflection of 262 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 demographic pressures in emigration countries than were most of those originating in Europe. Others, e.g. Canadian emigration to the United States, were due merely to the power of attraction exerted by some immigration countries. The American and African Continents have, over the past 12 years, been covered by a multitude of migratory currents. These generally originated in rural areas governed by the traditional forms of economic life, where a continuously increasing population—often combined with a deteriorating soil—made life increasingly difficult. This compelled the able-bodied to leave either permanently or, more frequently, for limited periods in order to take up paid employment and thereby supplement the meagre income produced by the land. Often this involved travel across national or territorial boundaries, and in some instances across the seas. The same problem of rural overpopulation, in varying form, accounts for recent emigration from the West Indies, Mexican emigration to the United States, population shifts in the Andean region (particularly from Bolivia to Argentina) and, in Africa, movements of indigenous workers from one territory to another for periods of varying duration. Population pressure in emigration countries is not, of course, the only explanation for these movements : the pull exerted by immigration countries was also important, as evidenced by the clear preference of the emigrants for those with the better employment or earning prospects. Sometimes, areas not protected by effective immigration control provisions have been swamped by the influx of foreign labour, e.g. in the United States, where inadequate surveillance of the Mexican border at one time permitted illegal entries on a large scale. In Africa, on the other hand, emigration from the tribal areas has not, as a rule, given rise to a labour surplus. Through their basic instability, unwillingness to abandon their traditional forms of economic life entirely, and low level of productivity, African migrant workers nearly always constitute a precarious labour supply at best, and competition for their services therefore remains keen among the industries of the various territories. Other movements, of quite a different character, have also taken place in America and Africa. These include Canadian emigration to the United States and that of Europeans from the Union of South Africa to the Central African Federation, consisting in both cases of skilled or professional workers attracted by favourable conditions in the immigration country. The latter of these two movements is the result of exceptionally rapid economic growth and vastly expanding employment opportunities, particularly in Southern Rhodesia. The former is probably due less to higher wages in the United States than to a more diversified employment market. However, there are also other factors, THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 263 e.g. close cultural kinship between English-speaking Canada and the United States, the power of attraction of the great cities of the northeastern United States, and the tendency of French Canadians to move to the United States, where they have certain ties, rather than to the English-speaking part of Canada. From the United States itself industrial managers and technicians have gone to the various parts of the world as a result of the growing economic influence exerted by the United States everywhere. In Asia, finally, where overpopulation is general, emigration has borne no relation at all to the magnitude or nature of the problem. Emigration opportunities for Asiatics are extremely limited, both in and out of Asia, and are largely confined to certain privileged groups such as experienced farmers, craftsmen, businessmen, and semi-skilled workers. In addition, workers in the less privileged groups usually do not have the money to emigrate, with the result that Asian emigration on the whole has had a strongly selective flavour. The only exception would seem to be overland migration between contiguous countries, on which very little information is available. Conclusion While the foregoing gives an idea of the wide variety of factors which account for migration currents and, by way of consequence, the dangers of a dogmatic approach to the subject, it does suggest a few fairly definite conclusions. First, it is clear that such currents are determined fundamentally by differences in levels of productivity. To say that emigrants are attracted by higher earnings is tantamount to saying that they are drawn towards economies where labour productivity is high. In practice, however, the operation of this law is not as simple as it seems, conditioned as it is by international differences not in over-all productivity but in productivity within individual occupations. Mass movements, for instance, flow towards the more technically advanced countries or those where natural resources can be most readily exploited. Supervisors and technicians, on the other hand, tend to go to economically less developed areas where productivity of skilled labour is high, thus constituting a powerful stimulus for the economy. However, as already explained, such disparities do not in themselves suffice to set a migratory flow in motion. To a far greater extent than formerly, owing to restrictive immigration laws, migration takes places only to the extent that jobs are available and foreigners are capable of 264 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 filling them. Thus immigration depends largely on how far the pace of economic development outstrips the increase in the domestic labour force and the rise in productivity in the various sectors of the economy. It also depends on the availability of foreign workers, and this is determined not only by their suitability for the job but also by the potency of the incentives offered them and the extent to which physical or psychological difficulties impede their movement. The first of these prerequisites of immigration is necessarily bound up with such questions as labour force trends in immigration countries, capital formation, investment policy and its employment implications— problems which have only been touched upon, even though each would have warranted a detailed country-by-country analysis. One general observation which trends in the major overseas immigration countries does suggest is that foreign capital has played a far less important part in their development than formerly and that, while this is a sign of growing economic maturity, it also reflects the decline in western European ability to supply the capital. Thus, the relationship which used to exist between international movements of labour and movements of capital—or, more specifically, between European overseas emigration and capital exports from western Europe, and primarily the United Kingdom—has largely disappeared. The only exception worth mentioning is the flow of investments from certain European countries to their non-metropolitan territories, which is paralleled by a substantial current of European migration. The accession of the United States to the position of chief purveyor of capital, formerly held by western Europe, has given rise to a sort of triangular pattern, in place of the old parallel movement. Thus Canada and Venezuela have been developed in part thanks to a combination of American investment and European immigration; western European economic recovery has been helped by United States capital as well as by certain migration currents; and this same capital has contributed to the promotion of investment by certain countries, chiefly the United Kingdom and France, in areas outside Europe, particularly Africa—a process which, as stated above, has been accompanied by substantial emigration. However, in spite of the importance of such movements of American capital, they can hardly be said to bear the same fundamental relationship to migration currents as the flow of western European capital overseas did in an earlier day. As for the matching of supply and demand on the international employment market, the tendency over the past few years has been to rely less and less on private initiative to overcome the practical difficulties involved. To a varying degree, therefore, governments have gone THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 265 beyond their traditional regulatory functions and embarked on various promotional schemes which are described in the following chapter. Finally, it has become apparent that the concepts of " overpopulation " and " underpopulation ", frequently invoked in attempts to explain migration phenomena, are by themselves inadequate even if strictly defined as a long-term excess or shortage of population in relation to productive capital. Overpopulation will lead to emigration only to the extent (generally limited nowadays) that surplus workers can be assured of employment abroad. Moreover, much of the demand for such employment has arisen in countries enjoying a situation of full employment or, in those countries faced with underemployment, among those categories of workers least affected by it. Finally, the extent to which countries with a labour shortage have resorted to immigration has varied greatly depending on the development and employment policy pursued in each case, some countries having been either unwilling or unable to meet certain of their labour requirements in this way. In short, while differences in levels of productivity and development trends are an essential factor in the formation of international migration currents, there are other, more elusive, factors of a physical, psychological and political nature which play a part in determining the direction, size, occupational characteristics and distinctive sociological physiognomy of each. Bibliographical References STATISTICAL SOURCES In addition to the statistical sources listed in Chapters V and VI, the following may be consulted : INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND: Balance of Payments Yearbook. ORGANISATION FOR EUROPEAN ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION: O.E.E.C. Statistical Bulletins ; General Statistics (semi-monthly). OTHER SOURCES General UNITED NATIONS: Economic Survey of Europe (published annually). — Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East (published annually). — Economic Survey of Latin America (published annually). — Proceedings of the World Population Conference, 1954, Summary Report (New York, 1955). ORGANISATION FOR EUROPEAN ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION : Annual reports. " Inter-Territorial Migrations of Africans South of the Sahara ", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LXXIV, No. 3, Sep. 1957, p. 292. 266 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 J. ISAAC : Economics of Migration (London, Kegan Paul, Trench, Trubner & Co., 1947). A. SAUVY: L'Europe et sa population (Paris, Les Editions internationales, 1953). A. DELPÉRÉE: Politique sociale et intégration européenne (Liège, Georges Thone, 1956). C. MARTÍ BUFILL: Nuevas soluciones al problema migratorio (Madrid, Ediciones Cultura hispánica, 1955). Brinley THOMAS (edited by): Economics of International Migration (London, MacMillan and Co. Ltd., 1958). A. SAUVY: "Some Aspects of the International Migration Problem", in International Labour Review, Vol. LVIII, No. 1, July 1948, pp. 18-37. J. ISAAC: " International Migration and European Population Trends ", ibid., Vol. LXVI, No. 3, Sep. 1952, pp. 185-206. A. OBLATH: " The Problem of Surplus Manpower in Europe ", ibid., Vol. LXX, Nos. 3-4, Sep.-Oct. 1954, pp. 301-322. X. LANNES: "International Mobility of Manpower in Western Europe". ibid., Vol. LXXIII, No. 1, Jan. 1956, pp. 1-24, and No. 2, Feb. 1956, pp. 135-151. Brinley THOMAS : " International Movements of Capital and Labour since 1945 ", ibid., Vol. LXXIV, No. 3, Sep. 1956, pp. 225-238. Law and Contemporary Problems (Durham, N.C., Duke University School of Law), Vol. XXI, No. 2, Spring of 1956 (issue devoted to migration questions). Material concerning Individual Countries Australia. Sir Douglas COPLAND : " Australian Development and Immigration ", in International Labour Review, Vol. LXIII, No. 6, June 1951, pp. 633-656. W. D. BORRIE: Immigration ; Australia's Problems and Prospects (Sydney and London, Angus and Robertson, 1949). Hon. H. E. HOLT, Hon. A. A. CALWELL, W. D. BORRIE, Jean CRAIG, P. H. KARMEL and Sir Bertram STEVENS: Australia and the Migrant (Sydney and London, Angus and Robertson, 1953). Brazil. F. BASTOS DE AVILA, S.J. : Economic Impacts of Immigration; The Brazilian Immigration Problem, Publication IX, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1954). — L'immigration au Brésil (Rio de Janeiro, Agir, 1956). Canada. M. TIMLIN: Does Canada Need More People ? (Toronto, Oxford University Press, 1951). D. CORBETT: Canada's Immigration Policy (Toronto, University of Toronto Press, 1957). •— " Immigrants and Canada's Economic Expansion ", in International Labour Review, Vol. LXXVII, No. 1, Jan. 1958, pp. 19-37. France. X. LANNES: L'Immigration en France depuis 1945, Publication VIII, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1953). THE LABOUR DEMAND AND SUPPLY 267 A. SAUVY: " Besoins et possibilités de l'immigration française ", in Population (Paris, Institut national d'études démographiques), Fifth Year, No. 2, Apr.-June 1950, p. 209; and No. 3, July-Sep. 1950, p. 417. Ireland. COMMISSION ON EMIGRATION AND OTHER POPULATION PROBLEMS: Reports, 1948-54 (Dublin, The Stationery Office, 1955). J. MEENAN: " Some Features of Irish Emigration", in International Labour Review, Vol. LXIX, No. 2, Feb. 1954, pp. 126-139. Italy. COMMISSIONE PARLAMENTARE DI INCHIESTA SULLA DISOCCUPAZIONE: La disoccupazione in Italia (Rome, Camera dei Deputati, 1954). CAMERA DEI DEPUTATI: Relazione generale sulla situazione economica del paese (Rome, Istituto Poligrafico dello Stato, 1957). Japan. "Post-war Migration Problems in Japan", in International Labour Review* Vol. LXXV, No. 1, Jan. 1957, pp. 53-67. Netherlands. W. PETERSEN : Some Factors Influencing Post- War Emigration from the Netherlands, Publication VI, Research for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1952). — Planned Migration : The Social Determinants of the Dutch-Canadian Movement (Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press, 1955). Willem STEIGENGA : Industrialisation Emigration ; the Consequences of the Demographic Development in the Netherlands, Publication X, Research Group for European Migration Problems (The Hague, Martinus Nijhoff, 1955). United Kingdom. J. ISAAC: British Post-War Migration, National Institute of Economic and Social Research, Occasional Papers, XVII (Cambridge, the University Press, 1954). CHAPTER IX ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION Constituting, as it were, the positive counterpart of more stringent controls, there has been in recent years a remarkable effort on the part of governments to promote movements considered desirable through planned migration schemes and the provision of special assistance for the migrants. Responsibility in this field is entrusted either to existing government departments or to agencies set up specifically for the purpose. Details of both types of scheme, including the structure and operation of the responsible departments and agencies, are given below. This development of government action is a feature common to both immigration and emigration countries and has resulted not only in the setting up of new departments and agencies but in an increasing degree of co-operation between the countries concerned, usually under bilateral agreements. In addition, a number of entirely new forms of international action have been evolved. National Machinery Assisted migration schemes at the national level call for two general remarks. One is that such schemes—and the machinery to carry them out—are, by and large, far more elaborate in immigration than in emigration countries, in keeping with the more prominent role played by the former in the determination of economic migration currents. Secondly, immigration and emigration countries do not necessarily pursue the same goals, nor are their policies always mutually complementary. EMIGRATION COUNTRIES In emigration countries—defined as those countries whose interest requires that part of the population should emigrate—government action to promote emigration is focused on two major objectives : to limit emigration assistance to classes of persons which the country does not need, and thus operate a selection in keeping with the national interest; and to ensure for those who do emigrate the best possible chances of success. These are the two guiding principles on which planned emigra- ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 269 tion policies have been based from the beginning and which largely account for their increasingly systematic character and growing effectiveness. Thus, there is both a negative and a positive side to such policies —negative in so far as they aim at preventing the departure both of individuals needed at home and of those unlikely to succeed abroad (and also at protecting would-be emigrants from tendentious propaganda), and positive in so far as they imply a whole series of concrete promotional measures, ranging from publication of factual data on conditions abroad to the promotion of employment opportunities and including participation in selection operations, vocational training for prospective migrants, partial coverage of transport and establishment expenses, and payment of repatriation costs. The extent of the services provided naturally depends on the importance of emigration to the country concerned and on its financial resources. The structure and working of the agencies entrusted with these various responsibilities are discussed below. Administrative Structure of Emigration Services Emigration services may be organised in one of two ways : a special agency may be solely or chiefly responsible for the implementation of emigration policy, including co-ordination of the work of other services concerned; or responsibility may be divided amongst existing instrumentalities, each acting within its own sphere of competence. In the latter case, activities carried on within the country, i.e. information, issuance of documents, vocational training, pre-selection, grant of loans and, in some cases, inspection of vessels, are entrusted to the departments responsible for labour and social affairs. Those which entail dealings abroad, i.e. negotiation of agreements, contacts with government agencies in immigration countries or with international organisations, assistance to emigrants and repatriation are usually the responsibility of foreign ministries. Jurisdictional conflicts are avoided by setting up co-ordinating bodies or by entrusting primary responsibility to one of the departments concerned. Schemes of the latter type are still the more frequent, few countries having so far set up special agencies to deal with emigration matters. Italy, for example, has a system of the traditional type whereby responsibility is divided mainly between the labour and foreign affairs departments. 1 Separate emigration agencies, where they exist, have only 1 A proposed scheme for a complete reorganisation of the Italian emigration services, including the setting up of a separate administration, has been under discussion for several years in the Italian parliament. 270 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 limited powers. For instance, in the Federal Republic of Germany the Federal Emigration Office merely provides information and advice for prospective emigrants. Similarly, in the United Kingdom an Oversea Migration Board was established in 1953 to advise the government departments responsible for emigration policy. The countries in which special administrations with sweeping powers have been established are Spain, Portugal, the Netherlands and Japan. In Spain the decision was quite a recent one: the Spanish Emigration Institute, operating under the direct authority of the President, was only set up in 1956. Its purpose is to enable the Government to pursue a more vigorous emigration policy while at the same time concentrating responsibility, formerly divided among several ministerial departments, in a single agency. In Portugal an Emigration Board set up in 1947 performs important functions in the field of information, protection and material aid to migrants and, although Portuguese emigration is traditionally spontaneous, has over the past few years sponsored several planned emigration projects. In the Netherlands the government services responsible for emigration planning and assistance were completely reorganised in 1952. They report to the Minister of Social Affairs and Public Health and are entrusted with the full range of government responsibilities in the emigration field. Their structure is rather complicated, consisting of an Emigration Council which advises the Minister, an Emigration Commissariat entrusted with foreign relations, an Emigration Board which co-ordinates government activities with those of private agencies, and an Emigration Service which reports both to the Commissariat and to the Board and is responsible for the operational aspects of organised and assisted migration schemes. In Japan, the Advisory Emigration Council, an advisory body reporting to the Prime Minister, was set up in 1955. An executory organ set up in the same year and known as the Emigration Bureau operates under the authority of the Minister of Foreign Affairs but does not perform the full range of tasks concerned with emigration : it co-ordinates the work of several administrative departments, which remain entrusted with important responsibilities at the national level, and supervises the activities of two semi-public bodies, the Federation of Overseas Associations in Japan and the Japan Emigration Promotion Company Limited. The main purpose of the former is to maintain contact between the mother country and Japanese settlements abroad ; in particular, it carries out selection operations. The latter body is essentially a financing agency. In none of these four countries has the existence of special emigration agencies completely stripped existing government departments, e.g. * ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 271 employment, diplomatic and consular services, of their traditional functions. All of these agencies are of a mixed character : they are partly executory organs and partly liaison and co-ordination bodies, empowered as such to issue certain instructions to government departments. Nor has their existence always lessened the tendency of the authorities to leave part of the work of organising emigration and even of protecting emigrants to private organisations and voluntary agencies such as have played an important part in the past and whose experience, contacts and financial resources enable them to render invaluable assistance. Thus, in the Netherlands the Emigration Service relies both on the public employment service and on local offices of voluntary welfare organisations for registration, guidance and briefing of prospective emigrants. Administrative centralisation of emigration functions has led in some cases to a tightening of the links between such private organisations and the responsible government departments; in the Netherlands the latter effectively supervise and co-ordinate the activities of the former, whose representatives sit on the Emigration Council and the Emigration Board. In Japan, the Government has recently made some inroads in fields formerly reserved for private organisations, as witnessed by the establishment of the two semi-public bodies mentioned above. Work of Emigration Services The first duty of emigration services is to provide emigration opportunities for interested workers. This is traditionally done mainly by negotiating bilateral agreements with the responsible authorities in foreign countries. Under such arrangements, the advantages and facilities of collective recruitment are placed at the workers' disposal, supplementing whatever opportunities may already exist for spontaneous, unaided emigration. An increasingly common practice is for emigration countries to entrust their diplomatic or consular officers or special study missions with the task of searching systematically for new employment opportunities in the immigration countries. This presupposes close contacts not only with government departments but also with private organisations or big individual employers who may be interested in recruiting foreign workers. The Netherlands Emigration Commissariat, for one, has from the beginning placed heavy stress on this phase of its work. To provide emigrants with jobs which they might not be able to obtain through their own efforts is not, however, the sole purpose of diplomatic negotiation. Another is to secure legal safeguards and other advantages in immigration countries both for persons who emigrate « 272 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 spontaneously and for those recruited under bilateral agreements, and to ensure through the local diplomatic and consular authorities that the undertakings given are respected. The second major function of emigration services is to bring foreign employment opportunities to the attention of would-be emigrants and also to inform them as accurately as possible of living and working conditions abroad. The need for objective information on these subjects is obvious. Of course, immigrants can also obtain such information from other sources, e.g. foreign diplomatic and consular missions and voluntary or other private organisations concerned with migration matters. The accuracy of the information thus supplied is usually guaranteed by law.1 Even countries not pursuing active emigration policies, such as the Federal Republic of Germany and Switzerland, have entrusted specific government departments with this function.2 In some cases not only information, but advice as well, is provided either by the emigration department or by the regular employment services : in the past it was usually left to voluntary organisations to help future emigrants with their plans. In this field, as in many others, there has been a general shifting of responsibility towards the State. Emigration services are also concerned with other essential matters, such as recruitment and vocational training. In the case of recruitment, the authorities act in two ways : by supervising private recruitment for protective purposes, and by engaging directly in recruiting operations under bilateral agreements. In Italy, for instance, the supervision exercised over recruitment consists of an examination by the authorities of the employment contracts produced by applicants for emigration passports : if the stipulated conditions are not deemed satisfactory, the applicant is turned down. In African emigration territories, controls are exercised on recruiting methods, proposed conditions of employment and the health of migrants. As for the participation of emigration services in the work of recruiting missions sent by immigration countries, this may either take place at the time of final selection or (as in Italy and the Netherlands) consist of a pre-selection process carried out under the sole responsibility of the emigration country. This procedure simplifies the work of foreign missions and spares candidates not fulfilling the 1 Most countries have long since adopted laws aimed at preventing the publication of misleading information, and although cases of propagandistic misrepresentation are far fewer than in the past, court proceedings are occasionally instituted on the basis of these laws. Some countries have even restricted the right to publish migration information to certain recognised agencies. 2 In the Federal Republic of Germany the Federal Emigration Office, and in Switzerland the Manpower and Emigration Section of the Federal Office of Industry, Arts and Crafts, and Labour. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 273 requisite conditions as to age, health or other qualifications an unnecessary journey to the recruiting centre. Regarding government action in the field of vocational training, this has been substantially developed in recent years with a view to permitting applicants for emigration to meet the occupational requirements of immigration countries. The need for such training has been felt acutely in southern Europe where emigration pressures are strong but where few applicants have the necessary qualifications. In the absence of specific information concerning the nature and extent of the labour demand in immigration countries, the competent administrative departments have recently resorted to a new formula whereby basic and, to some extent, multi-purpose training is given in a limited number of trades for which demand is both constant and heavy, e.g. building, metallurgy and engineering construction, it being left to the immigration countries to supplement this basic training according to their needs. This has been done in Italy, Greece, Malta and, more recently, in Spain ; in some cases the training was given specifically with emigration in view, while in others the training programme was designed to satisfy both foreign demand and the needs of the national economy. In the Netherlands special centres for agricultural vocational training were set up for prospective emigrants while those intending to enter non-agricultural occupations were admitted to training centres for craftsmen. In some instances, bilateral agreements were concluded between emigration and immigration countries specifically with a view to training workers in certain occupations. Such an agreement has recently been concluded between Italy and France, and unofficial negotiations looking to another arrangement of this type are now under way between an Italian organisation for the training of commercial employees and hotel trade organisations in Switzerland and Germany. In many instances, vocational training has been accompanied by an attempt at psychological preparation of future emigrants for their new life, chiefly through the teaching of languages. However, worthwhile as efforts made in the field of vocational training have been, they have not so far, in spite of aid from foreign governments and above all from certain international organisations, achieved fully satisfactory results owing to inadequate financial support. Another increasingly important form of government assistance consists of total or partial coverage of the emigrants' travel expenses through money grants, loans or services in kind. The Government of the Netherlands, in particular, has provided quite generously for its nationals in this respect; similarly, the United Kingdom and the Government of Malta have subsidised many passages, particularly to 274 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Australia. In the United Kingdom, financial provision has been made for this purpose in the Commonwealth Settlement Act, 1957, which extends until 1962 the provisions of the former Empire Settlement Act. In Italy, applicants for emigration are entitled to free transport to preselection centres; successful candidates are then transported, again free of charge, to one of the three emigration centres (Milan, Naples and Messina) where they are housed and fed at government expense and where medical—and, where appropriate, vocational—selection is carried out by representatives of the immigration country; administrative formalities connected with their departure and establishment in the country of destination are also performed for them at this stage. In Japan there are two emigration centres of this type, founded in 1952 and 1956 respectively; the Japan Emigration Promotion Company Limited is charged with providing financial assistance for emigrants requiring it. In some cases the assistance provided extends beyond contributions to travel costs and includes advances to help the emigrant pay his initial establishment expenses. Thus, in Italy a semi-public body known as the National Credit Institute for Italian Labour Abroad grants loans to emigrants for this purpose, including loans to employers settling in foreign countries and providing employment opportunities there for Italian workers. The Italian Government also provides financial assistance for emigrants' families having stayed behind pending receipt of the first remittances from the head of the family, and also in certain cases where members of the family have been declared unfit for emigration. In Japan, the Japan Emigration Promotion Company Limited has been entrusted with a similar task. At the same time voluntary organisations have continued to play an important part in financing the transport and settlement of emigrants, e.g. by subsidising land settlement schemes. Assistance to emigrants does not end when they leave the country. In most cases, transport conditions are regulated by statute. Moreover, the authorities of the emigration country take a more or less active part in their reception in the country of destination, where they further enjoy consular protection. Finally, many governments have established special funds to aid any of their nationals finding themselves disabled, sick or destitute abroad and, if necessary, repatriate them. These forms of government action are, of course, unevenly developed from one country to another, since the interests and, above all, the financial resources of the various countries are not the same. A statistical appraisal of the proportion of assisted emigration to total emigration would undoubtedly be of interest. Unfortunately, the statistics of the various countries cannot be compared owing to variations in the definition of " assisted " emigrants. In Italy the figures ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 275 cover, in the case of continental emigration, persons selected and moved under the auspices of the Ministry of Labour pursuant to bilateral agreements. They account for practically all of the emigration to Belgium and most of that to France. In the case of overseas movements, the only official figures published since 1952 are those of the Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration with which the Italian Government co-operates in providing assistance (particularly as regards transport facilities). Even though the proportion of emigrants assisted in this way has increased in recent years, from 1952 to 1956 it did not average more than a quarter of the total figure—thus bearing witness to a strong and persistent strain of self-reliance among overseas emigrants. Maltese emigration since 1948 has been assisted by the joint efforts of the British and Island Governments with the result that more than 70 per cent, of all emigrants receive some assistance towards their travel expenses. More than half of the British emigrants to Australia have travelled partly, and more than one-tenth wholly, at government expense. In the Netherlands the proportion of emigrants receiving financial assistance from the Government has also been considerable, at least in recent years, and has grown steadily: from 1953 to 1956, nearly 135,000 out of 160,000 emigrants proceeding to overseas countries other than Indonesia, Surinam and the Netherlands Antilles and the Dutch possessions in the Pacific received assistance in one form or another from the Emigration Service, and nearly 100,000, i.e. more than 60 per cent, of the total, received financial assistance to cover part of their travel and establishment expenses. The proportion, which amounted to approximately one-half in 1953, increased to three-quarters in 1956. IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES Even by restricting assistance to certain classes of persons, as is quite generally done, emigration countries are not always able to select emigrants in accordance with their wishes. Immigration countries are in a stronger position in this regard, since freedom to emigrate is a generally recognised principle whereas freedom to immigrate is not. In addition, a number of these countries—the major ones, in fact—are in a more favourable economic position and have greater resources to devote to organising and assisting desired movements. This form of government intervention has developed considerably in recent years. Usually, it has been entrusted to specialised administrative agencies whose range of duties and resources have been considerably extended throughout the period under review and whose structure has 276 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 often been modified in response to new needs. As in emigration countries, this new trend has both a negative and a positive side—negative in that selection has grown stricter, and positive in that it is more actively guided than in the past, with increasingly numerous and elaborate assistance services being provided for the chosen candidates. Finally, in spite of the development of government action, nongovernmental organisations have continued to play an important part in the reception and placing of immigrants and have given them valuable help in adjusting to their new surroundings. Administrative Structure of Immigration Services The admission and settlement of immigrants impinges on various fields of public policy, including employment, social security, housing, public health and national security. Formerly it was the responsibility of foreign ministries to ensure the necessary co-ordination between the various departments concerned. This system has now been generally abandoned in favour of other schemes of co-ordination, and special agencies have, far more generally than in emigration countries, been set up both to take direct responsibility for immigration matters and to co-operate as necessary with other government departments having retained more or less wide powers in this field. The details of such schemes vary from one country to another; a few examples are given below. In France six ministries are concerned with the execution of immigration policy : those of Foreign Affairs, Interior (which is responsible for issuing residence cards), Labour and Social Security, Health and Population, Industry and Commerce, and Agriculture. An Inter-Ministerial Commission for Immigration Affairs co-ordinates their policies, and an operational agency known as the National Immigration Office, established in 1945 and placed under the joint supervision of the Ministries of Labour and Health, is responsible for the selection and movement of immigrant workers and their families once they have been accepted by both Ministries. Workers are recruited only if a vacancy has been notified to, and recruiting authorised by, the labour authorities (who are assisted by tripartite advisory committees set up at the national and regional levels). This may or may not involve designating the worker by name: only in the latter case is the National Immigration Office directly responsible for recruitment. For this purpose it maintains permanent recruiting missions abroad 1 and transient centres in France. By virtue of its monopoly on recruitment it is also empowered to regularise the situation of foreign workers having entered France and taken 1 Such a mission was set up in Italy in 1946 and another in Germany in 1947; the latter was withdrawn in 1953. More recently, another was sent to Spain. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 277 up employment irregularly, subject to the approval of the ministries concerned. The Office's operations are financed by employer contributions fixed at a flat rate for each foreign worker whom the Office recruits or whose situation it regularises. The travelling expenses of families are paid partly by the workers themselves and partly by the Ministry of Health. The monopoly vested in the National Immigration Office does not extend to self-employed workers: these fall within the competence of the Ministry of Agriculture or of Industry and Commerce, as the case may be, but are not covered by any special arrangements. In the United Kingdom the Home Office supervises the admission, and the Ministry of Labour and National Service the employment, of foreigners. A National Joint Advisory Council consisting of representatives of employers, workers, the nationalised industries and the Government assists the Minister of Labour in formulating policy, and, in particular, planning migration programmes ; the execution of the latter has on several occasions involved sending temporary recruiting missions to various European countries. In Belgium, contrary to the practice followed in France and, to some extent, in the United Kingdom, the Government does not undertake recruitment of foreign workers and does not assist them. Nevertheless, immigration is governed by a prescribed procedure under which the Ministries of Foreign Affairs and Justice are responsible for the delivery of residence permits, and the Ministry of Labour and Social Welfare for that of employment permits. In formulating policy, the Minister of Labour consults a Tripartite Committee on Foreign Labour consisting of government, employer and worker representatives. In Switzerland, as in Belgium, the authorities supervise, but do not actively assist in, the recruitment of foreign workers. The federal structure of the State has resulted in a sharing of administrative responsibility, except as regards the foreign relations aspect. Employment permits are delivered by the cantonal authorities entrusted with the control of foreign residents, subject to approval of the cantonal and federal labour authorities. The federal, and sometimes the cantonal, authorities are assisted by an advisory committee on which employers and workers are represented. The structure of immigration services in western Europe thus varies greatly from one country to another. As a rule, they are simply control organs, except in France where they have clearly been designed to serve state planning objectives. In the United States, the enforcement of legislative provisions relating to immigration, except those which reserve certain powers for the Presi- 278 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 dent or entrust specific responsibilities to the Secretary of State or officiais of the State Department, is normally the responsibility of the AttorneyGeneral, who delegates part of it to the Commissioner of Immigration and Naturalization. The Immigration and Naturalization Service cooperates closely with the State Department Bureau of Security and Consular Affairs, which supervises the issuance of visas by the consular authorities.1 These various administrative organs have only a passive responsibility, which is to ensure that the regulations are properly applied. However, the emergency laws of 1948 and 1953 led to the development of government action along more positive lines. The 1948 Act established a Displaced Persons Commission reporting directly to the President, with authority to organise the immigration and settlement of refugees entitled to admission under the Act. This was done in liaison with the regular administrative agencies concerned, the International Refugee Organisation and a large number of voluntary organisations. The 1953 Act empowered the State Department to take certain measures aimed at facilitating the movement and settlement of immigrants admitted under the Act and to conclude agreements for this purpose with the governments concerned and with the Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration. Seasonal farm immigration, finally, is covered by a special scheme and to that extent may be said to be " organised ". Organised immigration, however, is far more developed in Canada. The scheme includes an Inter-Departmental Advisory Committee on Immigration, placed under the chairmanship of the Deputy Minister of the Department of Citizenship and Immigration, and including officials of that department and of others concerned, i.e. External Affairs, Labour, National Health and Welfare, and Finance. This Committee offers advice on immigration policy and helps to co-ordinate the work of the various departments. Responsibility for the execution of immigration policy is largely in the hands of the Immigration Branch of the Department of Citizenship and Immigration, which draws up programmes of admission, makes the necessary approaches to foreign governments, selects applicants and, where necessary, provides transport, reception, guidance and placement assistance for immigrants. Outside Canada, the Immigration Branch maintains missions in Europe including an office in London, whose sphere of activity in some cases extends beyond the United Kingdom and includes continental Europe. The respons1 The 1952 Immigration and Nationality Act has established a Joint Congressional Committee consisting of five representatives and five senators who study immigration problems and submit periodical reports to both Houses of Congress. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 279 ibility of the Labour Department, on the other hand, is confined to supplying information on employment opportunities in Canada to the Immigration Branch and directly to the workers concerned through its offices in Europe, and also to taking part in selection operations. The Department of National Health and Labour, in co-operation with the Immigration Branch, conducts medical examinations locally, and the Royal Canadian Mounted Police examines the applicants' records of conduct. Finally, the Citizenship Branch of the Department of Citizenship and Immigration has the responsibility of helping immigrants to become integrated in the Canadian community. In Latin America organised immigration has often developed in conjunction with land settlement policies. In several countries, e.g. Brazil and Venezuela, the authorities in charge of land settlement also have responsibilities in the field of immigration, and these sometimes extend to categories of immigrants other than rural settlers. In Brazil executive responsibility for immigration matters has since 1954 been entrusted to the National Institute of Immigration and Settlement, an autonomous body placed under the control of the Ministry of Agriculture, which has taken over powers previously vested in the Immigration and Settlement Council, the National Immigration Department of the Ministry of Labour, Industry and Commerce, and the Land and Settlement Division of the Ministry of Agriculture. The Institute is composed of an executive board, an advisory committee consisting of eight members representing the various ministries concerned, the Bank of Brazil and the Brazilian Rural Confederation, and a finance committee. Thus it enjoys considerable independence and is in a position to co-ordinate the work of the various departments effectively. Its powers are far-reaching and include preparing bilateral agreements in co-operation with the Ministry of Foreign Affairs ; formulating admission criteria for the guidance of consular authorities; establishing rules for police inspection of migrants (in co-operation with the Ministry of Justice) and for medical examinations (with the Ministry of Public Health); and carrying out immigration programmes through the various stages of recruitment, selection, admission and settlement of classes of immigrants considered desirable.1 Prior to the establishment of the Institute these functions had been performed by the agencies then responsible through recruiting missions in Europe and reception centres in Brazil. Both the missions and the centres now report to the Institute. Venezuela has a less integrated system. Immigration is controlled, in the traditional fashion, by the Ministry of Foreign Relations through 1 It also carries out occasional surveys of foreign labour requirements and operates one or more employment services in each of the various states. 280 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the diplomatic and consular authorities. These nevertheless receive instructions from the National Agrarian Institute concerning selection criteria. This body has since 1949 replaced the former Technical Institute for Immigration and Settlement. It is attached to the Ministry of Agriculture and one of its functions is to organise and assist immigration related directly to its own land settlement programme. For this purpose it maintains missions in Europe and operates reception centres in Venezuela. In Argentina responsibility for immigration has since 1949 been largely concentrated in the hands of the National Migration Directorate. Immigration policy is not conditioned by land settlement imperatives to the same extent as in Venezuela, since these play a far less important part in development planning. The National Directorate is entrusted with powers formerly divided among several agencies, namely the General Migration Board, the Argentine Delegation for Immigration in Europe and the Immigrant Reception and Settlement Commission. Its duties include negotiating bilateral agreements and dealing with all problems of selection, transport, reception and final settlement. Other agencies assume certain responsibilities in liaison with the National Directorate ; these include the consular authorities (which issue visas) and the police. More recently an Inter-Ministerial Advisory Committee and a National Co-ordinating Committee were set up to promote and carry out immigrant land settlement and development projects. In Australia the various executive functions are highly centralised: since 1945 there has been a Commonwealth Department of Immigration which since 1949 has been headed by the Minister for Labour and National Service; moreover, in each state a minister is responsible for immigration matters falling within the competence of state governments. The Commonwealth Department of Immigration controls admissions, formulates and carries out immigration programmes, and is responsible for aftercare of immigrants admitted under such programmes. It has set up a number of missions in Europe 1 whose duties include, among others, selection and transport organisation. State governments are responsible for checking nominations made by Australian sponsors and also for the reception of assisted immigrants. In addition, three advisory bodies assist the federal Government in the formulation of immigration and assimilation policy. These are the Immigration Advisory Council, consisting of representatives of trade unions, employers' organisations and various private associations, which provides advice on assimilation problems; the Immigration Planning Council which is made up of 1 In London, The Hague, Cologne and Rome. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 281 representatives of industry and labour and of economists, and is concerned with immigration problems having economic development implications; and the Australian Citizenship Convention which meets annually to discuss civic problems. In New Zealand responsibility for the implementation of immigration laws and the execution of immigration programmes also lies with the Minister of Immigration who, as in Australia, is at the same time Minister of Labour and Employment. The Immigration Division, placed under the authority of the Director of Employment, is the agency specifically responsible, the functions of the customs administration having been confined since 1951 to exercising control at ports of entry. Two immigration offices have been established in Europe, one in the United Kingdom and the other in the Netherlands, to carry out assisted immigration programmes. An Immigration Advisory Council which includes representatives of employers' and workers' organisations has been attached to the Ministry since 1947. In the Union of South Africa immigration is not " organised " in the true sense : it is merely supervised by the Minister of the Interior. An Immigrant Selection Board deals with non-British entrance applications. Work of Immigration Services The duties of immigration services vary in scope depending on whether or not the national policy is one of active promotion. In the United States, for instance, they normally consist only of selection; but in other cases they may cover the entire process of recruitment, transport and placing in employment. In countries pursuing active immigration policies, the first step, of course, is to make recruiting arrangements through bilateral agreement, and often to send temporary or permanent missions abroad to provide information for interested workers, select suitable candidates and facilitate their movement. Selection proper, however, remains the chief duty of immigration services. This may take place either through the normal diplomatic and consular channels or through ad hoc missions. The two methods do not differ fundamentally, although selection missions are more expeditious and effective in the case of large-scale recruiting. Owing to its recent development, this latter practice is worth discussing briefly, even though most immigrants are still selected by traditional methods. As a rule, selection missions consist of specialised officials, who must ascertain whether or not the candidates fulfil general admission criteria, and of 282 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 physicians who examine them not only from the point of view of general health but also, in some cases, of suitability for the employment contemplated. Selection officers and physicians are often accompanied by technical advisers, whose function it is to ascertain the vocational skills of applicants, and sometimes by police officials charged with detecting potential security risks. Once all of the particulars have been obtained they are usually referred to a higher authority—either a regional office or the central headquarters—for decision. The work of the mission, of course, varies depending on whether or not it has to fill a specific demand. Only in the former case does it perform a genuine recruiting function, e.g. where immigration laws specify that no foreign worker shall be admitted into the country unless there is a job waiting for him, as in France, the United Kingdom, Sweden and the Federal Republic of Germany. Some non-European countries, e.g. Canada, Australia and Southern Rhodesia, have also resorted on occasion to such practices when faced with well-defined and urgent needs for workers in certain industries. In some cases immigrants are selected in part by private organisations, as in Belgium, where the Federation of Belgian Coal-Mining Employers recruits on behalf of coal-mining companies. The system is also used in Africa (particularly the southern part) for the recruitment of African labour. In the Union of South Africa, for instance, the Witwatersrand Native Labour Association undertakes the recruitment of foreign workers in neighbouring territories for the account of various industrial undertakings, in co-operation with the Government and subject to its supervision. These private societies also assume responsibility for medical examinations and administrative formalities. Once the immigrants have been accepted, a wide range of facilities is usually provided for them by the authorities of the immigration country. Foremost among these is financial aid towards coverage of travel expenses. This is an increasingly widespread practice, although the amounts and methods of financing vary considerably. In Europe, the travel expenses of workers recruited either by the government or (in the case of Belgium) by private organisations are wholly covered by the agencies responsible for selection and reimbursed by the employers. In Canada the Department of Citizenship and Immigration only provides loans. The United States Government has contributed generously towards the transport of refugees and displaced persons admitted under the emergency relief legislation. In Venezuela immigrants admitted under the auspices of the National Agrarian Institute have hitherto been sent free of charge to their place of settlement, but have had to pay their own travel expenses to Venezuela. In Argentina, the passage of ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 283 the Italian immigrants who entered under the bilateral agreement of 1948 was paid by the Argentine Government. In Australia the Government pays part of the travel expenses of immigrants selected under bilateral agreements with the United Kingdom, Ireland, Malta, the Netherlands, Italy, the Federal Republic of Germany, and under the special arrangements with Greece; the balance is borne by the immigrants, the governments of countries of origin and the Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration, which is a third party to some of these arrangements. The Government of New Zealand grants free passage to certain categories of British immigrants and pays part of the expenses in the case of certain Dutch immigrants. In Africa recruiting societies provide free transport for the workers to their place of employment. Often, the immigration authorities provide additional services for immigrants during the voyage ; these may include payment of personal maintenance expenses, medical supervision on board ship and sometimes language and orientation courses. Further assistance is often provided on arrival, e.g. at reception centres where immigrants are temporarily housed and fed free of charge or at a nominal cost. Arrangements of this kind exist in France, the United Kingdom, Canada, Venezuela, Brazil, Argentina, Australia and New Zealand. Immigration services also undertake, where necessary, to help new arrivals find jobs. Canada and Australia are particularly well organised in this respect. Financial assistance to immigrants sometimes covers not only travel but also establishment expenses, usually in the form of direct government loans or government-guaranteed bank loans. Such assistance has been a feature of some land settlement schemes in Latin America. Selected immigrants receive loans to cover their establishment and initial operating expenses, and sometimes also technical assistance from the government. Such schemes are not, as a rule, organised and financed solely by the immigration countries, except in Venezuela where they have been carried through without any outside help. In other countries, e.g. Brazil, land settlement projects have been the subject of bilateral arrangements with the countries of origin, the latter providing financial assistance from either government or private sources. Generally speaking, however, government assistance towards the establishment either of land settlers or other classes of immigrants has not so far reached significant proportions. Similarly, comparatively little has been accomplished in the field of vocational training : the problem in immigration countries is regarded ' primarily as one of practical, on-the-job adjustment for which the employer is responsible. Vocational training centres for adults, where 284 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 they exist, are, of course, open to foreigners, and apart from this there have been instances during the past few years where immigration countries have helped technically and financially to operate training programmes for prospective emigrants, either directly under bilateral agreements or, more often, under tripartite arrangements made through I.C.E.M. Some countries, e.g. Canada and Australia, have also organised language and civic education courses for immigrants. In spite of the considerable efforts made by governments to assist immigrants, voluntary organisations have continued to play a dominant role in many areas such as preparation and financing of the journey, reception and, above all, placement. They also sponsor welfare and cultural activities to help the immigrants adjust to their new surroundings. Statistical analysis raises the same problems in the case of assisted immigration as in that of emigration. Immigration in most countries is organised to such an extent that there are few, if any, immigrants who do not receive government assistance in one form or another. The only data seriously worth considering, therefore, are those relating to the main form of assistance, i.e. payment of travel costs. In France, such assistance is available to all immigrant workers moved by the National Immigration Office and to their families. All officially registered immigrants could therefore be counted as assisted immigrants, were it not for the fact that the figures also include irregular, and hence unassisted, entries subsequently regularised by the Office.1 In the United Kingdom immigrants recruited under collective programmes have received some forms of government assistance, e.g. hostel accommodation, but travel expenses have been paid by employers. In Canada, elaborate provisions have been made for reception and placement. Moreover, between the entry into force of the assisted passage scheme in February 1951 and the end of 1955 nearly 32,000 immigrants received loans totalling more than 5 million dollars under its provisions. In the United States German expellees admitted under the Displaced Persons Act of 1948 were assisted out of funds provided by the Displaced Persons Commission. In Venezuela the National Agrarian Institute, between its establishment in 1949 and the end of 1956, contributed financially to the establishment of more than 45,000 persons. This figure, however, represents a fairly small fraction of total immigration during the period considered. Moreover, as already mentioned, this assistance did not extend to the oversea journey: the dependants of immigrants already established in Venezuela were about the only persons to receive such aid; this was done under a family 1 It will be recalled that even in the case of movements organised by the Office transport costs are ultimately borne by the employers. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 285 regrouping programme carried out with I.C.E.M. assistance. In Brazil the National Institute of Immigration and Settlement assisted some 30,000 immigrants from late 1954 until early 1956, contributing financially towards their passage ; but the number of immigrants who have received passage assistance since 1952—mainly under I.C.E.M. schemes, most of which antedate the Institute's foundation—is much higher. In the case of Argentina the only available figures relate to immigration assisted by I.C.E.M. since 1952, mostly under government-sponsored schemes for the reuniting of families. In Australia transport assistance reached considerable proportions: from 1947 to 1956 the Government contributed financially to the movement of 600,000 immigrants, i.e. about three-fifths of the total figure, under a series of programmes drawn up on a bilateral, and later, with the assistance of I.C.E.M., on a trilateral basis. New Zealand has, on a more modest scale, pursued a similar policy: some 45,000 immigrants, i.e. more than 20 per cent, of the total immigration figure, were moved either wholly or partly at government expense. Most of these were British, the remainder consisting of Netherlands nationals and displaced persons. Bilateral and Multilateral Agreements Another major development in the field of government-organised and sponsored migration has been the conclusion of many bilateral and a few multilateral agreements concerning the organisation of movements and the economic and legal status of immigrants in their new homeland. Formerly, migration provisions were included in friendship, trade or navigation treaties, and a number of establishment and labour treaties concluded between European countries contained clauses defining the rights of nationals of either contracting party living and working on the territory of the other. However, agreements having the joint organisation of migratory movements as their primary purpose are a new development in international law, just as are bilateral and multilateral social security agreements. TREATIES Friendship, trade and navigation treaties, which contain clauses defining the rights of citizens of either contracting party on the territory of the other are comparatively few and of limited practical significance. Such treaties have recently been concluded between a number of countries of Europe and Latin America. Another example is the friendship treaty concluded in 1955 between Japan and Cambodia which provides, 286 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 among other economic and cultural clauses, for the admission of Japanese nationals to Cambodia as farm settlers, fishermen and craftsmen. Many bilateral treaties of establishment have in the past been concluded between European countries, the greater part by far before the war. These treaties usually grant foreigners the right of entry into, residence and travel in, and departure from, the country concerned, but usually specify that such rights shall be as defined in existing laws; their practical significance nowadays is accordingly slight. The same may be said of treaties granting certain foreign nationals the right to engage in a gainful occupation. Only clauses providing for the return to their countries of origin of foreigners expelled by the authorities constitute an exception to this rule. Finally, bilateral labour treaties have been concluded between certain countries, mainly in western Europe between the two wars, although France has concluded two such treaties since 1946: with Switzerland and with the Netherlands. These treaties have a more direct bearing on migration since they deal with such matters as recruiting procedures, conditions of residence, employment, working conditions, social insurance and welfare, and repatriation. MIGRATION AND RECRUITING AGREEMENTS The proliferation of migration and recruiting agreements since 1946 is due to several reasons. Foremost among these is the increasing tendency of immigration countries to entrust selection of migrants to ad hoc missions rather than to the diplomatic and consular authorities : the work of these missions clearly depends on mutual co-operation between the governments concerned. Another reason has been the need to organise and finance increasingly large movements, and the resulting awareness on the part of governments with common immigration and emigration interests of the need for co-ordinating their activities and sharing expenses according to a mutually agreed plan. A third factor has been the almost universal practice of currency exchange restrictions and the need for special provisions to permit the transfer of savings. Finally, the progress of social security has made it necessary to harmonise benefits in the various countries, and many countries have in fact concluded special agreements for this purpose. Migration agreements are of many different kinds. Some are general, while others cover specific classes of workers : an example of the latter is the agreement concluded by France and Italy in February 1946 concerning the recruitment of Italian workers for French mines. Some agreements are concerned with migration movements in general while ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 287 others cover only frontier movements (e.g. the 1949 agreement between France and Belgium and the 1952 agreement between Germany and Belgium) or seasonal ones (e.g. the 1951 agreement, since amended on several occasions, between the United States and Mexico). While some agreements are concluded for an indefinite period, subject to unilateral denunciation, they constitute an exception rather than the rule; periods of validity, however, may differ considerably. Less commonly, a limit is placed on the number of persons to be admitted; this is the general practice in the case of agreements covering very short periods such as those concluded by France in 1947 and 1948 with the British and American Occupation authorities in Germany for the recruitment of German workers. Finally, governments may not be the sole parties to migration agreements : many have been concluded between governments and, first, the I.R.O. and, later, I.C.E.M. In Africa the contracting parties are, as a rule, the territorial administrations concerned. In some cases one of the parties may be a private person or body. Thus, the Japanese Ministry of Foreign Affairs has, with the agreement of the Brazilian Government, concluded agreements with Japanese settlers in Brazil aimed at promoting further immigration of Japanese agricultural workers, and in Africa recruiting agreements have been concluded between territorial governments and certain private recruiting agencies. In spite of the variety of forms in which they occur, most migration agreements have a number of common features which are briefly analysed below. Agreements concerned exclusively with social security matters are dealt with separately in a further section. Most agreements contain provisions limiting their duration and sometimes also the number of persons covered. Where the latter is not specified, agreements commonly require the parties to exchange periodical information concerning manpower needs and availabilities. This, for instance, is a strict obligation under the Franco-Italian agreement of 1951. More important are the qualifications required of the migrants —even though many agreements merely repeat the conditions already stipulated in the laws of the immigration country, at least as regards age and health. However, while national health standards are usually rigidly adhered to, a more lenient attitude may be adopted in the case of age, i.e. a higher age limit may be fixed with respect to certain groups such as workers with particular skills or (as in the 1946 agreement between Australia and the United Kingdom) heads of large families. A few agreements, such as the two concluded in 1948 by Italy with the Netherlands and with Luxembourg, for the recruitment of Italian 288 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 miners and agricultural workers respectively, provide that, unless suitable housing is available, bachelors shall be accorded preferential treatment. More important still are the clauses which relate to vocational qualifications ; these are usually more detailed and more stringent than those contained in existing laws, since immigration countries providing special advantages, e.g. financial contributions towards transport costs, for workers recruited under bilateral agreements, naturally expect some assurance that the immigrants will make a useful and effective contribution to the economy. Just how stringent these conditions are naturally depends on whether the purpose of the agreement is to recruit workers requested by employers for specific jobs or simply to select immigrants who, once admitted, will be left to find work for themselves. The basic factor underlying most agreements, however, is the need for administrative co-operation between the countries concerned with recruitment and selection. Under many existing agreements—e.g. those between France and Italy, the 1954 agreement between France and Greece, and the 1955 agreement between the Federal Republic of Germany and Italy—pre-selection is a responsibility of the emigration country. This is followed by the process of selection proper, under the responsibility of the immigration authorities. There are, however, some exceptions: thus, the 1954 agreement between Italy and Belgium for the recruitment of coal miners calls only for a single medical examination by Belgian physicians. In no case do agreements provide for participation by the emigration authorities in the work of final selection. On the other hand, some of them give employers the right to be present at selection operations either occasionally or as permanent advisers. In the case of recruiting for individual employers, agreements may provide that, if a candidate selected by the immigration authorities is not accepted by the prospective employer, the immigration authorities shall undertake to find alternative employment for him or, if this is not possible, to repatriate him. A similar provision usually applies in the event that the worker loses his employment owing to disability arising in the course of his work. The provision of information for prospective migrants may also be covered by bilateral arrangements, sometimes as a responsibility of one of the contracting parties, sometimes as a joint obligation of both. In addition, many agreements assign responsibilities to the immigration authorities with respect to reception, placement, contracts of employment, repatriation, and observance of the generally accepted principle of equal treatment for national and foreign workers. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 289 Another extremely important aspect of migration agreements concerns the financing of transport. In some cases—e.g. the agreements concluded by Australia and New Zealand with the United Kingdom—this constitutes the heart of the agreement. Methods of financing vary widely. In the case of migrants recruited for specific employers the latter often have to bear the whole of the expense, as is done under the agreements concluded by Italy with France and Belgium. Where there is no recruiting in the proper sense, provision is usually made for the expense to be shared in varying proportion between the immigration country (which usually bears the greater part), the emigration country and the individual migrant. There are cases, however, in which the emigration country has no financial obligations, e.g. Italy under the 1948 agreement with Argentina. In other cases the immigration country pays part of the transport expenses by unilateral decision and in the absence of any formal agreement. Such assistance was extended by Australia in 1948 to Irish nationals, in 1954 to Scandinavian, Swiss and American immigrants and by New Zealand in 1947 to British immigrants, the latter scheme having been expanded on several occasions. Sometimes no contribution at all is required of the migrants, as in the case of certain British movements to Australia and New Zealand and of Italian immigrants entering Argentina under the 1948 agreement. Finally, trie transport assistance provisions of bilateral agreements are not usually confined to the workers themselves but extend in greater or lesser degree to their families, subject in some cases to the availability of suitable housing. Other important provisions of migration agreements have to do with the transfer of savings, and sometimes family benefits, from immigration countries applying currency restrictions. Such agreements, while recognising the right to make such transfers, subject them to specified limits and other conditions. Some agreements also contain social security clauses, although there is an increasing tendency to regulate these matters through special instruments. Finally, many agreements provide for the establishment of committees to supervise their enforcement, settle any differences which may arise and suggest any necessary changes. SOCIAL SECURITY AGREEMENTS An emigrant leaving his country of origin ceases to be covered by the social security scheme in that country and often loses his accrued rights thereunder. At the same time, in the immigration country he may find himself assimilated for social security purposes to a person entering 290 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 employment for the first time. The aim of international social security agreements and social security clauses contained in migration agreements is to minimise the prejudice thus incurred by amending existing social security laws. Many such agreements have been concluded since 1946, particularly in Europe, and more especially in western Europe, where they now constitute a highly comprehensive network of mutual obligations. One of these is a multilateral agreement concluded in 1949 between the five Brussels treaty powers, which co-ordinates the provisions of earlier Conventions concluded on a bilateral basis.1 Social security agreements usually cover the entire field of social insurance and insurance against industrial accidents and occupational diseases; sometimes they also extend to family benefits and unemployment insurance. They cover not only the establishment but also the maintenance of rights, including acquired rights and rights in course of acquisition. Such agreements may deal with either temporary or permanent migrants. In the case of the former (e.g. seasonal workers) their purpose is to ensure coverage against personal and occupational risks comparable to that enjoyed by nationals of the immigration country and to provide adequately for dependants remaining in the immigrant's country of origin ; in the case of permanent movements most agreements provide for the totalisation of periods of coverage and a proportionate sharing of expenses between the countries concerned. Sometimes they also provide for the transfer of acquired rights from the former country of residence to that of immigration, as in the case of the arrangements concerning old-age pensions between the United Kingdom on the one hand and Australia and New Zealand on the other, and the more recent agreements between eastern European countries. Intergovernmental Organisations International action in the field of migration is an outgrowth of the political refugee problem which arose immediately after the First World War. Not only have political refugees ever since been regarded as a matter of international concern but the extension of international assistance to the field of economic migration followed as a logical further step. The machinery which was set up to deal with the tremendous refugee problem which arose after the Second World War has already been described.2 1 Since 1957 the six Members of the European Coal and Steel Community have been parties to this treaty, since converted into a regulation of the European Economic Community. s See above, Chapters II and IV. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 291 In addition to the difficulties raised by the speedy resettlement of the refugees who had fled to western Europe, however, some European countries after the war were faced by large manpower surpluses resulting from the long interruption of traditional migration currents and from rapid natural population growth. These surpluses could not be readily absorbed and the need was acutely felt for international action to help solve the problem through organised migration. The initiative was taken by the International Labour Organisation whose tripartite structure as early as 1919 had set it apart from other bodies and entrusted it with unique responsibilities, and whose enlarged objectives, as defined by the Declaration of Philadelphia appended to the Constitution in 1944, included the promotion of programmes designed to facilitate " the transfer of labour, including migration for employment and settlement ". In April 1950 the Organisation accordingly convened a conference for a preliminary exchange of views on the problem. This was the starting point for many new international activities in the migration field. A group of countries belonging to both the O.E.E.C. and the I.L.O. placed nearly 1 million dollars at the disposal of the latter to enable it to develop its activities in the migration field and above all, to supply advice on migration and related problems to governments requesting it. For nearly two years such technical assistance, covering not only migration questions but also the organisation of the employment market and vocational training for prospective emigrants, was provided through missions of experts set up in Bonn, Rome and Vienna and through a group of experts attached to the I.L.O. Latin American Field Office. Pursuant to the conclusions of the 1950 conference and with a view to strengthening international action the I.L.O. called a second conference which met at Naples in October 1951. This conference had before it a programme aimed at facilitating European migration movements, both economic and political, and at solving various problems directly or indirectly related to such movements. The programme, however, was not discussed by the conference owing to the opposition of certain governments. Another international conference, held at Brussels in November 1951 on the initiative of the United States and Belgium, decided to set up a new organisation to dispose finally of the refugee problem and to tackle that of European overpopulation. A Provisional Intergovernmental Committee for the Movement of Migrants from Europe (P.I.C.M.M.E.) accordingly began to operate in the early part of 1952, using the administrative machinery of the International Refugee Organisation, and in the following year became the Inter-governmental Committee for European Migration (I.C.E.M.). Its establishment marked a new departure in the 292 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 field of internationally sponsored migration. Whereas formerly operational activities had been confined to political refugees and limited, in the case of others, to protection and information (of the kind provided under the auspices of the I.L.O.), the new organisation from the outset assumed responsibility for migration planning and assistance on a vast scale. The considerable part which I.C.E.M. has continued to play over the past few years should not, however, be allowed to overshadow the work done in related fields by other bodies; this will be discussed at a later stage. THE INTERGOVERNMENTAL COMMITTEE FOR EUROPEAN MIGRATION The Intergovernmental Committee for European Migration, set up under a resolution adopted on 5 December 1951 by the Brussels Conference, initially consisted of 14 members.1 Today it has 27 2 divided into three groups, namely European emigration countries, non-European immigration countries and sympathising countries. Its constitution was adopted in October 1953 and entered into force in November 1954. The purpose and functions of the Committee as defined in Chapter I of its constitution are " to make arrangements for the transport of migrants for whom existing facilities are inadequate " and " . . . to promote the increase of the volume of migration from Europe by providing, at the request of and in agreement with the governments concerned, services in the processing, reception, first placement and settlement of migrants which other international organisations are not in a position to supply, and such other assistance to this purpose as is in accord with the aims of the Committee". The budget of the Committee consists of two parts : an administrative part, financed by compulsory contributions from member governments which are fixed according to an agreed scale; and an operational part, which is by far the larger and consists of voluntary or negotiable contributions paid by governments interested in specific programmes, and contributions from voluntary organisations and the emigrants themselves or their sponsors. The major source of operational income consists of government contributions which are based on the number of migrants or refugees moved with the assistance of the Committee. The contribution of the United States ($74.90 for each migrant transported), however, is not 1 Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Federal Republic of Germany, France, Greece, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Switzerland and United States. 2 The following countries joined subsequently: Argentina, Colombia, Costa Rica, Denmark, Israel, New Zealand, Norway, Paraguay, the Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland, Spain, Sweden, Uruguay and Venezuela. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 293 limited to persons proceeding to that country, but extends to all migrants or refugees moved by the Committee. The other governments concerned pay contributions based on the number of persons having emigrated or immigrated. Migrants able to do so personally contribute a modest amount (50 dollars for the head of the family and less for its members) towards their travel costs; sometimes a loan is made to them prior to their departure but must be reimbursed after their arrival in the country of destination. Other facilities provided by the Committee at either end of the journey and in direct relation with it, as well as technical assistance and grants to voluntary organisations, are financed without reference to the number of persons moved. The Committee has its headquarters in Geneva and operates missions in all countries covered by its activities in and out of Europe. It requires a large maritime and air transport fleet to move European emigrants and in so doing uses normal commercial facilities, so far as possible; in addition, however, it charters its own ships and planes, its position as a major charterer enabling it to secure particularly favourable financial terms and physical transport conditions. Like the I.R.O., it employs escort personnel who provide welfare and medical services for emigrants during the voyage. Migrants moved by the Committee are divided into two categories : the so-called " spontaneous " migrants, whom it aids either directly or through voluntary organisations and—by far the more numerous— those who move under programmes sponsored by overseas immigration countries. With respect to the latter, the Committee acts as a third party to the arrangements between the governments concerned, on whose behalf it undertakes certain planning and assistance functions in return for contributions to its budget. Thus it has played an important part in the execution of the immigration programme established in the United States under the Refugee Relief Act of 1953, family regrouping schemes sponsored by several Latin American countries and Australian assisted immigration projects which were originally to have been carried out on a purely bilateral basis and included immigrants from Germany, the Netherlands, Italy, Greece and Malta. More recently, the Committee has played a major part in [the evacuation of Hungarian refugees.1 The work of the Committee, however, has by no means been confined —indeed it is less and less confined—to making transport arrangements. It has had, for instance, to explore ways and means of developing and improving European migration by promoting agricultural settlement in 1 See above, Chapter II. 294 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 several Latin American countries and by helping governments to improve their administrative machinery in such fields as pre-selection, selection, reception and placement; in one country—Greece—it has even assumed direct responsibility for providing complete emigration services. Technical assistance is being provided to an increasing extent in such fields as information, guidance, selection, vocational training and placement. In order to provide adequate information for migrants on living and working conditions in countries of destination and to prepare them for their future life there, the Committee resorts to every available medium, including manuals and other printed matter, moving pictures and the wireless. It also helps with recruitment by taking part in preselection and selection operations. In Italy, continuing the work initiated by the I.L.O., it has trained 40 employment service officials in preselection methods. In addition, several experts attached to its local mission participated as required in subsequent operations, including selection. Scientific selection methods, including vocational aptitude tests, were developed for this purpose. The Committee has also made great efforts to develop vocational training for prospective emigrants, e.g. in Greece and, with I.L.O. co-operation, in Italy and has thus been largely responsible for increasing the migratory flow to Latin America and the Commonwealth countries. In order to fit the training, so far as possible, to the actual needs of immigration countries, a joint I.L.O.I.C.E.M. inquiry mission was sent in 1956 to various Latin American countries to collect data concerning the standards which skilled workers in those countries should meet and the wage level required to enable such workers to enjoy a standard of living comparable to that which they had in Europe. In 1957 a special meeting was convened by the Committee to discuss technical problems arising out of the vocational training of migrants. This meeting, in which a number of European emigration countries, some Latin American immigration countries and various international organisations participated, reviewed existing skilled labour requirements and the possibility of meeting them. The Committee has also organised language courses and prepared language training manuals. Einally, : .it. : has helped several Latin American countries, in particular Brazil, Argentina and Colombia^ to organise and develop appropriate services for the placement • of migrants. ^ The activities of I.C.E.M. have constantly expanded. In its early days it was concerned primarily with the resettlement of refugees whose cases the I.R.O. had not been able to settle definitively, and played a correspondingly modest role in the organisation of ordinary migration. However, this latter phase of its work expanded rapidly: whereas in 1953 295 ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION TABLE 91. MIGRANTS MOVED WITH I.C.E.M. ASSISTANCE, O F ORIGIN A N D DESTINATION, 1952-57 1 (In thousands) BY COUNTRIES Total 1952 Countries 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Absolute Perfigures centages Countries of Drigin Europe : Austria Federal Republic of Germany Greece Italy Netherlands . . . . Spain Other countries 2 . . . 11.0 5.5 6.4 12.3 47.7 49.3 132.3 17.3 38.0 0.5 12.3 10.1 40.3 4.1 22.3 2.3 34.9 11.8 54.0 1.3 21.9 14.1 45.9 12.7 — — 9.4 11.2 12.9 32.7 11.9 39.4 12.6 0.1 16.2 20.4 8.6 43.4 9.1 10.4 49.8 188.1 51.0 217.2 48.2 10.6 104.3 24.6 6.7 28.5 6.3 1.4 13.7 . . . 76.6 84.0 119.6 119.8 160.6 191.0 751.6 98.5 . . . . 1.0 0.1 3.3 0.2 1.5 0.1 0.6 0.1 1.2 0.2 3.0 0.1 10.5 0.8 1.4 0.1 Total . . . 77.7 87.5 121.2 120.4 162.0 194.1 762.9 100.0 1.2 0.8 8.7 41.1 6.0 11.3 0.4 0.2 6.3 1.7 18.1 43.7 11.3 46.4 0.8 0.9 14.2 2.1 80.8 205.1 65.0 133.5 5.2 1.4 25.9 5.1 10.6 26.9 8.5 17.5 0.7 0.2 3.4 0.7 Total Far East Miscellaneous 4.8 — — Countries of destination Overseas : Argentina Australia Brazil Canada Chile Colombia 0.5 15.5 9.8 8.7 1.3 9.0 13.3 12.7 36.9 0.8 0.1 2.4 29.3 37.8 16.4 21.3 0.8 0.1 1.0 — — — — — 0.2 0.4 0.2 1.9 0.3 1.8 2.9 4.2 4.0 0.5 0.5 38.1 — 1.5 0.8 6.4 0.1 3.9 0.8 7.2 0.4 5.3 0.6 20.5 2.8 5.0 0.3 54.3 1.7 4.9 0.3 27.2 2.3 8.6 0.7 153.7 7.3 29.2 3.5 20.1 1.0 3.8 0.5 — New Zealand . . . . Central African Federation . . . . Union of South Africa United States of America Uruguay Venezuela Other countries . . . 0.8 0.4 0.1 0.2 15.2 53.8 8.9 8.9 1.0 — . . . 77.6 86.8 120.5 119.0 139.1 181.0 724.0 94.9 Miscellaneous European countries . 0.1 0.7 0.7 1.4 22.8 13.1 38.8 5.1 Total . . . 77.7 87.5 121.2 120.4 162.0 194.1 762.9 100.0 Total M February 1952-31 December 1957. 'Including Malta and, for 1957, Yugoslavia (Hungarian refugees). 296 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 less than one-third of all emigration from Austria, the Federal Republic of Germany, Greece, Italy and the Netherlands was assisted by the Committee, this figure had risen to about one-half by 1957. The statistics given in table 91 illustrate this trend, bringing out the importance of refugee movements from Germany and Austria, Italian emigration to Latin America under family regrouping schemes, Italian, Dutch and Greek movements under the Australian programme, and the impact of the recent accession of Spain to membership in the Committee. The table also shows that the largest numbers of migrants were moved to Australia (26.9 per cent, of the total), the United States (20.1 per cent., largely under the Displaced Persons Act, for the execution of which a Committee became responsible following the disappearance of the I.R.O., and other refugee relief laws) and to Canada (17.5 per cent.). Movements to Latin America were smaller, particularly those to Venezuela. Altogether, from 1952 to 1957 the Committee moved more than 760,000 emigrants; of these 250,000 were refugees, including Hungarians, presumed to come within the mandate of the United Nations High Commissioner. Finally, it may be noted that persons moved under family regrouping schemes numbered 164,700 (86 per cent, from Italy), most of whom went to Argentina (47 per cent.), Brazil (24 per cent.) and Venezuela (17 per cent.). THE UNITED NATIONS AND ITS SPECIALISED AGENCIES Within the United Nations family, several organisations have a direct or indirect interest in migration problems; one of these is the International Labour Organisation which, apart from its responsibilities in its own technical field, performs a co-ordinating function. Questions falling directly within the competence of the United Nations include the rights of aliens, the demographic, economic and financial aspects of migration, and some of its social aspects. The I.L.O. is concerned with all matters connected with the migration of workers and their families and is empowered to lay down international standards, disseminate information and provide technical assistance in these fields. The United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees is responsible for the international protection of refugees and administers a special fund for the financing of projects aimed at solving the refugee problem permanently. The World Health Organization is entrusted with the health aspects of migration, the Food and Agricultural Organization with certain aspects of land settlement schemes and the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization with integration ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 297 problems. Finally, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development is concerned with the financial aspects of migration and is empowered to advance funds for thefinancingof certain programmes. Apart from the activities already mentioned and in keeping with its constitutional obligations, the I.L.O. immediately after the war tackled the problem of the revision of pre-war international instruments which subsequent social developments had rendered obsolete. In 1949 the International Labour Conference adopted a new Convention and a new Recommendation on migration for employment.1 Both instruments lay down general principles concerning information, recruitment, selection, transport, reception, placement, repatriation, and migration of families. The Convention, while making separate provision for workers recruited collectively under government sponsorship and persons recruited on an individual basis, lays down the fundamental rule, applicable to all, that no migrant shall be treated less favourably than nationals of the immigration country in respect of remuneration and other conditions of employment, trade union membership, housing, social security and taxes. The Recommendation is more detailed and lays down three cardinal principles : first, that the policy of member countries should be " to develop and utilise all possibilities of employment and for this purpose to facilitate the international distribution of manpower and in particular the movement of manpower from countries which have a surplus of manpower to those countries that have a deficiency " ; secondly, that the measures taken by each member country " should have due regard to the manpower situation in the country " and that " the Government should consult the appropriate organisations of employers and workers on all general questions concerning migration for employment " ; and thirdly, that where restrictions are placed on the employment of migrant workers, such restrictions should so far as possible be lifted after the worker has completed a prescribed period of residence in the country, in principle not exceeding five years. Appended to the Recommendation is a model agreement on temporary and permanent migration for employment, including migration of refugees and displaced persons, for use by governments wishing to conclude bilateral migration agreements. A similar model agreement, together with a number of basic principles, was drawn up in 1950 with respect to land settlement. Special international standards were also adopted in 1955 for the benefit of migrant workers from underdeveloped countries or terri1 The Migration for Employment Convention (Revised), 1949, and the Migration for Employment Recommendation (Revised), 1949. On 1 June 1959 the Convention had heen ratified by the following 11 countries: Belgium, Cuba, France, Guatemala, Israel, Italy, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, the United Kingdom and Uruguay. 298 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 tories; they are embodied in a Recommendation 1 intended to cover more particularly movements taking place within Asia, Africa and Latin America and containing provisions aimed at protecting migrants during their journey and at providing various other forms of protection, discouraging movements contrary to the interests of the workers and their countries of origin, and settling them permanently in their territories of destination. Moreover, pending the adoption of detailed regulations concerning equal treatment for foreigners under national social security schemes, a number of general principles have been embodied in the Social Security (Minimum Standards) Convention, 1952. Finally, the Preliminary Migration Conference of 1950 arrived at a number of conclusions concerning the practical organisation of migration at the national level; a further result was the production of a vast amount of technical literature for the guidance of responsible agencies, which has occasionally inspired, first, the I.R.O. and later I.C.E.M. This material includes recommendations concerning the organisation of medical pre-selection and a definition of medical selection criteria for certain occupational categories (arrived at with I.R.O., I.C.E.M. and W.H.O. co-operation); an international standard classification of occupations designed to provide a valid basis for international job comparisons; manuals on the organisation of employment services, with particular reference to immigrant selection and placement; and a guide for the vocational training of emigrants. In addition to these technical publications, the I.L.O. has issued material of more immediate practical interest, such as an analysis of immigration laws and regulations in various countries 2 and a series of guides concerning living and working conditions in a few Latin American countries. Finally, its purely operational activities have included provision of technical assistance to help governments improve their emigration or immigration services, operate vocational training projects for prospective migrants (e.g. in Italy, Greece and Malta) and solve their manpower problems in general. Projects of the latter type, though not directly concerned with migration, have obvious migration implications. They have in the past included a number of manpower surveys and the setting up of a regular service to provide information on the labour supply and demand in certain Latin American countries. 1 The Protection of Migrant Workers (Underdeveloped Countries) Recommendation, 1955. 2 See the list of bibliographical references for Chapter VIII. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 299 The I.L.O.'s responsibility for co-ordinating the migration activities of the various United Nations agencies is discharged through a Technical Working Group on Migration which reports to the so-called Administrative Committee on Co-ordination, a body grouping the SecretaryGeneral of the United Nations and the executive heads of the specialised agencies. Representatives of other international organisations, namely I.C.E.M., the O.E.E.C, the Council of Europe and the Organisation of American States, have also been associated with the work of the group. The latter co-ordinates the studies and the information work of the various bodies concerned, as well as their technical assistance activities. Its purpose is to ensure better co-ordination of the programmes of the various organisations, including where appropriate the preparation of joint projects, and thus to give governments the benefit of more effective and better-integrated international action. Apart from the Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees, whose work has already been described1, the remaining United Nations agencies play a somewhat more limited role. The United Nations itself has adopted a Convention concerning the enforcement abroad of personal maintenance obligations and a resolution dealing with indigent aliens. The W.H.O., in co-operation with the I.L.O., has formulated medical standards for pre-selection and selection examinations. Finally, U.N.E.S.C.O. in 1956 convened a world-wide conference on the cultural integration of immigrants, as a result of which a manual containing policy recommendations for governments in this field is now in course of preparation. EUROPEAN REGIONAL ORGANISATIONS European regional organisations, foremost among them the O.E.E.C, have concerned themselves chiefly with the statutory side of the problem, and in particular the relaxation of immigration regulations.2 The Council of Europe has prepared, in co-operation with the I.L.O., a series of interim social security agreements under which the contracting parties undertake to grant equal treatment to each other's nationals under their respective social security schemes; the European Convention on Establishment, drawn up in 1955, has not yet come into force. The Resettlement Fund established by the Council in 1956 to deal with the problem of " national refugees and overpopulation " has not so far exerted any sizeable influence on European migration. It has, however, advanced moneys for the construction of housing for a group of Italian 1 2 See above Chapter II. See above, Chapter VII. 300 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 immigrants in France and for the establishment at Verona of a new migrant assembly and selection centre. The European Coal and Steel Community, in co-operation with the I.L.O., drew up a social security Convention in 1957, the provisions of which apply to all migrant workers travelling among the six countries. The Convention was signed in Rome on 9 December 1957 and has since been converted into a regulation issued under Article 51 of the treaty establishing the European Economic Community. Finally, pursuant to Article 69 of the treaty establishing the European Coal and Steel Community, the governments concerned have estabUshed an agreed administrative procedure to facilitate the movements to which this Article applies. Non-Governmental Organisations The development of government action at both the national and international levels has been paralleled by an expansion of the activities of employers' and workers' associations and voluntary organisations. EMPLOYERS' AND WORKERS' ORGANISATIONS Since the war, employers' and—to an even greater extent—workers' organisations have played an increasingly important part in migration policy discussions and decisions. Their consultation on such matters —which is explicitly provided for in the I.L.O. Recommendation of 1949—is a common practice in most major emigration and immigration countries, and even in those where no formal consultation machinery exists they are always in a position to make themselves heard. At the international level, trade union and employers' federations not only participate with full voting rights in the work of such bodies as the I.L.O., the European Coal and Steel Community and the European Economic Community, but are associated in an advisory capacity in the work of the United Nations, the O.E.E.C, I.C.E.M. and the Council of Europe, where even though they have no voting rights they are in a position to wield considerable influence. Employers' organisations have a direct interest in international migration as a means of relieving population pressures in emigration countries and providing immigration countries with the labour required for their development. Their participation does not stop at the formulation of migration policy or recruitment and placement programmes; sometimes they also recruit directly on their members' behalf or pay the expenses of the government agency entrusted with such operations (as in France). In some countries, e.g. Brazil and Colombia, they also play an active part in determining what manpower requirements cannot be filled through the domestic employment market. ORGANISED AND ASSISTED MIGRATION 301 The part played by workers' organisations is, of course, more important still owing to the repercussions of migration on the living and working conditions of workers in both emigration and immigration countries, and also to the fact that migrants are usually more in need of protection than other workers. Such organisations—particularly the International Federation of Christian Trade Unions, the International Confederation of Free Trade Unions and their affiliated occupational or inter occupational bodies—are guided by two major preoccupations: to ensure that the number of migrants as well as their occupational, cultural and psychological characteristics are compatible with economic and social conditions in immigration countries and do not result in a distortion of the national employment market or any other consequence prejudicial to the interests of national workers and earlier immigrants ; and to provide special protection and assistance for the migrants. Such organisations have consistently come out in favour of properly organised international migration, calculated to serve this dual purpose, and in many countries immigration policy and the development of government responsibility in this field are, to some extent at least, traceable to the efforts of organised labour. The type of protection or special assistance provided for migrants by trade union organisations varies according to the country, the needs of the migrants and the resources of the organisations. Their aim is generally to facilitate the occupational adjustment and social integration of the immigrants and also to protect them against discrimination and other abuses. Trade unions, moreover, take steps to ensure that the generally recognised principle of equal treatment for national and foreign workers is respected ; they also assist immigrants in solving any occupational or social problem arising out of their relations with the employer or the authorities. Unfortunately, the effectiveness of their action is often limited by the reluctance of immigrant workers to join local unions.1 VOLUNTARY ORGANISATIONS Far from diminishing the importance of voluntary organisations, the extension of government responsibility in the migration field has contributed to develop their activities as an essential adjunct of government action. 1 For further information on the work of international trade union organisations in this field, see the reports of the congresses of the various international organisations mentioned. See also A. OBLATH: The Attitude of Workers'1 Organisations to Immigration (mimeographed), paper submitted to the Third International Catholic Migration Congress, Assisi, September 1957. 302 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Many of the organisations confine their assistance to specific religious or occupational groups of migrants.1 Some, however, extend their services to all indiscriminately.2 These organisations provide assistance in many forms, including information and guidance; vocational and language training; financial guarantees, where required by immigration laws; protection during the journey; reception, placement and assistance to facilitate adjustment; and legal assistance. They have all played an active part in family regrouping schemes. During the immediate post-war years, such organisations contributed greatly to the resettlement of refugees, particularly in the United States. More recently, while continuing their work on behalf of refugees they have also helped many ordinary emigrants particularly by facilitating their psychological and vocational preparation for emigration and their adjustment to their new life in the country of destination. Such organisations co-operate with governments, I.C.E.M. and the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees. The need for co-ordinating the activities of these organisations was felt as early as 1924, when a Permanent International Conference of Private Organisations for the Protection of Migrants was established under the auspices of the International Labour Office. A similar coordinating body was set up in 1950 at the joint suggestion of the United Nations and the I.L.O. : this is the Conference of Non-Governmental Organisations Interested in Migration which has already met six times under the auspices of these two bodies and has adopted many resolutions as a result of its discussions. A permanent liaison committee co-ordinates the work of these various organisations and maintains the necessary contact with intergovernmental agencies. Arising out of the resolutions of the Conference, minimum standards of protection for migrants during their journey have been adopted, as well as general and special principles governing other forms of protection, and a centre for the co-ordination of migrant legal assistance has been attached to the International Committee of the Red Cross. Bibliographical References This chapter is based on unpublished I.L.O. material. 1 Such organisations include the International Catholic Migration Commission, the National Catholic Welfare Conference in the United States, the Lutheran World Federation, the World Council of Churches, the United H.I.A.S. Service, the American Joint Distribution Committee, the International Labour Assistance and the Catholic Italian Workers' Association. 2 These include the International Social Service, the International Committee of the Red Cross and the League of Red Cross Societies. SECTION C EFFECTS OF ECONOMIC MIGRATION CHAPTER X DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS The economic migration currents of the post-war period have represented only a minor factor in the demographic evolution of the world as a whole : neither the geographical distribution of the population by continent and within each continent nor, with the exception of Oceania, the demographic expansion of any one continent were noticeably affected. However, in a number of individual countries, the demographic effects of these movements were noteworthy, and in some they were considerable ; it is with these that the numerical analyses in this chapter are mainly concerned. Only as regards the direct effects of recent migration on population volume, age structure and sex structure, and on the volume and composition of the labour force do available statistics add up to a fairly definite picture; their indirect effects, i.e. their repercussions on natural population trends, are at best a matter for conjecture based on migration statistics by age and sex. Effects on the Size of the Population ANALYSIS BY CONTINENT Only European emigration, the greater part of which has gone to swell the population of America and Oceania, has had a noticeable effect on the distribution of population among the continents. However, except in Oceania, the effects of intercontinental migration have been practically negligible in comparison with natural growth, as shown by table 92. Thus, for Europe, net emigration amounted to about 1.4 per cent. •of the 1946 population figure and considerably less than the natural 304 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 92. WORLD POPULATION, BY CONTINENT, IN 1946 AND 1957, AND BALANCE OF INTERCONTINENTAL MIGRATION IN THE INTERVENING PERIOD (In millions) Population figure Continent or major region Africa America Asia Oceania U.S.S.R 1 In 1946 In 1957 185.0 300.0 1,302.0 379.0 11.8 175.0 225.0 381.0 1,556.0 414.0 15.4 204.0 Total population increase • + 40.0 + 81.0 +254.0 + 35.0 + 3.6 + 29.0 Net immigration +0.5 +4.4 1 -0.5 -5.4 + 1.0 Exclusive of movements towards Israel. increase for two years, while in America net immigration produced an increase of 1.5 per cent, over the 1946 figure, which was considerably less than the natural increase for one year. In Oceania, on the other hand, immigration produced a very high increase: 9.3 per cent, of the 1946 population, or more than the increase resulting from natural growth over a period of five years. With respect to the distribution of population within the different continents, the movements of the last 12 years, with their widely differing effect on various countries, caused particularly noticeable changes in Europe and Oceania. In Europe emigration has appreciably decreased the population of the southern countries—by more than 2.5 million since 1946, or the equivalent of about one-quarter of the natural growth for this part of Europe between 1946 and 1957. The effects of economic migration were also considerable in central Europe (Western Germany, Austria and Switzerland), where their net result was to decrease the 1946 population (amounting to about 55 milhon) by more than 1.3 million. In north-western Europe, on the other hand, losses by emigration were largely offset by gains resulting from intercontinental and transcontinental immigration, the net result being positive for a few countries (France, Belgium and Sweden) and negative for the others. In Oceania the population was increased by immigration only in Australia and New Zealand. In America, lastly, population gains due to migratory movements were much higher in North America, where they amounted to 3.4 million (2.4 million for the United States and 1 million for Canada) for a 1946 population figure of 153 million, than in South America where they do not appear to have greatly exceeded 1.4 million for a corresponding figure of 101 milhon, while Central America lost half a million inhabitants by emigration. 305 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS ANALYSIS BY COUNTRY While post-war economic migration currents had no really important demographic effects on a continental scale, they did considerably affect the population of certain countries which were the source or the recipients of relatively strong migratory movements. An attempt has been made to evaluate the net losses and gains resulting from all migration movements for each country for which sufficient data are available; the results are given below. European Countries The data in table 93 cover nearly all European countries, except those of eastern Europe which since 1946 have remained completely outside the major economic migration currents. These data give an idea of the part played by external migration in the general evolution of the T A B L E 93. POPULATION GROWTH AND NET IMMIGRATION FOR COUNTRIES, (In 17 E U R O P E A N 1946-57 thousands) Estimated net immigration Country Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany (Fed. Rep.) s Greece Ireland Italy Malta Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom . . . 1946 population 7,000 8,370 4,100 3,810 40,280 43,950 7,480 < 2,960 45,290 290 9,420 3,120 8,120 27,010 6,720 4,470 49,220 Natural growth 296 481 497 661 3,538 3,132 1,230 316 5,154 78 1,930 421 1,219 3,524 543 434 3,165 As percentage of 1946 population In absolute figures -330 l + 160 -70 -100 + 350 3 -1,300* -1503 -380 -1,8003 -60 -125 -403 -400 -480 + 180 +220 3 -350 3 Total for entire period Annual average -4.7 + 1.9 -1.7 -2.6 +0.9 -3.0 -2.0 -12.8 -4.0 -21.0 -1.3 -1.3 -4.9 -1.8 +2.7 +4.9 -0.7 -0.39 +0.16 -0.14 -0.22 +0.07 -0.25 -0.17 -1.07 -0.33 -1.75 -0.11 -0.11 -0.41 -0.15 +0.22 +0.41 -0.06 As percentage of natural growth -111.0 + 34.0 -14.0 -15.0 + 10.0 -41.0 -12.0 -120.0 -35.0 -77.0 -6.5 -9.5 -33.0 -14.0 + 33.0 +51.0 -11.0 N.B. The figures for population and natural growth are taken from the United Nations Demographic Yearbook. Net immigration has, as a rule, been calculated on the basis of migration statistics, using population statistics as a countercheck. 1 Except refugees and emigrants to Israel. * Except national refugees (other than those arriving through Austria), foreign refugees and emigrants to Israel. • Margin of error greater than 5 per cent, in either direction possible, owing to incompleteness of migration statistics. ' 1949 figure. 306 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 population. They cover the population figure at the beginning of the period, i.e. in 1946, the natural growth between 1946 and 1957, and estimated net immigration between these two dates. The table shows that only in four countries did immigration exceed emigration.1 In all the others (excluding Malta, which is an exceptional case) there was a net emigration balance varying from 0.7 per cent, of the 1946 population for the United Kingdom to 12.8 per cent, for Ireland. The four countries with an immigration surplus were France, Belgium, Sweden and Switzerland. In France, net immigration was probably less than 1 per cent, of the original population figure. It was relatively higher in Belgium where it amounted to 1.9 per cent., the equivalent of the natural increase for almost four years, and even higher in Sweden where it increased the population by some 2.7 per cent., also equalling the natural increase for four years. The country where immigration resulted in the greatest population increase by far was Switzerland, where it amounted to nearly 5 per cent, of the 1946 population, or half the natural increase for the entire period. In the 13 other countries the excess of emigration over immigration varied considerably. It was slight in the United Kingdom, where it represented hardly more than one year's natural increase. It was moderate in Norway, the Netherlands, Denmark and even Spain, where net emigration decreased the original population by only 1.8 per cent., the equivalent of the natural increase for one-and-a-half years approximately. The effects of emigration were hardly more considerable in Greece, where it decreased the original population by approximately 2 per cent., as compared with a natural increase of about 1.3 per cent, each year. In Finland the population loss due to emigration reached 2.6 per cent., but this was less than two years' natural increase. As for Western Germany and Austria, these two countries are listed as having an emigration surplus only because refugee immigration was not taken into account and because the figures in table 93 (1.3 million for Germany and 330,000 for Austria) refer exclusively to economic migration. Taking the migratory movements of the post-war period globally, it is quite obvious that there was an enormous immigration surplus in Western Germany and a very substantial one in Austria. The effects of emigration were much more marked in Italy and Portugal, the former losing some 4 per cent, of its 1946 population 2 , the 1 This was also the case in Luxembourg. The figure given for Italy (1.8 million) allows for probable underestimation by Italian statistics of the number of returned emigrants. These place net transoceanic emigration at 1.1 million and net continental emigration at 0.65 million, but the latter figure does not include net emigration towards Switzerland—a sizeable omission. 2 307 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS latter 5 per cent. 1 , and both countries having suffered a decrease in population roughly equivalent to the natural increase for four years. But it was in Ireland and in Malta that the volume of emigration was proportionately the highest. In the former, it amounted to about 13 per cent, of the 1946 population figure, more than offsetting the natural increase during the entire period.2 In the latter, the population loss exceeded 20 per cent., almost equalling the very large natural increase from 1946 to 1957. For these four countries, and particularly the last two, the emigration rate was so high as to raise the question whether emigration was not actually responsible for inhibiting the natural increase ; there can, in fact, be little doubt that, besides the direct effect of diminishing the population, emigration contributed indirectly to lower the birth rate, though in a proportion which it is virtually impossible to determine. 3 American Countries Table 94 contains data for certain American countries comparable to those given for Europe in table 93. Unfortunately the statistics available are insufficient to give a complete picture. The figures reproduced in table 94 show that four countries— Canada, Venezuela, Argentina and probably Uruguay—had a relatively high balance of immigration from 1946 to 1957, representing some 5 per cent, of the 1946 population in the latter two countries, and between 7 and 8 per cent, in the first two. These figures, moreover, leave out of account the surplus of births over deaths among recent immigrants, which was probably considerable. For Canada, net immigration was estimated at around 1 million 4, a figure which is none too reliable in view of the absence of Canadian 1 For Portugal a figure of 400,000 has been taken, in spite of probable underestimation of returns, in order to allow for continental emigration, i.e. emigration to France. However, the figure may still be somewhat too high. 2 This estimate of net emigration from Ireland is confirmed by the censuses taken in 1951 and 1956, which show a net emigration of over 320,000 between the 1946 and 1956 censuses, or a yearly average of 24,000 from 1946 to 1951, and of 40,000 from 1951 to 1956. 3 This subject is dealt with further under the heading " Effects on Natural Population Trends". 4 The method of calculation was as follows : European immigration Other immigration Canadian citizens and former immigrants returning from the United States (estimate) Canadian emigration to the United States United States citizens returning from Canada (estimate) . . . . Returns to and departures for Europe (estimate) 1,466,000 103,000 70,000 —385,000 —45,000 —150,000 Total . . . 1,059,000 The figure is therefore definitely higher than 1 million. It does not, however, take into account all emigration to the United States or emigration to other parts of the world (although the latter was probably negligible). 308 TABLE 94. INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, POPULATION GROWTH AMERICAN AND 1945-1957 NET COUNTRIES, (In IMMIGRATION FOR EIGHT 1946-57 thousands) Estimated net immigration Country Jamaica Brazil Uruguay 1946 population 12,620 141,390 1,300 23,180 15,650 47,310 2,280 4,390 Natural growth As percentage of 1946 population absolute figures1 3,305 + 1,000 27,735 + 2,200 348 3 -90 8,689 -250 3,358 + 800 16,000 45 +450 320 + 110 3 1,812 + 330 Total for entire period Annual average + 7.9 + 1.6 -6.9 -1.1 + 5.1 + 1.0 +4.8 + 7.5 +0.66 +0.13 -0.58 -0.09 +0.43 +0.08 +0.4 +0.63 As percent age of natural growth + 30 +8 -23 -3 +23 +3 + 34 + 16 N.B. With regard to sources and the method of estimating the balance of migration, see N.B. under table 93. The estimates here are on the whole more uncertain than for the European countries. For Uruguay, net immigration had to be calculated from population figures. This estimate should be considered as particularly conjectural. 1 Margin of error greater than 5 per cent, in either direction possible, owing to incompleteness of migration statistics. 'And Newfoundland. '1946-56 only. * Approximation based on population estimates. • Approximation based on partial data. statistics for continental immigration. This figure represents almost 8 per cent, of the 1946 population and is equal to nearly one-third of the natural increase during the period reviewed. In Venezuela, net immigration seems to have been about 330,000, most of it from Europe. This figure represents roughly the same proportion of the 1946 population as in Canada (7.5 per cent.) but is equivalent to the natural increase for only two years. In Argentina, the direct population gain from external migration between 1946 and 1957, estimated at about 800,000 1 (though this figure is purely conjectural), would appear to be about 5 per cent, of the 1946 population, representing almost one-quarter of the total natural increase during the period. For Uruguay, lastly, there are no statistics relating directly to continental movements. The figure of 110,000, which represents a proportionate increase of the same size as that for Argentina, is based solely on the fact that annual population estimates for 1946 and 1957 show a total increase which exceeds by roughly that figure the probable natural increase for the intervening 1 This corresponds to the net difference between all arrivals and departures, whether of nationals or aliens, by all means of transport, as given by official statistics. The official net figure for European immigrants (second and third class passengers arriving by sea) is fixed at 610,000. The remainder—perhaps slightly overestimated— represents the balance of other movements, the greater part of which is attributable to the positive balance of migration from other Latin American countries. 309 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS period. However, the population statistics themselves are not entirely reliable, so that this estimate of net immigration must be considered as very approximate. 1 At least two other American countries have positive immigration balances: the United States, with a little over 2.4 million (which, however, omits the negative balance of movements of American citizens, particularly towards Canada and, to some extent, towards Europe); and Brazil, where net immigration is estimated at 450,0002, almost all of it from Europe. These balances amount respectively to a little more than 1.5 per cent, and a little less than 1 per cent, of the population of the two countries at the beginning of the period. Finally, in two countries the balance was definitely negative : Mexico, with a net emigration figure of 250,000, practically all of it to the United States; and Jamaica, whose statistics of arrivals and departures of travellers show, for the whole period, a surplus of departures of about 90,000, representing roughly 7 per cent, of the 1946 population. In other American countries the balance of international migration, whether negative or positive, would probably appear negligible in comparison with the size of the population, with the possible exception of some Central American countries and certainly with that of Paraguay, whose balance with Argentina was definitely, and with Uruguay probably, negative. Countries of Africa From 1946 to 1957 the population of non-African stock in most African countries was increased notably, and sometimes considerably, as a result of immigration. Unfortunately, it is seldom possible to assess the increase accurately. It is still more difficult to measure the effect of continental migration on the indigenous population. In the Union of South Africa, the net immigration balance for persons of European stock from 1946 to 1957 was a little under 85,000, or about 3.5 per cent, of the white population in 1946, which amounted to 2.4 million; this corresponds to the natural increase for about two years. But it was in tropical Africa that immigration increased the white population to the greatest extent. In the three territories of the 1 The figures on which these calculations were based are as follows (in thousands) : Population in the middle of 1957 Population in the middle of 1945 2 2,685 —2,255 Difference (increase from 1945 to 1957) Natural increase, 1946-57 (estimate) 430 —320 Difference (net immigration, 1946-57) +110 For a gross immigration figure of 565,000. In the absence of Brazilian emigration statistics, this figure was drastically reduced to allow for both returns recorded in Europe and the negative balance of known continental movements. 310 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland, where the European population rose, between 1946 and 1957, from 105,000 to 274,000, the contribution of immigration to this increase was about 116,000, and was proportionately higher in Northern than in Southern Rhodesia.1 In British East Africa as well European immigration added considerably to the original white population and was, in fact, the main factor in the increase of over 100 per cent, in Kenya and 200 per cent, in Tanganyika and Uganda which took place between 1946 and 1956.2 In all these countries, where European immigration is heavy, its share in population growth is compounded by its considerable indirect effects on natural growth. In the Belgian Congo, immigration was responsible for nearly two-thirds of the European population increase (from 34,000 to 102,000) between 1946 and 1956.3 If comparable data were available regarding the evolution of the European population in Portuguese 4 and French 5 1 The European population figures for the three territories at the beginning of 1946 and in the middle of 1957 were as follows (in thousands): Territory Population in 1946 Population in 1957 Natural increase Net immigration 82 21 2 194 72 8 37 15 1 75 36 5 105 274 53 116 Total . . . 2 The official estimates of European population for the three territories are as follows (in thousands): Territory M id-1946 Mid-1956 24.9 9.3 2.8 57.7 27.7 8.4 Uganda Source: East African Statistical Department: Annual Report, ¡955-1956 (Nairobi, 1957). 3 See United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1957 (New York, 1957). At least for Angola and Mozambique, where the white population amounted to 79,000 and 48,000 respectively at the end of 1950 and where, according to Portuguese statistics, net immigration from Portugal between 1946 and 1957 reached 80,000 in Angola and 36,000 in Mozambique. 5 For the French territories, the only data available are the censuses taken in 1946 and 1951, which show the following increases in the non-indigenous population (in thousands): 4 Territory 1946 1951 Increase French West Africa . . . French Equatorial Africa . 32 8 4 54 62 22 12 66 + 30 + 14 +8 + 12 Madagascar Source: Population (Paris, Institut national d'études démographiques), Ninth Year, No. 3, July-Sep. 1954, p. 532. It should be noted that the non-indigenous population includes persons of non-European stock. 311 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS territories, they would doubtless show that immigration there played a similar role and that its effects were also considerable. Lastly, in Morocco, where the non-Moroccan population rose between 1946 and 1955 from 305,000 to 460,000 \ natural growth accounts for less than half of the increase, most of the remainder being attributable to immigration by persons of European stock coming from Europe or Algeria. No data are available for other countries. In some territories—particularly those of British East Africa— recent immigration considerably increased the population of Asian origin, and principally the Indian minority.2 With respect to indigenous continental migration, it is impossible to quote exact figures. The most that can be said is that certain territories had a positive migration balance (the Gold Coast (Ghana), Southern Rhodesia and the Union of South Africa), while others had a negative one (French West Africa, Ruanda-Urundi, Nyasaland, Mozambique and the three British protectorates in southern Africa). The situation is less clear with regard to the other territories, although Kenya, Tanganyika, Uganda and the Belgian Congo appear to have had a positive balance. Countries of Asia Recent migratory movements do not appear to have had noticeable demographic effects in the countries of Asia, apart from population shifts resulting from political events. The only other development worth mentioning was the diminution of European settlements, in Indonesia in particular, but also in India, Pakistan and Viet-Nam. 1 See United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1957, op. cit. The figure has, however, diminished considerably since 1955. 2 The following figures illustrate the evolution of the population of Asian origin in the three territories of British East Africa between 1946 and 1956 (figures in thousands, estimates made at mid-year) : Territory Indian population Arab population 1946 1956 1946 1956 88.4 42.0 32.0 151.9 76.4 54.3 23.3 10.6 1.4 33.0 16.9 2.0 Source: East African Statistical Department: Annual Report, 19551956, op. cit. The increase in the Indian population is particularly noteworthy. At least half seems to be due to net immigration. 312 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Australia and New Zealand In Oceania, on the other hand, immigration between 1946 and 1957 considerably increased the population of Australia and New Zealand, as shown by table 95. TABLE 95. AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND: POPULATION GROWTH AND NET IMMIGRATION, 1946-57 !. (In thousands) Net immigration Country : Australia New Zealand 1 . . . . 1946 population Natural growth 7,460 1,66o1 1,391 351 In absolute figures As percentage of 1946 population As percentage of natural growth 930 145 12.5 8.7 67 41 European' population only. Thus, Australia and New Zealand are the two countries in which immigration caused the highest proportionate increase in the population during the last 12 years. In Australia, net immigration represented more than 12 per cent, of the 1946 population figure and about two-thirds of the natural growth during that period ; in New Zealand it amounted to about 9 per cent, of the 1946 population and about two-fifths of the natural growth. Furthermore, a not inconsiderable part of the natural increase itself was due to recent immigration. Effects on the Age Structure and Sex Distribution of the Population Economic migration movements, of which a much higher percentage than normal consists of economically active individuals, must of necessity alter the age and sex structure of the populations which they affect. They generally involve a proportionately greater number of adults, particularly young adults, than are to be found in the population of the countries concerned and, usually, a greater number of men than of women. Thus they tend to increase the average age of the adult population in the country of origin and to lower the proportion of males, while producing the opposite effect in the country of destination. Recent migratory currents were, on the whole, no exception to this rule. It is obvious that the intensity of these effects varies considerably according to the ratio of the net migration balance to the total popula- DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 313 tion in the countries concerned. But the eífects also vary according to the ratio of dependants to economically active persons. They depend, moreover, on whether movements in opposite directions are similar in demographic structure or not, since the demographic effects of immigration and emigration can either accentuate each other or cancel each other out, according as the immigration consists of genuine immigrants or of returning emigrants. EFFECTS ON AGE STRUCTURE The age structure of recent migratory currents is still characterised mainly by an exceptionally high proportion of young adults, i.e. adults under 40, and particularly under 30. This is due both to the fact that workers usually choose to emigrate in the early part of their active life rather than in the second half, and to the fact that immigration countries usually prefer, where possible, to recruit young workers. However, relatively important variations occur in the proportion of young adults to other immigrants. This is due to the varying proportion of those who have children travelling with them or joining them later. Return currents, on the whole, show a much higher average age. Countries with an Emigration Surplus The data available for countries with an emigration surplus all refer to Europe. The age groups from 20 to 40, particularly the 20-30 group, formed a much larger percentage of the number of emigrants than of the total population. This was also true of the 15-20 age group in the case of emigration from the southern European countries, where emigration traditionally takes place at an early age. As for the 0-15 age group, this accounted for a much smaller proportion of the emigrants than of the total population, particularly in the southern European countries; in north-western Europe, with the exception of Ireland, the tendency for whole families to emigrate together was more marked. Only in a few countries did emigration result in a substantial aging of the population. These countries are Ireland and Malta in the first instance and, to a lesser degree, Portugal and Italy. Ireland and Malta. Analysis of the effects of emigration on the age structure of the Irish population is rendered difficult by the absence of statistical data on the most important emigration current, namely that towards the United Kingdom. Comparison of the 1946 and 1951 census figures does, 314 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 however, yield valuable indications. Thus, in 1951 the 20-30 age group showed a steep decline from the 1946 figure for the 15-25 age group, and the 15-20 and 30-35 age groups showed smaller but still considerable losses in proportion to the corresponding age groups in the 1946 census.1 As emigration has greatly developed since 1951, this phenomenon must have been even more marked in the second half of the period under review. Taken by and large, the age pyramid of the Irish population has since 1946 narrowed considerably at the height of the strata representing the 15-40 age bracket, growing wider again at levels above 40. The base, on the other hand, has remained more or less the same size because of a persistently high birth rate and a relatively low emigration rate below the age of 15. In Malta, too, emigration drastically diminished the young adult generation, so that its effects, together with those of the decline in mortality, resulted in a marked narrowing of the pyramid between the ages of 20 and 45 and particularly between the ages of 20 and 30, with a considerable widening above the age of 45.2 This aging effect was further accentuated by the relatively high emigration rate among children up to 14 years of age, which placed a check on the widening of the pyramid's base, in spite of a high birth rate. Thus, the strata under 14 years of age increased relatively less between 1948 and 1956 than those above 45. However, the population as a whole remains very young and its future is by no means seriously compromised. 1 See United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955. For a total population which remained practically stable (2,955,000 in 1946 and 2,900,000 in 1951) the difference between the 20-30 age group in 1951 and the 15-25 group in 1946 amounted to 82,000 (401,000 as against 483,000, or a loss of nearly one-fifth), that between the 15-20 age group in 1951 and the 10-15 age group in 1946 to 21,000 (241,000 as against 262,000), and that between the 30-35 age group in 1951 and the 25-30 age group in 1946 to 16,000 (192,000 as against 208,000). 2 This relationship between emigration and changes in the age structure of the population is clearly brought out by the following comparison between the 1948 and 1956 population figures and the 1950-56 emigration data (figures in thousands): Population Emigration, 1950-56 Age groups 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-45 45 and over Total . . . 1948 census 1956 (estimate) Absolute figures Percentages Absolute figures Percentages 106.6 27.6 48.4 55.0 68.2 34.9 9.0 15.8 18.0 22.3 114.7 25.9 42.0 51.3 80.3 36.5 8.2 13.4 16.3 25.6 306.0 100.0 314.1 100.0 Source: United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955 to 1957. Including persons of unknown age. 1 Absolute figures 15.3 8.1 14.9 8.8 3.8 > 51.0 Percentages 30.0 16.0 29.2 17.3 7.5 100.0 315 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS Italy and Portugal. For Italy and Portugal the aging effect produced by emigration was less marked because the rate of emigration was much lower. Moreover, it mainly affected youthful populations able to withstand the alteration without serious inconvenience. For Italy, statistics show (table 96) that about three-fifths of the overseas emigrants in the period 1946-57 belonged to age groups between 15 and 40 years of age, about half of these being between 20 and 30, whereas the same age groups accounted for only 30 per cent, of the total population in 1951. TABLE 96. ITALY: A G E DISTRIBUTION O F T H E POPULATION I N 1951 AND OF OVERSEAS EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 1951 population 1 Age groups 0-15 15-20 . . . . 20-30 . . . . 30-40 . . . . 40-50 . . . . 50 and over . Age unknown Total Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 12,248 4,053 7,998 6,219 6,056 10,164 26.2 8.7 17.1 13.3 13.0 21.7 — — 46,738 100.0 Emigration ' Absolute figures (thousands) 253.4 3 161.0 3 418.6 247.9 144.2 104.0 31.8 1,361.0 1 Estimate (see United Nations:3 Demographic Yearbook, 1954). from Mediterranean countries. 0-14 and 14-20 years. Immigration * Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) 18.6 11.8 30.8 18.2 10.6 7.7 2.3 22.0 7.9 60.5 66.7 51.6 49.0 2.5 100.0 260.3 2 3 3 Percentages 8.5 3.0 23.3 25.6 19.8 18.8 1.0 100.0 Excluding movements to and The percentage of emigrants under 15 years of age, on the other hand, was relatively low and considerably less than the proportion of the same age group to the total population. The same applies to the age group over 40 and particularly to persons over 50. As for immigration, it was composed entirely of returns, and, for the most part, of persons over 30 years of age, so that it accentuated the aging effect produced by emigration, though hardly to a noticeable extent because of its reduced scope. Altogether, the balance of transoceanic migration for Italy adds up to a relatively high loss for the age groups between 15 and 40, particularly the 20-30 groups; insignificant losses for age groups above 40; slightly less than proportionate losses for the 0-15 age group; and slightly more than proportionate losses for the 15-20 group. 316 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 With respect to continental migration, for which there is no breakdown by age, it is probable that the resulting demographic losses affect the young adult generations in an even higher proportion, and children under 15 to a considerably lesser degree. In the last analysis, recent migration has played a considerable part since 1946 in accelerating the aging of the Italian population: it was only a secondary factor in narrowing the base of the age pyramid but was by far the main cause of its relative widening in the above-40 age groups. In Portugal, where demographic losses due to emigration were proportionately higher than in Italy, the aging effect seems to have been even more marked. It would appear, furthermore, that the average age of emigrants was lower (table 97). However, it is impossible to come to a definite conclusion in this matter, since the available data give the age distribution of emigrants to foreign countries only, excluding the overseas provinces 1 , and since no data at all are available for immigrants. The age groups between 15 and 30 years contributed 50 per cent. of Portuguese emigration, whereas in transoceanic Italian emigration they accounted for only a little over 40 per cent., most of the difference probably occurring in the over-20 group. TABLE 97. PORTUGAL: AGE DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION IN 1949 AND OF EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population l Emigration * Age groups 0-15 15-20, 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over Age unknown Total . . . Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 2,471 806 1,458 1,170 956 1,534 29.4 9.6 17.4 13.9 11.4 18.3 8,395 100.0 Absolute figures (thousands) 60.6 3 53.9 4 94.8 5 54.9 19.8 10.0 1.5 295.7 'Estimate at 1 July 1949 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1951). 1946-54 cover only emigrants to foreign countries departing for the first time. 0-14 years. «For 1946-54, 14-22 years. ' F o r 1946-54, 22-30 years. Percentages 20.5 18.2 32.1 18.6 6.7 3.4 0.5 100.0 * The figures for * For 1946-54, It should, however, be noted that, while the aging effect produced by emigration was more marked in Portugal than in Italy—both because 1 Statistics of passengers travelling to and from overseas provinces divide them into two classes only: above and below 14 years of age. 317 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS the emigration rate was a little higher and because the average age of emigrants seems to have been lower—the population which it affected was considerably younger, with a much higher birth rate, and therefore much better able to withstand it. Other Countries. Elsewhere, the size of the loss by emigration was not so great as to affect seriously the age structure of the population, particularly in countries with youthful populations such as Finland, the Netherlands, TABLE 98. N E T H E R L A N D S : A G E DISTRIBUTION O F T H E POPULATION I N 1950 A N D O F E M I G R A T I O N A N D I M M I G R A T I O N F R O M 1946 TO 1957 Population Emigration Immigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 50 and over . . . . 2,963 811 1,596 2,615 2,128 29.3 8.0 15.8 25.9 21.0 198.3 45.1 221.4* 240.3 46.8 26.4 6.0 29.4 32.0 6.2 163.2 44.6 142.6 210.4 67.0 26.0 7.1 22.7 33.5 10.7 Total . . . 10,113 100.0 751.9 100.0 628.1 100.0 Age groups 1 l Estimate at 1 July 1950 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1951). TABLE 99. U N I T E D K I N G D O M : A G E DISTRIBUTION O F T H E POPULATION I N 1950 A N D O F OVERSEAS E M I G R A T I O N AND I M M I G R A T I O N F R O M 1946 TO 1957 Population ' Age groups Emigration * Immigration • Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages . . . . 14,541 7,349 11,187 6,701 10,595 28.9 14.6 22.2 13.3 21.0 494.2 474.9 460.2 136.2 151.1 28.8 27.7 26.8 7.9 8.8 217.1 193.0 205.5 79.5 92.8 27.5 24.5 26.1 10.1 11.8 Total . . . 50,373 100.0 1,716.6 100.0 787.9 100.0 0-20 3 20-30 30-45 45-55 55 and over 1 Estimate at 1 July 1950 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1951). "British migrants (Commonwealth citizens only). 'The breakdown into age groups of 0-15 and 15-20 years appears in the Board of Trade statistics only from 1950 onwards. 318 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Spain and Greece. In Western Germany, however, the loss resulting from emigration among young adults was felt somewhat more acutely since it affected generations already reduced in size. In the Netherlands (table 98) the balance between emigration and immigration is such that the 20-30 age group suffered relatively higher losses than anywhere else. In the United Kingdom, losses caused by transoceanic emigration in the young adult generations (table 99) were doubtless more than offset by the gains resulting from continental immigration. Countries with an Immigration Surplus Just as emigration has had an aging effect on the population of the countries mainly affected by it, so the result of immigration has been to rejuvenate the population in countries with an immigration surplus. While available statistics are insufficient to give an accurate picture of this phenomenon, they do have considerable illustrative value in several important cases. These are, in Europe, Sweden and, outside of Europe, Canada (except that these statistics deal only with immigration), the United States, Argentina, the Union of South Africa, Australia and New Zealand. European Countries. In Sweden the population gain of nearly 3 per cent, resulting from the balance of external migration during the period under consideration was relatively high in the 15-30 age group, thus increasing, in a much greater degree than was warranted by their size in relation to the total population, a number of generations born at a time when the birth rate was particularly low; and while the gain in the 0-15 age group was considerably lower than would have been proportionate to the size of that group, it is evident that, together with the high post-war birth rate, migration has contributed notably to slowing down the aging process in a country where it was one of the most advanced in the world.1 The detailed figures are given in table 100. No data are available regarding the age distribution of migrants to and from the three other European countries with an immigration surplus, namely Belgium, France and Switzerland. In these countries, as in Sweden, the average age of the population is relatively high. For France the immigration surplus appears to have benefited almost ex1 This is illustrated by a comparison between the age structure of the population on 31 December 1945 and on 1 July 1955. The group of persons who in 1945 were between 10 and 20 years of age had by 1955 increased by about 50,000. The 10-20 and 20-30 age groups totalled 857,000 and 1,056,000 respectively at the end of 1945, whereas in the middle of 1955 the corresponding age groups (20-30 and 30-40) totalled 905,000 and 1,077,000 respectively. 319 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 100. SWEDEN: AGE DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION IN 1950 AND OF IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population Immigration Emigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages . . . . 1,651 416 993 1,087 1,029 1,866 23.5 5.9 14.1 15.4 14.6 26.5 58.8 32.8 135.2 59.5 28.0 22.3 17.5 9.7 40.2 17.7 8.3 6.6 29.5 9.4 56.9 33.4 15.6 10.8 19.0 6.0 36.6 21.5 10.0 6.9 Total . . . 7,042 100.0 336.6 100.0 155.6 100.0 Age groups 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over 1 l Census taken on 31 December 1950 (See United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1954). clusively those generations which in 1946 were between 10 and 35 years of age, but the rejuvenating effect on the population as a whole was hardly noticeable in view of the relatively low net immigration figure. In Belgium, on the other hand, and even more so in Switzerland, the effect of migration was to increase these same generations considerably. Since, moreover, unlike in Sweden, only the very oldest and youngest generations had been born at a time when the birth rate was low, the effect of immigration, in widening the age pyramid at a level corresponding to the young adult generations, was probably to accentuate rather than to attenuate existing distortions. American Countries. Table 101, which compares the age structure of the population in Canada in 1950 and that of immigration from 1946 to 1957, shows that the latter consisted mainly of young adults, and more especially persons in the 20-30 age group who accounted for 35 per cent, of all immigrants (as compared with only 16 per cent, of the population). Gains due to immigration in the 15-20 and the 40-50 age groups were more or less proportionate to the size of those groups in the population as a whole, but such gains were considerably less than proportionate for the 0-15 age group and even less so for the over 50 group. Moreover, the very generations which gained the most by immigration were probably those from which emigration to the United States took the heaviest toll. Taken by and large, however, it can be safely said that the greater part of the relatively high population gain (nearly 8 per cent.) which resulted from net immigration to Canada during the period under consideration affected generations under 40 years of age and had the 320 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 101. CANADA: AGE STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION IN 1951 1 AND OF IMMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Popul ation Age groups 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over Total . . . 1 Immigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 4,251 1,058 2,220 2,042 1,613 2,826 30.3 7.6 15.9 14.6 11.4 20.2 365.3 120.2 592.1 330.7 157.0 104.2 21.9 7.2 35.5 19.8 9.4 6.2 14,010 100.0 1,669.4 100.0 Census taken on 1 June 1951. net result of widening the lower half of the age pyramid in an already remarkably young nation. In the United States, where the population is considerably older than in Canada, the age structure of immigration was fairly similar, although the average age of immigrants was slightly higher. Here again, the increase due to immigration was proportionately higher in the 15-40 age groups, and particularly in the 20-30 group, than for the rest of the population, but was proportionately lower for the groups under 15 and over 50 years of age. Emigration, moreover, mainly composed of persons over 40, considerably enhanced the rejuvenating effect of immigration. The balance of migration therefore resulted in a much higher gain for the groups in the lower half of the pyramid than for those in the upper half. This gain, however, was at all events a minor one by comparison with the size of the population (table 102). In Argentina the age structure of immigration 1 was fairly similar to that of the United States, although it included far fewer adults between 20 and 30 years of age, far more persons between 15 and 20 and an even higher proportion of persons over 40. The last-named group, however, formed a very high percentage of emigration, so that the final net gain, as was the case for Canada and the United States, was much higher than proportionate for the age groups between 15 and 40 years (particularly the 20-30 age group), a little less than proportionate for the 0-15 age group and much less than proportionate for the groups above 40 (table 103). 1 The analysis deals only with migration by sea. No data are available concerning the age of continental migrants. 321 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 102. UNITED STATES: AGE STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION IN 1950 AND OF IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population l Immigration Emigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 40,483 10,617 23,724 22,763 19,274 33,836 26.9 7.0 15.7 15.1 12.8 22.5 533.5 228.7 852.1 508.8 311.6 267.3 19.7 8.5 31.5 18.8 11.5 10.0 24.7 11.7 77.8 60.1 37.7 74.8 8.6 4.1 27.1 21.0 13.1 26.1 Total . . . 150,697 100.0 2,702.0 100.0 286.9 100.0 . Age groups 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over . . . . • 1 Census taken on 1 April 1950. TABLE 103. ARGENTINA: AGE STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION IN 1947 AND OF IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population a a Immigration Emigration Age groups 1 Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over . . . . 4,885 1,570 2,776 2,386 1,897 2,380 30.7 9.9 17.5 15.0 11.9 15.0 170.2 81.9 233.1 176.0 114.1 116.1 19.1 9.2 26.2 19.7 12.8 13.0 17.1 9.5 45.9 56.4 63.0 84.9 6.2 3.4 16.6 20.4 22.7 30.7 Total . . . 15,894 100.0 891.3 100.0 276.9 100.0 1 For 1945-48, the age groups are slightly different: 0-14, 14-22, 22-31, 31-41, 41-50 and over 50. Census taken on 10 May 1947 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1951). Over the whole period, therefore, migration appreciably increased the generations of young adults (already very numerous) and, to a less degree, the generations of children which were also very large. This trend towards rejuvenation took place in a country with an even younger population than that of Canada. Other Countries. In the Union of South Africa, where the white population, comparatively speaking, contains few young adults and a large proportion 322 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 104. UNION OF SOUTH AFRICA: AGE STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION IN 1950 AND OF IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population 1 a Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 0-15 15-20 . . . . 20-30 . . . . 30-40 . . . . 40-50 . . . . 50 and over . Age unknown 817 213 408 386 319 466 31.3 8.2 15.7 14.8 12.2 17.8 — Total 2,609 Age groups Emigration Immigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages — 47.7 11.7 54.3 50.2 28.1 22.9 0.5 22.1 5.5 25.3 23.2 13.0 10.6 0.3 35.3 7.3 35.2 25.5 13.9 11.3 2.7 27.0 5.5 26.8 19.5 10.6 8.6 2.0 100.0 215.4 100.0 131.2 100.0 1 For 1955-57 the age groups are 15-21 and 21-30 instead of 15-20 and 20-30. 1 July 1950 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1954). 2 Estimate at of persons over 50, the balance of migration by Europeans favoured the 30-40 age group more than others. Outside this group, the gain was relatively higher above the age of 40 than below the age of 30 (table 104). This was due not so much to the composition of immigration as to that of emigration, which was directed mainly towards Central Africa and in which the average age was considerably lower. In Australia, where in 1951 the age structure of the population was practically identical to that of the United States (i.e. its average age was TABLE 105. AUSTRALIA: AGE STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION IN 1951 AND OF IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION FROM 1946 TO 1957 Population 1 Immigration Emigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages . . . . 2,281 554 1,341 1,277 1,074 1,904 27.1 6.6 15.9 15.1 12.7 22.6 307.4 92.4 393.6 250.7 131.8 94.7 24.2 7.3 31.0 19.7 10.4 7.4 54.3 12.5 112.0 68.5 41.0 52.1 16.0 3.7 32.9 20.1 12.0 15.3 Total . . . 8,431 100.0 1,270.6 100.0 340.3 100.0 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over 1 Estimate at 30 June 1951 (Demography (Canberra, Commonwealth Bureau of Census and Statistics), Bulletin No. 69, 1951). 323 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS higher than in Canada) immigration comprised a higher proportion of persons in the 15-40 age groups (particularly the 20-30 group) than did the original population, and nearly as high a percentage of children under 15. Since immigration was considerable in relation to the size of the population, its rejuvenating effect was quite an important one. Emigrants, moreover, added to this effect, since "their average age was distinctly higher than that of both immigrants and the original population. All told, some two-thirds of the total net immigrants (which increased the original population by more than 12 per cent.) consisted of persons in the 0-30 age groups, which accounted for a little less than half of the 1951 population (table 105). In New Zealand, where the 1951 population comprised a slightly higher proportion of children than that of Australia and a slightly lower proportion of adults between 20 and 40 years of age, immigration attenuated this difference by increasing the latter group somewhat more and the former much less. By and large, immigration from 1946 to 1957 has not had as distinct a rejuvenating effect in New Zealand as in Australia, although the effect was noticeable among the adult population (table 106). TABLE 106. NEW ZEALAND : A G E STRUCTURE O F T H E POPULATION IN 1951 AND O F IMMIGRATION A N D EMIGRATION F R O M 1946 TO 1957 Popu ation ' Age groups 1 Immigration Emigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 0-15 15-20 20-30 30-40 40-50 50 and over . . . . Age unknown . . . 571 130 287 275 239 435 2 29.4 6.7 14.8 14.2 12.3 22.5 0.1 42.7 12.8 80.6 45.8 24.7 26.3 0.7 18.3 5.4 34.5 19.6 10.6 11.3 0.3 15.3 4.4 32.1 16.6 8.8 12.3 0.1 17.1 4.9 35.8 18.6 9.8 13.7 0.1 Total . . . 1,939 100.0 233.6 100.0 89.6 100.0 Census taken on 17 April 1951 EFFECTS ON SEX DISTRIBUTION As the foregoing has shown, the predominance of young adults in recent migratory currents was general, the variations above or below the average being confined within relatively narrow limits. On the other 324 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 hand, predominance of the male element, while usual among adult migrants, does not appear to have been quite so general, and the figures given in tables 107 and 108 show that in some cases the female element was in fact in a majority. These exceptional cases are the United Kingdom, the United States, Sweden and Ireland. They will be discussed at a later stage. The preponderance of the male element among adult migrants is bound up with the conjunction of two traditional factors : the predominance of economically active persons over inactive ones and, among the former, the predominance of men over women. These two factors, whose role and intensity varied from one case to another, caused variations in the balance of the sexes, with the proportion of the male element ranging from a little more than a half to a little over two-thirds. Even so, this proportion seems to have been exceeded considerably in the case of certain continental migration currents comprising few dependent persons, such as indigenous movements between African territories. The data given in tables 107 and 108, which refer for the most part to intercontinental movements only, show that the proportion of men among adult migrants was highest in southern Europe and Latin America (between 60 and 65 per cent, on an average). The correlation between the figures for these two groups of countries is hardly surprising since Latin America is still the main outlet for emigration from southern Europe and most of the immigrants who settled in Latin America after the war came from that part of Europe. Actually, this applies neither to Greece nor to Malta, and even Italy supplied fewer immigrants to Latin America than to the rest of the world. But, whether directed towards Latin America or not, emigration from southern Europe shows on the whole a particularly high preponderance of males, together with a relatively high proportion of workers to dependent persons and, above all, a low proportion of working women.1 In major emigration countries such as Malta and, to a lesser degree, Italy and Portugal, this was enough to cause a noticeable distortion in the sex distribution of the 20-40 age group, to the detriment of the male sex which should normally have a slight numerical advantage in that group, particularly as the higher mortality rate for men does not really begin to operate below the age of 40. In Malta 2, therefore, recent emigration resulted in a considerable, 1 With the exception, for Italy, of emigration towards the United States and Switzerland, which comprised workers of both sexes in more or less equal proportions. 2 It appears from an estimate of the Maltese population on 30 June 1956 that the 20-30 age group included only 17,300 men as against 24,200 women, and the 30-40 age group 16,900 men and 18,500 women (United Nations : Demographic Yearbook, 1957). TABLE 107. EMIGRATION COUNTRIES: SEX DISTRIBUTION OF ADULT MIGRANTS DURING THE POST-WAR PERIOD (In thousands) Immigration Emigration Absolute figures Countries Men Federal Republic of Finland Ireland 4 Italy 5 Malta * 5 ' 7 8 Netherlands 4 Portugal 6 Spain 5 6 9 4 2 United K i n g d o m 2 4 Total Men Women Men Women Total Men Women . . . . Ö a S O O Ger- many * 2 3 Women Percentages Absolute figures Percentages 73 51.0 49.0 51.4 53.0 47.0 51.6 49.0 51.0 408.0 1,107.6 63.0 37.0 25.2 12.6 37.8 67.0 33.0 299.1 254.5 553.6 54.0 46.0 155.0 80.1 235.1 65.0 35.0 100.4 95.1 195.5 27.3 24.1 25.3 26.3 699.6 > X 5.3 176.5 4.8 10.1 238.3 52.5 74.0 47.5 61.7 238.1 226.8 464.9 51.0 49.0 26.0 283.0 197.4 480.1 59.0 41.0 95.2 50.3 145.4 65.5 34.5 523.2 699.2 1,222.4 43.0 57.0 252.1 318.8 570.8 44.0 56.0 M O H 4 ' Period covered: 1953-57. ' Persons over 20 years of age. ' Period covered : 1947-57. Persons over 15 years of age. "Period covered: 1946-57. 'Persons 8 over 14 years of age, but over 15 for 1955-57. ' Period covered: 1950-57. Persons over 15 years of age, but over 14 for 1957. ' Persons emigrating for the first time. to TABLE 108. IMMIGRATION COUNTRIES: SEX DISTRIBUTION OF ADULT MIGRANTS DURING THE POST-WAR PERIOD (In thousands) Immigration Countries Emigration Absolute figures Men 1 2 Women Percentages Total Absolute figures Percentages Men Women Men Women Total Men Women 303.2 205.6 508.8 59.0 41.0 233.0 153.2 386.2 60.0 40.0 Sweden 3 4 Canada 3 4 127.9 710.0 149.8 594.0 277.8 1,304.1 46.0 54.0 54.0 46.0 56.5 69.6 126.1 45.0 55.0 — — — — — United States 3 4 937.4 1,231.2 2,168.5 43.0 57.0 141.2 121.0 262.2 54.0 46.0 Brazil 3 239.3 161.0 40.3 317.2 400.3 721.1 59.7 404.0 56.0 44.0 163.5 96.3 259.8 63.0 37.0 37.5 28.8 66.3 56.5 43.5 — — — — — 88.5 552.2 79.1 53.0 47.0 50.8 45.4 96.0 53.0 47.0 411.0 167.7 963.2 57.0 43.0 144.3 141.7 286.0 50.5 49.5 98.6 92.0 190.6 52.0 48.0 35.1 39.2 74.3 47.0 53.0 Belgium 6 Argentina 3 6 Southern Rhodesia 4 ' Union of South Africa Australia 34 New Zealand 3 4 8 1 Period covered: 1948-57. data have not been published. 1 April to 31 March. . . . 3 4 . . s • Persons of all ages. Period covered: 1946-57. 'Persons over 15 years of age, but over 14 for 1946-48. 5 *7 Persons over 15 years of age. Periods covered: 1946-51 and 1954-57. The 1952-53 8 Period covered: 1950-55, except the last two months of 1954. Years counted from DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 327 and in Portugal 1 an appreciable, decrease in the proportion of young adult men, while in Italy it accentuated the effects of war losses.2 In the Latin American countries, or at least in Argentina, Venezuela and Uruguay (since the immigration rate was too low in Brazil for any effect to be noticeable) immigration caused a corresponding disequilibrium in favour of the male sex. No accurate data exist in this respect for Uruguay and Venezuela, but the 1954 population estimate for Argentina shows a slight but abnormal male surplus in all groups between 15 and 50 years of age. 3 The surplus of male over female immigration was also distinct in France and Belgium. No figures are available for France, but it is known that the great majority of immigrant workers were men, and that the dimensions of family immigration were much more modest. Immigration in France, therefore, attenuated the effect of war losses on the sex distribution of the young adult generations. It is true that emigration (whether composed of departing aliens or of French emigrants) cancelled out part of this compensating effect. In Belgium migratory movements left an adult male balance much higher than the female balance, even though this does not appear clearly from the figures in table 108, which include Belgian nationals and also children and do not take into account the important balance of the years 1946-47. Data for the main immigration countries of the British Commonwealth also showed a more or less marked surplus of male emigration. This was negligible in New Zealand and the Union of South Africa, more important in Canada and even more so in Australia where the proportion of men in the net adult immigration figure exceeded three-fifths. In Canada, except for 1946, when the large number of war brides among immigrants resulted in a female surplus, the proportion of male immigrants continued to rise above the median, reaching almost twothirds in 1951, when immigration rose abruptly (table 109). Variations in the sex structure of immigration during the period under consideration often appear to be related to fluctuations in the global immigration volume itself because a notable proportion of immigrant workers are not accompanied by their wives but send for them after a certain period of time. As a result the proportion of males tends to be highest in periods 1 An estimate of the Portuguese population on 30 June 1956 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1957) showed that the 20-30 age group included 752,000 men and 768,000 women, and the 30-40 age group 494,000 men and 553,000 women. 2 The only data available for Italy are given by the census taken on 4 November 1951. They are as follows: for the 20-30 age group, 3,900,000 men and 4,030,000 women; and for the 30-40 age group, 2,980,000 men and 3,227,000 women (the latter difference due partly to war losses). 3 Altogether, 5,860,000 men for 5,675,000 women, i.e. a ratio of more than 103 to 100 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1956). 328 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 109. CANADA: DISTRIBUTION OF IMMIGRANTS BY SEX, 1946-571 Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . Tota 1 1 Men Women Total Men Women 10.5 28.3 55.2 40.9 32.6 99.5 69.1 71.5 67.3 44.5 70.6 119.9 41.8 25.8 47.1 34.5 25.3 55.5 55.7 59.0 53.8 41.8 58.0 95.9 52.3 54.1 102.3 75.4 57.9 155.0 124.8 130.5 121.1 86.3 128.6 215.8 20.1 52.3 54.0 54.3 56.3 64.2 55.3 56.4 55.6 51.5 54.9 55.6 79.9 47.7 46.0 45.7 43.7 35.8 44.7 43.6 44.4 48.5 45.1 44.4 710.0 594.0 1,304.0 54.4 45.6 Persons aged 15 and over. of rising immigration and lowest in periods of decline. This phenomenon, coupled with the development from 1951 onwards of Italian immigration with a greater preponderance of males, explains the particularly high rates between 1951 and 1954. Examination of the figures for Australia leads to similar conclusions (table 110). It was from 1949 to 1952 and during 1955, when immigration TABLE 110. AUSTRALIA: DISTRIBUTION OF IMMIGRANTS BY SEX, 1946-57 1 Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Tota 1 1 . . . . Men Women Total Men Women 5.5 13.4 30.0 77.7 80.7 60.5 63.3 27.0 39.2 56.7 55.1 43.2 9.1 12.3 23.3 53.4 52.6 38.6 36.3 27.4 33.4 40.1 39.6 44.7 14.6 25.7 53.3 131.1 133.3 99.1 99.6 54.4 72.6 96.8 94.7 87.9 37.5 52.2 56.3 59.3 60.5 61.1 63.6 49.6 54.0 58.6 58.2 49.1 62.5 47.8 43.7 40.7 39.5 38.9 36.4 50.4 46.0 41.4 41.8 50.9 552.2 411.0 963.2 57.4 42.6 Persons aged 15 and over. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 329 reached its highest levels, that the greatest proportion of males was recorded. The fact that the average rate (57.4 per cent.) was considerably higher than in the case of Canada (54.4 per cent.) can doubtless be attributed to the higher proportion of immigration from southern Europe. In Canada, however, the predominance of adult male immigration was not sufficient to upset the existing balance of the sexes in the age groups particularly affected 1 : this was due partly to the size of Canadian war losses, and probably even more so to the neutralising effect of emigration, particularly to the United States. In Australia, on the other hand, recent immigration caused a constant numerical disequilibrium in favour of the male sex in the age groups above 20, and particularly between 20 and 35.2 A certain number of countries, however, constitute exceptions to the general rule of predominance of the male element among adult migrants; they are, among emigration countries, the United Kingdom and Ireland and, among immigration countries, Sweden, Switzerland and the United States. For the United Kingdom the very great predominance of the female element was due to a combination of factors, some adventitious, others permanent : the numerous departures of war brides in 1946, the important role of family emigration in total emigration, including not only wives but also ascendants of the female sex and, finally, the exceptionally high proportion of women among economically active emigrants. After 1946, when it reached an abnormally high figure, the proportion of female British emigrants remained remarkably stable at about 55 per cent. The effect which this had on the sex distribution of the population was probably accentuated by immigration, although it would be hard to say precisely to what extent.3 The balance of migration 1 It appears from an estimate of the Canadian population made on 1 June 1955 (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, J956), that men were in a minority in the age groups between 25 and 40 and in a majority above the age of 40. 2 This is reflected in an estimate of the Australian population at 30 June 1955 (see United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1956). 3 The proportion of women having been almost as high among overseas immigrants as among emigrants, net female emigration represented about 60 per cent. of total net emigration, exceeding the net male emigration figure by about 100,000 (table 107). The net balance of continental movements can unfortunately not be established by sex. Immigration by Polish soldiers, prisoners of war and workers recruited collectively (up to the end of 1951) was responsible for an approximate gross gain of 200,000 adult men and 60,000 women, while recruitment under individual employment permits, together with collective recruitment after 1952, was responsible for a compensating gain of some 220,000 adult women and 70,000 adult men. But it is certain that the final balance was much larger for the former group of movements than for the latter. There remains the unknown factor of Irish immigration, which seems to have been mainly female. 330 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 111. UNITED KINGDOM: DISTRIBUTION OF OVERSEAS EMIGRANTS, BY SEX, 1946-57 * Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Year 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Tota 1 . . . . Men Women Total Men Women 25.7 39.4 52.0 50.4 46.8 51.4 56.2 47.9 44.4 37.3 44.9 50.1 93.1 50.6 62.9 55.3 53.0 59.8 67.9 61.8 57.7 49.1 52.8 61.7 118.8 90.0 114.9 105.7 99.8 111.2 124.1 109.7 102.1 86.4 97.7 111.8 21.8 43.8 45.3 47.7 46.9 46.3 45.3 43.7 43.5 43.2 46.0 44.8 78.2 56.2 54.8 52.3 53.1 53.7 54.7 56.3 56.5 56.8 54.0 55.2 546.5 725.7 1,272.2 42.9 57.1 1 Persons above the age of 20 for 1946-49 and above 15 for the remaining years ; Commonwealth citizens only. in toto was much more distinctly negative for the female sex than for the male, in which generations above the age of 20 do not appear to have suffered any appreciable loss from migration. The differential effect of migration on the sex distribution would thus appear, if this analysis is correct, to have counterbalanced in part the effect of war losses, although this conclusion is without prejudice to the results of a more detailed analysis, that is to say, an analysis extending to age groups. The detailed data are given in table 111. It is even more difficult to establish the balance for Ireland \ from which the great majority of emigrants went to the United Kingdom. There are in fact no accurate statistics available for these movements. Several indications, however, such as the slight surplus of women among recorded overseas emigrants (table 107), the definitely higher number of women among emigrants applying for travel documents to the Irish authorities, and certain anomalies in the sex distribution of the young adult generations at the time of the 1951 census 2, suggest that, up to that date at least, female emigration was larger than male 1 The statistics in table 107 do not even cover the whole of Irish overseas emigration and are therefore of purely indicative value. 2 The 1951 census (United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955) showed that the proportion of men to women was abnormally high in a number of age groups, particularly between 15 and 25 years of age. On the other hand, for all age groups between 15 and 65, the surplus of male over female population increased by 18,000 between 1946 and 1951. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 331 emigration, owing in part to the many opportunities afforded to women by the employment market in Britain. But it cannot be said with any certainty that this trend persisted in the second half of the period. Among the immigration countries in Europe, Sweden and Switzerland seem to have received more female than male immigrants. In the case of Sweden, this is apparent from the immigration statistics (table 108) and, in the case of Switzerland, from various indirect data. 1 In both cases, the excess of female immigration seems to be due largely to the nature of the demand on the employment market. In Sweden, the effect on sex distribution, though slight, is clearly perceptible from a comparison of the data giving the sex distribution of the population by age group for 1945, 1950 and 1955.2 In Switzerland, the trend seems to have been more pronounced : it was distinct at the time of the 1950 census3, and has become even more marked since.4 However, more recent immigration, with a clear majority in favour of the male sex, has probably corrected it to some extent. In the United States, women accounted for no less than three-fifths of net adult immigration. This unusual distribution is due to several factors, which include the attraction exerted by the United States on female labour, the relative importance of family immigration, the high number of women admitted on a non-quota basis as wives of American citizens—war brides and others—and the lesser stability of male immigrants, who returned more frequently to their own country. In spite of its comparatively modest proportions (by comparison with the size of the population), immigration over the period considered nevertheless appreciably accentuated the predominance of the female element among the generations today comprised between the ages of 30 and 44. Effects on Natural Population Trends Migration not only reduces the population of emigration countries by a certain number of units, with a corresponding increase in that of 1 See Annuaire statistique de la Suisse (Berne, Bureau fédéral de statistique). The .1950 census, in comparison with that of 1941, showed an increase of the female population almost twice as high as that of the male population (nearly 38,000 as against 17,500, for the age groups between 15 and 65). Moreover, statistics of foreign workers subject to employment restrictions in February 1957 showed for the first time a slight surplus of men, the majority of immigrant workers having previously, and for a long time, been women. Two further factors have doubtless contributed to alter the sex distribution of the population in favour of women ; the immigration of non-workers, mainly women, and the emigration of Swiss citizens, mainly men. 2 See United Nations : Demographic Yearbook, 1955 and 1956. 3 Ibid., 1955. 4 Ibid., 1956. 332 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 immigration countries, but it also in some degree diminishes the growth potential of the former and increases that of the latter. This indirect effect is, of course, extremely difficult, if not impossible, to measure precisely. The problem nevertheless is a very real one in so far as certain emigration countries seek to reduce not only their population but also to check their rate of demographic growth; others, on the contrary, fear that result; and some immigration countries are deliberately endeavouring to increase, rather than reduce, their rate of growth. The question is therefore whether, and how far, migratory movements composed mainly of young adults increase or decrease the rate of natural population growth in the countries concerned. Their influence on average life expectancy is usually negligible, at least from a short-term point of view, in both immigration and emigration countries. As for their influence on the birth rate (which in turn depends principally on the marriage rate, or rather on the fertility rate among married couples), a distinction must be made between migration by married couples and movements of single persons. With regard to the former, emigration deprives the country of departure of its future births, which go to benefit the country of destination (since it may be assumed, for the sake of simplicity, that the number of children born to migrating couples is the same as it would have been had they not migrated). But the greatest unknown factor is the effect on the marriage rate of migration by single persons. By reducing the number of potential couples in emigration countries (in a degree which, of course, varies according as the sex distribution of the emigrants is more or less unbalanced), such movements tend to reduce the actual marriage rate; but this reduction is not necessarily proportionate—and, experience seems to show, is in fact often less than proportionate—to the losses suffered by the sex of which emigration takes the heavier toll, particularly in the many cases where male emigration is preponderant. Conversely, in countries of reception, where the number of possible couples increases, there is not necessarily a corresponding increase in the marriage rate, owing to the fact that, immigrants often live in conditions which discourage or even prevent them, temporarily or permanently, from getting married. Thus the positive effect of immigration on the rate of population growth is often less, and sometimes much less—particularly when the sex distribution of migrants is heavily lopsided—than might be expected in view of the very favourable age structure of most movements. Thus it would seem—and detailed analysis would probably bear this out—that the effect of migration on the natural growth of the populations concerned is not as pronounced as might be thought at first glance ; that the decline of the birth 333 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS rate in emigration countries, where compensating factors appear to come into play, is not as great as might be expected ; and that in immigration countries the rise in the birth rate is likewise held in check by certain restraining factors. The higher the proportion of single persons among migrants, the more widely this conclusion applies. This does not mean that the effects of migration on the birth rate in the countries concerned are invariably less than proportionate to the respective population losses and gains which it causes; even less does it mean that these effects are negligible. It simply means that in both emigration and immigration countries they are partially absorbed by a sort of cushioning effect which, it is true, varies widely from one case to another. While it is impossible, for lack of precise statistical information, to establish a clear mathematical correlation between migration and birth rate trends, it is nevertheless worthwhile to examine the latter in the case of a few major emigration and immigration countries. There can be little doubt, for instance, that the downward trend in the birth rate of several southern European countries since the war (particularly Malta) was due at least in part to emigration.1 Emigration appears also to have been responsible for the slight decline in the Irish birth rate. A similar correlation is to be observed in the case of immigration countries. For example, in Canada the birth rate increased slightly during the period under consideration whereas the size of the generations reaching marriageable age decreased, as did the marriage rate.2 In Australia, both the size of the generations reaching marriageable age and 1 The birth rates in four southern European emigration countries from 1946 to 1957 are given below (number of births per thousand inhabitants). Country 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 21.6 21.5 23.3 21.7 20.2 20.1 20.8 20.6 20.0 20.6 20.7 Italy 23.1 22.2 21.9 20.3 19.6 18.4 17.9 17.8 18.2 18.1 18.1 18.2 Malta 38.9 38.8 36.0 34.1 33.0 30.4 29.3 28.3 28.1 27.2 26.8 27.5 25.4 24.5 26.7 25.5 24.4 24.5 24.7 23.4 22.7 23.9 22.9 13.7 Portugal . . . . 21.7 Source: United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955 and 1957, and information supplied by the United Nations. 2 The trend in the marriage and birth rates in Canada from 1946 to 1957 is given below (number of marriages and births per thousand inhabitants). Item 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Marriage rate 10.9 10.1 9.6 9.2 9.1 9.2 8.9 8.9 8.5 8.2 8.3 8.0 Birth rate 27.2 28.9 27.3 27.3 27.1 27.2 27.9 28.1 28.5 28.2 28.0 28.2 . . . Source: United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955 and 1957, and information supplied by the United Nations. 334 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 the marriage rate declined somewhat more, whereas the birth rate declined only slightly.1 These data, however, are purely indicative and there are doubtless other factors besides immigration which contributed to these trends. Effects on the Labour Force Economic migratory currents normally include a more or less clear majority of economically active persons. Consequently, they produce a relatively greater variation in the size of the labour force than in the total population. The proportion of the latter represented by persons in gainful employment is normally about 40 per cent. In the case of migrants, however, the proportion is usually above 50 per cent., and sometimes considerably more, even for permanent movements; in the case of short-term migration it comes close to, and sometimes reaches 100 per cent. The aim of the present discussion is to assess the losses and gains to the labour force in the countries concerned, both in absolute figures and in percentages. This attempt has been confined to the major emigration and immigration countries. Wherever possible, the analysis has been extended to include a breakdown by occupation and sex. However, the statistical material available is far from complete; nor are the data generally comparable. 2 For one thing, the migration statistics on which this analysis is largely based do not always include a breakdown by occupations, so that it is not always possible to distinguish between economically active migrants and others. Although such a breakdown does exist for most of the more important countries it usually refers only to the workers' occupation proper, and not to their occupational status. Moreover, each country establishes its classification according to its own standards, and this considerably complicates the 1 Marriage and birth rate trends in Australia from 1946 to 1957 are illustrated by the following figures (number of marriages and births per thousand inhabitants). 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Item Marriage rate Birth rate . . . . 10.1 9.7 9.2 9.2 9.2 23.6 24.1 10.6 23.1 22.9 23.3 23.0 8.0 7.9 23.3 22.9 8.6 22.5 7.8 7.6 7.6 22.6 22.5 22.9 Source: United Nations: Demographic Yearbook, 1955 and Ì957, and information supplied by the United Nations. 2 For a more detailed discussion of the problem of the value and comparability of statistics relating to occupational characteristics of migrants, see United Nations : Economic Characteristics of Internationa! Migrants : Statistics for Selected Countries, 1918-1954, Population Studies, No. 12 (New York, 1958), Chapter III. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 335 problem of international comparison. Besides, the indications are often vague and not always meaningful. Finally, the classifications do not always coincide with those used in labour force or employment statistics. Gaps in the migration statistics can sometimes be filled by using indirect data such as figures relating to the employment of foreigners published by immigration countries. Such data, however, are not always easy to apply to the purposes of this study and can often lead to inaccurate results. The best migration statistics themselves cannot always be considered as wholly satisfactory tools. They are based on data collected at a critical moment, often a turning point, in the migrants' lives when most of them cannot clearly foresee what employment they will have (or whether they will have any). Thus they often represent classifications by projected occupation and as such must be approached with caution. Even statistics which refer to the former activity of migrants may contain important errors, due to poor interpretation of the questionnaires or to vague or inaccurate answers. The foregoing refers only to the direct or primary effects of migration on the size and structure of the labour force. Obviously, it is difficult to go much further and try to assess either secondary variations in size resulting from the effects of migration on natural labour force trends or variations in structure caused by occupational mobility bound up more or less directly with migration. Even on the basis of migration statistics by age and sex, the former problem is difficult to solve. As for the latter, it cannot even be gone into because of the lack of reliable data. The following analysis therefore deals only with the primary effects of migration on both the size and structure of the working population in the countries concerned. COUNTRIES WITH AN EMIGRATION SURPLUS Europe United Kingdom. The United Kingdom has a relatively slight emigration surplus, but while migration appears to have had a negligible global effect on the size of the labour force, it has had a comparatively far-reaching influence on its structure. Net transoceanic emigration of Commonwealth citizens travelling by sea from 1946 to 1957 (totalling approximately 930,000) included about 390,000 economically active persons, representing some 42 per cent, of the over-all figure; almost 280,000 of these were 336 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 112. UNITED K I N G D O M : OVERSEAS EMIGRATION A N D IMMIGRATION (BY SEA), BY OCCUPATION A N D SEX, 1946-49 1 Emigration Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Immigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Male workers2 : Agricultural Commerce, finance and insurance Professional Skilled trades Transport and communications Labourers not ¡n agriculture or transport Ill-defined occupations 3 . . Total male workers . . . Males not gainfully occupied . 168.1 74.4 69.3 30.7 73.7 33.4 68.8 31.2 Total . . . 242.5 100.0 107.0 100.0 10.7 3.4 34.5 20.4 63.5 16.3 12.5 19.7 6.9 2.8 6.7 25.4 1.4 17.7 Female workers2 : Domestic service, hotels, etc. Commerce, finance and insurance Professional Clothing trades Ill-defined occupations 3 . . 22.7 13.9 3.6 16.5 Total female workers. . . 65.5 18.8 27.2 20.4 Females not gainfully occupied . 282.1 81.2 106.2 79.6 Total . . . 347.6 100.0 133.4 100.0 2.8 8.5 7.3 1.0 7.8 1 Commonwealth citizens only. * Persons 18 years of age and over. persons not gainfully employed (e.g. students), particularly for 1946 and 1947. 3 Includes a number of men and over 110,000 were women. The detailed figures, including the occupational breakdown, are given in tables 112 (for 1946-49) and 113 (for 1951-57).1 The total balance of intercontinental movements, including foreigners and air travellers, came to a considerably higher figure, but was still less than 450,000. Continental movements are much more difficult to evaluate. They include not only a considerable fraction of the immigration surplus from continental Europe (recorded by the Home Office) and of Irish immigration, but also Polish soldiers of the " Polish Resettlement Corps ", 1 There are no figures for 1950. 337 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 113. UNITED K I N G D O M : OVERSEAS E M I G R A T I O N A N D IMMIGRATION (BY SEA), BY OCCUPATION A N D SEX, 1951-57 1 Immigration Emigration Occupation Male workers 2 Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages : 16.9 8.8 55.2 61.2 131.8 27.6 35.2 53.0 Clerical, distributive and nonProfessional and managerial Transport and communica- | . . Total male workers . . . Males not gainfully occupied2 . 300.8 161.3 64.9 35.1 139.8 84.1 62.4 37.6 Total . . . 462.0 100.0 223.9 100.0 Ill-deflned occupations 3 7.6 5.2 2.5 | 19.2 10.9 5.6 Female workers2 : Domestic service, hotels, etc. Clerical, distributive and nonProfessional and managerial Industrial Ill-defined occupations 3 . . 59.2 42.5 19.0 3.8 | Total female workers . . . Females not gainfully occupied2. 135.8 398.5 25.4 74.6 69.7 187.7 27.1 72.9 Total . . . 534.3 100.0 257.4 100.0 11.2 6.3 1 Commonwealth citizens only. * Persons 15 years of age and over. persons not gainfully employed (e.g. students). 24.5 26.0 11.4 1.5 3 | Includes a number of and war prisoners having become free workers. Out of the net gain of some 680,000 resulting from all such movements between 1946 and 1957, the proportion of economically active persons was beyond doubt very much higher than average. Even if it had amounted to no more than two-thirds—and it was certainly more than this—it would have offset all losses resulting from the negative balance of intercontinental movements. Thus it appears that, far from diminishing the United Kingdom labour force, the migratory movements of these 12 years increased it. Furthermore, this estimate does not take into account the contribution of Irish seasonal labour. It should, however, be noted that the balance seems to have been markedly positive only in the first few years of the 338 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 period ; since then there have been slight fluctuations, with gains and losses more or less offsetting each other. This compensating effect, however, applies only to the over-all figures and does not extend to individual occupational categories. Overseas emigrants leaving the United Kingdom were, for the most part, skilled or semi-skilled industrial workers, commercial and office employees TABLE 114. U N I T E D K I N G D O M : E U R O P E A N I M M I G R A N T S R E C R U I T E D COLLECTIVELY U N D E R OFFICIAL P R O G R A M M E S , BY 1946-57 (In Occupation Agriculture . . Manufacturing . Public transport Services 3 . . . Miscellaneous 4 Total . thousands) Ex-members of the Polish Re- Ex-war Displaced settlement prisoners persons Corps 8.2 7.3 17.0 12.0 22.3 15.5 24.0 84.0 5 OCCUPATION, 1 Total Miscellaneous * 0.1 2.8 14.0 1.4 1.2 29.7 11.8 19.8 0.3 0.1 14.5 1.0 24.8 77.2 26.9 0.8 9.1 Absolute figures Percentages 60.2 21.8 50.8 12.3 0.9 40.5 26.1 28.5 10.2 23.9 5.8 0.4 19.0 12.4 212.6 100.0 Sources: Unpublished O.E.E.C. data, and Ministry of Labour and National Service: Report for 1957 (London, H.M. Stationery Office, 1958). 1 No data are available concerning the distribution by occupation of Irish workers, apart from those who received assistance from the Ministry of Labour and National Service and who were not numerous except in 1947 and 1948. The majority of these were placed in agriculture, rural industries and mines 3 (men) and in hospital and domestic service (women).5 ' Mostly Italian workers. Domestic and 4 hospital service. Mainly industrial workers. Does not include dependants of Polish soldiers, of whom 16,000 took up employment. TABLE 115. U N I T E D K I N G D O M : I N D I V I D U A L E M P L O Y M E N T P E R M I T S ISSUED TO F O R E I G N W O R K E R S , BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 l Absolute figures (thousands) Occupation Total . . . Percentages 46.9 11.5 230.4 56.6 129.7 31.9 407.0 100.0 Source : Annual reports of the Ministry of Labour and National Service for the years 1939-46 and 1947-57. 1 The great majority of these permits were issued to nationals of European countries. * Including 8 nurses and hotel staff. For the most part artistes and student employees in various occupations. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 339 and professional workers. Continental immigration, on the other hand, increased the population by far fewer skilled workers and consisted mainly of agricultural workers, general or semi-skilled industrial labour and domestic staff. The contrast is evident from tables 114 and 115. The most noticeable effect of recent migration on the British working population has therefore been to increase the labour force at the lower levels of the occupational scale and to weaken it at the middle and upper ones or, in other words, to lower the over-all standard of technical skill. This effect, however, may be considered negligible in relation to a total labour force of over 23 million (the figure for 1951) with particularly high vocational standards. Ireland. It would doubtless be interesting to assess precisely the effects of the heavy emigration of recent years on the labour force of Ireland. This is unfortunately impossible on the basis of available statistics. It has, however, been established that a very high proportion of the population losses due to emigration were sustained by the generations of working age—probably a much higher proportion than by the population as a whole. In actual fact, the labour force which (assuming the 1946 proportion of the labour force to the total population to have remained constant) should have increased by something like 170,000 or 180,000 between 1946 and 1956, decreased by some 80,0001 (reducing the proportion of the labour force to the total population from 43.9 to 42 per cent.). The occupational characteristics of Irish emigrants are not well known. They seem, at any rate, to have included few skilled workers and to have consisted mainly of farm workers, labourers and female domestic servants.2 This may have resulted in a rise in the over-all level of vocational skill of the remaining population. Netherlands. According to Netherlands statistics, net emigration of economically active persons from 1948 to 1957 came to more than 100,000, including 1 1,298,000 at the time of the 1946 census, as against 1,216,000 according to an O.E.E.C. estimate made in 1956. 2 See Commission on Emigration and Other Population Problems, 1948-1954: Reports (Dublin, the Stationery Office), p. 127; and numerical data in Statistical Abstract of Ireland (Dublin, the Stationery Office), 1947 to 1952: of the men who obtained travel permits, identity cards or new passports to go abroad, 47.3 per cent. declared that they were labourers and 30.1 per cent, indicated that they were farm workers, while 64.3 per cent, of the women stated that they were housewives or domestic servants and 9.9 per cent, nurses (statistics for 1946-51). 340 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 84,000 men and 19,000 women. This represents about 60 per cent, of total net emigration, which amounted to some 170,000 during the same period. Comparison with the ratio of the labour force to the total population—scarcely more than 40 per cent., according to the 1947 census—shows that the former lost considerably more to emigration, proportionately speaking, than did the latter. In the absence of adequate data on the occupational status of migrants for the years 1946-47, it is impossible to give a complete picture for the period under consideration. However, it may be surmised that the balance of migration for these two years, which left an immigration surplus of 47,000 due to large-scale repatriations from Indonesia in 1946, did not increase the labour force by as much as 20,000, because of the relatively low proportion of workers TABLE 116. NETHERLANDS: EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION AND SEX, 1948-57 Emigration Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) Male workers : Employers and self-employed . Professional Managerial Salaried employees and public servants Immigration Percentages 15.7 6.3 15.0 72.5 104.8 x Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 6.4 5.1 10.8 | 64.3 43.6 2 | Total male workers . . . 214.2 63.4 130.3 54.9 Males not gainfully occupied . . 126.4 36.6 108.2 45.1 Total . . . 340.6 100.0 238.5 100.0 Female workers : Employers and self-employed Professional Salaried employees and public servants Manual 0.7 1.0 23.5 18.8 3 j 0.4 0.7 15.1 ILO 4 | Total female workers . . . 45.8 14.9 27.1 11.4 Females not gainfully occupied. . 248.6 85.1 198.1 88.6 Total . . . 294.4 100.0 225.2 100.0 1 Including workers employed in agriculture (23.7), industry and mining (53.9), building (11.7) and miscellaneous occupations (15.6). 'Including workers employed in agriculture (4.5), industry and mining (28.3), building (3.7) and miscellaneous occupations (7.1). 'Including industrial workers 4 (4.8) and others (13.9), mainly household servants. Including industrial workers (2.4) and others (8.6), mainly household servants. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 341 among those repatriated. The net effect of migratory movements from 1946 to 1957 was therefore to reduce the working population by some 80,000 persons, or a little over 2 per cent, of the 1947 labour force.1 It appears, moreover, from table 116 that the heaviest losses consisted of manual workers engaged in agricultural or industrial trades. The category of " employers and self-employed workers " also sustained fairly heavy losses. For the other groups—the professions, managerial staff, salaried employees and civil servants—the net loss was fairly low. Federal Republic of Germany. The statistics available for Western Germany cover only the years 1953-57 and, within that period, a small part only of continental emigration. They show a very high proportion of workers among the emigrants (more than 55 per cent.) and an exceptionally large proportion of gainfully employed women (table 117). However, it may be risky to extrapolate these proportions to the whole of post-war German emigration, TABLE 117. FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF GERMANY: EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION AND SEX, 1953-57 1 Women Men Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Workers : Personal service Administrative and legal . . . Intellectual and artistic . . . Unspecified 7.3 63.5 5.1 16.6 1.5 3.1 1.6 8.3 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied2 . . . . 106.8 38.7 73.4 26.6 55.2 83.2 39.9 60.1 Total . . . 145.6 100.0 138.5 100.0 Industrial Technical 1 Nationals and aliens. The figures include West Berlin. of age. | 0.8 12.7 0.3 12.2 13.5 7.5 2.0 6.3 | "Includes all persons under 16 years 1 This covers only permanent movements. In addition, the Netherlands labour force has been considerably supplemented, particularly in mining and manufacturing, by Belgian and German frontier workers; these numbered nearly 14,000 on 31 December 1956. 342 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 even if displaced persons and alien refugees are excluded. It would seem, on the one hand, that overseas emigration prior to 1953 comprised a much lower percentage of workers than did subsequent movements and, on the other, that in continental emigration currents the percentage was still higher. On balance, the loss of working population in the Federal Republic resulting from the emigration of nationals between 1946 and 1957 was probably somewhere between 350,000 and 400,000, or less than 2 per cent, of the labour force at the time of the 1950 census. Italy. Italian statistics of overseas migration show for the period 1946-57 a net emigration of 515,000 workers, which is a little less than half the total net emigration (table 118). Unfortunately, it has not been possible, for lack of complete data on the labour force status of continental migrants, to obtain exact figures covering all migratory movements. However, an approximate assessment can be attempted. Net Italian emigration towards the rest of Europe amounted to about 700,000, and it is obvious that the greater part of this figure by far consisted of economically active persons, the share of family TABLE 118. ITALY: OVERSEAS EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 l Immigration Emigration Occupation Workers : Employers Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 19.6 j 19.7 225.8 406.4 2 I 9.0 34.5 107.5 3 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied Occupation not stated . . . . 684.7 626.8 20.3 51.4 47.1 1.5 170.7 81.8 4.9 66.3 31.8 1.9 Total . . . 1,331.8 100.0 257.4 100.0 and professional 32.8 Management staff and salaried Agricultural workers . . . . Wage earners and craftsmen . 1 Exclusive of movements between Italy and non-European countries of the Mediterranean basin, and air travel. 'Including masons (74.4), mechanics (59.0), carpenters (31.9), and tailors and shoemakers (38.2). 'Including masons (20.8), mechanics (16.0), carpenters (8.5), and tailors and shoemakers (7.3). DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 343 migration in continental movements having been quite small.1 Thus, taking account of both transoceanic movements and emigration to other European countries (movements to non-European countries of the Mediterranean having been negligible), the loss of working population in Italy due to emigration from 1946 to 1957 may be estimated at 1 million at least, equivalent to about 5 per cent, of the labour force counted in 1951 2, or about two-fifths of its natural increase between 1946 and 1957 (assuming that the proportion which it bore to the total population in 1951 remained constant). Nor do these figures include seasonal emigration to Switzerland and France, which accounted for an additional 70,000 workers each year on the average, the figure having been much higher in the latter part of the period under review. Losses by emigration consisted almost exclusively of manual workers in agriculture and industry (especially the latter), although the statistics available give no clue as to their level of skill; this, at all events, appears to have been higher among transoceanic than among continental emigrants. The lack of data concerning the proportion of labourers among the emigrants is particularly to be deplored, as this group is among those most seriously affected by the labour surplus in Italy. Nor is there any basis for assessing the number of women among emigrant workers, though this was probably very low. Spain and Portugal. Spanish statistics show for the years 1946-57 a net emigration of less than 190,000 economically active persons. This figure does not include emigration to Africa nor the comparatively large movement to France; had these been taken into account, the total would probably have come to about 250,000. Here again, the loss of working population due to emigration—slightly less than 2.5 per cent, of the 1950 labour force 3 —was considerably higher, relatively speaking, than the population loss as a whole. While economically active persons accounted for 38.6 per cent, of the 1950 population, the proportion of workers in net transoceanic emigration came to 46.5 per cent. The proportion of workers in continental emigration was probably, as in the case of Italy, considerably higher. The case of Portugal is even more typical: here emigration abroad and to the overseas provinces appears to have cut 1 Statistics of continental emigrants by occupation for 1950-53 show that over 80 per cent, were economically active; the same applies to statistics of assisted intercontinental emigration during the psriod 1950-56. 2 20,672,000 persons, according to the census taken on 4 November 1951. s 10,793,000, according to the census of 31 December 1950. 344 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 119. SPAIN: OVERSEAS EMIGRATION AND IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 Emigration Occupation Workers : Agricultural Industrial Commerce and related occupations Professional Immigration Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) 97.0 108.7 9.2 \ 14.9 25.1 7.9 35.0 1.9 8.7 42.8 7.8 15.1 Percentages 1 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied . . . . 280.7 283.8 49.4 50.6 93.5 64.7 59.1 40.9 Total . . . 564.4 100.0 158.3 100.0 down the working population by about 200,000 1, or between 6 and 7 per cent, of the 1950 figure.2 If these figures are compared with those which express the growth trend of the working population in both countries, it becomes apparent that emigration absorbed between 12 and 15 per cent, of the natural labour force increase for Spain and approximately one-third of that for Portugal.3 In both cases, practically all of the emigrating workers seem to have been men. In this respect, no precise data are available for Spain, but the Portuguese statistics disclose that the number of working women among emigrants was insignificant.* As for the manner in which emigration affected the different occupations in both countries, a particularly heavy toll seems to have been taken from the farm sector (almost 45 per cent, for Spain and around 42 per cent, for Portugal, as shown by tables 119 and 120). But, in proportion to its size, the labour force in the industrial sector (building, mining and manufacturing) sustained much greater losses in both countries. Manual workers in these two 1 According to the Portuguese statistics, returns from abroad were negligible (see Chapter VI). They need not in any case be deducted from the figures in table 119 : these refer only to emigrants departing for the first time, and the number of emigrants outside this category happens to have been approximately equal to the number of returns. As for emigration to the overseas provinces, it left a balance of 69,240 male emigrants 14 years old and over, a figure which may be taken as indicating the approximate size of net emigration by workers. 2 3,288,000, according to the census of 15 December 1950. 3 1.5 million approximately for Spain and 550,000 to 600,000 for Portugal. 4 Approximately 4,000 out of a total exceeding 153,000. 345 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 120. PORTUGAL: EMIGRATION \ BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) s 63.5 29.3 28.5 32.0 s 153.4 51.9 134.5 45.5 7.8 2.6 295.7 100.0 Workers : 3 Commerce and related occupations Miscellaneous occupations4 . . . . Total workers . . . Percentages 1 For 1946-54, the data refer to emigrants leaving their country for the first time; for 1955-57, to 8 total emigration. The occupational breakdown 1955 onwards includes additional details and Total . .from . sake, is grouped under different headings. For simplicity's however, it has been 3deemed preferable to group the data for the last two years together with those of previous years. Performance and supervision of services other than personal services (at least, with reference to 1955, 1956 and 1957). 4 6 Mainly industrial occupations. Children and housewives. • Probably includes a majority of persons not gainfully occupied. sectors accounted for the bulk of emigration, although it is unfortunately impossible to determine in what proportion the various levels of skill were represented.1 Net emigration for other occupational categories was low in Spain, in spite of a fairly high emigration rate for the commercial and related occupations, gross emigration in these categories having been very nearly offset by immigration. The situation was apparently different in Portugal: emigration was high in the commercial sector whose limits, however, are ill-defined. Malta and Greece. In Malta the proportion of workers among emigrants was also relatively high. Emigration statistics show for the years 1946-57 almost 28,000 male workers out of a total of about 60,000, a ratio of more than 47 per cent, which inclusion of the female element would doubtless raise to about 50 per cent., whereas the number of economically active persons in Malta at the time of the 1948 census amounted to only 32 per cent. of the population. Thus, emigration took a very large slice out of the labour force (which in 1948 numbered less than 100,000), amounting to twice the figure by which it would have risen had its 1948 ratio to the total population remained constant—an exceptional proportion, higher 1 Spanish statistics count labourers separately, but certain classes of comparatively unskilled workers may nevertheless have been included in the figures for agricultural and industrial emigrants. 346 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 even than in Ireland. More than half of this loss concerned skilled industrial workers 1, most of them trained in building and civil engineering trades. The remainder was divided up among various unskilled categories, mostly farm workers and labourers. It would appear that the proportion of economically active persons among emigrants from Greece was even higher, although the statistics are at best fragmentary. Those of I.C.E.M., which sponsored most overseas movements from that country during the last few years, show that from 1952 to 1956 the proportion of workers reached two-thirds— an exceptionally high figure, almost double the proportion of the Greek labour force to the general population. The rate for emigration as a whole was doubtless a little lower; assuming—somewhat arbitrarily, perhaps—a rate of 60 per cent., the total number of emigrant workers over the entire period would work out at some 90,000 (mostly men), or over 3 per cent, of the 1951 labour force. Non-European Countries For most non-European emigration countries, it is quite impossible to arrive at even a rough estimate of the occupational distribution of emigrants. Only for Mexico are relatively accurate data available, thanks to United States immigration statistics. Between 1 July 1949 and 30 June 1956, almost 195,000 permanent immigrants entered the United States from Mexico, of whom nearly 100,000 (slightly over 50 per cent.) were recorded as workers. Applying this rate to the entire 1946-57 period, the loss of working population sustained by Mexico as a result of permanent emigration to the United States 2 can be estimated at some 130,000, representing about 1.5 per cent, of the 1950 labour force. Approximately 60 per cent, of the emigrants were unskilled workers, i.e. labourers, farm workers and household servants. To gain a true picture of the movements of Mexican workers towards the United States, it should be remembered that seasonal as well as permanent emigration took place, and that the former, for which figures have already been given, was considerably greater than the latter. Regarding emigration from the British West Indies towards the United Kingdom, some estimates are available from British sources.3 1 This extremely high proportion can doubtless be explained by the action taken by the public authorities to promote vocational training for prospective emigrants. 2 Permanent returns to Mexico were insignificant. 3 Commonwealth Relations Office: Fourth Report of the Oversea Migration Board, December 1958 (London H.M. Stationery Office, 1958). See also " Post-War Migration of West Indians to Great Britain", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LXXIV, No. 2, Aug. 1956, pp. 193-209; and Industry and Labour (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. XVI, No. 12, 15 Dec. 1956, pp. 512-513. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 347 The net movement for the whole period would appear to have involved more than 90,000 persons, more than two-thirds ofthemmen and at least 80 per cent. (i.e. more than 80,000) economically active persons, mostly from Jamaica. This figure represents a high percentage of the West Indian labour force, which in 1946 amounted to approximately 1 million. As for the other non-European countries with an emigration surplus, little is known about the occupational structure of migratory currents originating in them. In most cases the numbers involved were so small that it is hardly worthwhile to try to fill the gaps in the statistics of emigration countries with the help of those compiled by immigration countries, even where this is practicable.1 The only movements important enough to justify systematic statistical investigation are the interterritorial ones on the African Continent. But the inaccuracy of available data concerning these movements, and indeed of the actual labour force statistics for the territories in question, does not allow of such investigation. All that can be stated is that these movements, which are usually temporary, consist almost wholly of male workers. COUNTRIES WITH AN IMMIGRATION SURPLUS Europe Sweden. In Sweden international migration from 1946 to 1957 resulted in a net gain of 180,000 persons, representing the difference between net continental immigration, which amounted to 210,000, and net intercontinental emigration of about 30,000. For the purposes of the present survey, these two trends will be treated separately, as one related essentially to Swedish nationals and the other to aliens. In the absence of direct data concerning the occupational status of migrants to and from Sweden, the effect of recent migration on the Swedish labour force can only be estimated on the basis of other statistics. From 1 January 1946 to 1 January 1958, the number of aliens gainfully employed in the country rose to 128,000 from somewhere between 45,000 and 50,000 2, making an increase of around 80,000. This does not include aliens naturahsed between 1946 and 1957, of whom some 40,000 to 45,000 (out of a total of 70,000) were gainfully occupied. The overall increase in the working population attributable to continental immigration was therefore in the neighbourhood of 123,000. As for 1 As in the case of Japanese immigration to Brazil. The figure was 58,000 at 1 November 1946 and had probably increased by something between 8,000 and 10,000 since the beginning of the year. 2 348 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 121. SWEDEN: ALIENS IN EMPLOYMENT ON 1 JANUARY 1947 AND 1 JANUARY 1958, BY OCCUPATION 1 January 1947 Occupation 1 January 1958 Absolute Absolute figures figures Percentages Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Agriculture Industry Transport Commerce and the hotel trade . . Administrative and intellectual professions .Health services Domestic service Miscellaneous Total . . . 6.4 29.6 ' 2.6 5.4 48.6 4.2 8.9 13.2 60.6 s 9.3 15.0 10.3 47.3 7.3 11.7 5.2 3.2 5.5 3.2 8.5 5.3 8.9 5.2 9.0 6.4 8.8 5.7 7.0 5.0 6.9 4.5 61.0 100.0 128.0 100.0 10.4 1 Including 9.2 for mining and metallurgy and 9.1 for textiles and clothing. for mining and metallurgy and 12.3 for textiles and clothing. 1 Including 29.3 overseas migration, it does not appear to have decreased the working population by much more than 15,000. Thus, the total net gain to the labour force due to migration between 1946 and 1957 can be estimated at somewhat more than 100,000, a figure about equal to its natural increase between the two censuses of 1945 and 1950 and representing about 4 per cent, of its size as disclosed by the 1950 census.1 Table 121 gives an approximate idea of the increase due to immigration in the different occupational sectors, based on the number of aliens employed in each at the beginning and at the end of the period considered. The sectors which gained the most from the influx of foreign labour were industry (principally mining and metallurgy), agriculture, the hotel trade and transport. Belgium. The data for Belgium are even less informative than those for Sweden, even though Belgian migration statistics include a breakdown by occupational sector. This is because the breakdown exists only for the years following 1948 and also because industrial workers are lumped together with commercial workers, and persons not gainfully occupied with workers in unspecified occupations. Moreover, in Belgium as in Sweden migration is divided into two main currents, one continental, 1 The 1945 figure was 2,988,000 and that for 1950, 3,105,000. 349 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS with an immigration surplus, the other intercontinental, with an emigration surplus, the occupational characteristics of the two being basically different. From 1946 to 1957 international migration in Belgium resulted in a total immigration surplus of about 150,000. This included a figure of 130,000 for 1948 and subsequent years, when net continental immigration amounted to 185,000 and net intercontinental emigration to 55,000, the corresponding numbers of economically active persons having been at least 75,000 and 26,000. The balance for the years 1948-57 would thus appear to have been positive and to have amounted to some 50,000, or about one-third of total net immigration, excluding the workers counted under the heading " miscellaneous " in table 122. Applying the same rate to the immigration surplus for the years 1946-47, total net immigration of workers would seem to have been approximately 65,000, or less than 2 per cent, of the Belgian labour force at the time of the 1947 census.1 There can, however, be no doubt that this is appreciably less than the real figure, not only because of the exclusion of some categories of workers from the total, but also because continental immigration during the years 1946-47 very probably included a considerably higher proportion of workers than in subsequent years. In these circumstances, the real figure may be placed at around 80,000—still a fairly low one in relation to the total labour force. However, while migratory movements to and from Belgium increased the labour force only by a moderate amount, their effects on its structure were fairly marked, since they derived from a fundamental TABLE 122. BELGIUM: IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1948-57 Continental migration Immigration Intercontinental migration Emigration Immigration Emigration Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages . . . . 9.0 193.5 18.0 237.1 2.0 42.3 3.9 51.8 6.1 126.0 14.0 132.7 2.2 45.2 5.0 47.6 0.8 8.2 7.7 34.4 1.6 16.1 15.0 67.3 3.9 27.6 11.4 64.4 3.7 25.7 10.6 60.0 Total . . . 457.6 100.0 278.9 100.0 51.2 100.0 107.4 100.0 Agriculture Industry and commerce . Miscellaneous 1 Percentages 3,481,000. 350 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 difference between the two types of movement involved, i.e. continental and intercontinental. From 1946 onwards continental immigration increased the Belgian labour force by more than 100,000 units, mostly men engaged for work not requiring prior vocational training, principally coal mining. Intercontinental emigration, on the other hand, decreased it by roughly one-third as many comparatively skilled manual and nonmanual workers. Hence the effect of migration, in Belgium as in the United Kingdom, was to swell the lower ranks of the occupational hierarchy and to thin out its middle and upper strata, though not to such an extent as in the United Kingdom. This trend was accentuated by two further factors, both negative: seasonal movements towards France of workers employed in agriculture and rural industries, which averaged 10,000 a year from 1946 on, and frontier migration of industrial workers to France and, subsidiarily, to the Netherlands, which averaged no less than some 50,000 per year during the period considered.1 France. The effects of migration on the French labour force between 1946 and 1957 are impossible to assess precisely. As in the case of Belgium, a distinction must be drawn between continental movements, which showed a large immigration surplus consisting for the most part of unskilled workers, and intercontinental ones, which were less important numerically but involved a net emigration of highly skilled workers. Data are insufficient on the former and practically non-existent on the latter. TABLE 123. FRANCE: ALIEN WORKERS PLACED IN EMPLOYMENT BY THE NATIONAL IMMIGRATION OFFICE, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 Occupation Agriculture Metal working Construction Domestic service Miscellaneous Total . . . Absolute figures (thousands) Percentages 119.7 69.1 80.2 146.5 26.0 56.0 24.1 13.9 16.1 29.4 5.2 11.3 497.5 100.0 1 See above, Chapter V. The number of these workers fluctuated within relatively narrow limits as regards France and more widely as regards the Netherlands which was, moreover, the source of a smaller movement in the opposite direction. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 351 From 1946 to 1957 the French National Immigration Office placed approximately 500,000 alien workers in employment; their occupational distribution is given in table 123. To this figure should be added some 40,000 prisoners of war who became free workers in 1946 and who chose to remain in France at the expiry of their contract, Italians having entered illegally in the early part of 1946, and a number of refugees whose number is difficult to estimate and whose placing in employment was not supervised by the National Immigration Office. Thus, gross immigration for employment during these 12 years would appear to have amounted to about 550,000 to 600,000 persons. As for net immigration, the 1946 and 1954 census data provide the basis for a rough estimate. Taking into account persons who acquired French nationality in the meantime, total net immigration of aliens between these two years may be estimated at approximately 310,00o1, as compared with 450,000 to 500,000 for total gross immigration. Departures of aliens would thus appear to have amounted to roughly one-third of the number of arrivals. Assuming this proportion to hold good for the entire period considered, net immigration of foreign workers between 1946 and 1957 would come to about 400,000; this, however, as already stated, is at best a rough approximation. Agriculture, construction, mining and metallurgy were the sectors which benefited most from these arrivals which, although their total was impressive, represented only about 2 per cent, of the 1954 labour force.2 In addition, seasonal workers numbered 15,000 to 20,000 annually between 1946 and 1950, around 30,000 between 1951 and 1955, and approximately 50,000 in 1956-57, and the number of frontier workers from Belgium fluctuated between 40,000 and 50,000 between 1946 and 1955. With regard to overseas movements of French nationals—both to French overseas territories and to foreign countries—the figures are, as already stated, too imprecise to allow of an assessment of the resultant loss of working population. However, taking into account persons recently repatriated from Egypt, Tunisia and Morocco, it is probable that the net loss was negligible. 1 Calculated as follows : Alien population in 1954 Persons having acquired French nationality between 1946 and 1954 Natural increase from 1946 to 1954 Alien population in 1946 Total net immigration by aliens 2 18,824,000. 1,560,000 + 500,000 - 7,000 — 1,744,000 309,000 352 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Switzerland. As in the case of Sweden, Belgium and France, immigration to and emigration from Switzerland differed vastly in size and in structure. Immigration of aliens was on a large scale and consisted mainly of manual and relatively unskilled workers; emigration of Swiss nationals, on the other hand, was principally to overseas countries and was largely confined to the more highly skilled categories. The increase in the working population which resulted from all foreign immigration (including permanent, frontier and seasonal movements) was very large in proportion to the Swiss labour force (2,156,000, according to the 1950 census). Permanent and frontier movements alone seem to have resulted in a net gain of at least 240,000 workers 1 or over 10 per cent, of the 1950 labour force. As for seasonal movements, they averaged 50,000 a year between 1949 and 1952, and since then progressed considerably until in 1957 they exceeded 135,000. As tables 124 and 125 show, the sectors which rely most heavily on foreign labour are the manufacturing industries, principally metallurgy, and construction, the latter mainly under seasonal contracts. Then come the hotel trade, agriculture and domestic service. In comparison with the massive influx of foreign workers, emigration was on a modest scale. Statistics of departures and returns of Swiss TABLE 124. SWITZERLAND: FOREIGN WORKERS SUBJECT TO EMPLOYMENT RESTRICTIONS IN 1950 AND 1958, BY OCCUPATION 1950 Occupation Absolute Absolute figures Percentages figures Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Agriculture Construction 1 Manufacturing Hotel trade 9.4 1.8 22.5 2 16.7 30.7 8.9 Total . . . 1 Including mining and quarrying. 1 1958 90.1 10.5 1.9 25.0 18.6 34.1 9.9 14.3 14.7 129.7 45.1 33.8 23.9 5.5 5.6 49.6 17.3 12.9 9.1 100.0 261.6 100.0 * Including metallurgy (7.2) and textiles (5.6). This figure is borne out by the statistics of foreign workers subject to employment restrictions, which between February 1949 and February 1958 showed an increase of 155,000 approximately. In addition, between 1949 and 1957 some 40,000 persons, presumably workers for the most part, were freed from employment restrictions. As for the balance for 1946-48, this would appear to have been somewhere between 50,000 and 60,000. 353 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 125. SWITZERLAND: EMPLOYMENT PERMITS ISSUED TO SEASONAL WORKERS IN 1949, 1952, 1954 AND 1957, BY OCCUPATION 1952 1949 Occupation Absolute Absolute Absolute Absolute figures Percenfigures Percen- figures Percen- figures Percen(thou(thoutages tages (thou(thoutages tages sands) sands) sands) sands) Agriculture . . . 13.3 Construction . . 11.7 Manufacturing * 1.1 Hotel trade. . . 12.0 Domestic service 7.4 Miscellaneous 2.0 28.1 24.7 2.3 25.2 15.6 4.1 15.0 33.7 2.3 11.3 0.3 1.0 23.6 53.0 3.5 17.8 0.5 1.6 15.9 43.4 3.9 16.0 0.2 1.7 Total . 47.4 100.0 63.5 100.0 81.1 1 1957 1954 19.6 53.5 4.8 19.7 0.3 2.1 18.2 88.8 6.8 20.7 0.3 1.7 13.3 65.1 5.0 15.2 0.2 1.2 100.0 136.3 100.0 Including mining and quarrying. citizens subject to military service suggest that the loss of economically active persons during the period considered was in the neighbourhood of 20,000, of which approximately two-thirds went to overseas countries. This figure does not include women or aliens, but these do not appear to have weighed heavily in the over-all total. The Americas Canada. In the case of Canada, lack of emigration statistics makes it extremely difficult to assess net immigration of economically active persons. The changes in the occupational classification of immigrants which were made in 1953 further increase this difficulty. According to the data given in tables 126 and 127, which cover the whole of the period, nearly 900,000 immigrants entered Canada in order to engage in a gainful occupation. This should be set off against losses resulting from returns of immigrants to Europe and the United States and emigration by Canadian citizens or residents, mainly towards the United States, which during the period under consideration caused a total population loss of some 580,000 persons of whom less than half, apparently, were economically active. Judging by these figures, the gain in working population resulting from total migration during the period must have amounted to over 600,000, representing nearly 12 per cent, of the working population counted in 1952.1 This means 1 5.3 million. 354 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 126. CANADA: IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-52 Absolute figures (thousands) Occupation Percentages Workers : Skilled Semi-skilled and unskilled Commercial Professional Domestic service Miscellaneous . . . . 103.0 99.9 94.2 ' 17.7 27.9 20.2 32.1 25.7 | Total workers. . . Not gainfully occupied2 . . 420.7 368.6 53.3 46.7 Total . . . 789.3 100.0 •Including lumbermen (11.5), miners (8.9), labourers (27.7), industrial workers (6.8), construction workers (6.8), transport workers (8.9) and others (23.7). * Including persons whose occupations were not stated. that the Canadian labour force was greatly increased as a result of immigration, and to a proportionately much greater extent than the total population. The figures reproduced in tables 126 and 127 give an idea of the occupational distribution of the immigrants. A particularly high proportion were manual workers destined for the primary and secondary sectors of the economy, i.e. skilled and semi-skilled workers for mines, construction and, above all, manufacturing, farm and forestry workers, and general labourers. Taken together, these different categories accounted for more than two-thirds of all immigrant workers. The other important groups were female domestic servants, office staff and professional workers. As for emigration to the United States and returns to Europe, these seem to have affected mainly skilled industrial workers, clerical and commercial employees and professional workers.1 To the relatively small extent that emigration cut down the working population, the change in the labour force structure was entirely different from that caused by immigration. Roughly speaking, immigration strongly reinforced the middle and lower strata of the occupational hierarchy, whereas emigration had a tendency to weaken the middle and upper strata. However, even in the categories most affected by emigration, the balance of arrivals and departures appears to have been clearly on the positive side. 1 This information is based on United States and United Kingdom statistics. DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS 355 TABLE 127. CANADA: IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1953-57 Absolute figures (thousands) Occupation Workers : Professional and technical Managerial, administrative and clerical . Transport and communications . . . . Commerce and finance 1 Services Agriculture Other primary occupations Mining Industry and construction General labour Miscellaneous 49.7 51.6 12.5 18.5 66.7 53.5 2.3 4.1 151.0 63.1 3.0 Total workers . 476.0 54.1 404.1 45.9 880.1 100.0 Not gainfully occupied Total . 1 Percentages Principally domestic service. United States. American immigration and emigration statistics only give a breakdown by occupation for fiscal years ending on 30 June. Table 128 shows that net foreign immigration between 1 July 1945 and 30 June 1957 increased the labour force by 1,090,000 persons, representing a little less than half (actually 47.3 per cent.) of total net immigration. If the same proportion is applied to net immigration for the 12 calendar years 1946-57, which amounted to 2,415,000, the corresponding increase in the labour force comes to about 1,150,000 persons—still a very low figure in comparison with the total labour force, which in 1950 amounted to 60 million.1 The proportionate increase in the labour force was slightly higher than that of the total population, of which the number of economically active persons at that time represented only 40 per cent. ; nor does this include seasonal farm workers, of whom officially recorded immigrants alone numbered about 200,000 in 1951, 400,000 in 1955 and 450,000 in 1957. In view of the small size of the over-all proportionate increase in the labour force, there is no need to go into a detailed analysis of its breakdown by occupation. Suffice it to say that the number of skilled 1 This does not allow for losses resulting from emigration of United States citizens, which reduced the net gain to less than 1.1 million. 356 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 128. UNITED STATES: FOREIGN IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 l Immigration Occupation Absolute Absolute figures Percentages figures Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Workers : Professional and technical . . Farmers Proprietors and management staff Clerical and sales workers . . Craftsmen and specialised work- 1 Emigration j 35.0 3.3 1,227.8 1,372.4 47.2 52.8 136.7 158.1 46.4 53.6 2,600.2 100.0 294.7 100.0 180.1 77.6 66.9 198.6 Skilled and semi-skilled workers Domestic service workers. . . Other service workers . . . . 196.3 186.4 100.2 63.8 39.9 118.0 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied . . . . Total . . . 22.2 15.1 8.4 12.8 6.7 10.9 5.8 16.6 Year ending on 30 June. industrial workers and, even more so, of professional workers was proportionately much higher among immigrants than among the American working population. On the other hand, it is probable that emigration by United States citizens, on which very little information is available, also consisted mainly of persons in these two categories, particularly the latter. Argentina. Immigration and emigration statistics for Argentina, as already stated, apply only to movements of aliens by sea, thus covering most, but not all migratory movements. For 1945-57, they show a net immigration of 224,000 workers, representing only 36.4 per cent, of total net immigration. This exceptionally low figure can be explained by the importance of family immigration, the small number of working women among immigrants and the high percentage of workers among repatriates. Argentina would seem to have been the only immigration country where the working population gained proportionately less than the total population as a result of immigration, the proportion of the population gainfully occupied at the time of the 1947 census being 40.6 per cent. 357 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 129. ARGENTINA: IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 Immigration Occupation Emigration Absolute Absolute figures Percentages fìgures Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Workers : Agricultural and related . . . Industrial Construction Transport and communications Professional Services Miscellaneous 114.0 132.7 23.6 57.8 10.2 18.6 6.1 4.7 Total workers . . . 367.7 523.7 41.3 58.7 143.9 133.0 52.0 48.0 891.3 100.0 276.9 100.0 | 11.9 50.4 7.8 50.0 6.7 12.0 2.1 3.1 | Total . . . In relation to the labour force counted at that date 1 , the contribution of immigration by sea represented less than 3.5 per cent. It consisted mainly of farm, industrial and construction workers, no details being available as regards their degree of skill. The figures given in table 129 exclude, among other things 2 , the large balance (amounting probably to about 190,000) of continental movements, other than by sea, to and from neighbouring countries. In the absence of precise data, it may be assumed that half of this figure consisted of workers, mostly unskilled. In addition, there was some immigration of seasonal labour on which, however, no data are available. Other Countries. For Brazil, where gross immigration between 1946 and 1957 amounted to approximately 570,000, the proportion of active immigrants appears to have been slightly higher than 50 per cent, (table 130). Net immigration of workers during the same period may be set at about 220,000, or slightly more than 1 per cent, of the 1950 labour force.3 This gain consisted principally of farm workers and of skilled and semiskilled industrial workers. 1 2 3 6,446,000. There are no figures available for 1952 and those for 1951 are unreliable. 17,117,000. 358 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 130. BRAZIL: IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-50 AND 1953-57 1946-50 Occupation 1953-57 Absolute Absolute figures Percentages figures Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Workers : Agricultural Skilled Unskilled Technicians Traders Miscellaneous 13.6 16.3 1.3 2.4 25 6 j 46.8 61.7 8.6 3.0 22.6 20.6 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied1 . . . . 59.2 52.7 52.9 47.1 163.3 142.7 53.7 46.3 Total . . . 111.9 100.0 306.0 100.0 } - { | 1 This includes immigrants classified under the heading domésticos which appears to include children and the great majority of female immigrants. In Uruguay, immigrant workers—some 35,000 for the entire period— seem to have accounted for at least 60 per cent, of total overseas immigration. Approximately half the immigrants were farm workers, and most of the remainder were skilled industrial and construction workers. For Venezuela no national statistics are available. Most of the immigrants came from Italy and Spain, whose statistics show that at least 60 per cent, of net emigration to Venezuela consisted of economically active persons. Assuming net immigration during the period considered to have totalled approximately 330,000, net immigration of workers can reasonably be estimated at about 200,000, or roughly 12 per cent, of the 1950 labour force.1 With regard to Italian and Spanish immigration, the gain consisted almost entirely of manual workers, mostly for manufacturing and construction. Africa In the Union of South Africa, where gross immigration by persons of European stock reached 215,000 during the period under review, nearly half this total consisted of economically active persons, including a high proportion of industrial workers, a remarkably high percentage of professional workers and a remarkably low one of farm workers 1 1,706,000. 359 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 131. UNION OF SOUTH AFRICA : IMMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 Absolute figures (thousands) Occupation Workers : Agricultural Industry, mining and construction Transport and communications Administrative, commercial and clerical Professional Personal service Independent Miscellaneous and unspecified Total workers . . . Percentages 4.5 40.3 1.9 22.9 22.1 3.5 3.7 6.8 | 105.5 49.0 109.9 51.0 215.4 100.0 Total . . . (table 131) ; however, owing to heavy emigration, mostly to the Rhodesias, total net immigration came to little more than 80,000. This would mean a net gain of only 40,000 for the working population—a figure which, however, represents 4 per cent, of the entire European labour force counted in 1951.1 This gain was further increased by African immigration, which must have run into hundreds of thousands, although it is impossible to make an accurate estimate. With regard to the three territories which now form the Central African Federation, where net immigration by persons of European stock reached 135,000 for the period as a whole, the resultant gain for the working population can be estimated at about one-half of this figure.2 This means that the increase considerably more than doubled the European labour force in the whole of the Federation, the figure for 1946 being less than 45,000. The sectors benefiting most from this influx were manufacturing, mine construction (in Northern Rhodesia) and transport. Immigration by African workers was also considerable, though lower than in the Union of South Africa; between the censuses of 1951 and 1956 African wage earners from other territories (principally 1 983,000. A breakdown by occupation for 1949-53 is available in the case of Southern and Northern Rhodesia, but this includes movements between the two territories, a distinct breakdown for the whole of the Federation being available only from 1955 onwards. These figures show that the proportion of workers among immigrants, including persons seeking employment, was about 50 per cent. 2 360 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Mozambique) employed in the three territories of the Federation increased in number by some 30,000 only, while their proportion to the total number of African wage earners dropped from 22 to 16 per cent. It is, however, probable that the increase had been greater between 1946 and 1951.1 Australia and New Zealand Out of a total net immigration of 939,000 persons to Australia from 1947 to 1957 2, the number of economically active persons appears to have been around 480,000, representing a proportion of 51 per cent. This increased the 1947 labour force 3 by no less than 13 per cent. —a much larger proportionate gain than that registered by the total population. Table 132 shows that this increase concerned manual occupations chiefly (skilled industrial and construction workers having accounted for nearly one-fourth of the total), agricultural workers, semi-skilled industrial workers, labourers and domestic staff. The gain was also relatively large in the professional category and relatively low in that of commercial TABLE 132. AUSTRALIA: IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1947-57 1 Immigration Occupation Absolute figures (thousands) Workers : Agricultural Professional Administrative . . . . . Commercial and clerical . Domestic service Skilled workers Semi-skilled workers . . Labourers Occupation not stated . . Percentages Emigration Absolute figures Percentages (thousands) . . 88.9 49.0 13.0 80.5 56.2 158.9 90.5 69.0 37.5 Total workers . . . Not gainfully occupied 643.1 596.4 51.9 48.1 156.4 143.7 52.1 47.9 Total . . . 1,239.7 100.0 300.2 100.0 1 . . . . . . | 6.6 28.3 7.3 35.6 9.6 34.7 15.5 14.3 4.5 | From 1 July 1947 to 31 December 1957. 1 2 3 The total number of African wage earners rose from 759,000 to 1,038,000. The data for 1946 showed a negative balance. 3,238,000, representing 42.7 per cent, of the total population. 361 DEMOGRAPHIC EFFECTS TABLE 133. NEW ZEALAND: IMMIGRATION AND EMIGRATION, BY OCCUPATION, 1946-57 1 Immigration Occupation Emigration Absolute Absolute figures Percentages figures Percentages (thousands) (thousands) Workers : Agriculture, forestry, etc. . . . Industry and construction . . Transport and communications Commerce and finance . . . Administrative, clerical and Miscellaneous and unspecified . . 11.1 41.0 7.5 8.3 S > f I) 44.5 10.0 10.9 2.7 10.5 2.5 4.1 > 25.8 2.9 3.0 f . S > (<J ; ( ) Total workers . . . 133.3 100.1 57.7 42.9 51.5 38.1 57.5 42.5 Total . . . 233.4 100.0 89.6 100.0 1 From 1 April 1946 to 31 March 1958. all types of personal service. * In the statistics for 1956 " domestic service " includes and clerical workers. Thus the occupational structure of immigration to Australia during the period in question was similar to that of immigration to Canada. The figures in table 132 also show that it was vastly different from that of emigration, the latter including, in particular, a much higher proportion of non-manual workers. Here again there was a marked similarity between Australia and Canada. In New Zealand, out of a total net immigration of 144,000 from 1946 to 1957, economically active persons numbered 82,000, or almost 56 per cent, (table 133). This represents a gain of nearly 12 per cent. over the 1945 labour force.1 The proportionate gain for the working population was therefore much larger than that for the population as a whole. Its occupational structure differed slightly from that for Australia : it included fewer industrial workers and considerably more non-manual workers. Bibliographical References See the list of statistical sources for Chapters V and VI. See also Proceedings of the World Population Conference, 1954, Papers, Vol. II (New York, 1955). UNITED NATIONS: 1 679,000. CHAPTER XI ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS The economic and social consequences of post-war migration are more difficult to assess than its demographic effects. There are two reasons for this. In the first place, the analytical problem is not merely one of establishing the facts ; it also entails the working out of complex relationships between a series of factors, which leaves much more scope for personal judgment. In the second place, many of the data needed to ascertain the facts are lacking. These two considerations apply even more to the social than to the economic aspects of the analysis, for by their very nature the social consequences are much more difficult to measure statistically than the economic ones. Even the choice of a standpoint from which to judge the facts is a highly controversial problem. There can be no doubt that international migration, by moving men to countries where better use can be made of their working capacity, tends to raise the over-all level of productivity; on the other hand, the argument that migration removes the difficulties which gave rise to it is open to challenge. In other words, the supranational, liberal approach, which tends, a priori, to favour migration, overlooks the fact that the world is still divided up, from the economic point of view, into national units and therefore cannot be accepted without qualification. Account must therefore be taken of the interest of each of the countries concerned, particularly that of emigration countries. But the choice of national interest as a criterion is an equally controversial matter. If income per inhabitant is taken as the yardstick for measuring national interest, the problem of increasing it will differ according to the length of the period during which that increase is to take place. A measure which is beneficial in the short term may cease to be so in the long run; on the other hand, a short-term sacrifice may prove beneficial in the long term. The problem is even more complicated if, in addition to the increase in average income, account is also taken of the social problem of the distribution of income. In view of all these conflicting considerations it has been considered preferable to confine this chapter as far as possible to descriptive material, dealing successively with the repercussions of recent migratory movements on economic and social development in emigration and immigration countries and the effects of migration on the migrants themselves. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 363 Effects on Emigration Countries GENERAL The effects of emigration on economic and social development in emigration countries can be expressed in terms of its repercussions on real average incomes and on the distribution of the national income. It is readily apparent that emigration will immediately tend to raise average personal income if the income of the emigrant is below that level and to lower it if his income is higher. But such a view of the question is too superficial; for obviously the departure of an income earner will do more than simply reduce the national product by the amount of his contribution to it. In this connection a fundamental distinction must be made between emigration by persons in regular employment and emigration by the unemployed.1 The former gives rise to a loss of production and a consequent drop in the national product, the amount of which will vary in direct proportion to the productivity of the emigrant workers measured in terms of their incomes. This loss will cause a fall in consumption and in savings corresponding to the proportions of their income which the emigrants previously allocated to each. The effects of emigration by unemployed persons are different in that it does not cause a fall in production; its only effect is to make an income which previously had to be drawn from savings for consumption purposes available for consumption of a different type or for investment. Thus the effects of emigration on development are different in the two cases. In the former the fall in consumption resulting from emigration has an adverse effect on propensity to invest, while the fall in total savings gives rise to a corresponding fall in the capacity to invest. On the contrary, in the second case propensity to invest may decrease in the sectors in which consumption is reduced but will increase in others, while investment capacity will also increase. However, emigration will produce its full investment-curtailing effect only if the emigrant workers are not replaced, either because there is nobody to replace them or because their departure and that of their families have resulted in such a fall in demand in the particular branch or branches of production in which they were previously employed as to make their replacement unnecessary. On the other hand, if emigrant workers are replaced by others previously employed in another branch 1 The dependants of an economically active person need not be taken into account if they have no income of their own, as their consumption can be considered as part of the consumption of the breadwinner. 364 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 —who may in their turn be replaced by yet other workers from other sectors, and so on—the pressure to disinvest is ultimately transferred to the sector or sectors in which the vacancies remain unfilled. This effect is, however, eased by the fact that each switch of jobs involves a transfer from a less productive to a more productive job; and if the migrants are replaced by unemployed or previously inactive persons, there will be no tendency towards disinvestment at all, since the emigrants' incomes —and consequently their consuming and saving potential—passes to new producers who were not previously obtaining incomes from employment—a situation, in effect, analogous to that resulting from emigration of unemployed persons, the only type of emigration likely, a priori, to stimulate development. It follows, then, that emigration will have a completely different effect in a country with full employment and in an overpopulated one suffering from underemployment. In the latter case emigration may make for higher productivity (provided that the producers lost can be replaced immediately and without difficulty). In countries with full employment, on the other hand, emigration may create a cumulative tendency to disinvest which may have a repercussion on the national income much greater than the direct fall in earnings and thus exert a depressing influence on average incomes even if the incomes of the emigrants were themselves relatively low. It has been assumed so far that each country is a completely independent economic unit and that migration only affects production and income in so far as it alters the employment situation. Obviously this is never the case in practice. Emigration has certain effects on the balance of payments; this is adversely affected by the capital exports which the emigrants are allowed to make, and favourably affected by the capital repatriated by those who return, remittances of savings and, in some cases, increases in certain exports. These secondary effects of emigration are sometimes important and will inevitably have some influence on the manner in which emigration affects development in the last analysis. The conclusions reached so far must therefore be reexamined in this new light. They are valid only to the extent that the effects of emigration on employment and income within the country are not partially or completely offset—or even more than offset—by its favourable or adverse effects on the balance of payments. Of course, these two series of effects need not be opposite : they can be cumulative as well. Even so, these conclusions require yet further qualification, for full employment and overpopulation—the two situations considered so far— may be of a purely temporary nature. If a fairly long recession takes ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 365 place in a country, full employment may for a time be replaced by underemployment. A much more serious and long-term danger to full employment may exist where population growth gives rise to a need for investment which exceeds the actual investment potential. Here the surplus of labour may be not an immediate problem but a latent threat which emigration can help to avert. Similarly, underemployment is not necessarily a permanent situation; it may be absorbed by the natural play of economic forces, with the result that the need to combat it by emigration becomes less pressing. In any case, there are many recognised forms of overpopulation, ranging from unemployment due to underdevelopment to labour surpluses resulting from structural unbalance between the labour supply and demand ; and emigration is not necessarily the best remedy in all cases. The situations that can arise and the ways in which they can develop are in fact so many and varied that it would be dangerous to try to formulate hard and fast conclusions covering all conceivable cases. Mention should be made at this point of one of the arguments frequently put forward against emigration, namely that, as emigrants are for the most part young adults, it tends to destroy the balance between economically active and inactive age groups and to increase the average age of the population. This argument requires qualification, since the economic effects of emigration are actually harmful only if it gives rise directly to a fall in employment; if, however, the migrants are unemployed (though of employable age) the immediate effects will be nil. But if a long-term view is taken it becomes clear that even in the second case the immediate benefit which the economy in general and its workers in particular derive from the departure of the unemployed may well be lost later if economic conditions improve, for then development will be hampered by labour shortages, while the burden of supporting the inactive part of the population will have become heavier. Lastly, it should be pointed out that the effects of emigration—for better or worse—on development cannot usually be distinguished as such. As a rule, it slows down certain demographic trends, but this influence is rarely strong enough to affect them substantially, let alone reverse them. Thus it may help to siphon off surplus labour without necessarily diminishing the labour surplus; the latter may, in fact, continue to increase. Similarly, emigration may draw off useful labour without apparently affecting development in any way. Emigration affects such a small proportion of the population that in most cases it can be considered as a secondary phenomenon; this adds to the difficulty of finding factual evidence to confirm theory. 366 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 The problem of measuring the effects of emigration on the distribution of income involves a similar difficulty. From a purely theoretical point of view, it can be expressed in relatively simple terms, although the argument that emigration will always be beneficial to the workers who remain behind because it reduces the labour supply and thereby tends to force labour costs upwards is obviously an oversimplification, applicable only to cases where emigration makes for an increase in productivity—which, as has already been seen, does not automatically follow. Actually, emigration will only benefit the workers left behind if it takes place under conditions which will stimulate development. If this is the case it will, other things being equal, be a positive factor of economic and social progress. The question then arises as to how this benefit, expressed in both relative and absolute terms, will be distributed among the different groups of workers. This, however, is a problem which goes far outside the field of emigration and its consequences ; it is, rather, a facet of the much wider problem of general trends in development. EFFECTS ON OVERPOPULATED COUNTRIES Even in the absence of detailed statistical evidence, there can be little doubt that emigration from the overpopulated countries since the Second World War has on the whole facilitated the development of those countries by easing population pressure, which was retarding the rise in productivity. Thus the problem is usually one of assessing the benefit obtained rather than of establishing that the country has in fact benefited from emigration. There are, however, a few cases in which emigration seems to have assumed unduly large proportions or to have followed patterns which were in some ways to have undesirable consequences. There can be no doubt that southern Europe has benefited from emigration, although the extent to which the latter has helped to relieve population pressure—which can be roughly measured by comparing net emigration with the natural population growth—has varied considerably from country to country. In the absence of more direct evidence, the active interest which the governments of the countries concerned usually take in emigration should be sufficient proof that these countries have in fact benefited from it. The most detailed information available relates to Italy, where approximately one-third of the natural population increase since 1946 has been offset by emigration. As in all the other countries of southern Europe, the employment market in Italy, during the whole of the period ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 367 under consideration, was subjected to pressure from two—not always readily distinguishable—sources: the labour surplus in agriculture and that due to natural population growth. The latter alone added 300,000 persons to the number requiring employment every year; and although productivity in the economy was increasing rapidly, the provision of so many new jobs was beyond the country's powers. Thus, except in the years immediately following the war, the level of employment until quite recently rose far more slowly than would have been necessary to keep pace with demographic growth. The result was saturation of the employment market, the principal sufferers being the younger generations. Unemployment continued to rise steadily until 1953, when it was slightly short of the 2 million mark—that is to say, approximately 10 per cent, of the entire labour force—and remained at about that level for some years; not until 1957 did it begin to fall. Even so, this figure does not, as was seen earlier 1 , take account of underemployment. Clearly, then, emigration—both permanent and seasonal—to the extent that it did not deprive the economy of workers difficult to replace (and in fact very few were difficult to replace) can be considered for practical purposes as having reduced the level of unemployment. Admittedly, in some regions workers in certain categories have emigrated in such numbers as to give rise to actual labour shortages 2, but where such shortages occurred they were on too small and too local a scale to alter the benefit which the Italian economy as a whole and the workers in particular received. Moreover, by contributing, as it probably has done, to reducing the birth rate, emigration has slightly reduced the over-all cost of maintaining the inactive population. In addition, Italy's national income and ability to pay for her imports have been directly increased by the funds remitted by emigrants either for themselves or for members of their families remaining in Italy.3 Table 134 shows the annual amounts involved and the proportion of the country's imports which they represent, as communicated by the Italian Exchange Control Office. It will be seen that savings remitted through official channels between 1946 and 1957 totalled nearly 1,200 million dollars. On the average, the remittances covered nearly 5 per cent, of Italy's imports and one-seventh of her foreign trade deficit. Some of this money—but probably not 1 See above, Chapter VIII. See G. PARENTI: " I t a l y " , in Economics of International Migration (London, MacMillan & Co. Ltd., 1958), pp. 85-95. 3 Remittances of savings properly so called (rimesse) by permanent migrants and earnings from employment (redditi da lavoro) transferred by temporary migrants. 2 368 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 TABLE 134. ITALY: SAVINGS REMITTED BY ITALIAN EMIGRANTS, 1946-57 (In millions of dollars) Currency i Year Dollars 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . Total remitted . . . . . . . . . . . . Sterling j . . . . . . . . . . . . 36.1 21.3 29.0 18.6 21.5 16.3 28.2 43.3 49.0 57.3 58.3 61.2 9.0 7.1 5.4 7.0 6.8 12.1 21.3 24.9 24.8 29.1 36.0 38.9 Total. . . 439.9 222.4 Clearing credits 0.1 0.2 1.2 0.2 1.1 45.1 29.1 35.1 25.7 30.4 33.2 49.5 68.3 74.0 86.4 94.5 101.2 0.2 3.2 35.3 65.1 41.8 36.3 52.5 50.6 40.0 38.3 60.0 86.1 45.3 32.2 70.4 90.8 72.2 69.5 102.0 118.8 114.1 124.7 154.5 187.3 5.2 2.6 4.6 4.9 5.0 3.2 4.4 4.9 4.7 4.6 4.9 5.2 11.3 672.5 509.4 1,181.9 — 0.7 0.6 0.2 2.2 4.8 Absolute figures As percentage of imports Total Other Source: Notiziario delV emigrazione (Rome, Ministero degli Affari Esteri), Ninth Year, N o . 5, May 1955, and information communicated to the I.L.O. very much, especially in recent years—was certainly remitted by persons who emigrated before the war. On the other hand, the amounts which passed through Italian exchange control channels probably came to little more than half the total amounts actually remitted to Italy (at least in recent years).1 In addition, it should be borne in mind that the Exchange Control Office does not count social security payments or payments made abroad by Italian emigrants to Italian transport companies for travelling expenses as savings transferred. This suffices to show the importance of emigration as a source of invisible earnings, and particularly of hard currency 2—a source of income, in fact, ranking before shipping and even the tourist trade. However, these are not the only beneficial effects which emigration has had on Italy's balance of payments. Foreign trade statistics show that since 1949 Italy's exports to Canada, Australia and Venezuela, all countries with hard or fairly hard currencies, have increased sharply. There can be no doubt that there is a connection between this increase 1 Some of the remittances were effected by arrangements between private individuals and others by illegal transfer operations; in addition, some returning emigrants brought money back to Italy with them. Money sent from Venezuela and Switzerland seems to have made up a particularly large proportion of these " free market " remittances. Mainly through the free market. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 369 and the development of emigration to those countries. By the same token Italy's ability to pay for her imports has been increased appreciably.1 However, the effects of emigration on the Italian economy have not all been favourable. There are also negative items in the balance-sheet. First of all, the direct costs of emigration and its consequences must be considered. These are made up of both government and private expenditure, the former including the operating costs of the emigration services, the State's contributions towards travelling expenses, selection and vocational training for prospective emigrants and, above all, assistance to emigrants before and after emigration, while the latter consists of the proportion of travelling expenses paid by the emigrants themselves, the capital taken by them on their departure from Italy, and such private assistance as they may have received. This is not the place to examine these items in detail and to try to work out a comprehensive financial balance sheet for emigration : in any case, much more information would be needed. However, it may be said in passing, first that a large part of the cost of emigration operations was borne in one form or another by other countries and, secondly, that the overwhelming majority of the emigrants were of very modest means and consequently unable to take any substantial sums out of Italy with them. It thus appears that, while from the financial standpoint emigration has been extremely profitable to the Italian economy, it has not been so profitable as the figures of savings remitted suggest. It has also been pointed out that the groups of the economically active population in which the surpluses are largest have not contributed to the migratory movement in proportion to their share in the total surplus ; it can be argued that this is an effect of the combined influence of selection by the public authorities and individual choice. A particularly striking case is that of agricultural workers and unskilled labourers. In 1952, 45 per cent, of all unemployed persons belonged to these two groups, and by 1956 the percentage had risen to over 50; but it is unlikely that anywhere near the same proportion of the migrants during these years came from those groups. Thus emigration has probably checked the spread of unemployment less in those sectors of the labour force where levels of skill are lowest and the labour surplus highest than in the others. In addition, there can be no doubt that a similar tendency existed as regards physical qualifications. One of the obstacles in the fight against unemployment is the low general level of vocational skill of a considerable proportion of the surplus labour force; and a study of the development of the Italian economy with particular reference 1 See Emilio BETTINI: " Alcuni aspetti economici dell' emigrazione italiana", in Homo Faber (Rome), No. 56, Aug. 1956, pp. 3555-3560. 370 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 to the gradual reduction of unemployment—a field in which encouraging progress seems to have been made during the last few years—reveals that, where the better elements have been or are being siphoned off by emigration, the latter is actually making a reduction in unemployment more difficult, especially where it results in shortages of skilled labour, even in very small sectors. It can be added—looking into the future rather than at the present—that emigration has hastened the aging of the population, the undesirable economic effects of which have already begun to appear and will make themselves felt much more severely in years to come. There can be no doubt that the conclusions reached in the case of Italy are valid for the other emigration countries of southern Europe, which during the period under consideration have had to cope with similar and even more serious—though sometimes less apparent— problems of underemployment.1 It is, however, worthwhile examining the case of each country separately, although the information available s scanty. In Spain emigration was on a much smaller scale than in Italy and was more localised; thus its contribution to easing the employment situation was much smaller, and only in a few provinces did it have a noticeable effect. There is not enough information available on the subject of funds remitted by emigrants to indicate whether they increased to any great extent as a result of emigration during the last few years. The only information available, which concerns a few recent years, reveals that the sums involved were quite considerable and suggests that at least during the years in question such remittances formed a substantial item on the credit side of Spain's balance of payments.2 In Greece emigration did not develop on any substantial scale until after 1950 and even so did not assume substantial proportions until 1954. Transfers of savings increased rapidly with the development of emigration, rising from 14.3 million dollars in 1950 to 75 million in 1957 (table 135). In 1950-51 they represented a very small fraction of the value of imports, but during the years 1954-57 they accounted for more than 15 per cent. ; in other words, the recent increase in the amount transferred in this way has very substantially—in fact, proportionately 1 Greece and Portugal do not publish any unemployment statistics, while those published by Spain cover only part of actual unemployment. 2 See C. MARTÍ BUFILL : Nuevas soluciones al problema migratorio (Madrid, Ediciones Cultura hispánica, 1955), p. 321. In 1952 legal transfers of funds amounted to 75 million dollars, or more than 13 per cent, of Spain's imports (571.7 million dollars). In 1953 and 1954 the corresponding figures were 90 million and 150 million dollars respectively; transfers of funds by emigrants are estimated to have made up about three-quarters of these amounts. 371 ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS TABLE 135. G R E E C E : S A V I N G S 1 REMITTED BY G R E E K EMIGRANTS, 1948-57 Amounts In millions of dollars . . As a percentage of imports . . 1948 11.1 3.3 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 Total 8.6 14.3 17.0 18.0 45.6 47.0 50.7 60.9 75.0 348.2 2.7 3.7 4.2 7.2 20.1 15.5 14.6 14.1 16.3 10.3 Source: Balance of Payments Yearbook and International Financial Statistics (Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund). 1 The figures actually represent total private donations, the greater part of which consisted of remittances. far more than in Italy—increased the country's importing capacity. The effects of emigration on the employment situation seem to have been very small up to 1954, for prior to that year total emigration lagged far behind the increase in the domestic labour force. Since 1954, however, it has been catching up rapidly, rising to over 70 per cent. of the natural labour force increase in 1956. If the inactive elements are left out of account it appears that some 40 per cent, of the increase in the working population was siphoned off by emigration in 1955 and approximately 50 per cent, in 1956. This is admittedly a high proportion, but it was not enough even to check the increase in unemployment, let alone to reduce the number of unemployed persons. In other words, in spite of its recent development emigration from Greece since the war still falls considerably short of what is needed to offset the particularly rapid population growth. In Portugal the rate of emigration among the active population was about three times as high as in Spain and was comparable to that of Italy. Emigration thus proved a fairly effective check to the spread of underemployment, at least in those parts of the country where the rate was above the average. The amount of savings remitted by Portuguese emigrants seems to have increased considerably during recent years; there is probably some relationship between this fact and the development of emigration; at least, an examination of the item " private donations " in Portugal's balance of payments, which rose from 10.4 million dollars in 1952 to 48.3 million dollars in 1957 \ suggests that such a relationship exists. However, on the average this item only covered about 6 per cent, of imports during that period. On the other hand, the item " private donations " probably does not include 1 Figures taken from International Financial Statistics (Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund) and converted from escudos into dollars. 372 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 all the remittances effected by emigrants.1 It should also be remembered that a considerable proportion of all emigrants from Portugal went to Portugal's overseas provinces, and the repercussions of these movements on the Portuguese economy can only be examined within the general framework of the efforts of the metropolitan territory to develop its overseas possessions—a subject which is outside the scope of this study. Malta is a special case. The rate of emigration is very high and has more than offset the natural labour force increase. As a result, unemployment was kept down to a very low level until 1954. On the other hand, Malta is not self-governing and therefore has few other means of coping with the extremely severe strain which the high rate of population growth has placed on its economy. Unfortunately, a policy of relying principally, if not exclusively, on emigration as a means of combating overpopulation is not without drawbacks and, in the case of Malta, has proved insufficient in the long run to improve economic conditions on the island. Consequently, there has been during the last few years a tendency to turn away from the old policy, under which surplus workers had no choice but to emigrate, and to try to strike a more satisfactory balance between emigration and local development ; but in spite of the attention now being paid to development emigration will still remain a necessary safety valve.2 The only other European country chronically beset with overpopulation (in the sense of an oversupply of labour) is Ireland, where the situation has also been dealt with by large-scale emigration. As in Malta the rate of emigration has considerably outstripped the natural growth of the labour force, with the result that the latter has fallen substantially; this decline was particularly severe in agriculture, without there being an equivalent expansion in the non-agricultural 1 The Bank of Portugal has communicated to the I.L.O. figures slightly higher (except for 1957) than those appearing under " private donations" in the balanceof-payments data published by Internationa! Financial Statistics. The figures are as follows (millions of dollars): Amounts transferred by emigrants Private donations Year From North From South From E.P.U. From other America America countries countries 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5 7.1 8.4 6.0 4.3 5.9 10.8 11.6 11.2 9.0 6.2 6.5 7.7 9.9 4.0 1.4 2.4 4.4 3.7 0.7 Total 20.1 20.3 26.4 36.0 25.0 10.4 17.0 15.8 20.2 30.6 48.7 2 See Colonial Office: Malta, Interim Report of the Economic Commission (London, H.M. Stationery Office, 1957). ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 373 labour force to offset it.1 There is nothing unusual about the first of these two phenomena; it should even be considered as a factor of progress since agricultural production, instead of falling, has risen considerably since 1946. In this case, emigration seems to have made for an improvement in agricultural productivity and acted as a catalyst in bringing about a necessary change. On the other hand, the slow rate of expansion of the non-agricultural labour force suggests a certain lack of resiliency in the Irish economy for which emigration may well be partly responsible, first because it reduces the propensity to invest, and secondly because, in spite of the fact that a large number of emigrant workers are comparatively unskilled, many are needed at home if the country is to make full use of its resources.2 Admittedly, the gross product per inhabitant increased considerably during the period under consideration, but this increase was relatively slow, particularly when the decline in population is borne in mind. Moreover, it is symptomatic that although more than 300,000 workers have emigrated since 1946 there has not been any falling trend in unemployment, the rate having in fact remained one of the highest in Europe. 3 The balance-of-payments figures 4 do not give a clear picture of the extent to which the Irish economy has benefited from remittances of savings by emigrants, as there are no figures for remittances from Great Britain, which make up a considerable proportion of the total. Examination of the item " private donations " in the balance-of-payments data reveals that during the period under consideration there has been no definite upward trend. The money entering the country in this way—nearly all of it sent by emigrants, as far as can be ascertained—was equivalent to about 5 per cent, of the value of imports between 1950 and 1957. In the other overpopulated emigration countries of Europe, the link between problems due to overpopulation and the patterns 1 See Central Statistics Office: Ireland, The Trend of Employment and Unemployment in 1956 (Dublin, undated); and J. F . MEENAN: " Eire ", in Economics of International Migration, op. cit. pp. 77-84. 2 See Commission on Emigration and Population Problems, 1948-1954: Reports (Dublin, The Stationery Office, undated), pp. 136 ff. 3 There were 62,700 unemployed persons in 1946, 61,400 in 1956 and 69,700 in 1957. 4 The amounts coming under the heading of " private donations " on the credit side of Ireland's balance of payments between 1946 and 1957 were as follows (millions of Irish pounds) : 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 9.4 9.4 8.4 9.7 10.3 10.1 Source: United Nations: Statistical Yearbook. 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 9.9 10.8 10.8 11.0 11.3 12.1 374 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 of emigration is much less obvious: this has already been pointed out in the section dealing with the factors of emigration. It applies, for instance, to the emigration of non-German refugees from Germany and Austria under the auspices of international relief organisations, the effect of which on the economies of the two countries was practically nil. It applies with even greater force to emigration of German nationals from Germany, of Austrian nationals and Volksdeutsche refugees from Austria and, though in a rather different way, to emigration from the Netherlands. In Western Germany, as has already been seen, emigration of nationals from the country developed at a comparatively late stage, when the problem of overpopulation resulting from the refugee influx had passed its critical stage. Moreover, many of the persons who emigrated—whether overseas, to Sweden or to Switzerland—were highly skilled workers, only a few of whom were without employment in Germany. Under the circumstances, therefore, it may be wondered whether emigration has made any contribution at all to the return of full employment in Western Germany. In any case, in the present situation of the employment market further emigration appears to have become not only economically useless but actually undesirable. In Austria, too, it is doubtful whether the large-scale emigration of nationals and Volksdeutsche which has been going on since 1952 helped to reverse the rising trend in unemployment, which levelled off in 1953. Admittedly, the information available is not sufficient to establish a connection between the two; but emigration can in any case have played no more than a secondary role in comparison with the factors which have enabled the Austrian, as well as the German economy, to expand rapidly in recent years. As in Germany, the problem can therefore not really be set against a background of underemployment. The case of the Netherlands is more complex. As has already been seen, the net result of migratory movements during the period under consideration was a comparatively slight decrease in the labour force. In fact, but for the considerable increase in emigration to Europeanpopulated Commonwealth countries during the second half of the period, the number of immigrants would have been considerably in excess of the number of emigrants. Even so, it can hardly be asserted that the employment situation would have been less favourable during the last few years if there had been no emigration or if it had been on a smaller scale; for even in 1951-52 unemployment was not serious, and since then the economy has been moving rapidly towards overemployment. Nor, however, in the absence of any statistical correlation between the occupations of the emigrants and the labour surpluses ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 375 in certain occupations—which, once again, were very small—can the opposite assumption be made. What can be said is that, even in the boom conditions of recent years, it is doubtful whether the equilibrium of the employment market could still have been maintained if the excess population had not been siphoned off on such a large scale by emigration, and it could in any case have been maintained only at the price of a considerable investment effort, which in its turn would have slowed down the rise in the standard of living. Thus, on balance, emigration in recent years seems to have preserved the Netherlands economy from excessive strain. Emigration does not seem to have had as favourable an effect on the balance of payments in the Netherlands as it had in many other countries.1 However, even if the net profit which the country has received has been small, the policy of promoting emigration is still justified in terms of longer-range economic benefits. Outside Europe overpopulation due to underdevelopment and the continuous and rapid growth of the economically active population is rife in large areas. Emigration there has rarely reached sufficient proportions to make a substantial contribution to the solution of the problem. This is true of all the countries of Asia, including India and Japan, from which emigration has been very small. It is also true of most of the countries in Central and South America which have large surpluses of farm labour. There are, however, three exceptions : Mexico, the British West Indies and probably Paraguay; possibly, there may be others. From Mexico emigration to the United States has been considerable in recent years. Until it was brought under effective control seasonal emigration was chaotic and sometimes disorganised agricultural production in the northern part of the country; this, however, is apparently no longer the case.2 Emigration of this type has provided an outlet for a considerable proportion of the surplus population in rural areas, and the invisible earnings which it has brought in have been a substantial item on the credit side of Mexico's balance of payments. 3 In the British West Indies the relief obtained as a result of seasonal emigration to the United States, and above all from permanent emigration to the United Kingdom, seems to have been even more marked, at 1 It appears that capital transfers effected by the emigrants and appearing on the credit side of the balance of payments (remittances of funds, reimbursement of travelling expenses and payment of interest) have been largely offset by substantial capital exports. 2 Economic Review of Mexico (London, The Economist Intelligence Unit), No. 3, Aug. 1952. 3 Even so, during the last few years at any rate, they have fallen far short of the earnings derived from the tourist trade. 376 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 least during recent years, when emigration to the United Kingdom developed on a considerable scale. Lastly, Paraguay, whence large numbers of persons emigrated to Argentina (and probably to Uruguay), has also probably reaped considerable benefit from emigration; the persons involved have been mainly agricultural workers. In Africa—at least, in Africa south of the Sahara—movements of indigenous labour take place on a very large scale. The information available is insufficient to allow an estimate to be made of its effects on economic development in the territories from which the migrants come. Has emigration from these territories helped to improve the productivity of the tribal economy ? Or has it had a depressing effect on productivity by depriving that economy of badly needed workers ? Has it hampered the development of the non-indigenous economy by creating labour shortages ? Lastly, have the savings of the migrant workers (even though their wages are usually very low) made up an appreciable proportion of the incomes of the territories from which they emigrate ? All that can be said in answer to these questions is that the regulations in force in these territories are intended to prevent their economic development from being adversely affected by emigration, and there is good reason to believe that in most cases this, at least, has been achieved. EFFECTS ON COUNTRIES WITH FULL EMPLOYMENT Migratory movements from countries with full employment have usually been on a very small scale. There is, however, one outstanding exception : the United Kingdom, a highly developed country with a high level of employment and without serious problems of overpopulation from which, nevertheless, large numbers of persons have emigrated every year. It is true that this movement has been nearly offset by immigration and that the proportion of economically active persons among the immigrants has been even higher than among the emigrants. It may indeed be asked whether the United Kingdom can be classified as an emigration country at all, particularly since emigration only exceeded immigration between 1949 and 1955. The somewhat confused picture as regards the economic consequences of this two-way movement can be made clearer by reference to two factors which have already been mentioned in the previous chapter. First of all, migration during the period under consideration helped to increase the proportion of economically active elements in the population; this was due partly to the slight surplus of economically active persons among immigrants but mainly to the heavy surplus of inactive ones among emigrants. On the other hand, the average level of occupa- ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 377 tional skill was considerably lower among the former than among the latter. The first of these two factors has certainly been beneficial to the country's economy. The second, however—at first sight at least— must be considered as adverse to economic development, as there had always been full employment in the sectors to which the emigrants belonged and in some of them emigration may well have given rise to critical shortages. But it may be wondered whether, in dealing with the economic effects of emigration from the United Kingdom, immigration need be considered at all, as if there were a direct connection between the two. Having regard to the nature of the immigration movement, there is in fact no ground for assuming (except, obviously, as regards emigrants returning to the country) that it would have been less if there had been no emigration. It is even difficult to establish that there was an indirect connection between the two movements; for emigration does not seem to have helped in any way to create vacuums likely to attract immigrants. Moreover, it is doubtful whether emigration has helped to improve the balance-of-payments situation. Admittedly, it has helped to reduce the need for imports and, by reducing domestic consumption, to increase exportable surpluses; on the other hand, productive capacity has been reduced, and the capital exported by the emigrants has formed a debit item in the balance of payments. It is thus difficult to see what direct benefit the economy of the United Kingdom has derived from emigration in recent years. It would probably be true to say that its adverse effects on development have been more or less offset by the favourable effects of immigration, and that the demographic and economic losses resulting from emigration are the price which the United Kingdom has to pay in order to go on making a contribution to the population of certain Commonwealth countries. Emigration directed towards the other Commonwealth countries with a view to providing them with an élite of trained men is so closely linked with the United Kingdom's policy of investment in those countries to promote their development that it can only be analysed within the over-all context of that policy and its achievements. Emigration from other countries with full employment in northwestern Europe (the Scandinavian countries, Belgium, France and Switzerland) and from Canada and the United States suggests similar remarks. Most of these countries have been receiving immigrants far in excess of the number of emigrants; the inward movement, though different in composition from the outward movement, has more than offset the adverse effects which the latter might have had on the development of those countries. In many cases, too, these movements 378 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 have represented part of a deliberate effort to carry economic expansion beyond national frontiers, a general discussion of which would be out of place here. Effects on Immigration Countries GENERAL The starting point for analysing the consequences of immigration is the same as for those of emigration, namely the dual question of its influence on real average income and on the distribution of income. To say that immigration tends to increase average income if the immigrant enters a job in which he earns more than the average, and vice versa, is hardly a satisfactory answer, since it would imply a blanket indictment of immigration not only by inactive persons but also by workers earning less than the average. Actually, to assert that the only direct effect of immigration is to add to total income is just as much of an oversimplification as to say that the only direct effect of emigration is to reduce it. The addition of an immigrant to the labour force can, under certain conditions, have an effect on development which will multiply in the same manner as an investment. If these conditions are fulfilled—i.e. if the extra worker is really needed and if the economy is able to undertake the investment which immigration calls for—income in the branch of the economy which the immigrant has joined will increase, and in addition income in the sectors from which he purchases his consumer goods and those into which his savings are channelled in one form or another will also rise. These secondary effects may go on spreading through the economy almost indefinitely. On the other hand, if these conditions are not fulfilled immigration may set up an inflationary pressure and cause a fall in productivity which in its turn may have a depressing effect on average income. The vital question is therefore whether, assuming that in the short term immigration tends to reduce over-all productivity, it will in the long run tend to increase it. This is a most important question, for restrictive immigration policies are intended not only to safeguard full employment but also to ensure that immigration does not slow down the rise in average income. The difficulty of answering the question put in these terms is that much depends on the intended length of the initial stage. However that may be, immigration can make an immediate contribution to development provided that three conditions are fulfilled: first, the immigrant must take up a useful occupation (that is to say, one for which there is a market demand); secondly, the job must be one that cannot be done efficiently ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 379 by anyone else ; and thirdly, his total remuneration in the form of wages and social benefits must not be greater than the value of the goods or services he produces. Clearly, if these three conditions are fulfilled the inflationary pressure the immigrant may give rise to in the sectors from which he purchases his consumer goods (if those sectors are not in a position fully to meet the additional demand which he creates) will be more than offset by the reduction in the inflationary pressure on the sector of production to which he belongs, for his income, which is already less than the market value of what he produces, is further reduced by taxes and similar charges; moreover, the immigrant does not necessarily spend all that remains of his income after these deductions. It should be pointed out that the situation will differ considerably according as the immigrant has a family or not. Workers with families often receive higher wages for the same work than those without families ; they always keep a greater proportion of their income as take-home pay; and they usually spend a larger proportion of their take-home pay on consumer goods. Thus the immigration of whole families inevitably gives rise to a greater inflationary pressure than that of workers without dependants. So far, however, no account has been taken of the possible effects —both direct and indirect—of immigration on the balance of payments ; these may be quite considerable. Immigrants often bring with them some capital, however little, and this will appear on the credit side of the balance sheet. On the other hand, immigration often entails assistance to the immigrant, part of which has to be paid for abroad. A more important debit item, however, lies in the savings which migrants often send back to their countries of origin; in addition, the government may also have to pay social security benefits and even family allowances to persons in those countries. The amount expended in this way will obviously be greater if a large proportion of the immigrants have dependants from whom they are separated; thus it is in the interest of the immigration countries that such separations—except where they are inevitable by-products of temporary migration—should be kept as short as possible. Lastly, immigration will have a favourable effect on the balance of payments if the resulting increase in production increases the country's ability to export or reduces the need to import; on the other hand, the need to increase investment and at the same time to cope with an immediate rise in the demand for consumer goods may have the opposite effect. However, even if immigration satisfies these different conditions —that is to say, if it can be absorbed without unfavourable effects on the employment situation, without inflationary pressure ensuing and 380 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 without upsetting the balance of payments—it does not necessarily follow that the average income will tend to increase as a result. This can only happen if immigration has, directly or indirectly, a stimulating effect on productivity. The next step is therefore to ascertain under what conditions immigration can have that effect. The problem does not arise in countries with enormous natural resources and highly developed industries, whose economies, as a result of these two factors, are governed by the law of increasing returns. In such countries productivity inevitably tends to improve as the population increases, particularly if the latter is still well under its optimum size. This does not necessarily mean, however, that immigration is undesirable in countries where conditions are not so favourable, even if full employment has not yet been achieved ; for a situation can be brought about in which the law of diminishing returns ceases to operate, and immigration may actually be a prerequisite for bringing such a situation into being. This is true, for instance, of the underdeveloped countries in which immigration of skilled workers will tend not only to increase productivity but also to create new jobs. In addition, in an economically advanced country there may be bottlenecks in the productive system which make it impossible to achieve full employment in certain sectors ; these bottlenecks may be the consequence of labour shortages which can only be made up by immigration. In all these situations immigration obviously has a direct and positive influence on the general level of productivity. If, however, none of these three situations exist, can it still be argued that immigration, by stimulating investment, is likely to raise the general level of productivity in the long run, even though it may have opposite effects in the short run? If the population is increasing rapidly the answer will obviously be in the negative. If, on the other hand, the population is declining or not increasing rapidly enough, immigration may provide the necessary stimulus for certain forms of progress which could not otherwise have been achieved—provided, of course, that the other prerequisites for such progress exist. Such a situation rarely occurs in practice, for the makers of immigration policy are extremely careful to ensure that the admission of foreign workers does not lead to even a momentary decline in productivity. The case deserves mention, however, as an illustration of how the long-term advantages of immigration can point to the same conclusions as a chain of reasoning based solely on its short-term benefits. Immigration is often opposed on the ground that it makes labour more abundant and thereby tends to slow down the rise in real wages. This objection has some validity where immigration affects sectors in which higher productivity can be achieved but in which an abundant ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 381 labour supply acts as a brake on such progress. However, it reflects a narrow outlook and does not take all the facts into account. For one thing, shortages of labour do not necessarily result in increased productivity : the investment needed must also be technically feasible and the necessary financial resources available. Otherwise, the increasing cost of labour may simply have a depressing effect on production and eventually cause unemployment. Experience shows that advances in productivity depend more on the vitality of the economy in general (two facets of which are propensity as well as capacity to invest) than on the existence of labour shortages in particular sectors of employment. Immigration —which, as has been seen, has a stimulating effect on production, savings and consumption and thus has the same snowball effect as an investment—may be an important factor in developing or maintaining that vitality. Thus, even if in the short run it tends to reduce wage levels it will not necessarily do so for long. It may therefore be concluded that immigration kept within reasonable limits need not prevent productivity from improving or wages from rising as productivity improves. Developments in countries where it has been an important economic factor fully confirm this thesis. WESTERN EUROPE In western Europe immigration has been mainly of the " replacement " type; that is to say, the great majority of immigrant workers have entered the lower ranks of the occupational hierarchy replacing workers who have moved on towards less arduous or better-paid jobs. This tendency, in itself a natural one, has been accentuated by existing regulations.1 Moreover, conditions governing the entry of migrants into these countries have been such that productivity has not been adversely affected, even in the few cases where immigration has been unrestricted. Thus there can be no doubt that western European economies have benefited directly from the influx of foreign workers. In a few cases immigration has actually become an economic necessity. One example is Switzerland, where immigrants make up a greater proportion of the economically active population than anywhere else in the world. In some other countries the majority of the persons admitted have been workers intending to enter certain key sectors (such as agriculture, mining, metallurgy and public works) in which, especially during the years immediately following the Second World War, it was essential to increase production rapidly in order to clear 1 See above, Chapter VII. 382 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 bottlenecks in the economy, combat inflationary pressures and improve the balance-of-payments situation. The benefits derived from immigration have been all the more remarkable as most of the occupational branches which the immigrants entered achieved striking advances in productivity, while wages—at least as far as one can tell from current statistics on wage trends—rose at a rate which, generally speaking, seems to have been commensurate with the general trend. Even where this has not been the case, e.g. in the building industry, where wages have nearly everywhere lagged behind the general index, their slowness to rise cannot really be ascribed to an excessive influx of foreign workers. The low wages paid in this industry were in fact a cause far more than an effect of immigration, which they helped to develop—at least in Switzerland and France—by creating a chronic labour shortage ori the domestic market. In any case, in none of the countries under consideration did immigration ever achieve such proportions as to have a depressing effect on wages. The question only arose in the case of Switzerland, where the proportion of national income represented by profits has been increasing slightly at the expense of that represented by wages, whereas in most countries the tendency has been for the ratio between the two to remain stable.1 However, it has yet to be proved that immigration has been in any way responsible for this trend. The price paid for these benefits seems small indeed by comparison. The direct cost—i.e. that of organising and assisting movements—has certainly been very small. Similarly, the inflationary pressure to which the immigrants have given rise in consumer goods industries has not been serious, for most of them save as much as they can; this is particularly true of housing, with respect to which the requirements of the overwhelming majority of immigrants are comparatively simple. The only debit item has been the transfer of savings—often representing a considerable proportion of the immigrants' earnings—to other countries. It is, however, extremely difficult to ascertain the effect of such transfers on the balance of payments in most countries.2 Switzerland is certainly 1 United Nations: Economic Survey of Europe, 1956 (New York, 1957), Chapter VIII. 2 In Belgium remittances of this kind have been more than offset by similar transfers from Belgian emigrants working in foreign countries, particularly in North America and in France. In the case of France the item " private donations " in the balance of payments does not disclose any definite trend, at least since 1950 (the first year in which it was published separately), and on the basis of the rather small amounts shown, it is impossible to reach any conclusion concerning the size of such transfers. In the case of Sweden, the item " private donations " has consistently shown a deficit which, moreover, has been increasing in recent years, probably owing to an increase in the amounts transferred abroad by immigrants. However, this item also contains other elements—including, among others, money transferred into the country. There is no " private donations " item in Switzerland's balance of payments; transfers are effected through unofficial channels. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 383 the country in which it has been most marked owing to the considerable volume of immigration in recent years, the fact that most of it has been temporary in character, and the absence of exchange control in any form. Even though these transfers have to some extent offset the benefits of immigration, they are of small consequence compared with the favourable effects which it has had on productivity—both directly, by clearing production bottlenecks, and indirectly, by stimulating investment in general and, more specifically, by making possible larger profits, part of which could be devoted to increasing productivity. A particularly strong case could be made out for immigration if it could be proved, in addition, that the immigration countries of Europe are well below their optimum population level, having regard to their present degree of economic development. This may not be true of the United Kingdom, Belgium or Switzerland, but it is probably true of Sweden (which since 1954 has removed all restrictions on the employment of nationals of the other Scandinavian countries) and of France. UNITED STATES AND CANADA In the United States and Canada permanent immigration, with a highly varied occupational composition, has continued to predominate. However, its scale has been proportionately much larger, and its influence on development consequently much greater, in Canada than in the United States. In the United States permanent immigration has affected all branches of the economy to some extent, but has never been on a sufficient scale to cause disturbance in any one of them. On the other hand, the advantage which the country has reaped from immigration has probably been fairly small, even though a considerable number of the immigrants were workers with a high level of skill; thus immigration not only increased the population but also added some extremely valuable elements to it. On the other hand, immigration by Mexican seasonal workers has not been so beneficial—not because the immigrants were not needed, but because during the period when the movement was not adequately controlled it rose to a level where it considerably exceeded the demand. Thus it gave rise to cut-throat competition and forced down agricultural wages sharply in all the regions into which the immigrants came, with the result that a considerable proportion of the local labour force moved to other areas. Moreover, the law of supply and demand operated against the immigrants themselves, for they were often forced to work on extremely unfavourable terms. The situation has been improved by the stricter controls over movements of Mexicans which 384 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 have now been in force for some years, but wages have not yet risen to their former levels. The part played by immigration in the economic development of Canada since the end of the war has been of a completely different order. During that period immigration was at a high level, but the absorption of the immigrants never gave rise to any serious difficulty. The beneficial effects which immigration has had on development are proved beyond dispute by the spectacular rise in the over-all productivity of the Canadian economy during the same period. Not enough detailed information is available to give a clear-cut picture of the manner in which immigration has stimulated development. The only information available on the occupations of the immigrants is to be found in the immigration statistics, which only mention the types of job which they intend to take up, and the census, which now dates from several years back (1951). It must often have happened that immigrants accepted jobs other than those they intended to take up, and cases of persons subsequently changing employment must have been even more frequent; thus it is practically impossible to ascertain the nature of the contribution of immigration to the labour force in recent years from the immigration statistics. The 1951 census gives a much clearer picture and, by the same token, an indication of the degree of occupational mobility during the years preceding 1951.1 But the greater part of the immigrants who entered Canada during the period reviewed arrived after 1951, and it is doubtful whether the conclusions that can be drawn from the census figures are fully applicable to the years following it. In spite of these reservations, some information can be obtained from the figures available. The first is that immigration made a much greater contribution to the active than to the inactive population and consequently had a favourable effect on the ratio of the labour force to the total population, which otherwise would have fallen more than it actually did. Immigration has thus reinforced the Canadian economy at one of its weakest points ; for not only is there a continual shortage of labour but in addition the labour force is too small in comparison with the size of the population. It appears, moreover, that immigration has provided larger numbers of workers for the basic sectors of the economy than for the others; in particular, it has provided manual labour essential to agriculture, forestry, mining, metallurgy and building. Lastly, highly skilled workers entered the country in relatively 1 It appears, for instance, that displaced persons, who made up a considerable proportion of the total amount of immigration before 1951, proved particularly unstable in employment. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 385 large numbers, especially during the second half of the period considered, arriving at a particularly opportune moment to fill the places of workers of comparable skills who had emigrated to the United States. There is thus a good deal to suggest that immigration has during recent years been of vital importance to the Canadian economy. In addition, although most of the immigrants settled in the most densely populated areas (and particularly in Ontario) it helped to solve the labour problems arising from the opening up of natural resources in new and hitherto untouched areas. Nor can there be any question that immigration has been an essential factor making for increases not only in production but also in productivity. The country is far from having reached its optimum population level, and the recent spurt of development seems to have postponed still further the day when that level will be reached. In other words, Canada affords a typical example of an economy of rapidly increasing returns, in which there are sufficient material resources and capital available to enable the productivity of labour to increase rapidly; thus the entry of additional workers into the labour force cannot but have made a direct contribution to this trend. It has also made an indirect contribution, first by increasing the size of the home market and thus making some activities economically more viable, and secondly by enabling the burden of certain relatively constant overhead expenses to be spread over a considerably larger labour force. Under such ideal conditions the potentially stimulating effect of all immigration movements on investment was bound to make itself fully felt. It may be added that by helping to make certain activities profitable which had previously not been so because the home market was too small, immigration has made a contribution to one of the most encouraging aspects of recent developments in the Canadian economy, namely its diversification. Indeed, immigration provided not only a market but part of the labour force for the new industries. Thus, even if due allowance is made for such items of financial outlay as selection and assistance expenses paid abroad and transfers of savings out of the country 1 , there can be no doubt that immigration has been a factor making for a rise in average real income. Necessarily imperfect synchronisation between the arrival rate of immigrants and variations in the level of employment does not seem to have increased the level of unemployment to any great extent, although at certain 1 Transfers of savings out of Canada were largely offset by inward movements of capital from the United States. There was no substantial deficit under this head until 1951, and in subsequent years it steadily increased—without, however, representing more than an extremely small proportion of total outgoings in the balance of payments. 386 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 times immigrants were arriving faster than the economy could absorb them. Bottlenecks of this kind occurred in 1951-52 and in 1954; a more serious one occurred in 1957, when large numbers of immigrants arrived in the country at the beginning of a fairly severe recession. But these difficulties never lasted very long; and although during the entire period under consideration unemployment remained relatively high in Canada, immigration does not seem to have had any substantial influence on the structural factors responsible for it. LATIN AMERICA The four countries on the Atlantic seaboard of South America (Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay and Venezuela) were also the recipients of permanent immigration with a highly varied occupational structure. It is, however, very difficult to decide from the information available on employment among immigrants whether the movement has always achieved its purpose, that is to say, whether it has really helped to raise the general level of productivity and thereby to counteract inflationary tendencies. In the case of Argentina there is certainly good reason to doubt whether this aim has been achieved. During the first half at least of the period under consideration migrants came into the country in very large numbers. On balance, the net increase in the labour force due to immigration was relatively small, and relatively few of the immigrants were skilled workers. Moreover, the rate of capital formation does not seem to have been sufficiently high to permit the absorption of immigrants—to whom the country's doors had been thrown open indiscriminately—on such a large scale as to have a stimulating over-all effect on productivity. On the contrary, it is quite probable that immigration increased the strains from which the Argentine economy has been suffering since 1949 and which have aggravated inflation. Admittedly, the immigrants included not only large numbers of workers with low levels of skill but also needed technicians and skilled workers. Moreover, consisting as it did largely of workers previously employed in primary and secondary industry, immigration may have helped to counteract a widespread tendency for Argentine workers to move into service occupations. 1 However, it is by no means certain that the immigrants always took up employment in line with their occupational background. A case in point is that of farm workers from Europe, the majority 1 Between the census of May 1947 and the industrial census of July 1954 the farm labour force increased by 9.1 per cent., that in the various branches of industry decreased by 6.9 per cent, and that in the service industries increased by 14.8 per cent. in the case of commerce and 66 per cent, in the case of other branches. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 387 of whom did not take up agricultural work on arrival. Even if all immigrants had taken up employment in their previous occupations this would not be conclusive proof that all of those entering industry or agriculture were actually needed; even less would it constitute proof that immigration had a stimulating influence on productivity. The large number of persons returning to their countries of origin from 1950 onwards suggests, in fact, that this was not the case. The Government, for its part, realised the drawbacks of allowing large numbers of immigrants to enter the country without first making a proper selection, as was done during the years 1948-51, and immigration policy has since become a good deal more restrictive. Its present aim is to prevent immigration from further increasing the population of congested urban areas and to use it only as a means of obtaining additional agricultural workers, skilled industrial workers of particular types and technical personnel. But there are today far fewer persons seeking to emigrate to Argentina than there were ten years ago, and the problem now is not so much one of restricting entries as of providing incentives for workers in the categories desired. In Brazil, as in Argentina, the flow of immigrants has included persons representing all kinds of occupations and many different degrees of skill, ranging from agricultural workers to technical and supervisory staff. Immigration of technicians has often been related to foreign investment, and it has had a stimulating influence on development, out of all proportion to the small number of persons involved. Immigration of Dutch, German and Italian rural settlers, in which foreign capital also played an important part, seems likewise, in spite of certain initial difficulties, to have given satisfactory results, but only on an experimental scale. As for the main body of the immigrants, it is difficult to judge whether they have made a noticeable contribution to the improvement of productivity. A considerable proportion of them certainly possessed skills for which there was a demand on the Brazilian employment market, and, all things taken into account, immigration did introduce into the labour force certain elements with levels of skill above the average. It may, however, be wondered whether these workers were always used to the best possible advantage and whether immigration would not have brought more substantial benefits with it if a more selective policy, of the kind which has been followed during recent years, had been applied from the beginning. Lastly, in Venezuela immigration increased the labour force much more, proportionately speaking, than it did in Brazil (where the increase was actually very small) or even in Argentina. It took place during a period of particularly rapid economic expansion, which was 388 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 made possible by an abundance of capital unequalled in any other country of Latin America. The availability of capital on such a scale is the reason why the very substantial increase which has taken place in the labour force (particularly since 1950) under the combined influences of natural growth and immigration has been paralleled by equally substantial rises in productivity and average income. Immigration, which brought with it an extremely high proportion of economically active persons, including many technicians and skilled workers essential to industrial development, has made a considerable contribution to this development. It provided many of the technical and supervisory personnel and skilled workers required by the natural resources industries, both old and new, and by the metallurgical, engineering and chemical industries which have come into being in recent years. It also provided a majority of the technicians and skilled workers who implemented the Government's public works and housing programmes and carried out construction projects for the big companies. Lastly, immigration has facilitated the implementation of the land settlement schemes of the Technical Institute for Immigration and Land Settlement, which in 1949 changed its name to the National Agrarian Institute. It should not be concluded from the foregoing that the workers admitted since the war on such a large scale and sometimes rather indiscriminately were all equally necessary. From the Venezuelan workers there have, in fact, been complaints that too many immigrants entered the country, with the result that in some industries labour surpluses occurred, at least in certain areas, particularly the Federal District. Moreover, the difficulty which some immigrants had in finding jobs may explain why in recent years large numbers of them returned to their countries of origin. On the whole, however, absorption of the immigrants does not seem to have given rise to any serious difficulty. It certainly does not appear to have had any depressing effect on wages or to have given rise to inflationary pressures on prices. On the contrary, the disturbances it has caused on the employment market have probably been very small and fully offset by the stimulating effect of immigration in other sectors. Although experience has shown that more care in the occupational selection of the immigrants is needed, there can be no doubt that the largescale movements which have taken place during recent years have been of benefit—probably of considerable benefit—to the Venezuelan economy. AFRICA During the period under consideration there has been considerable immigration from Europe into most of the independent and non- ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 389 metropolitan territories of Africa; as in earlier years, many of the immigrants were supervisors and technicians. Concurrently, there has been an inflow of government and private capital, also from European countries. The conjunction of these two factors made investment possible on a large scale and helped to raise the level of employment among the local populations, often quite substantially. As a result, production expanded and, notwithstanding the very low levels of productivity which have remained general among African workers, average incomes rose—often considerably. Moreover, as has already been seen, development in some territories made it necessary to recruit additional labour from other territories. Generally speaking, the statistics available are totally inadequate as far as an assessment of the precise effect of these various movements is concerned. In any case, the close relationship existing in most cases between immigration and the inflow of foreign capital raises aspects of the problem of the economic effects of migration which are outside the scope of this study. Only in the Union of South Africa has foreign investment played a relatively small part in the recent phase of development. Even in the other major African centre of attraction—the Central African Federation—where domestic capital formation has also risen to a high level, the inflow of foreign capital has considerably stimulated the rate of expansion. In the Union of South Africa the rate of immigration slowed down considerably after a rush in 1947-48; since then it has done little more than offset the drain on the labour force caused by emigration to Northern and Southern Rhodesia. The question therefore arises whether, in view of this two-way movement, net immigration still suffices to meet the need for European personnel arising from the rapid rate of economic expansion. To judge from the acute shortages of technicians and skilled workers which have occurred in recent years, the answer would seem to be negative. The experience of recent years has shown the difficulty of attracting immigrants meeting the more severe selection criteria now applied without resorting to a policy of active recruitment. In the countries of the Central African Federation selection also gave rise to serious problems for similar reasons, but the proportion of active elements among the immigrants was higher, and immigration, which in 12 years more than doubled the European labour force, was considerable. It provided not only new recruits for technical and supervisory posts in the older, established industries, such as agriculture and mining, which were in course of expansion, but also the majority of the technicians and skilled workers who built up the Federation's 390 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 social overhead capital and started up the new manufacturing industries. In addition, it gave impetus to the expansion of the African labour force, which between 1951 and 1956 increased by more than 35 per cent. The increase in the European population and in the size of the African labour force widened the domestic market considerably and facilitated the development of activities of all kinds. On the other hand, the rate of immigration was so high that certain branches, such as construction and utilities, had difficulty in coping with the ever-increasing demand. Nevertheless, it was immigration which enabled these bottlenecks to be cleared. Thus the recent phase of development which has been taking place in the Central African Federation is a striking example of the chain reaction which may be sparked off by any migratory movement in the receiving country. Admittedly, in this case the immigrants were of a particularly high standard and immigration was accompanied by exceptionally large capital movements. It is less easy to assess the consequences of the immigration of African workers into the Union of South Africa or the Central African Federation. Undoubtedly, it has had a favourable influence on the general level of productivity by meeting a need for unskilled labour in certain essential industries. However, this influence has probably been small, for the output of African workers is still extremely low, and it is doubtful whether the use of migrant labour, the basic instability of which is a further obstacle to achieving higher productivity, has directly helped to improve the situation. AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND Australia and New Zealand also receive large numbers of permanent immigrants; in fact, immigration has accounted for the greater part of the substantial increase in the labour force which has taken place in both countries since the war. Immigration has had a beneficial effect on the structure of the population, in which the rising proportion of old people, together with a high birth rate, would have reduced the relative size of the labour force sharply if there had been no immigration. This applies more to New Zealand than to Australia, where the immigrants included a higher proportion of inactive persons. Immigration has not only made a considerable contribution to the labour force in the two countries. It has also, thanks to appropriate selection methods, brought its structure into line with changes in the economic pattern which have taken place since 1946. Immigration and ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 391 the occupational mobility of the labour force have both contributed to this process of readjustment, in different but complementary ways; for immigration has filled the gaps left by labourers, agricultural workers, domestic servants and less skilled industrial workers moving into other types of employment. On the other hand, an increasingly large proportion of the immigrants were skilled workers representing many different trades, e.g. construction, metallurgy, engineering construction and electricity. The immigrants also included a fairly large number of technicians. Thus in both Australia and New Zealand immigration made a considerable contribution to industrial development, and particularly to that of the basic industries. Moreover, as in Canada, it seems to have enabled workers to move away from the main centres into new territory. Finally, immigration in these two countries, both of which are rich in opportunity and in which the economic viability of many activities tends to increase rapidly as the number of consumers increases, has helped considerably to extend the home market. Again as in Canada, therefore, immigration into Australia and New Zealand has had the snowball effects of an investment from which the entire economy has benefited. On the other hand, it is doubtful whether immigration has to any noticeable extent accelerated the rise in real average income, especially in Australia. In that country immigration was a prerequisite of an economic policy based on industrialisation. This, however, does not mean that standards of living could not have been raised more rapidly if some other policy had been followed. In fact, for various reasons (fewer natural resources, a smaller home market and fewer outlets abroad for industrial products) conditions are much less favourable for industrialisation in Australia than in Canada, and the attractiveness to foreign capital correspondingly less. This is also one of the reasons why industrial development and immigration subjected the Australian economy to greater strains than the Canadian economy, particularly as the proportionate population increase resulting from migratory movements was much greater, with a considerably higher proportion of the immigrants made up of inactive elements. These difficulties, however, did not give rise to any employment problems. Apart from a slight and very temporary rise in unemployment in 1951 and 1952 Australia was, during the whole of the period under consideration, a country of overfull employment, and there was no difficulty in absorbing the immigrants into the various branches of the economy. On the other hand, the rapid extension of the employment market which enabled the immigrants to be absorbed so easily was for several years accompanied by fairly severe inflation. Admittedly, this 392 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 had set in before the great rush of immigrants of the years 1949-52. In fact, immigration actually helped to remedy this situation by providing the workers needed to clear certain bottlenecks. On the other hand, it did give rise to considerable inflationary pressure by considerably increasing the demand for consumer and capital goods and for services, while large sums had to be raised to cover the cost of assistance to the immigrants. However, the extent of inflation was limited by the fact that, in spite of the diminishing trend in exportable surpluses, the terms of trade were favourable enough to Australia to allow her to import all she required, at least until 1951. But in 1952 the balance-of-payments situation became so serious as to force the Government to curtail imports and to take anti-inflationary measures, one of which was the restriction of immigration. As a result of these measures—but above all thanks to a substantial increase in production and to an improvement in the terms of trade—the inflationary spiral was checked in 1953 and real incomes, which had remained stationary for some years, resumed their upward trend. The stability of prices achieved in the years 1953-54, was, however, short-lived. The return to boom conditions, together with a new wave of immigration, set prices rising rapidly again, though not so rapidly as before. All in all, the disturbances caused by the policy of development and immigration pursued by Australia since the end of the Second World War have been relatively minor ones. They have shown that to ensure a more balanced development in future years Australia needs, not to restrict immigration, but to increase production in the primary sector of industry, which provides the bulk of her exports and in which expansion has not been sufficiently rapid to enable her to import on a scale commensurate with her increasing requirements. However, though the policy adopted since the end of the war may have meant that average real incomes have risen less than they might have done if some other policy had been followed, the price which Australia has had to pay for the long-term benefit of increasing her population and providing herself with a more solidly based and more diversified economy has not, all things considered, been excessive. Similar conclusions can be reached with regard to New Zealand, where the policy of development and immigration has had similar effects, i.e. sharply rising prices and an increasing balance-of-payments deficit. The situation differs, however, from that in Australia, probably because immigration pohcy has probably been guided less by purely demographic considerations, because the effects of immigration have been less marked and because real average incomes have tended to rise more rapidly. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 393 Effects on the Migrants GENERAL Since the purpose of economic migration is essentially to move workers to countries where their labour will be more productive and hence better paid, it is hardly surprising that most of those involved in recent movements should in fact have found themselves better off as a result. However, there have been exceptions—modest in scale, it is true, but exceptions nonetheless. Even where migration has resulted in a net economic gain for the migrant, other factors must be taken into account in attempting to determine whether it has been on the whole a success or a failure. This is particularly important in the case of permanent migrants intending to make their home in a country where legal or sociological obstacles may impede their adjustment and assimilation as persons and as workers, particularly by placing them on an unequal footing by comparison with local workers. Immigrants are clearly apt to have special difficulty in this respect, either because of ignorance of the language or because of inadequate technical or psychological preparation for their job or working environment. Bad living conditions are another problem: the climate may be unhealthy, or unpleasant, or there may be a housing shortage, with the result that the newcomers have to pay high prices for substandard accommodation. Some of these difficulties can no doubt be quickly overcome, but others cannot and are liable to lead to disappointment and failure. Another important question is how far immigrants of equal ability enjoy equal treatment as regards employment opportunities, and whether immigrant workers are not sometimes discriminated against, either under local laws or regulations or as a result of certain practices which the law tolerates. The question does not appear to arise as far as earnings or working conditions are concerned, but it does arise in other respects. An example of this is stability of employment. Immigrant workers tend—as long as they have alien status—to be more hable to dismissal in case of redundancy and are therefore distinctly more exposed to unemployment. Moreover, the mere fact of being a foreign migrant worker may be an obstacle to a change of employer or place of work, to promotion or to entry into another occupation, in other words to any attempt at individual betterment. This is not the place to pass judgment on the reasonableness or otherwise of obstacles placed by law or the community in the way of complete and rapid assimilation of foreign immigrants either as workers or as individuals. The difficulties encountered vary a good deal from one 394 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 country to another, and they can in any case only hinder assimilation, rather than prevent it. Moreover, the strictness of the regulations, if any, may often be tempered by flexible administrative practices as well as by liberal naturalisation policies. However, the obstacles must be mentioned because, coupled with the reactions of the local population, they may be directly responsible for certain failures. In dealing with this broad problem, one difficulty is to decide what source material to use in trying to reckon the proportion of successes and failures and in determining the reasons for the latter. The clues provided by available statistics are distinctly patchy and not very useful. It is true that in most cases the failures tend to return home and the statistics usually show the number of repatriations. But it sometimes happens that they cannot go back and then a dissatisfied immigrant has no option but to remain where he is or, if possible, try his luck elsewhere. Moreover, the repatriation statistics do not make the necessary distinctions, e.g. between individuals who have failed and others who left with no intention of settling down permanently but made a success of it nevertheless. Nor do they usually give any information as to the reasons for the returns or the length of the stay abroad.1 A general idea as to the integration of the immigrants into the labour force can be obtained from censuses and employment statistics whenever aliens are distinguished from nationals and this material can sometimes be supplemented by the results of various surveys. But by and large it is impossible in most cases to come to any hard and fast conclusions. There is also ample material on aspects other than the quantitative, but this has to be treated with even greater caution. The following two sections, dealing respectively with the settlement of the migrants and with their absorption into the labour force, are therefore tentative at best. THE PROBLEM OF SETTLEMENT Statistics on permanent migration show that many migrants do not settle down in the countries they first go to but leave after some time. To what extent are these returns due to disappointment or to inability to settle down? In other words, how far do they represent failure? Some light can perhaps be cast on this problem by a comparative study of national statistics. These lead to a number of conclusions. The first is that there is a tendency not to settle down when the country of immigration is geo1 The Spanish statistics are an exception, but even they give only vague indications as to the reasons for returns. The Portuguese statistics have for some years stated the length of each individual's stay abroad in the case of repatriated emigrants. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 395 graphically close to the home country. The second is that, even where distances are comparable, this tendency varies appreciably as between one country of destination and another, and also apparently as from one occupation to another. The third is that instability is more marked among immigrants who are not accompanied by their families than among those who are. But these general conclusions themselves raise a variety of problems. The fact that emigration over short distances is often followed by returns on a relatively large scale (as is shown for example, by the Swedish and, above all, the Belgian statistics for continental migration) Can clearly not be interpreted a priori as evidence of failure by the workers to settle down in their jobs. It merely proves that when only short distances are involved people are apt to migrate temporarily without the same determination to make a fresh start as when they have to travel a long way; also, perhaps, they tend to maintain closer ties with their countries of origin, and this, too, encourages them to return home. This is at least one of the reasons why many short-distance movements tend to involve a constant two-way flow, e.g. between Italy and Belgium, Italy and Switzerland or Ireland and the United Kingdom, even if (as in the last two cases) seasonal movements are left out of account. In Africa, where this phenomenon is even more marked among African migrant workers, it seems to be due primarily to the close ties which most of them maintain with their tribal economy and which official migration regulations aim at preserving. But while distance is a factor which tends to affect the stability of migrants by making it more or less easy for them to return home, or temporary migration a more or less practicable proposition, it is by no means decisive. Instability is not always found among short-distance emigrants, any more than those who journey far afield invariably tend to settle down. For example, a higher proportion of immigrants from continental Europe than from Great Britain tend to settle down in Commonwealth countries. Similarly, proportionately more Italian immigrants tend to settle down in France than in Belgium1—even though distance in this case hardly enters into the picture—and in the Commonwealth countries than in Latin America. These observations suggest a 1 Despite the inadequacy of French statistics on this point, France does seem to have kept a higher proportion of post-war Italian immigrants than Belgium (threequarters instead of one-half). Italian statistics show that for the years 1946-56 these proportions were respectively 90 and 73 per cent, but these figures are clearly too •high, owing to an underestimate of the number of returns. The proportion assumed in the case of Belgium is based on Belgian statistics and in the case of France on a comparison between the 1946 and 1954 censuses; this latter estimate, however, may be somewhat overoptimistic. 396 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 variety of explanations, the first of which is based on the type of occupation involved. Emigration of managerial personnel to the underdeveloped countries, for instance, is still very often only temporary, and quite apart from the fact that the " normal " return movement has sometimes been swollen by mass repatriations due to political circumstances, this type of emigration, by and large, does not lead to permanent settlement. On top of the traditional reasons for this instability, such as the climate, homesickness, and rotation of staff by government departments and private concerns, recent political trends in the underdeveloped countries have introduced a new factor—the tendency to restrict the employment of foreigners. However, the failure of European or North American managerial personnel to settle down (which has been the rule in south-east Asia and the Middle East) has not been universal in Africa and Latin America. In Africa, the Central African Federation is engaged in the experiment of importing both executives and settlers, while Portugal is trying to colonise Angola and Mozambique with settlers from the home country; and until quite recently European settlement continued to expand in Morocco. In Latin America foreign managerial staffs do tend to settle permanently in some countries, although few of them are British or North American, the bulk being immigrants from continental Europe. Movements of managerial personnel to the underdeveloped countries, however, are not the only form of typically temporary movement. Italian immigration into Belgium illustrates a very different type of shortterm migration. The overwhelming majority of Italian workers allowed into Belgium are recruited for work in the mines, which is well paid but unpleasant. Some of the Italians have difficulty in getting used to the job and in any case most of them have no intention of remaining in it for any length of time, but only of working long enough to save something out of their wages. Thus the Italian labour force shares the general instability of mineworkers, which is particularly marked in Belgium. And since it is fairly difficult in that country for immigrants to change their occupation, it often happens that Italian workers who give up mining for one reason or another go back home. This probably helps to account for the difference between the stability of Italian workers in Belgium and in France, where the range of occupations open to immigrants is a good deal wider and where it appears to be easier for them to change occupations and even, after some years, to leave the more unpopular occupations altogether. Apart from mining there are several types of job in which immigrant labour is usually fairly unstable, e.g. domestic service, a largely female occupation where there is a constant turnover in the United Kingdom and Switzerland. This also apphes to ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 397 some extent to construction, largely because of the vicissitudes of the industry itself. These points help in distinguishing between normal and abnormal repatriations, or in other words in singling out the causes of failure. The best way to go about this task is to analyse the statistics of returns as carefully as possible and to note any fluctuations. But non-statistical information is the only way of picking out the possible causes of repatriations which are found on statistical examination to be abnormal in scale. Repatriations may be due to causes of three types. The first group are related to the job itself—unstable conditions within the industry, inability to settle down in the job and restrictions on mobility; the second are due to material circumstances, e.g. inadequate purchasing power or uncomfortable living conditions; and the third are personal in character— separation or homesickness. Bearing these points in mind, some attempt can be made to assess the proportion of successes and failures in the main migratory movements and decide on the reasons for the failures. In western Europe the position has tended to vary somewhat from one country to another. Thus migration from various sources to Sweden has been accompanied by large-scale movements in the reverse direction, at least as far as Denmark and Norway are concerned. But these movements, which comprise a good many returns as well as a flow of Swedish emigrants, merely bear witness to the normal mobility of labour between these countries which had achieved a common employment market in fact well before it was established by treaty. Much higher proportions of Finns, Germans and refugees of Baltic or Polish origin have settled down in Sweden. A segment of them, however, have preferred to reemigrate overseas but this was probably not because of any particular difficulty in settling down. The fairly liberal legislation exempting foreigners from the need to obtain a labour permit afterfiveyears' residence and the persistently buoyant state of the employment market, which have made it easy to move from one occupation to another, have all helped the immigrants to fit into the labour force. The figures show, nevertheless, that fluctuations in employment, though not serious, did have some effect on returns ; these jumped fairly sharply during the spell of increased unemployment which occurred in 1953. In the United Kingdom immigrants have come from many different areas and propensity to settle down has varied widely from one group to another. It has been very slight among immigrants entering the country with individual labour permits (most of them women recruited for domestic service), who usually come only to work temporarily. Settlement has been much more widespread among workers recruited in groups, particularly among the displaced persons but also among the 398 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 Italians. The proportion of Poles of the expeditionary corps who settled in the country has also been high. These facts seem to show that most of these classes of immigrants made a fairly good adjustment, having come originally to the United Kingdom with the intention of staying there for some length of time, and in many cases for good. The liberal practice concerning the employment of aliens, who are normally exempted from the need to obtain a permit after four years' residence and allowed thereafter to change jobs as and when they like, has also probably been an important factor. It is true that during the early years the immigrants from eastern Europe had some trouble in settling down owing to a variety of factors such as poor housing, homesickness, unstable employment and, in many cases, the need to accept a lower-grade occupation. Nor could they solve their problem by giving up and going home, although to some extent they had the option of emigrating overseas. A fairly large number in fact availed themselves of this possibility, including, it may be presumed, some who had already made a successful adjustment in the United Kingdom. Nevertheless, the fact that the rise in unemployment of 1951-52 coincided with a sharp increase in emigration of this kind does suggest that the feeling of insecurity caused by the former had a good deal to do with the latter. Irish immigration is in many respects an internal, rather than an international, movement and the Irish workers seem to have had no difficulty in settling down. While Irish labour tends to be somewhat unstable, with a heavy turnover, this is probably due to a large extent to the nature of the occupations concerned. Despite everything, however, the net immigration figures show that there is quite a strong tendency to settle down. The influx of coloured immigrants from various Commonwealth countries is too recent for it to be possible to judge whether it will lead to any permanent settlement or whether, like the movement of Algerian Moslems to France, it will prove to be mainly temporary. Whether or not this happens will probably depend on such factors as the presence of families, which have hitherto tended to stay behind in the country of origin, and above all on the arrival of more women than previously. It will also depend on the continuation of a level of employment such as will enable the immigrants—who have the same rights as British workers—to fit in without arousing opposition. In Belgium immigrants have come from various countries but by far the most important flow has consisted of Italians, most of them recruited for work in the mines. The migration statistics, which show a very high proportion (around 50 per cent.) of returns to Italy, suggest at first sight that the number of failures must have been very high. In point of fact it has not been as high as might be thought because ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 399 many of the workers went to Belgium without any intention of staying there. The fact remains, nevertheless, that, whatever their original intention, many of them failed to settle down and despite all the material incentives offered (such as high wages, cheap hostel accommodation and holidays), gave up either for reasons of health or because they could not get used to an arduous and, to them, totally new job or else because they felt homesick. Owing to the regulations governing the employment of aliens and the general state of the employment market these individuals usually had no option but to go home before their time. On the other hand those who have been able to settle down have good opportunities of promotion with turnover so heavy and constant, and this probably helps to explain why so many Italian miners have stayed despite the unpleasant features of the work. Far less information is available concerning the immigrants who entered France after 1946. This is due to lack of adequate statistics and of any surveys similar to those carried out in Belgium. A large proportion of the Germans recruited in the immediate post-war years appear to have gone home as the rapid recovery of the Federal Republic got under way. The displaced persons, for their part, do not appear in the main to have been satisfied with the earnings and housing provided for them in agriculture (for which most of them were recruited) and usually they moved on to other jobs. Many of them in fact re-emigrated from France, as they did from Belgium, despite the relatively privileged treatment they were given with respect to employment in both countries. This was true not only of displaced persons, but of other refugees as well. The Italian immigrants seem to have settled down better and to have made their homes in France in fairly large numbers even though not all of them remained in the same occupation; it would seem, in this connection, that although controls on occupational mobility are theoretically very strict, workers have in practice been allowed a good deal of freedom in changing jobs, at least after a certain length of time. The efforts of the Government to encourage family immigration and the liberal naturalisation arrangements have perhaps helped the process, apart altogether from the fact that Italians and Spaniards have traditionally had little trouble in settling down in France. In Switzerland, despite a constant increase in the number of foreign workers, turnover has been fairly heavy, even in occupations for which permanent labour permits are issued. This instability is encouraged by the proximity of Austria, Germany and Italy, from which Switzerland draws most of its foreign labour; its basic cause, however, lies in the types of occupations for which immigrants are chiefly recruited, namely farming and, above all, domestic service and the hotel trade, which do 400 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 not normally keep their workers for long periods. Another reason is the fact that a high proportion of the workers are women. Manufacturing industry (which has relied far more heavily on foreigners during the second half of the period than during the first) appears to have been more successful in keeping them. As in France and Belgium, the employment situation—which has been generally favourable except in 1949-50 when some labour permits were not renewed because of the slight increase in unemployment—has accounted to only a minor extent for instability among foreign workers. Such instability, by and large, has been a voluntary phenomenon and should not be interpreted as indicating abnormal difficulties of adjustment. The proportion of immigrants settling down in North America has been particularly high. In the United States permanent departures of foreign residents have barely exceeded 10 per cent, of the total number of immigrants; and in a number of these cases, subsequent re-immigration remains a possibility. There are no figures for Canada, which does not compile emigration statistics, but the statistics of European emigration countries show on the whole a very small return movement from Canada. The United Kingdom seems the only exception and it is also one of the few countries with a substantial return movement from the United States. Needless to say, this is not due to greater inability on the part of British immigrants to settle down in Canada or the United States. It is simply part of a normal and traditional two-way movement between countries with close economic and cultural links. The return movement mainly involves persons with occupational qualifications of a high order, students, and women not gainfully employed. Generally speaking, therefore, it can be said that Canada and the United States have kept almost all of their post-war immigrants. Absorption into the labour force has been helped by the rapid and almost constant increase in the volume of employment and by the fact that immigrants in both countries enjoy almost complete freedom as regards the choice of an occupation. In Canada vocational selection by the authorities has also been important as have the very efficient reception and placing arrangements—essential in a country where, unlike in Europe, admission is not conditional on the existence of a specific job vacancy. In the United States, where there is no machinery of this kind, private initiative, sponsors, voluntary organisations and a number of international organisations have to some extent filled the gap. The high level of wages in Canada, and even more so in the United States, has naturally been a powerful factor of stability. This does not mean, however, that the integration of the immigrants into the labour force has raised no problems at all. Minor fluctuations ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 401 in the level of employment have made it difficult at times to find work for them. This seems to have been especially true of Canada, where immigration has been on a particularly large scale. But both in Canada and in the United States immigrants have sometimes found it hard, technically or psychologically, to settle down in jobs for which they were unfitted by previous experience or to accustom themselves to different working methods. In the United States, for instance, it has often proved impossible to absorb displaced persons in agriculture, even if they had a farming background, because they could not get used to methods completely different from those to which they were accustomed. A further point is that the refugees, here as elsewhere, have often had to start off at a lower level in the occupational scale and they have not always been able to make up the lost ground. The position has been somewhat different in Latin America, where repatriations have been on a far bigger scale, bearing witness to an above-average rate of failures. In the case of Argentina, the statistics show that the general proportion of returns to Europe has been of the order of 30 per cent, and it would appear (leaving out the return of temporary migrants) that the worsening of the economic position after 1949 led to a good many unplanned departures. How exactly did this worsening of the economic position affect the immigrants personally ? The information available on this point is extremely vague. Probably a number of factors were involved: the fall in industrial employment 1 ; the decline in the workers' purchasing power owing to inflation; restrictions on the transfer of savings ; and the housing shortage in the towns, particularly Buenos Aires, which made it difficult for the immigrants' families to join them. A high proportion of the returning workers were either single or unaccompanied by their dependants, so that, despite adverse economic conditions, family immigration clearly had a stabilising effect. This helps to explain why a relatively higher proportion of Italian immigrants (who were given special facilities for bringing over their families under assistance schemes sponsored by the Argentine Government and by I.C.E.M.) remained in the country. Even so, large numbers of them returned or left for other destinations. On balance, departures by workers through repatriation or re-emigration amounted to nearly 40 per cent of the incoming total, and it does seem that the overoptimistic and insufficiently selective immigration policy pursued by the Argentine Government was largely responsible for the abnormally high proportion of failures. 1 From 1,827,000 at the 1947 census to 1,701,000 at the 1954 census. Industrial employment reached its peak in 1948 and fell to its lowest point in 1953, when the index reached 88 (1948 = 100). It subsequently rose slightly. 402 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 There are no Brazilian emigration statistics, so that figures compiled by the main emigration countries (Portugal, Italy and Spain) are the only guide to the proportion of returning workers. There was a much bigger flow back to Italy (nearly 25 per cent.) than to the other two countries (under 15 per cent.), assuming that the Portuguese statistics do not underestimate the number of returns. In addition, it is known that many immigrants—though it is impossible to say how many— re-emigrated to Venezuela. These were mainly Italians, among whom the proportion of failures was particularly high owing to harsh conditions, particularly in agriculture, inadequate wages, and the depreciation of the currency, which made it a constant struggle for them to keep up their living standards and above all shrank the value of the savings they wished to transfer. The number of returns appears to have been particularly large among workers who were either unskilled or lacked the skills in demand, and were therefore faced with the prospect of accepting lower-grade jobs. The fact that returns seem to have been less numerous among Spaniards and Portuguese is probably due to their greater readiness to accept poor living conditions. The proportion of failures appears to have been even higher in Venezuela, to judge by the size of the return movement to Spain (25 per cent, according to the Spanish statistics) and above all to Italy (35 per cent, according to the Italian statistics). The reason for this seems to be that the high level of wages in Venezuela acted as a powerful attraction, and far too many foreigners went there without first being sure of finding stable—and suitable—employment. As in Brazil, those who had no skill or whose skills were not in demand seem to have been the least successful, since they had to enter industries where employment is insecure, or even casual, and where wages are relatively low. They also seem to have had to compete with local labour, which in turn tried to safeguard its own position and this again added to the immigrants' troubles in finding employment. Particularly large numbers of Italians returned home, most of them after a very short time, probably because they were less willing than the Spaniards and Portuguese to put up with conditions which were unexpectedly hard and also, by all accounts, because they were less able to stand the climate. A large majority of the workers returning were individuals who had emigrated alone. This high proportion of failures strikingly illustrates the drawbacks of spontaneous immigration when it is not subject to adequate control: the first to suffer in such cases are the immigrants themselves. While Latin America, despite the fairly high proportion of failures among recent immigrants, remains, by and large, a continent of permanent immigration, temporary movements have continued to pre- ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 403 dominate in Africa ; this applies to inter-territorial movements of African workers as well as to movements by European managerial staff. The increase in the number of African workers of foreign origin in a number of countries, particularly Ghana and the Union of South Africa, has not meant any reduction in the traditionally high turnover among such workers; it merely shows that the volume of this constantly changing labour force has risen in step with the growth of the industries in which it is employed. On the other hand, the generally substantial increase which has occurred since 1946 in the size of the European population (at least in some countries) shows a distinct tendency towards permanent settlement, e.g. in the Portuguese provinces of Angola and Mozambique, the Central African Federation, and even in British East Africa, where substantial numbers of Asians have also settled. The success of these settlements will in all likelihood depend on political circumstances more than anything else. However, a substantial return movement from Africa to Europe is still a regular phenomenon, even in the absence of events such as those which occurred in Morocco in 1955 and in Egypt in 1956, causing a sudden and temporary rise in the number of departures. It is impossible to ascertain how many of the European immigrants having entered the Union of South Africa since 1946 settled there permanently. Movements in the reverse direction have been slight, consisting almost exclusively of persons of British stock, some of them South Africans going temporarily to Great Britain. But some of the recent immigrants appear to have re-emigrated to the Rhodesias. Australia has been particularly successful, by comparison with most countries, in keeping its post-war immigrants. The only large-scale return movement from Australia to Europe has involved British subjects, some of them Australian citizens going to Great Britain temporarily. Of course, the displaced persons, who represent a considerable proportion of all postwar immigrants, have had no option but to settle in Australia. Still, the proportion of returns has also been very low among the Greeks (most of whom, admittedly, are very recent arrivals), quite low among the Dutch and not much higher among the Italians. It is no exaggeration to say that Australia has had virtually no repatriation problem. A number of factors help to explain this. One has been a practically uninterrupted spell of overemployment which has made it possible for the immigrants to be readily absorbed in the labour force and (except in the case of temporary restrictions imposed by law on certain classes of assisted immigrants) to change their jobs without any difficulty. The country has also reaped the benefit of methodical organisation of immigration—careful selection, efficient reception and placing, and, in 404 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 some cases, preparatory vocational training given to the immigrants in their countries of origin. Family immigration, which has been encouraged in preference to immigration by individual workers, has also been a major stabilising factor. Mention should be made, too, of the efforts of various public bodies and welfare organisations to help the immigrants of nonBritish stock in making their adjustment to the Australian way of life. Lastly, the level of wages, though lower than in the United States or, for that matter, Canada, has still been sufficiently high for most of the immigrants to be appreciably and often substantially better off. In short, the failures seem to have been confined to the inevitable proportion of individual misfits. The situation in New Zealand is much the same as in Australia and a high proportion of the post-war immigrants, including almost all those of non-British origin, have settled down permanently. OCCUPATIONAL INTEGRATION OF THE MIGRANTS The extent to which immigrant workers succeed in fitting into the local labour force and in acquiring the same legal and social status as their native-born fellow workers is another important problem which, as already seen, is partly linked with the general problem of settlement in the country of destination. Unfortunately, while the legal position in each case is clear, there is practically nothing to go on in trying to ascertain the situation in fact. For example, are immigrant workers (assuming equal seniority and skill) really less secure in their jobs? No doubt, this is still often the case, but there is hardly any conclusive evidence to show it. Even where unemployment statistics distinguish between nationals and foreigners and disclose a higher rate of unemployment among the latter, this can be explained simply by the fact that a higher proportion of foreigners are usually to be found among newly engaged workers, who are traditionally the first to be laid off in case of redundancy, and also that their distribution among the various occupational sectors is usually quite different from that of the local workers. The problem also depends on whether or not the foreigners are required to obtain labour permits. If they are, they are liable to lose their jobs not only by dismissal under the " last in, first out " rule, but also as the result of a refusal by the authorities to extend the permits when they expire. In such a case they run a severe risk of being eliminated completely from the employment market, since unless they can obtain permits for other occupations they have no alternative, not being entitled to unemployment compensa- ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 405 tion, but to return home. It follows that in countries such as those of western Europe, which have a system of labour permits, instability of employment among immigrants may be higher than among local workers without necessarily being reflected in a higher rate of unemployment. In point of fact, during the period under review there have not been in any of the major immigration countries economic swings of such size as to represent a genuine threat to employment security for the bulk of the immigrants. This applies to countries with a labour permit system as well as to others, probably because such a system forms part of immigration policies designed to channel workers into chronically undermanned industries where by definition there is hardly any unemployment, and also because of the precautions taken by governments before issuing permits. In western Europe, at any rate, instances of refusal to extend labour permits because of a worsening of the employment situation appear to have been few and far between (although this does not necessarily mean that the contracts themselves were renewed in all cases). The few known cases of discrimination against foreign workers in connection with dismissals or hirings have occurred in countries where immigrants enjoy extensive rights but where the local workers, through their trade unions, have taken what they regard as justifiable steps to protect their own interests. The problem of occupational mobility is more complex. It covers not only the worker's right to change his employer, but also his ability to better himself, either by promotion within his occupation or by changing to another occupation—in other words, to follow the career best suited to his bent and aptitudes. The question is how far and how soon opportunities which are open without restriction to local workers are made available to the immigrants and to what extent they are used ; for even though the immigrant worker is fully integrated in the labour force and enjoys the same stability of employment as local workers the process of assimilation cannot be considered complete as long as legal or practical obstacles denying him full equality of opportunity have not been eliminated. This process tends to be a fairly slow one depending on the size of the obstacles and the immigrant's own skills and character. Moreover, it is sometimes delayed by the downgrading in the occupational scale which the integration of immigrant workers often involves in the initial stages. It is by no means uncommon for immigrants (especially when they come from countries which are overpopulated or where wages are far lower) to be forced to accept less skilled occupations than they are fitted for. This is not only true of countries which, in order to allow their own workers to move up, only allow foreigners to enter on condition that they take jobs 406 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 at the lower end of the scale, but also in some instances of other countries, either because the immigrants do not know the language sufficiently well to perform certain trades or because their skills have not been tested or do not meet local standards, or again because—in the case of the self-employed—they do not possess the necessary capital. Displaced persons have suffered very generally in this way; many of them are professional workers who have had to accept manual jobs, or self-employed persons who have had to become wage earners. Nor are these the only examples : for instance, a large segment of the Italians recruited for employment as labourers in the Belgian coal mines and iron and steel industry were skilled or semi-skilled workers in other trades and even handicraftsmen, businessmen or smallholders. Similarly, in Canada and Australia industrial workers seem to have been taken on in lower-grade jobs than they might have expected and sometimes even in other trades; still more commonly, men who once had farms of their own have had to take jobs as farm labourers. A further point, however, is that this process has varied according to nationality ; for example, in the Commonwealth countries British subjects do not appear to have been affected at all. But whether owing to unavoidable circumstances (which they usually accepted quite willingly) immigrant workers were at first forced down the scale or whether they succeeded in avoiding this altogether is of comparatively small interest: what really matters is how far they tried to improve their lot, and how far they succeeded. Unfortunately, in most cases very little information is available on this point. In many immigration countries, there is definite evidence of shifts by immigrant workers from one occupation or sector to another. It is the general experience, for instance, that workers placed in employment as farm labourers do not normally remain there. This has been the case in the United Kingdom, where only a small proportion of the foreigners recruited for this purpose have stayed on the land, and in France, where demand for foreign labour in agriculture continues unabated as even the recently recruited foreigners join the general drift from the land and have to be replaced. A similar process appears to have taken place in Canada and Australia. In both countries, a high proportion of the refugees admitted since 1947 have left the industries which they originally entered, often even before their contracts expired.1 The question arises whether these changes should be considered as the start of an improvement in the immigrants' status, or simply as a sign of failure in the initial occupation. The former interpretation 1 In Canada, according to a survey conducted in 1951, this proportion amounted to 58 per cent, in mining, 72 per cent, in the paper industry and 93 per cent, in construction. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS 407 seems to be the right one in the frequent cases where the occupations abandoned by the immigrants are those in which wages or working conditions are worst, or employment least secure, and which are least attractive to immigrant and local workers alike. Examples of this are agriculture, construction (at least in countries where employment is subject to sharp seasonal fluctuations) and mining. In at least one country —Australia—there is statistical evidence of an improvement in the immigrants' status. This is provided by a comparison between the information regarding the occupations of immigrants collected on arrival in Australia and in the 1954 census, on the one hand, and corresponding figures for the local population on the other.1 It appears that, while the immigrants mainly entered manufacturing and construction, where they are still proportionately more numerous than workers of Australian origin, they are now fairly widely distributed among the other branches of the economy, particularly commerce. This is true not only of British immigrants, whose occupational distribution, through its similarity to that of the Australians by origin, testifies to their complete assimilation, but also of the other major groups, i.e. Polish, Dutch and Italian immigrants. As regards their employment status, a markedly higher proportion of immigrants are wage earners, but a substantial proportion of them have become employers or self-employed. It is true that among the Italians, if not among the Dutch and the eastern Europeans, most of these probably entered before 1946. Unfortunately there is no information of equal accuracy available for the other major countries of immigration. In Canada it is known that many Dutch immigrants who at first took jobs as farm labourers became farm managers after some years. It was also clear as far back as the 1951 census that the immigrants who entered in the immediate post-war years had subsequently become dispersed throughout the active population in a way which suggests conclusions similar to those that can be drawn from the Australian statistics. A further point is the degree of skill and the grade and rate of pay of immigrants as compared with those of longer-established workers in the same occupation, but there is no definite information on this subject in respect of either Canada or Australia. Nevertheless, if standards of housing are taken as a reliable guide to earnings, immigrants in either country are not appreciably worse off, by and large, than the rest of the population. Summing up, therefore, it is easier to infer than to prove the tendency for immigrants to rise higher in the occupational scale. The resulting 1 See W. D . BORRIE and J. ZUBRZYCKI: " Employment of Post-War Immigrants in Australia ", in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. LXXVII, No. 3 , Mar. 1958, pp. 239-253. 408 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 process of assimilation is more rapid and complete in countries which accept immigration for settlement and set out to give the newcomers full equality of opportunity by leaving them free to change jobs or by restricting such freedom only for a short time. On the other hand, it would be a mistake to underestimate the obstacles created for immigrants in some of these countries by legal proficiency standards or trade union rules. Moreover, even in countries where the labour permit system tends to confine immigrants to certain occupations they are at least, like the foreign miners in Belgium, given the opportunity of rising within their particular occupation. Very often, too, thanks to extended periods of full employment, administrative practice as regards the granting of permits has often been more liberal than the letter of the regulations might suggest. Bibliographical References The works listed below relate only to the third section of the chapter, entitled " Effects on the Migrants ". The source material for the remainder of the chapter is included among the references listed at the end of Chapter VIII. UNITED NATIONS EDUCATIONAL, SCIENTIFIC AND CULTURAL ORGANIZATION: The Positive Contribution by Immigrants (Paris, 1955). The D. P. Story ; The Final Report of the United States Displaced Persons Commission (Washington, D.C., 1952). H. B. M. MURPHY: " The Assimilation of Refugee Immigrants in Australia ", in Population Studies (Cambridge, The University Press), Vol. 5, No. 3, Mar. 1952, pp. 179-206. J. STADULIS: "The Resettlement of Displaced Persons in the United Kingdom ", in Population Studies, op. cit., pp. 207-237. A. GIRARD and J. STOETZEL: Français et immigrés (Vol. I: V attitude française ; radaptation des Italiens et des Polonais ; and Vol. II : Nouveaux documents sur l'adaptation), Institut national d'études démographiques, Travaux et documents, Nos. 19 and 20 (Paris, Presses universitaires de France, 1953 and 1954). W. D. BORRIE: Italians and Germans in Australia (Melbourne, F. W. Cheshire, 1954). C. and D. MANLEY : A Report on Jamaican Migration to Great Britain (Kingston, Jamaica, Government Printer, 1955). SENIOR R. T. APPLEYARD: " The Economie Absorption of Dutch and Italian Immigrants into Western Australia, 1947 to 1955 ", in R.E.M.P. Bulletin (The Hague, Research Group on European Migration Problems), Vol. 4, No. 3, July-Sep. 1956, pp. 45-55; and No. 4, Oct.-Dec. 1956, pp. 87-101. ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL EFFECTS I N S T I T U T D E SOCIOLOGIE D E L A F A C U L T É D E D R O I T D E L I È G E : Migrations 409 pro- voquées et problèmes de mobilité ouvrière, E t u d e exécutée p o u r l a C o m m u n a u t é e u r o p é e n n e d u C h a r b o n e t de l'Acier (Liège, H . Vaillant-Carmanne, 1956). J. Z U B R Z Y C K I : Polish Immigrants in Britain. A Study of Adjustment, in Social Life I I I (The H a g u e , M a r t i n u s Nijhoff, 1956). Studies W . D . BORRIE a n d J. Z U B R Z Y C K I : " E m p l o y m e n t of P o s t - W a r Immigrants in Australia " , in International Labour Review (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. L X X V I I , N o . 3, M a r . 1958, p p . 239-253. CONCLUSIONS Whereas the political migration movements of the immediate postwar years in some parts of the world have been on an unprecedented scale and have, in some countries, raised a difficult problem of integration, economic migration currents from 1945 to 1957 have, by and large, remained within relatively narrow bounds and, except in a few countries, have not had a major impact on economic development. They have certainly been smaller than those of earlier periods, including the years before the First World War, and even those immediately following it. This is not because the traditional sources of emigration (with the exception of eastern Europe) have tended to dry up. Nor is it because the rate of natural growth of the labour force in most of the major immigration countries has been rising (actually, it has fallen in a number of cases). The main reason is that these countries have, generally speaking, raised their productivity substantially and this has often enabled them to expand at an even faster rate than during the most remarkable periods of growth of the past without having to expand their labour force to anything like the same extent. Another point is that they have usually striven more consistently to maintain the highest possible level of employment among their own workers and, at the same time, been at greater pains to safeguard them against the danger of competition from immigrants. As a result, many economic migration currents are on a far smaller scale than they were 30 years ago and some of them, especially in south-east Asia, have ceased completely. It should be added, however, that as immigration countries have adopted more cautious and selective policies of admission, one of the salient features of earlier migratory movements—namely their wide fluctuations in both directions—has tended to disappear (helped, it is true, by greater economic stability). Where instability does occur among migrants it seems to be increasingly due to movements which were never intended to be other than temporary. In short, fewer immigrants have been admitted than would have been the case formerly, but on the whole a higher proportion of them have settled down, and this has been to the benefit of all concerned, first and foremost their own. On the other hand, it cannot be said that immigration policies have always been completely satisfactory. Some of them have probably been too restrictive, while others have not been selective enough. Regulating immigration in a country's best interests is certainly no easy task for CONCLUSIONS 411 any government, particularly when there are cultural considerations to complicate the purely economic issues. The fact is that in order to derive a clear and rapid benefit from heavy immigration, a country must be in a position to cope with the economic and social problems involved, i.e. it must have a sufficiently sound economic base to support the investments required, combined with adequate administrative machinery. If this structure is too weak, the effects of the investment that immigration itself can be expected to generate will be problematical, while there will be a distinct danger of disturbances in the shape of unemployment, lower wages and inflation. The example of Western Germany, where the influx of refugees at first burdened the economy but later gave added impetus to expansion, does not by itself constitute proof that it is always a good thing for immigration to be considerably in excess of an economy's immediate capacity to absorb it. The case of Israel is even less conclusive since the immigrants were only absorbed at the cost of even greater strain and —above all—with the help of large-scale aid from abroad. The longterm benefits of immigration depend in effect on the strength of the economy and for quite a long time the price which has to be paid for them may appear unduly heavy. This makes it hard for governments, for the sake of distant and possibly uncertain benefits, deliberately to court the risk of short-term and all too certain upheavals. Few countries in fact have been able to derive the full benefit from large-scale immigration during the last 12 years without suffering serious strain in the process. Canada and Australia have managed to do so, but even they may at times have overstepped the limit, particularly Australia. Most of the Latin American countries, on the other hand, do not possess an adequate economic foundation or the administrative machinery needed to handle immigration on a comparable scale, so that there is a wide gap between their actual and potential absorption capacity. In these circumstances, most of the countries suffering from overpopulation can hardly count on emigration as a way out of their difficulties and it seems unlikely that the position will improve very much, at least in the near future. This is unfortunate for the overpopulated countries, because the departure of unproductive workers naturally relieves painful economic pressures. On the other hand, the selective approach of the immigration countries and the fact that they are in a position to pick and choose, lead them not only to skim off the cream of the unproductive workers in the countries of emigration, but sometimes to offer inducements strong enough to attract even workers badly needed for the development of their own country. In other words, even though the workers mainly affected by emigration are not imme- 412 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 diately useful to the economy, their potential usefulness may be considerable and this may prove awkward in the event of a phase of economic expansion entailing a fall in unemployment. Observation also shows that while international migration always leads to a rise in general productivity, it does not always help to close the gap between levels of development in the countries affected. Migration by managerial staffs to the underdeveloped countries does have this effect, especially when accompanied (as is usually the case) by capital movements to the same countries. But this does not apply to mass migration, which raises productivity in the countries of immigration more than in those of emigration and which, even allowing for the indirect benefit accruing to the latter in the form of a more favourable balance of payments, has on the whole much more favourable effects on the former. Thus, while mass migration may help to solve the problem of overpopulation, it has a number of potential drawbacks and cannot in any event, given the circumstances in which it takes place today, help to eliminate disparities in levels of productivity and rates of growth. This is why emigration countries have tried, with varying success, to deal with overpopulation in other ways, e.g. by raising the employment level, increasing productivity and, generally speaking, making better use of their domestic manpower resources. In addition to the economic argument against mass migration of the type which has taken place recently—i.e. insufficient economic advantage for the emigration countries—there is also a psychological and social argument. Emigration necessarily uproots people and thereby involves many drawbacks for those who are driven to it by necessity alone. From the standpoint of the overpopulated countries, it would therefore be better to find other ways of raising productivity and the level of employment, particularly by making more efficient use of existing labour resources. This, however, is a somewhat theoretical approach, since freedom to choose between one course or another may be limited by the lack of production facilities, so that in fact emigration may be the only answer, or one among several, all inescapable. This being the case, the only way in which migration can help to equalise standards of development is to bring greater benefits to the emigration countries in the form of a return flow of capital or improved commercial facilities. It would then become an item in a balanced exchange of development factors instead of representing, as it now does, a partly or wholly one-sided loss of human resources. This, however, assumes that the countries with plenty of capital and a shortage of labour will show a deeper understanding of the long- CONCLUSIONS 413 term interests of those where the situation is the reverse, or, to put it another way, that they will look beyond their own immediate interests and perceive the benefits to be obtained by encouraging greater equality of production conditions. This prospect is not quite as fanciful as might appear at first sight. The idea of associating countries at different levels of development to form regional or interregional groups with a gradual pooling of resources and a harmonisation of living conditions has already been put forward, and with the establishment of the European Economic Community has even begun to take concrete shape. In associations of this kind, migration could take on a new significance as part of a concerted effort to equalise levels of productivity, and international action in the migration field could develop along entirely new lines. But, at the same time, it would cease to be a specific operation with a limited scope and would form part of a far broader levelling-out process than hitherto. These, from the economic standpoint at least, are the conclusions to be drawn from a study of international migration during the years following the Second World War. But the phenomenon cannot be expressed in purely economic terms, and it is impossible to overlook some of its political and social aspects, which unquestionably represent a net gain. For one thing, recent international migration movements have (apart from occasional difficulties that may have occurred in negotiating bilateral or multilateral agreements) helped to strengthen the links forged between countries by the great migratory currents of past years. There can be no doubt that the relations between certain European and overseas countries have been influenced by the presence in the latter of sizeable groups of immigrants brought in by traditional currents. Socially, emigration is often fraught with difficulties, but for many people it has been and still is the only way out of the dead end created in some countries by persistent underemployment. Thus, even assuming that international migration will continue to be curtailed by the same conditions which hitherto have limited its volume as well as its economic effectiveness, international action in this field continues to be justified. The experience of the past 12 years has amply demonstrated its value. It has been dovetailed into the schemes of governments and of many voluntary organisations ; as a result greater care has been taken of the migrants and their rights more effectively safeguarded. For this, some of the credit must go to the international organisations, which have taken a number of valuable measures. But more remains to be done by way of protecting and assisting the migrants. The international instruments on the subject should be extended, particularly as regards social security. Even more urgent than the establish- 414 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, 1945-1957 ment of new standards is the need to ensure that those already in existence are more widely enforced. International participation in organising and carrying out migration schemes continues to meet a real need even though, other conditions remaining equal, numerically impressive results should not be expected. This work should continue along the lines pursued hitherto, i.e. in the form of technical assistance to emigration and immigration countries which do not possess all the facilities needed to carry out the schemes that could benefit them. In order to be fully effective, however, such assistance should form part of a general effort covering all the objectives of national economic policy and extending to all of the relevant manpower problems. Its effectiveness will be enhanced if it draws on the experience and technical resources of all the organisations concerned and blends them into a co-ordinated joint effort.