INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE STUDIES AND REPORTS Series N (Statistics) No. 24 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS by ROBERT MORSE WOODBURY MONTREAL 19 4 1 PREFACE The comparison of real wages in different countries to set forth the relative economic positions of wage earners under different conditions of production and consumption is a fascinating study but one beset with difficult and intricate problems. On the one hand, the problems of securing data on wages, taking into account the many differences in methods of collection and the differences in the significance of wage rates, earnings, minimum and normal wages must be faced and the mass of data for different occupations and industries converted into manageable and useful figures. On the other hand, a means of comparing the cost of living of wage earners in different countries must be found in order to give a valid picture of relative standards of comfort. Even this latter problem, relatively the simpler of the two, is itself beset with difficulties. Analysing the cost of living into its component parts, food, rent, fuel and light, clothing, and miscellaneous items, and studying each part separately, has seemed to offer the best means of reaching a satisfactory solution. The International Labour Office has already published special reports on methods of international comparisons of food and of rent, and has made annual surveys of retail prices of certain foodstuffs, etc., as well as occasional surveys of rents in selected cities. The present report is a further study of the specific problem of international comparisons of food costs. It was prepared by Robert Morse Woodbury, assisted by Walter Kull of the Statistical Section of the International Labour Office. Prior to the emergency situation caused by the war, the work was carried on under the general direction of J. W. Nixon, Chief of the Statistical Section; a memorandum embodying the principal elements of the report was sent to the members of the Committee of Statistical Experts of the International Labour Office for their comments and suggestions. A meeting of the Committee planned for the spring of 1940 had to be abandoned. As a result of changes produced by the war it has been decided to issue the document as a research report in order that the 2 11 PREFACE various countries and interested persons may have an opportunity to consider and test the proposed method. It is believed that the method presented herewith represents a definite advance over previous methods of comparisons and that with progress in obtaining valuable results for other elements of the problem, including that of combining the ratios obtained for these different elements, the goal of international comparisons of real wages may be brought nearer. Acknowledgments are due for valuable suggestions and criticisms to members of the Committee of Statistical Experts, to E. F. Penrose and Robert Guye of the International Labour Office, and to Faith M. Williams and Alice C. Hanson of the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics. Other acknowledgments to authors and writers on the subject of international comparisons of food costs whose works have been consulted are made in the report itself. CONTENTS PREFACE i INTBODUCTION 1 Price Ratio Formulae Method of Regional Baskets and the Problem of Regions CHAPTER I. The Group Basket Method Formation of Groups T h e Group Baskets Method of Calculating Ratios Results , Correction Factors Errors of the Group Basket Method CHAPTER II. Applications 27 29 30 35 38 38 50 55 Substitutions 57 Types of Substitutions Criterion for Substitutions Basis for Equivalence Mathematical Methods Practical Techniques Substitutions and t h e Group Basket Method Results Scope of Substitutions Conclusions C H A P T E R V. Conclusions 58 58 59 61 63 64 65 68 69 71 APPENDIX I. Résolutions adopted by International Conferences, the Committee of Statistical Experts and the Governing Body of the International Labour Oßce APPENDIX II. 15 15 20 21 22 23 26 27 Cities Population Groups Eponomic Groups : Climatic Differences CHAPTER I I I . Errors in Basic Data Quantities Prices Exchange Rates C H A P T E R IV. 3 7 Tables 73 79 1. Correction factors t o P 0 ' and P i ' by countries 2. Values of P„' after application of correction factors, calculated by the Group Basket Method, based upon 18 commodities in 19 countries, prices as of October 1938 3. Values of P i ' after application of correction factors, calculated by the Group Basket Method, based upon 18 commodities in 19 countries, prices as of October 1938 4. Values of the substitution ratio for P 0 ', with substitutions between rye and wheaten bread 5. Values of the substitution ratio for P i ' , with substitutions between rye and wheaten bread 2 4 79 80 81 82 83 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS INTRODUCTION This Report presents the results of studies made by the Statistical Section of the International Labour Office in continuation of its work on the problem of international comparisons of cost of living. 1 Preliminary results were submitted to the members of the Committee of Statistical Experts of the International Labour Office by mail for criticisms and suggestions ; it was originally planned to call a meeting of the Committee to discuss them in the spring of 1940. Unfortunately, owing to war conditions, this project of a meeting of the Committee had to be abandoned. However, various members of the Committee sent in comments and suggestions, and these have been utilised in preparing this report for publication. The report is therefore presented as a research report on the methodology of international comparisons of costs of living, in continuation of the work of the Office on this topic. The present publication is limited to the subject of the international comparison of costs of food. The International Labour Office has already published a number of studies on the problem of comparative food costs. Its first work on the subject was undertaken following a recommendation by the First International Conference of Labour Statisticians in 1923 that the Office continue and develop statistics of relative wage rates and cost of living in different countries, begun by the British Ministry of Labour. In the British compilation the British worker's food consumption was adopted as the basis for calculating relative food costs in different cities in selected countries; for purposes of 1 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: International Comparisons of Cost of Living. A Study of Certain Problems connected mth the Making of Index Numbers of Food Costs and of Rents, Studies and Reports, Series N, Statistics, No. 20,1934. 2 4 2 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS international comparison this basis was replaced in the Office study, published in 1924, by a series of food budgets for different groups of countries or regions, seven in number; these were priced in each of a series of cities, the ratios of the cost of each regional budget in each city to that in London were computed, and finally these relative ratios were averaged to secure a single figure for each city.1 The basis for the regional grouping was stated as "the rough correspondence of quantities consumed" or "an approximate similarity in the quantities of the chief articles consumed".2 In general, the quantities were based on the budgets used in cost-of-living statistics of the different countries. Subsequently, the Office set up a single international food basket representing average quantities consumed per consumption unit in workers' families in the different countries and priced this basket in each country in order to show relative costs. The international basket as originally set up in October 1929 contained 25 articles3; in 1933 the number of articles was reduced to 14—omitting 11 relatively unimportant items covering only about 15 per cent, of the value of the 25 articles—in order to avoid problems arising where the price series did not cover all articles4; and the costs of this revised basket have been published each year. In addition, special mention should be made of two studies, one embodying the results of the enquiry undertaken to ascertain the cost of living in various European cities on the same standards as that of employees of the Ford factories in Detroit5; and the second, embodying a study of the theoretical problem of measuring the relative costs of food and rent.6 In the first of these the geometrical average of the Laspeyres and Paasche indices, the so-called Fisher "ideal" formula, as explained in the next paragraph, was used between Detroit and each other city ; the second included a proposal to set up "regions of good comparability" in order that accurate price ratios might be calculated between countries or cities within each such region. In connection with these various reports and 1 International Labour Review, "A Comparison of t h e Levels of Real Wages in Certain Capital Cities", Volume X , No. 4, Oct. 1924, p p . 630-652, especially 638 et seq. ' Ibid., p. 639. ' International Labour Review, "Comparison of Real Wages in Various Countries", Vol. X X , No. 4, Oct. 1929, pp. 580-588. 4 International Labour Review, An International Comparison of t h e Retail Prices of Certain Important Foodstuffs, July 1929 t o October 1932", Vol. X X V I I , April 1933, pp. 530-538. ' INTERNATION AI. LABOUR O F F I C E : A Contribution to the Study of Internal tional Comparisons of Costs of Living; on Enquiry into the Cost of Living of Certain Groups of Workers in Detroit, U.S.A. and 14 European Towns, Studies and Reports, Series N , Statistics, No. 17, 1932. •INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E : International Comparisons of Cost of Living. A Study of Certain Problems connected with the Making of Index Numbers of Food Costs and of Rents, Studies and Reports, Series N , Statistics, No. 20, 1934. INTRODUCTION 3 studies, furthermore, the recommendations of the International Conferences of Labour Statisticians should be mentioned 1 , as well as the work of the International Labour Office Committee of Statistical Experts. 2 PRICE RATIO FORMULAE The formula for an index number of prices starts from the concept that if the cost of identical quantities of a series of commodities is ascertained in two countries, prices being expressed in terms of a common currency, the ratio between the two costs is the index or average price-ratio desired. If the quantities are represented by q's and the prices by p's, one country designated as the "base" country, being represented by subscript 0, and the second country by the subscript 1, and the symbol 2 represents the sum, this formula, known as Laspeyres', may be given as: p „ 0 2 P!g° 2 PoQo Using the quantities of the second country as weights, another formula, known as "Paasche's formula", may be set up, p 1 = ^Ptfi 2 p0qi The classic formula for the price index ratio is the geometric average between those two ratios, the "ideal" formula of Professor Fisher: V 2 poÇo S PoÇx This formula gives the price ratio between two countries only. Obviously, if price ratios are to be ascertained for each pair of countries in a series of many countries, a considerable amount of calculation is required, depending on the number of countries. 3 'INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: The International Standardisation of Labour Statistics, Studies and Reports, Series N, Statistics, No. 19, 1934, pp. 2123, 32, 57-60. 2 A detailed review of these reports and recommendations, though of great interest in a study of the whole problem of international comparisons of cost of living and of real wages, is not attempted here. See Appendix. • For n countries the number of possible combinations is ••••" . For 19 countries—the figures given later cover 19 countries — there are 171 combinations of countries taken two at a time, or 171 pairs of countries between which price ratios are desired. 24 4 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS The device of averaging 2 indices, each of which has equal claim to be considered accurate, in order to obtain the best single value is obvious enough. The procedure of averaging has this further justification. Since the base for P 0 is the set of average quantities consumed in country 0, this value may itself be considered an average: and if detailed quantity baskets are available for each income or social class or even for each family, a different value of the price ratio would be obtained for each such quantity basket; in other words, P 0 expresses merely an average result. Similarly Pi represents an average price ratio based upon average quantities consumed in the second country. An average of these average results for P 0 and Pl would appear to be a logical extension to obtain a best single value for the price ratio between the two countries. In the usual interpretation, however, these values are considered to be limiting values. The price ratio, P 0 , allows the average dweller of country 0 a sufficient sum to enable him to buy in the second country the identical quantities of the articles consumed by him in the base country. But he may be able to obtain in the second country, for less money than he spent in the base country, a budget of goods that gives him his standard of food consumption—perhaps not precisely the individual quantities of the identical items—which will give him satisfactions equal to those obtained from his customary budget of goods in the base country. If an equal standard of food consumption or equal satisfactions are used as a test for budget equivalence rather than identity of quantities in the two budgets, then P 0 is a maximum for the ratio based on the quantities of country 0, since a budget costing less money, and giving therefore a smaller ratio, may give equal satisfaction in country 1 to that obtained by the budget of the base country. Similarly, if the budget of country 1 be used as the base, 2 p0qÍ7 (the denominator in the fraction P t ) is likewise a maximum and a smaller sum may give equal satisfaction in country 0 to that given by the commodities in country 1. In this case, Pi must be regarded as a minimum limiting value, since the denominator may be replaced by a different and smaller sum that still yields equal satisfactions in both numerator and denominator. If this reasoning is adopted, the further step may be taken. Letting the smallest value of P 0 and the largest value of Pi that give equal satisfaction in numerators and denominators in the price ratio fractions respectively be regarded as the true values—in other words, assuming for example that the true price ratio from the point of view of country 0 is represented by the smallest ratio which will satisfy the test of equal satisfaction in the costs of the commodities 5 INTRODUCTION consumed—and letting the difference between P 0 and the corresponding true value be represented by d0 and between P t and the corresponding true value by di, then the two true values are P0—do and Pi+di. With these two true values, the procedure of averaging to obtain the best single value appears equally appropriate. In order to obtain usable results, in the absence of direct evidence some assumptions as to the relative value of d0 and di may be made. Since neither can be negative, they tend to offset each other; if do equals d t —the simplest hypothesis—the average of the two true values is the same as the average of P 0 and Pi. 1 Another type of average ratio, which uses as weights the arithmetical average of the quantities, is 2 Pi (go + gi) ~ 2 Po (go + gi) In practice this does not differ materially from the result obtained by the formula P = \/p0pt at the range of values commonly found in price ratio comparisons. In a series of tests, for example, the formula using the arithmetical average of the quantities between two countries were found to give results differing only very slightly from those of the Fisher formula; in 5 cases, for example, the largest divergence was only 0.5 per cent, the average difference being only 0.2 per cent. For the practical purpose of computing the price ratio between the two countries, therefore, there is little to choose between the two formulae, and the choice may be influenced by such practical considerations as ease of computation, ease of manipulation, and other points. 2 This formula is of special interest, since if rates are to be calculated for a number of countries, a simple extension gives, for the price ratio between country 1 and country 0: 2 Vl (go + gl + gü + - gn-l) /oi = 2 Po (go + gl + g2 + ... gn-l) 1 If d is the average percentage correction and if d—d*¡=d¡, (1-ri) 2 p. g. / (1-d) 2 Pig. Zp.g", _ . . / I T T r = v \ 2 R Î , S p. 9, (1-d) \ ( l - d ) 2 p „ ? „ SPog> ^ ^ ' The calculation of the effect of substitutions may be regarded as an attempt to determine do and di. See Chapter IV. /= A/2Pig. 1 Bowley offers mathematical proof that the formula •„ ' / ' .—r is the ¿j Po wo "T gl/ best one to take account of the differences in the quantities consumed in the two countries. See A. L. BOWLEY, "Notes on Index Numbers", in Economic Journal, Vol. XXXVIII, 1928, pp. 216-237. 2u 6 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS the formula using as weights for the prices the quantities of the international basket if the q'a cover all the countries in the comparison, or of the regional basket if the q'a cover the countries in a particular region or group. This formula with the quantities of an international basket, i.e., the average of the quantities in the food baskets of all the countries in the comparison, has often been used in making international comparisons. It is analogous to the formula commonly used for price index changes over a period of time, the average quantities over the period being used as fixed weights. It has the great advantage of simplicity, since the ratio of the costs of the international basket in any two countries (in terms of a common price unit, e.g., the Swiss franc, the U.S. dollar) yields the desired price ratio. The formula just described, however, has the obvious defect that in a comparison between two countries, e.g., country 0 and country 1, the quantities taken into account include not only the quantities q0 and qi, for the two countries concerned, but also ?2. Î3 up to çn.i, quantities for other countries. The advantage of having quantities that do not change from country to country as the countries directly compared change, is countered by the disadvantage that the quantities used as weights do not correspond exactly to those of any pair of countries, but differ from these by larger or smaller amounts. The importance of this disadvantage depends in practice, other things being equal, upon the divergences between the international basket and the local baskets. The question may be raised how much of a difference is to be found in practice between the final ratios obtained by means of the international basket method and those reached by a direct calculation of P = y/pQpi between each pair of countries ? To test this point, average quantities for a new international basket, including 18 commodities, were calculated for the 19 countries for which satisfactory price and quantity (family budget) data were available.1 The ratios of food costs thus obtained were then compared with the ratios calculated by using the Fisher formula. The differences between the results of the two series, based on some 70 comparisons—about 2/5ths of the possible combinations —averaged 5 per cent., while in the extreme case, the difference rose to 20 per cent. If the "direct" method—the geometric average of 1 Quantity data were taken from the tables presented in "An International Survey of Recent Family Living Studies: II. Food Expenditure and Consumption Habits", in International Labour Review, Vol. XXXIX, June 1939, p. 81. All the countries covered by that article, except Colombia, are included in the international food basket, and France, Great Britain, and Italy are added. See also Robert M. WOODBURY, "International Comparisons of Food Costs", in International Labour Review, Vol. XLI, Feb. 1941, p. 160, footnote 14. INTRODUCTION 7 P 0 a nd Pi—between each pair of countries, gives a close approximation to the true cost-of-food ratios between them, the international basket method is thus subject to considerable error. Of these two methods, then, the one gives satisfactory results but involves extensive calculations where comparisons between many countries are involved, while the other, though requiring little work, shows large divergences from the true results. METHOD OF REGIONAL BASKETS AND THE PROBLEM OF REGIONS The possibility of an intermediate method having the advantages of both and giving substantially accurate results is suggested by previous work on regional baskets.1 So far as the formula is concerned it is evident that a regional basket formula T S Pi (g» + gl + - g») ~ 2 Po (go + gì + - qù will approach closer to Z pi (go + gi) ~ 2 po (go + gi) the more nearly the average quantities consumed in countries included in the region approach the average of the two countries concerned in the price ratio between them. It is equally clear that the regional basket formula will give better results than the international basket formula if the region includes only countries with closely similar food consumption. In the historical development of the subject it was suggested that a satisfactory price ratio between any two countries of the same region could be obtained if regions were established on the basis of "good comparability". Though the term "regions of good comparability" presents an alluring prospect, the problem of criteria for determining the regions offered difficulties.2 Furthermore, the problem of comparisons between the cities and countries in different regions or outside regions was left in an unsatisfactory state; the very term used to describe the regions tended to suggest that all other ratios were vitiated by "bad comparability", and the specific 1 See INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: International Comparisons of Cost of Living. A Study of Certain Problems Connected with the Making of Index Numbers of Food Costs and of Rents, Studies and Reports, Series N, No. 20. ' Ibid., pp. 31-59. 8 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS suggestion that chain relatives be used to construct ratios between cities in different regions1 was subject to the serious disadvantage that the results varied according to what cities were used as intermediate steps in the chain. The first task in the further analysis of the problem, therefore, was to examine the possible criteria for establishing regions. These include similarity in geographical elements and various tests involving similarity of food consumption. Similarity in Geographical Elements. Similarity in geographical elements including population, climate, language, etc., though an obvious and natural test, for present purposes seems vague and unsatisfactory. On this basis, for example, the' Scandinavian countries of Northern Europe might form a single group, those of Western Europe another, including, e.g., France, Belgium, and the Netherlands, those of Central Europe a third, including Germany, Austria, Czecho-Slovakia, and Switzerland, those of East Central Europe a fourth, including, e.g., Poland and Hungary, and those of Southern Europe a fifth, including Italy, Bulgaria, etc. Unfortunately the allocation of countries like the Netherlands, Switzerland, or Czecho-Slovakia appears arbitrary as between two contiguous groups, since the test does not specify which of the many elements, for example, nationality, language, traditions, income, food habits, is to be accepted as decisive in assigning a country to one or another group. Similarity in Food Consumption. For purposes of establishing regions for comparing food costs a criterion based on similarities of food consumption seems both logical and appropriate. Four tests were examined. A simple test of the level of food consumption can be found by comparing the quantities consumed in each country with a set of standard quantities. The quantities of the international basket give a suitable standard of reference. A simple method of combining the results for different commodities is to use their local prices. Following this plan, table I shows, an index of the level of food consumption as the percentage which the local consumption forms of the average consumption of 18 commodities of the international ' Ibid., pp. 6-7, 9-10, 69-71. 9 INTRODUCTION basket priced in each country at local prices. This shows how representative the international basket is of the local food consumption. On the basis of this index, Italy and Bulgaria appear at the lower end of the scale, not far from Poland and Hungary. Germany, Czecho-Slovakia, Austria, and Switzerland occupy a position in the middle of the range. Finland, Norway, and Sweden are close together well towards the upper end of the scale, with Denmark somewhat higher but not far distant. Countries with unusual positions (as compared with other indices) include Great Britain and the United States, which are both very low, and Belgium, which is unusually high. TABLE I. PERCENTAGE THAT THE COST AT LOCAL PRICES OF THE QUANTITIES CONSUMED LOCALLY BEARS TO THE COST AT LOCAL PRICES OF THE QUANTITIES IN THE INTERNATIONAL BASKET (19 COUNTRIES) OF THE COMMODITIES INCLUDED IN THE INTERNATIONAL BASKET Country Italy Per cent. Country Per cent. 50.8 68.6 74.8 76.5 78.0 101.8 107.2 108.4 111.0 111.9 78.7 80.8 93.6 95.5 96.8 112.1 123.1 123.6 142.7 Union of South Africa An index of the quality of food consumption may be made by comparing the relative consumption of the so-called "protective" foods and the energy-giving foods. Table II illustrates three indices of this type. In the first column the countries are ranked according to the percentage which the "protective foods", together with meats and fish, bear to the sum of these plus the staple foods (all measured in kilograms); in the second column the countries are ranked according to the kilograms consumed per consumption unit of the protective foods, together with meats and fish; while the third gives an average ranking in which double weight is assigned to the first index. In support of these types of index it may be pointed out that the staple foods tend to predominate in budgets where the strictest economy prevails, while relatively much larger proportions of the protective foods, together with meats and fish, are consumed in the upper income classes. The increase in the proportion of the protective foods may therefore be considered to correspond roughly with an increase in the level of living. Likewise 2 ¿ 10 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF POOD COSTS the larger quantities of these protective foods consumed per unit would correspond to higher levels. A combination of the two indices in which the first criterion is given double weight attempts to utilise both these indications. TABLE II. RANK OF COUNTRIES ACCORDING TO THREE CRITERIA OF LEVEL OF FOOD CONSUMPTION • - • • ' I. Percentage of protective foods plus meats and fish to total including staple foods1 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. Switzerland United States Finland Sweden Austria France Norway Union of S.Africa Denmark Great Britain Netherlands Czecho-Slovakia Germany Hungary Estonia Belgium Italy Poland Bulgaria 68 61 59 59 58 56 54 53 51 50 48 48 47 44 40 39 37 31 29 II. Kilograms per consumption unit of protective foods and meat and fish i. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. Switzerland Finland Sweden Netherlands Norway Austria Estonia Germany Belgium South Africa Czecho-Slovakia Denmark France United States Hungary Poland Great Britain Bulgaria Italy 483 416 410 363 357 343 318 303 298 297 286 276 274 267 221 205 192 137 126 II 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. . Weighted average rank of I and II* Switzerland Finland Sweden Austria United States Norway France Union of S. Africa Netherlands Denmark Belgium Germany Czecho-Slovakia Estonia Hungary Great Britain Poland Italy Bulgaria 1 The group of "protective foods, etc." includes milk, milk products, eggs, fresh vegetables and fruits, and meats and fish; the group of staple foods comprises bread and cereals, peas and beans, potatoes, sugar and fats. s The rank of the first column is given twice the weight of that in the second column. In this series of indices Finland and Sweden, together with Switzerland, have the three highest ranks, followed after an interval by Norway and Denmark. The United States has a high position. The countries of Central Europe, Germany, Czechoslovakia, and Hungary are close together in a middle position considerably below the positions of Austria and Switzerland. Italy, Bulgaria, and Poland occupy positions towards the bottom of the scale, somewhat below Estonia. Great Britain is well down on the list. Similarity in Quantities Consumed. An index of quantities consumed can be formed in a similar way to the price ratio P, namely, as the square root of Q0 and Qit as follows: Q = /2 Pogl V 2 po9o S Piqi S piqo 11 INTRODUCTION If Q is equal or nearly equal to 1, the quantities in the two countries compared may be considered roughly equal or at least similar. Table I I I shows the value of Q for a number of pairs of countries. TABLE III. VALUES OF THE QUANTITY RATIO, Q, FOR SELECTED COMPARISONS1 Region and country Q I. Western Europe Belgium/France Netherlands/France Netherlands/Belgium 1.61 1.23 .73 II. Central Europe 1.02 Austria/Germany Switzerland/Germany, ... 1.06 Czecho-Slovakia/Germany .93 1.04 Switzerland/Austria Czecho-Slovakia/Austria.. .93 Czecho-Slovakia/Switzer.89 Q = -.¡2 V» g' Z Region and country III. East Central Europe Estonia/Poland. Hungary /Poland Hungary/Estonia. .. IV. Scandinavian countries Nor way/Sweden.... Denmark/Sweden... Denmark/Norway... Finland/Sweden Finland/Norway.... Finland/Denmark... Q 1.05 .81 .76 .96 1.00 1.07 .92 1.00 .97 P. Q, v 2 Po 9o S Pi Ϋ Quantity indices equal or nearly equal to 1 are found between Denmark and Sweden, Finland and Norway, Finland and Denmark. For Norway/Sweden the index is .96; for Denmark/Norway 1.07; and for Finland/Sweden .92. If regions were formed on the basis of this criterion these Scandinavian countries would appear to constitute a fairly satisfactory region. The index for Estonia/Poland is 1.05, for Hungary-Poland .81, for Hungary/Estonia .76. If this criterion were to be adopted it would obviously be necessary to establish the appropriate limits within which departures from unity could be permitted for countries in the same region. Similarity in Proportionate Quantities Consumed. Another index based upon differences in proportionate quantities consumed is Staehle's index, which varies from zero for perfect similarity to 2 for complete dissimilarity. 1 K = 2 PoÇi Po9o Spoîi SpoÇo 1 See Hans STAEHLE, "A General Method for the Comparison of the Prices of Living", in Review of Economic Studies, Vol. IV, No. 3, June 1937, p. 206. 2 U 12 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF POOD COSTS This index is the sum (taken without regard to sign) of the differences in value weights (proportions) applicable to each commodity in the two countries compared, using however the same prices, i.e., those of the base country, to calculate the value weights. This index differs from Q in that it takes into account not the differences in the quantities consumed but the differences in proportionate consumption. Thus, if in one country twice as much of each item is consumed as in the other, the index Q will give a value of 2 corresponding to the fact that the consumption of one country is twice that of the other, while Staehle's index would give an index of zero, i.e., perfect similarity. The use of Staehle's index would require a considerable volume of calculations, since the value would have to be determined between each pair of countries—with 19 countries, 171 combinations of countries taken two at a time. Also, some decision would be needed on the criterion or limit for excluding a country from a region. The index furthermore varies between income classes. Thus, Staehle gives figures for Poland and Estonia comparing different income groups, showing a variation from .22 to .82 for different combinations of income.1 A general remark is applicable to all these specific criteria of regions, namely, that all the indices assume that the fundamental data on quantities are accurate. In certain cases, however, as suggested perhaps by the differences in rank of a particular country according to different indices, this assumption may be questioned. Thus, for example, the low position of Great Britain in the first test illustrated may be due to the character of the source data. A test based upon proportions, however, is not subject to the same errors as a test based upon absolute quantities. 1 Two other tests are directed to the question of t h e applicability or appropriateness of a comparison of price ratios. These include t h e size of the differences between P» and P i and the percentage of residual articles. I n regard to the first, while it is true t h a t if the quantities consumed in two countries are identical Po and P i coincide, it does not follow that if Po and P i coincide or are close together the quantities of t h e two countries are closely similar. T h e criterion D = (Pi — Po) / Po was developed at length in the study made by the INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E : International Comparisons of Costs of Living, Studies and R e ports, Series N , No. 20, pp. 18-19. Among t h e conditions of good comparability it is stated t h a t "D should have relatively low value". I t is pointed out, however, t h a t even though D may be very small in certain circumstances comparability may be bad. This criterion is therefore not further developed here. The percentage of residual articles is a test of the applicability and significance of the price ratio technique. If none of the articles in the two countries are alike, t h e percentage of the residual articles is 100 and any price comparison is impossible. The lower the percentage of residual articles t h e better t h e price ratio reflects actual conditions and the less scope is allowed for t h e possibility t h a t other prices not covered in the ratio are different from those included, as well as for the possibility t h a t some commodities are entirely different, with t h e result t h a t no price ratios covering them can be calculated. INTRODUCTION 13 A survey of the results of these different tests shows that some method for testing which is the best grouping of countries is necessary. For this purpose the value of P = y/pQpx calculated by the V TI ( rt Vl Kq I rt \ ° **"g , may be used. Though it is not 2 po (ïo + Ci) yet proved that either of these test values is a correct final result, at least they do not favour one grouping as against another. It may be said further that, if the test of the grouping is confined to intragroup ratios, a logical test would be to compare them with ratios based upon the data for two countries only and, as already noted, direct method, or the alternative values, namely P and — — are substan2 po (îo + ?i) tially equal. For the most part objections to these test values as the true value of the price ratio between two countries would apply equally to the regional basket formulae. Hence the use of P as a test for the regions based upon regional basket formulae seems justified. The results of certain of the groupings tentatively made show errors in intra-group ratios of a relatively small amount as compared with the international basket figures. Without proceeding further at this point to present the results of all possible groupings of countries to form regions, certain generalisations may be drawn from this discussion, and the method finally adopted to determine the grouping, namely, the group basket method, together with its results, will be discussed in detail in the following chapter. The following general conclusions may be drawn. First, many of the criteria under review appear to suggest the same or closely similar groupings of countries. In some cases there appears to be little to choose between alternative allocations of certain countries. For purposes of grouping countries to yield food price ratios a grouping based upon the data of food consumption appears logically preferable to one based upon other criteria. Proportional quantities offer a better basis of grouping than absolute quantities, since it can be shown that proportional rather than absolute quantities affect food price ratios and since the use of proportions tends to avoid the consequences of certain defects in the original data. Finally, as a consequence of the assumption that P can be used as a test of the regional grouping, the whole problem can be viewed from a different angle. From this point of view the use of regions may be envisaged as a short-cut method of calculating the value of P in n (n-l)/2 ratios in a series of n countries, by interposing a series of groups with the objective of diminishing the volume of calculations. The problem then becomes, how can the 2 ¿ 14 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS countries be grouped in such a way as to reduce errors in the approximate values, P', to the minimum, and the final question is then raised, are the results of the approximation sufficiently close to the true results to justify the use of the approximation? With this approach, the true criterion of grouping becomes that which reduces the differences between the P"s and the P's to a minimum and the problem of making comparisons between countries in different groups is immediately resolved by using the geometric average of the ratios formed with the respective group baskets instead of the local baskets as the weights.1 The group basket method is described in the next chapter. 1 A proposal for comparisons within regions by means of the relative costs of the regional basket and for comparisons between regions by means of the Fisher formula was outlined in a brief memorandum by John Lindberg, then a member of the Statistical Section of the Office, prepared for submission to the Fourth Conference of Labour Statisticians in May 1931. CHAPTER I THE GROUP BASKET METHOD The basic formula for the food price ratio, as already discussed, is the geometric average of P 0 and F 1 ( P 0 representing the average food price ratio weighted by the quantities of country 0, that is, using the food basket of country 0, and P t the average food price ratio weighted by the quantities of country 1, that is, using the food basket of country 1. The essential feature of the Group Basket Method is the use of the basket of the group to which each country is allocated as a substitute for the local basket, the group basket being sufficiently similar to that of each of the countries in the group to permit of its use for each local basket without impairing the substantial accuracy of the results. The group basket formula for the food price ratio between country 0 and country 1 is found by substituting the group basket for the local basket in the formula P - . Is pl q° S P l g l \ S Po ço S pogi If country 0 belongs to Group A and country 1 to Group B, and if P' is used to denote the price ratio obtained by means of the group basket method, then p, _ p Pi QA S pi qB V S po çA S pò ÇB It remains to show by what method satisfactory groups can be formed, and within what limits in practice errors are introduced by substituting the group baskets for the local baskets. FORMATION OF GROUPS The basic problem then is the formation of groups the baskets of which can be used without substantial loss of accuracy for the respective local baskets. Obviously, if two countries, or regions or cities have identical food consumption, the basket of one can be substituted for that of the other without affecting the food price ratio. Further, if the quantities in the basket of one country are equal to those in the basket of the other times a constant factor, the 2 4 16 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS food consumption not being identical but having "similar proportions", the food price ratio will not be altered by the substitution of one basket for the other. 1 Even if the baskets are not identical, if the differences between them are not great, no large error will be introduced into the calculation by substituting one for the other, or by substituting for the local basket a group basket with similar food consumption. The principle to be adopted in establishing groups, therefore, is similarity of proportionate food consumption. Proportions rather than actual amounts consumed are significant, since the baskets of two countries which have the same proportions of the different foods though differing absolute quantities can be interchanged without affecting food price ratios. In order to determine proportions, however, some method must be devised to eliminate the influence of varying prices upon the proportions that different foods form of the food budget in different countries. In order to test practicable methods for grouping countries, the basic data available for 18 commodities in 19 countries were utilised. 2 Three methods for determining the grouping of countries were tried. In the first two, a set of standard price factors was applied to the quantities of the different foods to afford a basis for calculating proportions. In the first and simplest method, median prices were utilised as the standard prices. All prices (October 1938 prices) were converted into Swiss francs, at the exchange rates as of October 1938. For each food, the median price—among the 19 countries in the series—was taken as the standard. These prices were multiplied by the quantities in the different countries, and the resulting values were reduced to percentages devoted to the different foods and food groups. In the second method, the price of each food in each country was expressed in terms of the price of bread in the same country, and the median ratio—among the 19 countries—of the price of each food in terms of the price of bread was taken as the standard price factor for that food. These standard price factors were multiplied by the actual consumption of the different foods in each country and the result summed and reduced to a percentage basis; the 1 Let ci = aq¡, and po = pi Then /., = J2_£l£° S ? " ? ' V S po Co S Po gJ ^ S Pi Ci S pi q> ' For basic data see chapter I I I . a Z P» go S p « g « V a S po go S Po g« = Itt THE GBOTJP BASKET METHOD 17 result giving figures of "proportionate consumption" into which varying prices in the different countries do not enter. In the third method—which in fact was the first one actually carried through—the consumption of each food in each country was noted in terms of the range: the interval between minimum and maximum consumption in any country in the series was divided into scale units from 0 to 100, and the consumption of a given food in a given country was rated to the nearest scale unit: for example, 50, if it fell half way between the lowest and highest points. These scale ratings were then averaged for four groups of foods: bread and cereals, meats, milk and milk products, and all other: in averaging, the ratings for the different foods were weighted in proportion to average values. These weighted average indices for the four groups were then summed and reduced to proportions on a scale of 10. In all these methods, as a final result, the food consumption of each country is epitomised in a series of key figures adding up to 10 which show the proportionate consumption of the different foods. In these proportionate consumption figures, the influence of price variations in different countries is eliminated. All these methods led to the same grouping of countries, although the percentages themselves varied according to the particular method used. The method of allocating the countries to groups is illustrated in table IV, which gives thefiguresof proportionate food consumption in the four food groups as calculated by the first method—that of using median prices. The table also gives a column showing the sum of deviations, in tenths of a point, of the key figures for each country from the key figures of the group in which it is placed. This furnishes a convenient test of the allocation of countries to groups; the best allocation should yield a minimum sum of deviations.1 With 19 groups—one country to each group—the deviations are of course zero, and the P"s coincide with the P's. With the number of groups fixed at less than the number of countries, however, allocations, in principle, can be made to groups in such a way as to yield a minimum sum of deviations; in other words, the allocation is not dependent upon arbitrary judgments. So far as the number of groups is concerned, the decision depends, first upon how closely the different countries can be grouped along definite lines: if all countries follow closely parallel lines of food consumption, a single group—the international basket—might 1 Without regard to sign; substantially the same result is found if the "sum of the squared deviations a minimum" is used as the test. 2 4 18 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS give a satisfactory result. Secondly, the decision depends on the balance between the accuracy of the result and the volume of calculations : the more groups the less error but the greater is the volume of calculation. In final analysis, it depends upon the degree of error which can be accepted as not invalidating or too greatly impairing the value of the results. TABLE IV. CLASSIFICATION OF COUNTRIES INTO GROUPS, ACCORDING TO SIMILARITY OF PROPORTIONATE CONSUMPTION Group and country Bread and cereals Meat Milk products Miscellaneous S Idi1 Group I Bulgaria Italy Group II Estonia Hungary Poland Group III Belgium Czecho-Slovakia.... Germany Netherlands Norway Group IV Austria Denmark France Great Britain Union of South Africa Group V United States Group VI Finland Sweden Switzerland 5.0 4.9 5.1 2.0 2.5 1.6 2.0 1.5 2.5 2.5 1.3 1.2 3.6 3.4 3.6 3.8 1.9 1.7 1.7 2.2 2.5 2.5 2.0 1.0 1.2 .8 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.0 2.1 .7 A 1.0 2.2 1.8 2.5 2.4 3.3 4.1 .5 1.3 .5 .1 1.7 2.0 1.7 3.2 1.7 1.8 1.6 5.8 1.1 2.4 .8 .3 1.2 1 3.8 2.3 2.5 3.8 1.1 3.7 2.0 2.3 1.4 2.4 2.0 1.9 1.3 2.3 4.2 2.2 5.1 5.0 4.8 5.4 2.1 2.1 2.6 1.6 Sum of the deviations from the group average taken without regard to sign. In practice the test used, namely, the sum of the deviations a minimum, does not correlate perfectly with the true criterion, which is that the sum of the differences between the P"s and the P's must be a minimum. In the true criterion, the correlation between the deviations of the q's and the deviations of the p's from their respective averages is a vital element in determining how closely the P"s approach the P's, whereas in the simple test adopted THE GBOUP BASKET METHOD 19 here for determining the grouping of countries this correlation finds no expression. Furthermore, as developed above, the test has been simplified to show deviations from the key figures for four groups of foods only, whereas a more detailed test would take into account each of the 18 food items. On the other hand, in so far as two or more items have the same or nearly the same price ratio, grouping them together gives a better test than if each one is taken separately, since the final price ratio is affected by the variation of this total quantity associated with a given price ratio and variations in the components of this total quantity cancel out. The allocation to groups as made in table IV seems reasonable enough, with the exception of Denmark, for which the sum of deviations from the average of Group IV is unusually high. In fact, the sum of deviations would be slightly smaller if Denmark were assigned to Group V with the United States, or if it were placed alone in Group V, the United States being assigned to Group IV. The allocation to Group V was made on the basis of method III, (which was the method first tried) which indicated a much better result with Denmark assigned to Group IV. The method of allocation is perhaps not sufficiently precise in any case to warrant too great attention to small differences in the criterion. An examination in more detail of the deviations when all the items instead of the four groups only were used indicated that the allocation of Denmark to Group IV was slightly better. A final test by comparing P"a with P'a showed that the United States alone in Group V gave slightly better results than with both Denmark and the United States in Group V, perhaps partly because with a single country alone in a group, all the P 0 ' s involving that country are correct, and the deviations are limited to the Pi ratios alone. Attention should be called to the fact that the allocations are made on the basis of the 18 commodities. If additional commodities are included the proportions, for example of fruits and vegetables, might be increased more in some countries than in others, and a new grouping based on more complete data might well differ in some respects from that adopted here. In view of this possibility, too much weight should not be given to the present allocation, since it is bound up with the limitation to 18 commodities and cannot be considered necessarily as a grouping that would be obtained if full data were available. The conclusion is nevertheless justified that with a given set of quantities, a definite allocation of countries to their groups can be made and for practical purposes the simple test here used, based on four food groups with the sum of deviations from the group averages a minimum, appears to yield a satisfactory result. 2 4 20 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS Once the grouping has been established, the method of diagnosis adopted has no effect whatever upon the price ratios. The ratios depend solely upon the quantities of the group baskets and the prices in the different countries. This point deserves special attention, since objections to and criticisms of the details of the method of diagnosis do not affect the final results. On the basis of the figures of table IV, the characterisation of the groups by the method of diagnosis in terms of the key figures for the four food groups is as follows : Group Bread and cereals Meat Milk, etc. I. II. III. IV. V. VI. 5.0 3.6 2.2 2.0 1.3 1.6 2.0 1.9 1.5 2.5 2.3 1.3 2.0 2.3 3.8 3.6 4.2 5.1 Miscellaneous 1.0 2.2 2.4 2.0 2.2 2.1 The groups are arranged in general in order of descending importance for the bread and cereals group and in order of ascending importance for milk and milk products. Group III, however, has a larger weighting of milk and milk products than IV. Group VI has a slightly higher consumption of bread and cereals than Group V, but is chiefly characterised by the very large consumption of milk and milk products. Group IV has the largest weighting of meats. The difficulty of allocating certain countries to the appropriate group is, in essence, due to the fact that in some cases they occupy intermediate positions in the relative consumption of different foods. T H E GROUP BASKETS The grouping of the countries having been established, a group basket is calculated for each group by averaging the quantities consumed per unit in the different countries in the group. 1 These quantities are given in table V for the six group baskets ; covering the 18 commodities for which adequate price and consumption data are available. 2 * An alternative procedure of averaging not the quantities but the percentages of total value (as found by multiplying quantities by the standard prices) did not prove on the basis of a test to give superior final results to those reached by use of simple average of the quantities. 1 Details of sources, etc., given in chapter III. 21 THE GROUP BASKET METHOD T A B L E V. . . . . ..... _.. ._ Item THE S I X GKOUP B A S K E T S 1 Group Group II Group III Group IV Group V Group VI 170.8 33.6 5.1 3.2 42.9 115.3 31.5 4.3 0.6 5.4 8.6 5.0 1.3 10.5 8.0 2.9 1.3 56.0 31.6 26.6 5.2 1.1 15.5 9.9 4.2 5.3 40.2 7.5 16.3 6.7 Beef Pork Mutton Veal 76.5 55.0 20.1 2.4 1.1 12.9 7.4 1.0 1.8 24.3 6.9 6.4 4.4 35.0 20.7 50.3 3.8 3.4 8.2 9.6 0.2 3.0 Lard Margarine 2.8 3.7 1.1 2.0 10.7 2.3 4.9 6.5 0.0 0.9 5.6 Milk (litres) Cheese Butter Eggs (no.) 28.9 5.1 0.8 88.5 172.6 5.6 7.0 166.4 110.8 4.1 8.0 169.2 Peas, beans Potatoes Sugar 7.6 23.7 7.4 0.4 115.9 0.7 2.7 48.0 3.7 159.9 23.2 1.1 2.7 149.4 21.4 3.6 3.6 68.6 27.3 2.9 152.1 4.4 11.9 326.0 7.4 88.9 31.6 5.5 284.5 4.8 11.7 158.0 1.5 98.4 33.2 5.1 Wheaten bread Rye bread Flour Rice Macaroni 1 Group I: Bulgaria and Italy; group II: Estonia, Hungary, and Poland; group III: Belgium, Csecho-Slovakia, Germany, Netherlands, and Norway; group IV: Austria, Denmark, France, Great Britain, and Union of South Africa; group V: United States; group VI: Finland, Sweden, and Switzerland. Quantities in kilograms, except milk (litres) and eggs (number). METHOD OF CALCULATING RATIOS Having the group baskets for the six groups and the price data for the 19 countries for October 1938, the calculation of ratios according to the group basket method involves five operations. First, the prices for each country are multiplied by each of the group baskets, and the result summed to give for each country the total cost, Spg, for each group basket at local prices. Secondly, these sums are converted to a common currency (Swiss francs) by using exchange ratios for the period to which the prices relate. Thirdly, P 0 ' and i Y are calculated for each pair of countries using the group baskets appropriate to each case.1 1 Here and subsequently Po and Pi are used to denote ratios with quantity weights of the denominator country and of the numerator country respectively; similarly c<¡ and ct are used for correction factors to P, and P, ratios with weights of the denominator country and of the numerator country respectively. 2 6 22 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS Fourthly, P 0 ' and Pi' are averaged geometrically to give P'. Finally, as will be explained later (pp. 23-24), correction factors are calculated and applied to P ' to give the final corrected ratios Though the primary concern of the present exposition is to discuss methods, the fact remains that the simplest and clearest way to describe the method is to illustrate its application to specific data. Accordingly, results of applying the method are presented for the 18 commodities and 19 countries with prices as of October 1938. Incidentally, the question of the size of errors due to the group basket method can be presented in equally concrete terms by comparison with the results obtained by the direct calculation of P using the same data. In this procedure, the quantities and prices are accepted as given, and the question of errors in either the basic quantities or prices is waived for present purposes (they are discussed later in chapter III). RESULTS The results of the first two operations can be illustrated in table VI, which gives the cost of each of the six baskets in each country expressed as a percentage of the cost in Great Britain. This calculation, though not required in the process of obtaining the ratio is of rather more significance than the actual values as expressed in Swiss francs, since the actual values are influenced by the arbitrary levels of the quantities of the different baskets. By expressing the results in the form of a ratio of the cost of each basket in each country to the corresponding cost in Great Britain, the general relationship existing between the several baskets can be presented. These results give also the necessary data for calculating the desired price ratios (uncorrected data) between each pair of countries, as well as the actual costs of the baskets themselves. For any given ratio, for example, Italy/Great Britain, P 0 ' is found from the table as the ratio for Group IV of Italy and Great Britain (119.8), Pi' as the ratio for Group I of Italy and Great Britain (123.6) and P ' is then found by taking the geometric average of these two ratios. 23 THE GROUP BASKET METHOD TABLE VI. RELATIVE COST OF STANDARD BASKETS IN NINETEEN COUNTRIES, OCTOBER 1938 1 {Great Britain = 100) Country Basket I Basket II Basket III 285.3 Austria 178.9 176.1 102.6 Belgium 89.9 85.0 78.7 Bulgaria 91.9 90.9 94.7 Czecho-Slovakia... 137.8 88.5 86.2 90.8 Denmark 86.7 103.8 63.3 143.0 Estonia 63.3 91.9 83.1 Finland 84.5 217.6 75.3 79.7 France 100.0 153.1 152.6 Germany 130.0 100.0 100.0 Great Britain 123.6 109.5 124.7 122.4 Hungary 157.5 107.8 114.4 Italy 94.0 97.6 101.2 Netherlands 149.8 109.2 110.7 Norway 128.5 75.5 72.8 122.9 Poland 148.3 104.1 116.4 Sweden 105.1 111.3 Switzerland 1 Unionof Africa 116.8 128.0 by exchange These South ratios are in many cases affected United States.... Czecho-Slovakia, Denmark, Estonia, Germany, and 126.9 143.5 Italy, Basket IV Basket V 183.1 99.1 91.2 92.1 167.3 92.7 64.9 84.5 81.6 164.0 100.0 132.0 119.8 101.9 113.5 79.1 106.6 120.1 112.6 restrictions, Poland. 126.9 Basket VI 153.8 81.2 91.4 87.7 90.0 80.3 88.8 81.4 58.6 55.2 73.7 67.3 75.5 71.7 154.3 136.4 100.0 100.0 .1 128.1 118.0 .3 111.8 101.2 .6 97.2 89..4 104.6 95..3 74.1 69..5 113.0 94.3 85. 117.0 98. as103.9 in Austria,105. Bulgaria, 113.7 94.3 CORRECTION FACTORS A comparison of these group basket P0"s for a considerable sample of ratios with the P 0 's as found by direct calculation reveals that the latter are in a great majority of cases in excess of the former. A reasonable explanation appears to be that when the ratios—using any two countries designated as 0 and 1, country 0 being in Group A— and — ^ - ^ are compared, the com2 Po 9A 2 po Ço bination of local quantities with local prices gives the best economic adjustment, that is the lowest relative cost, with the result that the ratio in which the best adjustment figures, e.g., always the fVs> is higher than its substitute ratio. Whether or not this explanation of the differences is applicable, correction factors to correct for the differences can be calculated and the final results will be somewhat better than the uncorrected ratios. The correction factor to be applied to a ratio using a particular country, say country 0, as base is obviously equal to the average ratio of all the group basket P0"s and the direct calculation PQ'a using that country as base. This average ratio of all the group basket P 0 "s and the direct calculation P0's can be computed 2 ¿ 24 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS without recourse to the lengthy process of first deriving all the P 0 's, by the use of the product sum of prices and quantities using average prices over all the countries in the comparison (the average taken after conversion to a common currency). Let Co be the correction factor to be applied to all the P 0 "s using country 0 as the base S Po' Co = S Po The numerator is S P„' = (^^ + * £ » £ + ï a L * +... ^ 2 ± l A VSpoÎA 2po£ (S Pi ÇA 2 Po ÇA S Po ÇA S Po ÇA / + S P2 ?A + 2 V» 5* + - 2 Pn-1 ÎA) But (2 pi qA + Sp 2 «A +••• 2 pa.t qA) + 2p0qA=> n2 p a v q A where p . is the average price. Likewise 2 P 0 - £ * * + * * * + * J Ü * + ... ^ ± A \ 2 po ?o 2 po <Zo 2 po Co 2 p 0 go / (2 pi go + 2 j>¿ q0 + 2 ps 9o +— 2 Pn-i ?o)2 po go (S pi g0 + 2 p 2 g0 + . . . 2 p n .i g0) + 2 p 0 g0 = n 2 p 8V g0 Hence, substituting these values = (w 2 p a v gA - 2 po gA) (2 po g0) (2 po qA) (n 2 p a v g0 - 2 p 0 go) The corresponding correction factors for the P / ' s for the base country may be derived from those for the P 0 "s of the numerator 1 2 pi Ci country, because they are reciprocal : — = 2 p 0 Ci 2 Po gì 2 pi gì To calculate these correction factors requires, besides the data already described, the following additional elements: (1) the set of average prices (after conversion to a common currency); (2) the product sum of each group basket by these average prices; and (3) the product sum of each local basket by local prices. The correction factors for P' are represented by the formula c = VcoTiTable VII gives the final ratios obtained by the use of the group basket method, including the correction factors. The results for P 0 ' and P\ and the correction factors are given in the appendix. TABLE VII. FOOD PRICE RATIOS CALCULATED BY GROUP B A S K E T METHOD, AFTER BASED ON BASKETS OF 1 8 FOOD COMMODITIES I N N I N E T E E N COUNTRIES N u m e r a t o r country Denominator country Austria Belgium Bul- Czecho Dengaria Slomark vakia Estonia Austria Belgium Bulgaria Czecho-Slovakia Denmark.. 1.00 1.94 2.64 1.91 2.00 .52 1.00 1.09 .94 1.02 .38 .92 1.00 .91 .78 .52 1.06 1.10 1.00 1.04 .50 .98 1.29 .97 1.00 Estonia Finland France Germany Great Britain 2.79 2.23 2.27 1.12 1.84 1.38 1.11 1.20 .55 .93 1.06 .86 1.01 .47 .87 1.44 1.16 1-21 .59 .94 1.36 1.13 1.14 .56 .92 Hungary Italy Netherlands Norway Poland 1.40 1.85 1.78 1.61 2.38 .70 .81 .87 .79 1.18 .68 .64 .82 .66 1.05 .73 .81 .92 .83 i:23 .68 .90 .90 .81 1.16 .51 .68 .64 .58 .88 Sweden 1.71 Switzerland 1.53 Union of South Africa 1.61 1.41 United States .82 .81 .80 .73 .73 .75 .73 .65 .90 .85 .81 .75 .91 .78 .80 .72 .58 .56 .53 .47 Ger- Great Finland France many Britain Hungary Ita .45 .90 1.16 .86 .89 .44 .84 .99 .83 .88 .89 1.81 2.14 1.71 1.77 .54 1.07 1.15 1.06 1.09 .71 1.43 1.48 1.37 1.46 .5 1.2 1.5 1.2 1.1 1.00 1.27 .79 1.00 .81 1.00 .41 .51 .65 .76 1.23 1.00 1.00 .48 .81 2.42 1.94 2.07 1.00 1.61 1.53 1.31 1.23 .62 1.00 1.94 1.61 1.62 .81 1.30 1.4 1.1 1.4 .6 1.2 .62 .87 .80 .74 1.00 .62 .69 .77 .70 1.05 1.23 1.58 1.57 1.42 2.08 .77 .81 .98 .89 1.30 1.00 1.07 1.25 1.14 1.70 .9 1.0 1.1 .9 1.4 .77 .68 .69 .60 .77 .69 .71 .62 1.50 1.42 1.38 1.25 1.01 .90 .87 .80 1.19 1.15 1.07 .96 .9 1.0 1.0 .8 .36 .73 .94 .70 .73 1 The differences between these price ratios and those published in the article in the February 1941 Internationa factor; in addition revised quantities (wheat and rye bread) were used for Groups I I and VI baskets and revised 26 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS ERRORS OF THE GROUP BASKET METHOD What are the errors attaching to these results? These are given full discussion in subsequent chapters so far as concerns the basic data (chapter III); in the present chapter the error due solely to the use of the group basket in place of the local basket is considered, as shown by comparing the result obtained with the group basket formula for P' with that obtained by using the formula for P. The comparison shows that the (corrected) group basket ratios averaged within 1.4 (1.39) per cent, of the ratios calculated by means of the formula for P. The average error, on the other hand, of the P's without the use of the correction factor is 1.7 (1.74) per cent. (These calculations were made using figures in which bread was considered a single item with a single price.) The extreme errors are also of interest. Using the corrected ratios, the largest deviation found was 5 per cent, in two cases out of 342 ratios. For countries in the same group the errors are somewhat less. For the 54 comparisons the average error is only 1.28 per cent., as compared with 1.41 per cent, for those outside the same groups. The uncorrected figures show slightly greater divergencies: 1.40 per cent, for countries in the same group as compared with 1.80 per cent, for countries in différent groups. These results throw light upon the average errors associated with the method itself. These average errors are well within the margin of error, as will be shown in later chapters, associated with the prices and quantities and other sources of inexactness in the price ratios. The group basket method thus appears to offer an acceptable technique for international or interregional comparison of food prices. The somewhat artificial limitations imposed for purposes of testing the method as method will be discarded in the subsequent chapters. Chapter II will discuss the significance of the results obtained in terms of the actual cities and countries compared and will consider methods of application to other cities, geographical areas, national groups, and specific economic classes. Chapter III will be devoted to problems of prices and quantities and their attending errors. Chapter IV, finally, treats of the problem of substitutions and the differences between the cost-of-food ratio obtained by substitutions and the food price ratio found by the Fisher formula and the group basket method. CHAPTER II APPLICATIONS The discussion in the preceding chapter has been artificially simplified to throw into relief the problems and procedure of the group basket method, and especially the errors associated with the method itself. The present chapter will treat of the applications of the method to the various specific cities and countries, and to different economic and other groups. The problem is to find an average ratio between prices in two different markets which expresses the difference in the cost of food, having regard to the differing habits and standards of food consumption in the two markets. There are thus two elements in the comparison: the prices, which are characteristic of a market, and the habits of food consumption, which may be considered to be characteristic of a population group. In the foregoing discussion of method, the term "country" has been used for both these concepts. In considering the significance of the results, these concepts must now be clarified. I. CITIES The prices for a given "country" are in fact actually the average prices for one or more cities in that country. In many cases, they are averages for a number of the larger cities (omitting metropolitan cities). The cities used as a basis foT the price calculations in each country are given in the accompanying list. LIST OF CITIKS Country Austria - Belgium - Bulgaria - Czecho-Slovakia Denmark - Estonia - Finland - France - - Germany - - - Cities Vienna Brussels Sofia, Plovdiv Brno, Bratislava Copenhagen Tartu, Tallinn Helsinki Bordeaux, Lille, Lyons, Nancy, Marseilles Hamburg, Breslau, Leipzig, Cologne, Munich 2 i, 28 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS Country Great Britain - Cities - Birmingham, Bristol, Glasgow, Leeds, Manchester, Newcastle Hungary . . . - Budapest Italy - - - - - Florence, Genoa, Milan, Trieste, Turin Netherlands - - - Amsterdam, The Hague, Rotterdam, Utrecht Norway - - - - Oslo Poland - - - - - Catowice, Lodz, Poznan Sweden - - - - Göteborg, Malmö, Stockholm Switzerland . . . Geneva, Basle, Berne, Zurich Union of South Africa Cape Town, Witwatersrand United States - - - Baltimore, Boston, Denver, Los Angeles, New Orleans, Philadelphia, St. Louis, San Francisco - In fact, therefore, price ratios are not between two countries, but between prices in the cities in the two countries respectively which are used as the basis of calculating average prices. In principle, each city has its own price data. Grouping of cities is subject to the condition that the prices of the group of cities present a significant average : this is reasonably true for cities of a given size range within a country or currency area where conditions of food supply are not too different. Applications to Other Cities. The results obtained for these cities or groups of cities may be extended to other cities by applying suitable conversion factors. If the price ratio is sought between a particular city in one country and the group of cities in another country used as the basis of the calculations in the table, the conversion factor to be used is the price ratio between the particular city and the group of cities in the same country which was used for the table. By multiplying by these appropriate conversion factors the price ratios in the table can be converted into price ratios for the particular city. 1 Thus if i For instance, suppose the price ratio Berlin/Vienna is sought. The table gives the price ratio Germany/Austria, where Germany is represented by 5 German cities and Austria by Vienna. The ratio Berlin/Vienna can be obtained by means of the price ratios Berlin/5 German cities, used as a conversion factor. The price ratio Berlin/5 German cities is found for each of the six group baskets, by multiplying each basket by the prices of Berlin and of the 5 German cities. Conversion factors for the six groups are then calculated by taking the geometric average of the ratio of Berlin/5 German cities for Group III (Germany) on the one hand and for each of the other groups on the other. The particular conversion factor required is that which uses weights corresponding to the groups covered in the particular ratio. Then, for the ratio Berlin/Vienna, the conversion factor for use is the geometric average of the price ratio Berlin/5 German cities with Group III and Group IV weights. In practice the conversion factors differ but slightly; thus the six conversion factors for Berlin/5 German cities are 0.981, 1.008, 1.003, 1.001, 1.000 and 1.006. In this case the prices of Berlin are substantially similar to those of the 5 German cities. A similar calculation of the price ratios, New York/8 American cities gives the six conversion factors: 1.078. 1.070, 1.075, 1.075, 1.074 and 1.083. APPLICATIONS 29 price ratios for metropolitan cities or for small cities or for rural areas are desired, the technique just indicated can be used to develop price ratios between these and cities in other countries a8 presented in the table. Applications to Cities in Other Countries. Cities in a country not included in the original list can be added to the scheme of food price ratios under the following conditions. If the new country has food consumption habits similar to those of one of the groups already established, price ratios can be calculated by using this group basket in conjunction with the prices of the additional cities. In practice, they can be calculated by using conversion factors in the manner just described, to substitute the new cities for those of one of the countries in the group with which the new country is assimilated. If the cities in the new country have consumption habits that do not accord with those of any of the groups already established, a new group must be set up and the necessary additions of the new prices and the new quantities made to the several basic tables. II. POPULATION GROUPS The application of the group basket method to population groups implies that the habits of food consumption represented by the basket are characteristic of the particular group. In the discussion of the preceding chapter, the term "country" has been used as if habits of food consumption were characteristic of the country. Types of food consumption within a country are doubtless largely determined by national habits and characteristics, or by the conditions of demand and supply. The validity of such a generalisation or the limits to its validity in any specific case must be established by evidence. One principal exception is where two nationalities or race groups, with differing food consumption habits, occupy the same area, in which case the national or racial food consumption habits may conceivably exert a sufficiently important influence to suggest the need for more than one local basket or basket type for that area; on the other hand, local conditions of supply may in fact be of sufficient importance to mask any effect of differing race customs. Another influence is that of economic or social class; if these different economic classes have markedly differing food habits 2 ¿ 30 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS —not merely differing absolute amounts but a differing composition of the diets—more than one local basket or basket type for a single area may be needed. In the next section, the effect of differences in habits of food consumption in differing economic classes upon food price ratios is examined in detail. III. ECONOMIC GROUPS The problem of economic groups is important only if consumption varies with economic position, and only to the extent that such changes in consumption produce an effect upon the price ratio. If consumption varies with economic position in a community, then when prices are weighted successively with quantities consumed in the different economic groups, a series of Po's are obtained which differ in accordance with the effect of these changes in consumption: hence the price ratios between these economic groups and any given group in another region or country will also vary. (a) Changes in Consumption in Different Economic Groups. To what extent is consumption affected by changes in economic position ? An analysis of changes in consumption with changes in income is presented for certain foodstuffs in an article on Food Expenditure and Consumption Habits in the International Labour Review for June 1939. * This shows changes in absolute quantities consumed; for purposes of the present problem, differential changes in quantities consumed affecting different foodstuffs differently are important, while changes affecting all items uniformly have no effect upon price ratios. A table showing the indices of relative change in quantities consumed, with changes in income per consumption unit, is reproduced below: the varying importance of these changes is indicated by the change of sign as affecting the different foodstuffs, and the change in degree as indicated by the varying size of the indices. In general, the change in income—100 per cent.— used as the unit is relatively large—in a number of countries, in the range of incomes shown in wage earning families, the average income in the highest income group is only about double that of the 1 Part II of An International Survey of Recent Family Living Studies. APPLICATIONS 31 lowest group, so that in such cases the percentage change in consumption shown in the table corresponds to the change from the lowest to the highest income groups among the wage-earning families. (b) Diagnosis of Consumption in Different Economic Groups. In terms of the method of diagnosis used in chapter I for classifying countries in groups, however, differences in consumption in different income groups are not especially great. Data were available for eight countries, including Estonia and Poland of Group II, Belgium, Czecho-Slovakia, Germany, and Norway of Group III, Denmark of Group IV and Switzerland of Group VI. The results show in general that while in most cases all economic groups are classified in the same group as the average for the country as a whole, a slight tendency appears in some cases for the lowest economic group to approach halfway towards a lower consumption group, and the upper economic groups to approach halfway towards one of the higher consumption groups. In detail, for the two countries of Group II, all the economic groups of Estonia are classed in Group II, and likewise all in Poland, except that in the last mentioned country the lowest income group occupied an intermediate position between I and II and might be assigned to either. In respect of the bread and cereals consumption alone, the lowest income group is fairly close to Group I, while the highest income group is halfway between Groups II and III; but when all food groups are considered the highest income group is very much closer to Group II than to any of the others. For the countries of Group III, in the case of Norway all income groups are best allocated to Group III. In the case of Belgium, the two lowest income groups are best allocated to Group III, while the two highest can be equally well assigned to Group III or Group IV. The four lowest income groups of Germany are definitely allocated to Group III, while the highest income group might be assigned to Group VI, Group V or Group III, the sum of the deviations being respectively 12, 13 and 14. In the case of Czecho-Slovakia, the two lowest income classes fall to Group III, while the two highest income classes appear to belong to either IV or V, although the advantage of such an assignment over an allocation to Group III is not great. For Denmark, the only country of Group IV for which the test was made, the original allocation to Group IV was in doubt, since it appeared to be assignable equally well to Group V. Of the five income classes, one, the highest, would be Group IV; two, the lowest 2 u TABLE VIII. INDICES OF RELATIVE CHANGES IN QUANTITIES OF SPECIFIC FOODS C WITH CHANGES IN INCOME PER CONSUMPTION UNIT IN Item Bread Meat and fish Belgium Colombia Czechoslovakia Finland Germ -10.9 104.4 -15.4 43.2 -1 -10.1 149.8 - 6.0 -0.1 - 75.9 182.4 56 6 57.2 .5 - 9.6 -4.1 -2 30.3 41.0 3 119.7 5 Fats -^7.7 Milk 29.7 227.4 Cheese 90.6 197.7 104.3 218.3 60.8 40.4 13 106.8 410.1 58.7 114.6 9 - 3.6 121.8 -15.8 20.3 Butter , Eggs. Potatoes , 2 17.5 Sugar 45.8 - 122.1 - 2.3 42.0 1 1 With 100 per cent, increase in income per consumption unit the index shows the percentage of change in quan * Wage earners and lower officials' families. APPLICATIONS 33 and the next highest, are equally good with either IV or V, and the other two appear to go better with Group V. Finally, with Switzerland, the only country in Group VI, analysed by income classes, all the income groups are assignable to Group VI. (c) Group Basket Method as Adapted to Economic Groups. In cases where the several economic groups are assigned to the same group as the average for the country as a whole, the price ratio obtained for each economic group by the group basket method will be the same as that for the country as a whole: in other words, the difference in consumption as income changes is ignored in calculating ratios. This does not prove that in calculating the P 0 and Pi by the direct method, differences in results would not appear if the actual quantities consumed in the different economic classes were used in calculations. These differences, however, are merely too small to be revealed by the group basket method. Where, for a particular economic class the diagnosis reveals a position, e.g., halfway between Groups III and IV, a close approach to P might be reached by using an average of these two baskets for the group basket corresponding to the base country. Thus, for the upper income levels of Czechoslovakia, a better result might be obtained by using average ratios calculated from group-baskets III and IV for P 0 , and for Pi the ratio indicated by the basket for the group in which the other country or the particular economic class of the other country falls. This point needs to be tested in practice to determine whether such a device gives any substantial increase in accuracy. Two final considerations are suggested. First, the negative conclusion just reached that, in general, changes in consumption as income changes do not produce substantial differences in the price ratio, does not prove that this conclusion is true for all countries, since in some countries such changes in consumption may be -more substantial. The question must then be kept open and when economic position is shown to be important, the method of calculating price ratios should take it into account. And in any case, for detailed analysis, a method may have to be utilised that permits of taking into account changes in consumption with the changes in income. Secondly, the possibility is suggested of introducing intermediate baskets, in such a way as to minimise the amount of additional calculation and to improve the fit between consumption 2 i 34 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OP FOOD COSTS in the particular case and the commodities in the basket chosen. Including in the scope of the problem not merely each country but each economic group in each country greatly increases the totaî volume of calculation in the direct method and would correspondingly permit of increasing the number of group baskets while still maintaining the relative advantage of the group basket method. (d) General Problem of Comparison between Different Economic Levels. A brief consideration should be given to the problem of price comparisons at different economic levels. Within a market, comparisons of cost of living at different levels reveal differences solely in the costs of differing standards, since the prices of identical articles are the same for all economic levels—the price ratio being 1. In different markets, the objective sought in the price ratio technique is to measure the difference in the price ratio irrespective of any differences in the costs of the varying standards themselves. The Fisher formula seems to offer the best means for obtaining this result. The slightly different weights associated with varying quantities consumed at different economic levels often have, it is true, a slight effect upon the price ratios, which may, in fact, show a slight trend as income changes. These differences are due to the different weights used, and not to differences in the costs of differing standards themselves. An alternative formula for determining the cost-of-food ratio is / = —P}_2lt where the level of food consumption in the two coun2 Po ?o tries compared is the same. If this formula, which merely compares the costs of the standards in the two countries, is used, the condition that the standards must be equal is obviously essential for present purposes. Where this condition is satisfied, the ratio of the costs of food in the two countries gives the desired cost-of-food ratio.1 In practice, this condition appears to be closely related to the concept of equal economic levels. Three methods of determining equal standards of food consumption may be considered: the double expenditure test, or Q equals 1 ; the equivalence of nutritive values ; and the equivalence of satisfactions or utilities. The double expenditure test of Frisch asserts that where "double expenditures are equal, standards of consumption are the same". The test is 2 Pi go 2 pi qi = S po Ço 2 p0 Ci 1 In this case t h e term "cost-of-food ratio" is preferred to food price ratio. APPLICATIONS 35 By dividing through by the right hand side of the equation, and extracting the square root, this reduces to \ / Q 0 Q , = Q = 1. Where this condition holds, the true ratio is given by the Fisher formula. 1 In other words, the condition for using the more general formula leads to the Fisher formula. To establish the equivalence of nutritive values or the cost of a new basket with equal nutritive content would require an elaborate technique of general substitutions, a problem which is considered in chapter IV. The equivalence of satisfactions or utilities seems to require substantial equivalence of economic level as a prerequisite to determining the ratio. The upshot of the matter appears to be, therefore, that the alternative formula for a cost-of-food ratio can be applied for practical purposes only between groups at approximately the same economic level. It is possible that the price ratio is of special significance and subject to less error or modification by substitutions or otherwise where calculated between two equivalent levels in different countries. If so, in order to obtain such a specially significant ratio, approximate methods of determining equivalence, such as equal real incomes, or equal food values, etc., might be utilised and the Fisher formula applied to these equivalent groups. This is not to say, however, that comparisons between different income levels in different countries are invalid or inappropriate. Comparisons may be made between any two income levels. As suggested at the beginning of the present section, comparisons may be made between two income levels in the same market: the fact that the price ratio is 1 means that the difference in costs corresponds to the differences in the standards. Between two cities, a similar price ratio may be needed if only to compare differences in costs of two different standards after eliminating price differentials, the latter being an essential step in the determination of the former. In any case, the present enquiry is concerned only with the price ratio, that is, the differences in costs due to price differences, and not with differences in the costs of differing standards. IV. CLIMATIC DIFFERENCES Application of the price-ratio technique to cities subject to large differences in climate raises the question whether adjustments 1 See Robert M. WOODBURY, "Quantity Adjustment Factors in Cost of Living Ratios" in Econometrica, Vol. 8, No. 4, Oct. 1940, pp. 323, 328. 2 4 36 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS should be made to take account of the differences in quantity requirements caused by climatic differences. This raises three important points. In the first place, in theory the price-ratio.technique may have to be supplemented by quantity adjustments where climatic differences produce differences in quantity requirements. This is perhaps best illustrated by the case of differing fuel requirements in warm and cold climates : where the amount of fuel required for a given degree of comfort varies, a fuel-cost ratio must adjust the quantities of the numerator country in comparison with those of the denominator to provide for the differences in requirements in the two regions. This whole question with relation to the cost of living index is discussed in an article "Quantity Adjustment Factors in Cost of Living Indices". 1 Secondly, with regard to food, there is as yet insufficient evidence in comparisons between countries in the temperate zone to show that more calories or other food elements are required in one country than in another, or,if more calories are required,to showhow much the allowance must be increased to yield the same standard. Family budget studies have shown, it is true, that the average consumption in calories per consumption unit varies from country to country, but this cannot be taken as valid evidence to show that these differences correspond accurately to differences in requirements. A primary obstacle to any attempt to take climatic differences into account is the relative crudeness of the methods available to judge calorie requirements of different individuals and the number of important factors, age, sex, degree of bodily exertion, etc., which have to be taken into account in any such study. The question of quantity adjustments in respect of food may therefore be dismissed from further consideration here. Thirdly, the reservation must be made that the whole procedure of comparing costs of food can be applied only where conditions are not too different. There is no significance in a price ratio between communities as different as the Eskimo and the Sahara desert tribesmen. The exact degree of difference which invalidates the procedure is difficult to determine, but in practice, where differences are great and striking, the mappropriateness of comparison is obvious. Specifically, an index of similarity and dissimilarity is afforded by the percentage of the food budget for one community which is not available in another with which a comparison is sought : the higher the percentage the less reliance is to be placed upon the » Ibid., pp. 322-332. APPLICATIONS 37 calculation of a ratio. Where all the items are different in the two markets, the price-ratio technique breaks down completely; and the alternative cost-of-food technique with substitutions required for each and every item would easily evoke sufficient doubts to emphasise the reservations that such a comparison must carry. In practice, the techniques have been applied principally to comparisons between countries of the temperate zone under Western modes of living. For some purposes, comparisons outside these restrictions may prove useful. For example, comparisons between the costs of living in the Philippine Islands and the United States are useful and of interest—for missionaries, for representatives of business firms seeking to establish trade relations or branch establishments, for discussions of problems such as migration, tariff adjustments, etc., etc. Such applications of the techniques discussed here between countries differing widely in climate, customs, and habits are obviously subject to much greater reservations as to margin of error, etc., than, for example, comparisons between the United States and Great Britain. CHAPTER III ERRORS IN BASIC DATA Errors in the basic data of quantities and prices affect price ratios calculated by any method. In describing and testing the Group Basket Method in chapter I, errors in the basic data on quantities and prices were expressly left out of account. They must obviously be considered, however, together with the means available for reducing them, in any complete discussion of the problem of international comparisons of food prices. In general, such errors depend upon the methods of collecting the basic data. Since sources of data, methods of collection, and techniques differ for quantities and prices, errors in quantities and prices must be considered separately. QUANTITIES /. Sources of Data. The principal source for data on quantities is the family budget study. For all except three of the countries included in the tables shown above, the quantity data were drawn from family budget studies as listed in "An International Survey of Recent Family Living Studies" in the May and June 1939 numbers of the International Labour Review. In order to place the data on a comparable basis the quantities of specific foods consumed are stated per (adult male) consumption unit of standard type, the results as given in the sources being converted where necessary by the Office to this form.1 In the three cases, France, Great Britain, and Italy, where family budget studies were not used, the data were derived from estimates of consumption supplemented by more or less detailed investigations approaching the family budget study type. The figures for France are the average quantities consumed per capita in the Paris region used by the Comité technique de l'Alimentation i For the method of conversion see International Labour Review, Vol. XXIX, No. 6, June 1939, p. 821. ERBOBS IN BASIC DATA 39 as weights for cost-of-living indices for this region, converted by the Office to quantities consumed per consumption unit. The figures for Great Britain are estimated by the Office on the basis of figures in Crawford's The People's Food and Sir John Orr's Food, Health and Income. Crawford's figures for population groups C and D and Orr's figures for income groups I to IV were averaged and the mean of these compared with the data published by the Advisory Committee on Nutrition : for each foodstuff for which data were available the lower of the two quantities, based on Crawford and Orr data on the one hand, and the Advisory Committee on Nutrition data on the other, have been used. This series was then converted into quantities consumed per consumption unit.1 The figures for Italy are quantities of food available for national consumption during 1937 as published in the Italian Statistical Yearbook. The per capita figures of the original were converted by the Office into quantities per consumption unit. 2. Errors in Data. (a) Methods of collection. The errors in data are dependent on the specific methods used in collection. In the case of family budget studies the usual method followed is a day-by-day accounting of items and quantities purchased in conjunction with changes in inventory at the beginning and the end of the period. For the most part the family budget data cover the period of a year. In some cases, however, the food studies are limited to four periods of one week each in each of the four seasons. Details of methods followed in each country are given in the article already referred to in the June 1939 number of the International Labour Review. An alternative method which is sometimes used in food studies, especially those dealing with nutrition, involves the weighing of foods actually eaten. This method is much superior in accuracy of final results. Unfortunately, where this method is utilised the scope of the study is usually restricted. Estimates based upon general figures for consumption are usually subject to considerable error. In the first place, such figures often are based upon production plus imports less exports, a procedure which disregards the diversion of supplies available to other uses than human consumption. The quantities of grain available for human consumption, for example, must be converted into flour or bread. At best, this method is unsatisfactory for estimates of consumption among the wage-earning population. i See footnote 2, p. 56. 2 4 40 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS (6) Errors of sampling and representativeness of data. Little evidence is available on the question of the representativeness of family budget data for wage-earners' families. The question whether the data obtained for the sample of wage-earners' families chosen for study are representative of the entire group of wage-earners' families in the country as a whole depends upon the methods used to select the families. Until recently, comparatively little attention has been paid in family budget studies to methods of sampling. An important question also is the geographical limitations of the study; in many cases the studies are limited to the chief city or cities of the country. An analysis of the variation of food consumption in different cities or income classes in the same country indicates comparatively minor differences, suggesting that food consumption is to a large extent determined by national customs and habits, as influenced or governed by conditions of supply or price. (c) Variability from year to year in quantities consumed. An important question relates to the problem of sampling in time, or, in other words, whether the quantities consumed vary significantly from year to year. This variability might be due to differences in the sample, i.e., if different families are chosen at different times, or to changes in quantities consumed arising from any of a number of causes, including specifically the effect of changes in prices. This question is important with reference to the comparison of family budget data in different countries at different periods. Is it permissible, for example, to compare food consumption in Germany as in 1926-7 with food consumption in Sweden as in 1933 ? Evidence on this question can be obtained for countries which have taken annual family budget studies. Among them is Austria for the period 1926-34. To test the influence of changes in quantities upon the price ratio, P0, between Germany and Austria, calculations have been made using successively the quantities as found in the Austrian enquiries for 1927, 1929, 1931, 1933 and 1934. The variations in quantities consumed are due to all factors including not only fluctuations in prices but also changing habits and changes in the sample. The enquiry covered about 70 families in Vienna, and as far as possible the same families were covered each year, so that changes in the sample are of comparatively little importance. The results showed that the value of P0 changed very little, the figures being respectively .924, .927, .928, .923 and .922. The low net effect is explained in large part by the fact that the changes tend to offset one another, the decreases in the consumption of certain articles being offset by increases in the consumption of others. The details of these changes are shown in table IX. ERRORS IN BASIC DATA 41 TABLE IX. CHANGES IN QUANTITIES CONSUMED PER CONSUMPTION UNIT IN AUSTRIA, 1 9 2 7 - 1 9 3 4 , AND THE EFFECT ON P0, GERMANY/ AUSTRIA, OF USING AUSTRIAN QUANTITIES FOR DIFFERENT YEARS Foodstuffs Quantities (kg.) consumed per consumption unit in Austria 1927 1929 1931 1933 1934 Bread Flour Rice Beef Pork 103.04 27.82 5.02 18.83 20.71 98.56 25.92 5.48 13.53 23.29 92.71 27.01 5.29 9.36 23.82 95.64 27.38 5.33 8.17 21.52 95.97 27.10 6.22 7.10 22.23 Veal Lard Margarine... .' Milk (litres) Cheese 4.22 4.70 1.81 194.00 2.92 4.62 5.37 2.34 195.64 3.43 6.05 3.29 2.34 179.22 2.77 3.88 2.70 2.63 169.76 3.07 2.99 2.27 2.82 148.17 3.21 Butter Eggs (number) 4.44 199 2.09 54.19 26.33 2.00 5.07 219 1.79 53.29 27.01 2.00 4.56 212 2.48 52.20 25.19 2.00 3.90 189 2.33 55.67 23.82 2.00 0.924 0.927 4.49 226 2.23 50.74 27.01 2.00 0.928 0.923 0.922 Potatoes Sugar Coffeei Po, Germany / A u s t r i a . . 1 Quantity estimated. The fact that such studies in successive years reveal approximately the same general pattern indicates that the results may be accepted as sufficiently reliable for present purposes. The variability of quantities over a period of time appears to have little influence upon the ratios. S. The Problem of Coverage. An important aspect of inaccurate or incomplete quantity data is the lack of complete coverage. In part this is due to insufficient detail in family budget studies but for the most part to gaps in price data. Table X presents the percentages of coverage formed by comparing the cost of the eighteen commodities used in the calculations of chapter I to the total food budget in each country. These percentages ranged from 54.4 per cent, for Denmark to 83 per cent, for Finland. The table shows also the percentages of coverage within each food group. These ranged from an average of 96.3 per cent. for the group of milk products and eggs, 84.4 per cent, for margarine and fats, and 79.8 per cent, for bread and cereals, to 52 per cent, for meat and fish and only 33.6 per cent, for vegetables and fruits. 2 ¿ 42 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS TABLE X. PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL EXPENDITURE IN EACH FOOD GROUP COVERED BY FOODS INCLUDED IN THE LIST OF 18 COMMODITIES, IN FOURTEEN COUNTRIES Food Group Country Bread and cereals Meat and fish Marg. and fats Milk, etc. Belgium Bulgaria Czecho-Slovakia... Denmark Estonia Finland Germany Hungary Netherlands Norway Sweden Switzerland Union of South Africa United States Average (14 countries). .. 87.7 89.8 79.6 49.6 91.5 92.9 82.0 85.6 72.7 81.6 96.3 64.9 49.7 68.2 54.5 38.8 43.5 49.7 33.3 60.5 63.0 30.6 59.6 51.0 85.6 58.0 100.0 98.0 100.0 100.0 88.5 99.9 88.6 97.1 100.0 5.5 100.0 100.0 100.0 87 99 93 99 96 100.0 89.1 90.3 96.9 76.9 66.2 71.0 54.1 100.0 60.6 79.8 51.9 84.4 Vegetables and fruits Miscel- Total laneous 51.7 59.9 63.7 56.5 80.3 88.6 71.1 67.4 69.8 79.7 82.0 28.0 72.0 72.1 72.4 54.4 75.4 83.0 66.2 74.8 70.6 66.6 76.0 55.9 100.0 95.9 45.5 22.9 27. 22 56. 60 39 35 27. 43 24.8 13.0 18.8 14.8 61.9 73.5 70.4 60.9 96.3 33.6 68.0 69.3 The principal shortcoming of family budget studies in respect of food items is lack of specific detail. An item of small importance is placed under a more general head or is lumped in with a group of "all other items", for example, "lard" may be returned as "animal fats", "margarine" under "vegetable fats and oils", rice and macaroni placed under "other cereals", etc. In such a case, for example, the omission of macaroni in the family budget study does not indicate whether consumption is zero or some (small) quantity less than the amount assigned to "other cereals". This point is of little significance from the viewpoint of the family budget study; but from that of cost of food comparisons, the absence of detail requires estimates of the missing quantities if the commodity is to be included at all. Obviously, no useful price quotations can be obtained for "all other" items. The different vegetables and fruit consumed are often not reported in detail separately. The different qualities of meat or the different cuts of beef, veal, lamb, etc., are often ignored. Sausage is returned as a single item rather than with details indicating food value or price. Difficulties are found also in comparing certain fish items often specified as merely fresh fish or salted fish, and lacking characterisation of the particular kind of fish. ERROBS IN BASIC DATA 43 These gaps in the specific details of foods consumed lead directly to gaps in the data on prices and raise the questions (1) what is to be done in regard to these gaps? and (2) how much effect do they have on the final price ratios ? The first question is usually answered by omitting the commodities for which either quantity or price data are wanting. Other expedients such as estimating the missing data are sometimes adopted where the items are unimportant or where a satisfactory method of estimate is available, and such expedients as pricing the particular kind of the food item, e.g., fish, principally consumed in each country—which raises the whole problem of substitutions (see next chapter)—are sometimes resorted to. But by far the simplest and easiest way is to omit the items altogether. Assuming that this method (of omission) is adopted, an important question is how much difference does it make in the final result. In other words is a P calculated on the basis of 18 commodities acceptable as approximating within a reasonable percentage of error a true P calculated on the basis of the full food budget ? No definite estimate of error can be given, since obviously the difference between the two results depends on the number and importance of the items omitted, in conjunction with the deviation of the price ratios for the omitted items from the final price ratio. In general, however, the smaller the omissions the better the results should be. In two cases the result of the computation based upon 18 commodities can be compared with the result based on full data. For the ratio Germany/Norway, a test can be made on the basis not of prices of October 1938 but of prices at the time the family budget enquiries were conducted during 1927-29. The average price ratio based upon all commodities in the food budget was .90, while that based on the 18 items included in the present calculations was .88, an error of - 2 per cent. In this case the coverage of meat and fish, as well as of vegetables in the 18 items was relatively low both in Germany and Norway. In the second case—the ratio of Germany/Switzerland—a similar test shows that the computation based upon 18 commodities was 3.2 per cent, in excess of the ratio based upon the detailed and comparable list of items in the full budget. Other evidence may be adduced in the form of a difference in the price ratio based on a small number of items and one based on a larger, though not the complete, number. Thus the price ratio Sweden/Norway based on 23 items was found to be .94, one based upon 15 principal items .94, and one based upon 10 principal items .95. In these figures, the items characterised as principal items were 2 i, 44 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS determined by the values of the Swedish budget. Where the "principal" items were determined by the values of the Norwegian budget, on the other hand, the result based on the 10 principal items was .92 and on the 15 principal items .92. One might infer from this that if the quantities included did actually cover the principal items, the final results should be fairly close to the true ratio. The unequal distribution of the gaps, in particular, the low coverage of meats and fish, and vegetables and fruits suggests a possible method of reducing the effect of the missing items. In one case, for example, comparing the United States with Sweden, an analysis of P 0 for the different food groups shows considerable differences between the different food groups. Thus, with an average price ratio of 1.37, the ratio for cereals and bread was 1.14, for meats and fish 1.41, margarine and lard 1.2, milk products and eggs 1.65, vegetables and fruits .89, and miscellaneous .93. Obviously, if similar and parallel differences appeared in the ratios for the omitted items, the final result would be affected by the relatively low coverage in the vegetables and fruit group. If it could be established that the price ratios for the various items within each food group were relatively constant, the price ratio for the items included of each group might be extended to the other items of the same group for which data on prices were lacking. 1 Sufficient evidence for this procedure is, however, lacking. But even if the inference is not justified that a price ratio for a few items in a group can be extended to cover all items in the group, it may well be true that a price ratio for a particular item may fairly be extended to cover closely similar items. For example, a price ratio for one kind of native cheese might be extended to cover other native cheeses, or in general, the price ratio for one quality of a particular kind of meat might be extended to other qualities. This means in practice, that, when this inference is justified, the weights given for a particular price ratio may be extended to cover not simply the specified articles but also the articles closely allied to it. This device would very considerably extend the degree of coverage of certain items. But it is important to show how far the inference is, in fact, justified, since otherwise errors may be introduced into the final results. Before such an extension is made of a particular case, the evidence for its applicability should be examined in detail. i That is, in effect, to weight the price ratios for each food group by the full weight of all the items in the groups instead of by the weight of the items for which price ratios were actually obtained. ERRORS IN BASIC DATA 4- Detail of Individual 45 Commodities. The extent and importance of the gaps and errors in the basic data on quantities can best be understood in connection with a review of some of the problems affecting the items as actually met with in the different countries. The specific problems include the following points: (1) Absence of detail in the family budget study where the specific item is not listed or shown separately, usually because it is deemed not to be of sufficient importance in the particular country to warrant itemisation, but occasionally because though important it is included with one or more related items in a total such as bread, coffee and coffee substitutes, beef and veal, etc. The latter raises the general problem of what is a commodity for purposes of price ratio analysis. (2) Absence of detail as to qualities is common to many items in family budget studies, but on the other hand too much detail may render the results almost unusable. For example, if all the many kinds and brands of tea are specified, each with its own price, the lack of agreement in brands and kinds consumed in the several countries might render comparison of prices difficult, if not impossible. The usual recourse in such a case is to obtain the quantities consumed on the one hand and the prices of the most typical brand or kind in the several markets on the other. This point, however, will be discussed further under "Prices". The quantities of the 18 commodities as used in the calculations are given in table X I . These are drawn from the summary table presented in "An International Survey of Recent Family Living Studies, Part I I : Food Expenditure and Consumption Habits". 1 The figures are compiled from the data of the original sources by converting the quantities consumed as given in the source to quantities consumed per consumption unit of standard composition, as described in the same article. 2 The notes as given in the table throw light upon the adjustments made to obtain the quantities consumed for the commodities chosen for the calculations. Those commodities were chosen for inclusion where (1) prices were available in all countries, and (2) quantities were available or could be estimated to a reasonable degree of accuracy. In some cases usually affecting items of lesser importance estimates were required, as explained in the footnotes. In a few cases, perhaps, estimates have been made even where the basis of estimate left something to be desired, in order to give as large a series of commodities in as large a number of countries as possible for a test of the group basket method. i International Labour Review, Vol. X X X I X , No. 6, June 1939, pp. 822-27. 2 ibid., p. 821. 2 4 TABLE XI. Foodstuffs Austria I SI i Wheaten bread.. 18.6 81.1 Flour 27.4 6.3 1.5 7.2 16.6« 0.1 3.0 2.3 2.3" Milk (litres), .,, 158.6 3.2 Butter 3.9 Eggs (number).. 191 Belgium QUANTITIES CONSUMED PER ADULT MALE CONSUMPTION U N I T TO FAMILY BUDGET STUDIES OF WAGE EARNERS' FAMILIES Bulgaria 195.4 1.2 7.2 1.8 1.6 211.7" 21.5 8.0 0.0 2.8 5.8' 13.6' 9.0> 1.0» 5.5" 2.9 4.8 145.1 5.3 17.5 192 2.3 3.1 56.2 220.2 24.0 Coffee b e a n s . . . . 2 . 4 « 14.7 6.7 50.5 4.9 1.3 30.7 6.2 0.5 70 11.5 19.1 9.3 0.3 CzechoDenslovakia mark 8.7 15.6» 0.0 10.2 28.3 159.4 10.3 4.0 0.9 9.2 6.3 7.7 1.7 0.6 3.1 2.2« 17.9 1.5 2.9 154.5 3.7 3.8 169 105.6 5.7 9.6 227 151.2 0.2 5.2 7 2.0 100.5 28.8 0.8 0.4 92.6 35.0 6.8 2.2 205.4 28.6 2.1 84.8 52.7 3.8 0.2 10.5 9.7 0.6 1.9 16.7 76.9 13.2 1.0 Estonia Finland France Germany Great Britain Hungary I 11.9 28.0 78.3 6.2 0.6 11.0 9.2 0.0 1.5 115.7« 70.5« 14.4« 3.5 8.0 1.6« 81.0« 27.0« 54.9 4.2 0.5 5.3 9.8 0.5 1.6 130 15.9 1.5 4.6 8.4 21.4 90.9 15.6 2.0 2.4 6.8 8.3 0.6 1.6 1.2 1.2 3.7 10.3 3.5 3.0 7.2 0.0 0 96.4 5.8 5.8 106 158.6 5.1 6.2 161 61.5 3.0 8.0 121 2 4 10.8 62.7 12.1 2.4 2.9 162.7 17.6 1.4 3.0 70.0 20.0 0.0 113.1 0.2 0.6 80 4.3 72.1 21.3 0.8 1.1' 4.6 331.6 1.1 14.7 61 1.6 114.7 29.8 6.1 2.4 3.4 3.9 1 Quantities converted by the I.L.O. into quantities consumed per standard consumption unit: for statement of method see "An International Survey of Recent Family Living Studies; Part II. Food Expenditure and Consumption Habits", International Labour Review, Vol. XXXIX, No. 6, June 1939, p. 821. « Bread in source, assumed to represent wheaten bread. • Estimated from 108.0 kg. of bread in source, divided 75 per cent, wheat, 25 per cent, rye, in same proportion as wheat and rye form of total production plus imports less exports. «Estimated from 121.6 kg. flour covering wheaten bread, flour, and macaroni: 100 kg. flours 130 kg. bread. « Distributed according to proportions derived from quantities consumed, p. 53, of League of Nations Report on "Statistics of Food Production, Consumption and Prices". 18.0 1.9 16 5 5 5 3 0 3 28 5 0 • Figures for vea cluding beef and vea ' Figure for fres Britain and the Neth > Estimated amo including bacon and ' Figure for anim '• Estimated. ««Figure for vege «i Coffee. ERRORS IN BASIC DATA 47 Certain special problems, however, relating to specific commodities are discussed below. Two problems are raised in regard to bread: one, a question of method, whether bread should be treated as a single commodity, and if so, how it should be priced, or as two or more commodities, that is, principally wheaten bread and rye bread; and the second that of a series of questions of detail to estimate the quantities of wheaten and rye bread consumed in those countries where family budget study data or other sources do not give the requisite information. The first question is resolved tentatively in favour of separate figures for wheaten and rye bread, partly in order to ascertain how much difference it makes in the final result whether bread is treated as a single item or as two items; this question is then deferred to the next chapter where the problem is discussed in connection with the question of adaptation to local customs or allowable substitutions. The importance of the second question is indicated by the series of notes attaching to bread quantities in the table. For a number of countries the sources used do not show whether the bread consumed is wheaten bread or other kinds. In most of these, however, the absence of characterisation merely means that wheaten bread is used so exclusively that it has not been thought necessary to provide for the alternative use of rye bread. This is true for Great Britain and the Union of South Africa, and probably for Italy and Bulgaria, where judging from production and import and export figures, wheaten bread seems to be used almost exclusively. In Switzerland, production, import, and export figures for the available supplies of wheat and rye give a ratio between the two of 93 to 7, suggesting that bread is principally wheaten bread. In Hungary, on the other hand, figures of available supply are in the ratio of about 75 to 25. An analysis of the figures of available supply in relation to the relative consumption of wheaten and rye bread in wage-earners' families according to family budget studies, indicates that in countries where the consumption of rye bread predominates, the percentage of rye bread consumed is usually greater than the ratio of rye to wheat in the available supply, while in countries where the consumption of wheaten bread predominates, the percentage of rye bread consumed is usually less than the ratio of rye to wheat in the available supply. 1 In the case of Hungary i Figures on production, imports, and exports are given in the INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE, International Year Book of Agricultural Statistics. See also N. JASNY, "Die Zukunft des Roggens", Vierteljahrshefte zur Konjunkturforschung, Special No. 20, Berlin, 1930, p. 95 and elsewhere. 2 4 48 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS the estimation of consumption assumes that 75 per cent, of the bread is wheaten and 25 per cent, rye. 1 The point might be made in passing that during the war period special regulations in certain countries specify that bread shall be composed of a mixture of grains. Thus in Switzerland the so-called "federal" bread must contain other grains than wheat in specified proportions. For purposes of calculation in such a case only one method appears to be feasible, namely, to use the commodity "bread" in conjunction with its price. When such commodity and price are compared with a country using wheaten bread exclusively, part of the difference in the price must obviously be attributed to the difference in the quality. The questions in regard to other commodities in the main merely involve minor problems of estimate. In the case of commodities of small importance, errors in estimates have little effect on final results. The estimates for the amounts of different meats in Bulgaria and the Union of South Africa are those the importance of which is greatest, but in these cases the total amount is given in the family budget reports and only the distribution among the four meats haB to be estimated. In the case of lard, in a number of countries the total for animal fats was. used, the quantity of the specific item "lard" not being available. The amounts involved, however, are small. The second general question is raised in those cases where details of family budget studies in one country cover a number of specific kinds and qualities of an article, for example, cheese (seven kinds in Norway), while in others all these articles are grouped together under one heading. For purposes of food analysis one may make shift perhaps with the grouping if the details are not available : for purposes of price comparisons too much detail may even prove embarrassing. Other items for which detail is often shown are milk : skimmed, whole, condensed, dried, other; meats, with specification of the kind of cut or other description of qualities. The problem of qualities raises the difficult question of definition in uniform terms applicable to all countries. In practice this question may best be treated with price problems, since it is of much greater importance that the prices should be correct than that the quantities should be exact. Peas and beans are grouped together since the family budget studies in some countries did not show the quantities of each separately. i A shift in the estimated consumption of wheaten and rye bread in Switzerland from 100 per cent, wheat to 50 per c«nt. of each leads to changes in the final price ratios averaging about 1 per cent. ERRORS IN BASIC DATA 49 A number of commodities were excluded because of problems of quantities or prices. As to fish, must the quantities of each kind of fish be obtained separately, or is it permissible to consider the total quantity of fish consumed as a single item, and, if so, how is "fish" to be priced? Is it legitimate to consider one kind of fish important in the consumption of one country as equivalent to the same quantity (or calorie value) of a different kind of fish important in the consumption of another country? A somewhat similar problem is whether tea and coffee are allowable substitutions one for the other, and on what terms ? Pending a satisfactory and general answer to these questions, these problems have been avoided in the calculations as presented above by excluding the commodities from their scope. 5. Errors in Quantities in Relation to Error in the Final Price Ratio. Errors in quantities affect the final price ratio only by affecting the weights attaching to the individual price ratios. The price ratio for a single item — is not affected at all by errors in the quantities. Since the price ratios of the individual items vary, the effect of a given error, say of 2 per cent, in the quantity of a particular item, upon the final ratio will vary depending upon two further elements: the deviation of the individual price ratio from the final average price ratio and the importance of the particular item in the whole budget. If the deviation of the individual price ratio from the final average price ratio is zero, the error in the quantity has no effect upon the final result. The positive error of 2 per cent, attached to the weight of a particular item tends to be offset in part by a corresponding underemphasis attached to the weight of all other items, since the deviation in price of the item itself is in an opposite direction to the deviation in price of "all other items". Thus, if the price deviation is positive and the error of 2 per cent, is also positive, the weight of the particular ratio is overemphasised but the effect is partially offset by the corresponding underemphasis upon all other items, which have a negative deviation. If, however, the price deviation is negative and the error of 2 per cent, is positive (or if the latter is in the opposite direction to the former), these two effects partially offset each other, and the result is further diminished by the corresponding effects upon the other group, and the final effect is relatively smaller. To take a specific illustration, if the item in question is a very important one, bread, and the price deviation substantial, the effect on the final ratio may be perceptible; with an item forming 2 t, 50 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS 50 per cent, of the budget, (in Italy bread is only 38 per cent.), a price deviation of 10 per cent., an error of 2 per cent, in the quantity of the item will, considered by itself, produce an error of .7 or .4 in the final ratio, depending upon whether the deviation is in the same direction as the error or in the opposite direction. If, as in most cases, the item is less than 5 or even 10 per cent, of the food budget, the final error is correspondingly reduced and is almost negligible. Errors in the different items, which are not correlated with one another, tend to offset one another in the final result. PRICES 1. Sources of Price Data. The sources of the price data are the current compilations of prices collected usually for purposes of cost of living analyses. In particular, the sources used in the calculations given above are the prices collected by the International Labour Office in its annual survey as of October 1938.1 The data are furnished by the competent statistical services of the different countries and collected by them either specifically on request of the International Labour Office or, more usually, for their own cost-of-living analyses. In general, the Office list of commodities has in the past been relatively limited, since it was found that in longer lists many items were missing for a certain number of countries. In short, the list has been restricted to commodities in common consumption in practically all countries. The prices are those given for the principal cities in each country (usually omitting metropolitan cities since prices for these might not be representative) and are presented in table X I I . The list of cities in each country for which prices are given is shown above, p. 27. 2. Errors in Data. Methods of collection. It may be helpful to state briefly the principles and techniques of the collection of price data. 2 First, the items to be priced, which must be, in general, commodities in demand by the wage-earning class, must be defined in simple and clear terms. This definition involves, of course, as much of a description of quality as is necessary to identify the item properly. Secondly, attention must be given to the sources of the quotations. These i "Retail Prices in Certain Countries in October 1938", International Labour Review, Vol. X X X I X , No. 3, March 1939, pp. 411-416. 2 See INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E : Methods of Compiling Cost of Living Index Numbers, Studies & Reports, Series N, Statistics, No. 6, esp. pp. 33-40, 48-64. TABLE XII. Items Wheaten bread.. Flour (wheaten). Macaroni Beef Pork» Veal5 Austria Belgium RM. FT. 1.11 .42 .45 .43 .75« 1.60 1.73 1.80« 1.87 1.73 .80 Milk (litres), Butter Eggs (number).. Peas, beans7 . . . . Coffee (beans)... .30 2.40 3.14 .10 .47 .09 .84 5.60 AVERAGE RETAIL PRICES OF 18 FOODSTUFFS IN 19 COUN Bulgaria Czecho- Denslova- mark kia Levas KÍ. Kr. 2.10 2.31' 2.49 2.88 7.49 2.49' 2.35 2.78 3.00 7.93 Estonia Finland France GerGreat many Britain E.Kr. F.Mk. FT. RM. .93 .22 .35 .80 1.40« .58 .20 .38 .65 .90 10.83 4.06 5.00 5.97 8.00« .71 .33 .44 .49 .78 1.64 1.62 1.79 2.08 Hungary I Pence Pengö L 4.6 4.6' 4.2 5.5 11.5 .42 .36 .39 .90 1.20 2 2 2 2 3 15.7 24.3 15.2 15.4 2.35 1.58 1.34 1.60 9 12 14 13 5.00 5.00' 4.10 15.00 20.00« 12.55 19.00 25.18 27.50 25.00« 25.00 25.00« 25.00 13.21 41.00 10.00 40.00« 12.63 12.25 10.00 11.50 1.45 1.85 1.70« 1.48 .60 .88 .68 .53 13.10 15.75 13.25 10.29 3.08 3.08« 4.31 4.19 8.86 10.11 20.02 11.73 14.60 14.75 12.60 2.15 1.34 1.42 .95 14.50 15.00 12.20 12.12 2.14 1.68 16.1 13.4 1.95 2.60 8 8 1.7« 6.00 15.59 26.00 63.00 26.51 2.00 .87 3.20 11.00 5.25 .62 3.25 22.90 19.60 145.00 1.55 14.00 20.00 .75 2.95 .83 6.23 40.00 .35 2.00 3.10 .13 .75« .15 .52 4.79 .11 1.50 1.70 .05 .34 .07 .46 4.00 1.87 23.00 30.70 1.18 1.92 20.70 27.78 .91 5.20 .76 5.47 21.26 .23 2.00 3.12 .12 6.2 24.3 37.7 2.1 .30 2.30 3.00 .10 1 14 15 .60 4.08 .76 4.74 5.4 1.7 5.5 59.1 .46 .09 1.28 8.40 2 5.50 1.19 5.74 20.00 1 Price per kg. except milk (litres) and eggs (number). From "Retail Prices in Certain Countries in October 1938", International Labour Review, Vol. XXXIX, March 1939, pp. 412-416. s Estimated from price ratio wheaten bread to rye bread in another year or years. > Estimated as equal to price of wheaten bread (see text). 6 30 * Estimated. * 2nd quality, exc *7 Average of 1st a Average price fo 52 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS are generally limited to retail establishments (grocers, etc.). serving working class communities. For purposes of showing changes in prices over a period of time, price comparisons are commonly limited to price changes occurring in identical establishments. No similar restriction is, of course, possible in comparing prices in different localities, the only recourse being to restrict the comparison so far as possible to shops serving the same types of clientele. Thirdly, quotations are usually secured for a number of establishments, thus tending to eliminate the effects of quotations markedly out of line with others. The difficulty of defining an item and its quality in sufficiently precise terms varies with the particular item. Thus, dry groceries are subject to less variation than fresh vegetables, for example, and the kind and qualities can be more easily defined. In some markets international or trade standards have been set up, for example, in the marketing of cotton, wheat, and other staples. These standards are based on trade practice and serve trade needs. In retail markets of food, however, no such international standards are as yet available, though in many areas or countries local or national laws or customs provide effective standards through the regulation of labelling or the specification of minimum requirements for certain commodities. Hence, for present purposes the task of ensuring uniformity in the items to be priced is usually entirely a matter of definition of the item and its quality. In some cases differences in quality may exist which affect consumption and price but which are not easily put into terms of specifications for obtaining prices of identical qualities in other countries. Fresh fish in a seaport town may be of much higher quality in regard to freshness and palatability than fish sold in an inland market. "Fresh" eggs are notoriously difficult to define in terms of their exact degree of freshness; the average freshness doubtless varies in relation to size of city and nearness to rural sources of supply. In other cases identical qualities may not exist, as in the case of bread, where in an emergency a Government prescribes an admixture of rye or maize to wheat, in making bread for the market. These variations in quality may be responsible for differences in prices due solely to the difference in quality, and thus the value of the data for purposes of determining the true price ratio between the two commodities is impaired. 1 1 The requirement often made, that in each market the commodity be of a quality locally consumed by the wage-earning group, may in some instances conflict with the requirement that qualities priced in the different markets must be identical. Where qualities are different, the problem is raised as to whether {continued on next page) EBROBS IN BASIC DATA 53 Averaging a number of quotations for a single market and averaging the quotations for a number of markets tends to eliminate unusual errors or lessen the influence of individual quotations subject to such errors. Such a procedure tends to improve the accuracy of the results, provided that the general plan of collection of the data is properly aimed to obtain substantially identical qualities. Prices are always specific. Thus, a price is for lard, not for animal fats; for coffee beans of a particular brand, not for "coffee" implying a combination of coffee and coffee substitutes; for a particular kind of cheese, not for cheese in general. In this respect the price data do not usually fit exactly with the quantity data. The quantity data, being derived from family budget studies, often do not have the detail of brand, or specific kind or variety of the item consumed, or if the detail is available in the original schedules or accounts it may usually be omitted in the published reports. Hence, the consumption data commonly give the amounts consumed of cheese, of coffee, etc., often without further detail. In such cases the usual practice is to obtain prices for a specific brand commonly consumed by the wage-earning classes, and to consider the quantity of the item consumed as if it were all of the specific brand that is largely consumed by the population groups under consideration. 1 In some cases price quotations may be wanting, particularly for articles not in demand in a particular country. Where this happens, either the item must be omitted from the comparison entirely or the price must be estimated : it is not correct to set the price at zero. It is true that where the price is wanting the quantity consumed in the particular country is zero, and hence does not figure in P 0 : but in Pi where the weights are the quantities consumed in the second country, the quantity is not zero and the price is required. In the present calculations, where price data are missing, the item is usually omitted; except in a few instances, usually of relatively minor items, where price data were omitted from one or two countries only, the item was retained if a satisfactory estimate for the missing items could be supplied. Notes are given in the table wherever an estimated price is used. the poorer quality in one market is an allowable substitution for the better quality; that is, whether as a result of a price "bargain" and the adjustment of consumption to it, the lowering of the standard by reason of the lowered quality is offset m part or wholly by an increase in the standard by reason of the larger quantity consumed at the iower price—this is a specific case of the problem of substitutions which1 is discussed in chapter IV. With more complete details, a more exact procedure of comparing prices of specific brands with their quantities might be followed: it would be of interest to compare the results obtained with the two types of procedure where full data were available. „ , 54 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS In one case, that of the price of rye bread in certain wheat consuming countries, the problem of estimation is of some importance: rye bread is an important item in the diet in a number of Countries. Omitting this item entirely is not an acceptable alternative since it would affect the price ratio in many countries and render it less representative. An examination of the relative position of rye and wheaten bread prices shows that in the rye consuming countries the rye price ranges from 24 to 83 per cent, of the wheaten bread price1, while in the wheat consuming countries the rye price is either just a little below or a little above the wheat price. Accordingly, in the four countries Bulgaria, France, Great Britain, and the Union of South Africa, where no rye price was reported and where it could not be estimated from the returns of other years2 the price of rye bread was set equal to the price of wheaten bread. This gives the same result in these cases as the alternative procedure of taking the price of "bread". It has the additional justification that in a country where rye bread is not consumed in any considerable quantity, a newcomer from a rye consuming country would naturally tend to substitute wheaten bread for rye. Form of quotation. One type of error is in the degree of approximation involved in the form of quotation. Thus, the price of potatoes in Great Britain, in its published prices, is quoted to the nearest farthing: for a unit of 7 pounds priced at around 6d. to 8d., this means an error varying up to 2 per cent. ; the price per egg, at around 2/^d., expressed to the nearest farthing, has an error, due solely to the form of quotation, varying up to 5 per cent. Each item has its own degree of approximate price, depending on the currency unit used in the quotations. Usually, if prices are quoted for a number of markets, an average can be given to a much closer degree of accuracy than is customarily obtained for purposes of publication. If the figures are to be used for comparing prices of identical qualities in different markets, it seems unwise to suggest a high degree of accuracy by presenting decimals for price quotations, which in fact may be subject to considerable error. In any case, this type of error is perhaps not of great importance, since such errors tend to cancel out in forming an average price ratio for a number of food items. 8. Relation of Errors in Prices to Errors in Final Price Ratios. In contradistinction to errors in quantities which affect the final ratios only through their effect upon the weighting given to 1 Except Czecho-Slovakia, where the rye price is about 94 per cent, of the estimated wheat price based on average ratios in October for some four years. 2 Estimates of rye prices from data obtained in other years were made in the cases of Belgium and Italy. ERRORS IN BASIC DATA 55 the different price ratios, errors in prices affect each price ratio directly. If in a comparison between two countries one price is correct and the other is affected by'an error of 2 per cent., the price ratio for that particular item will be in error by 2 per cent.—a positive error if the error is positive and in the numerator of the ratio fraction, or negative and in the denominator; or a negative error if the error is negative and in the numerator, or positive and in the denominator. If both prices in a comparison are subject to a 2 per cent, error: (1) the price ratio may be subject to a positive error of 4 per cent., if a positive error of 2 per cent, in the numerator is combined with a negative error of 2 per cent, in the denominator ; (2) to a negative error of 4 per cent, if a negative error of 2 per cent. in the numerator is combined with a positive error of 2 per cent. in the denominator; or (3) may be substantially correct if the errors in numerator or denominator are both positive or both negative. This illustration indicates the building up or cancellation of errors in prices : they may be termed "subtractive" (algebraically), that is, the percentage error of the denominator is subtracted from that of the numerator; in practice errors are not all of uniform size so that where errors of numerator and denominator have the same sign, their influence is merely offset rather than cancelled. Errors in the price ratios of the various commodities have an influence upon the final price ratios in proportion to the importance of the particular commodity. In general, these errors in price ratios for the different commodities tend to offset one another in the general average, since there is no connection in general between errors affecting the prices of different commodities. A possible exception to this last-mentioned relationship, however, may be found if errors in qualities priced in a particular market tend to too high or too low a quality, that is, if the qualities locally consumed by wageearning groups are biased, as compared with other markets, in the direction of too high a quality : such an error might affect more or less all the items. This is, however, one aspect of the general problem of pricing instructions and definition of items to be priced, and they should be so drafted as to avoid the possibility of systematic differences in quality. EXCHANGE RATES The data used for calculating exchange rates between countries are taken from the figures published in the Monthly Bulletin of Statistics of the League of Nations. They are applied in converting the prices of the several countries into units of a common currency, namely the Swiss franc. For this purpose, exchange rates for 2 ¡t 56 INTEBNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS October 1938 are required between the currency of each country and the Swiss franc. Two methods of conversion are possible. If all countries were on the gold standard, the exchange rates in normal times would fluctuate between the upper and lower "gold points", and the gold equivalents of the standards in the two countries would be an appropriate exchange rate. Since, however, relatively few countries were on the gold standard in 1938, but most of them were in 1929, the gold equivalents of 1929 could be used in conjunction with the percentages of currency depreciation in each country between 1929 and October 1938. The second method takes the average exchange rates as quoted on the exchange markets in October 1938. In the figures here given, the first method was used. 1 Two points require comment. Though exchange rates between countries are in most cases fairly stable, in a few cases, notably France, thé rates were in transition to new values in anticipation of an expected devaluation of the currency. In such circumstances, the ratios as calculated, though correct for the particular period, would not long remain significant. Secondly, the fact that in many countries exchanges were not free, leads to difficulties in interpreting the results. If the exchange quotations are artificial, the ratios, when costs of food only are compared, are equally so. Where comparisons are made between real wages in two countries, however, neither of these difficulties affects the final results: since the exchange rate appears in both prices and wages, they simply cancel out, leaving the ratio between the real wages in the two countries unaffected. But for comparisons involving the cost of food only, the difficulty arising from exchange restrictions must be borne in mind. Among the countries for which price ratios are shown, in 1938 such restrictions were found in Austria, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Estonia, Germany, Italy, and Poland. 2 1 Owing to the method of calculating the depreciation of currencies by means of official rates on New York, the two methods are essentially the same. 2 Since the manuscript was completed, new figures for (ireat Britain based on a broad family budget study have become available. They have not been introduced into the tables, however, since to incorporate them would have required extensive recalculations, and because the primary objective is the exposition of method. CHAPTER IV SUBSTITUTIONS In applying the price ratio technique it sometimes happens that in a particular country a commodity included in the basket of another country or group is not itself largely consumed and that the price quoted is out of line with what would normally be found if the item were more generally in demand. This may be caused by the fact that in the particular country a cheap and good substitute for the other article of food is obtainable and is favoured by the local population. These considerations suggest, on the one hand, that the price ratio technique in such a case presents a certain artificiality of method and, on the other, that a substitution procedure in which the local product is substituted for the item consumed in the other country may give a better cost-of-food ratio. The point of departure for the consideration of the problem of substitutions is the discussion of the formula which expresses the ratio of the costs of food in two communities. In its most general form, this formula may be given by J =—^—where the standards of food consumption in the two countries are the same. The formula gives merely the ratio of the costs, of food in the two countries and cannot be used as a food cost ratio at the same standard of food consumption as distinguished from a ratio of the costs of two different standards, without a satisfactory method for determining that the standards of food consumption as represented by the respective quantities of numerator and denominator are in fact equivalent. Another approach is afforded by the formula for the food price ratio as developed above. According to the usual explanation, the ratio P 0 = — is a maximum for the price ratio starting with the S po Ço quantities of region 0 : with the new set of prices in region 1 a consumer with the habits and preferences of region 0 can make adjustments in quantities purchased in the numerator such as will mean equal satisfactions at less expense—in other words, he can secure an equal standard of food consumption and make savings in the amount spent, which will then be less than 2 pi qB. (A similar reasoning shows f\ to be a minimum, since the denominator 2 Po 9i is a maximum starting from the quantities of region 1.) 2 4 58 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS Both these approaches suggest the possibility of substituting in the numerator in place of the quantities of the denominator other quantities which will yield the same standard of food consumption and will serve as a valid food cost ratio at the same food standard in place of the food price ratio hitherto discussed. The discussion of the formula suggests, in fact, that the food cost ratio is a better measure of the desired ratio than the food price ratio itself, provided that satisfactory means are available for determining it. The questions must therefore be examined, by what feasible methods can such a food cost ratio be determined subject to the condition that numerator and denominator give equal standards of food consumption, and does the result differ materially from the result shown by the food price ratio ? T Y P E S OF SUBSTITUTIONS Substitutions may be considered as of two types, the first, where there is substantial identity between the original items and the items substituted, and the second where there is no identity but merely approximate equivalence. Of the first type may be considered the natural and the synthetic products of extract of vanilla, beet and cane sugar, etc. Substitutions of one for the other are made without question in ordinary price ratio calculations, and they may be dismissed without further consideration here. The only problem perhaps is on the borderline, whether two items that are nearly alike can or cannot be considered identical for the practical purposes of price ratio calculations. Of the second type are such substitutions as rye bread for wheaten bread, beef for mutton, rice for macaroni, etc. A whole series of gradations can be set up in the extent of substitutions: (1) substitution of a given quantity of one item for a given quantity of another; (2) substitution of a set of quantities of various items in a substitution group for a different set of quantities of the same items ; or (3) the substitution of an entirely different set of quantities of all items for the original quantities. CRITERION FOR SUBSTITUTIONS The criterion for substitutions is the savings in cost of the substituted over the original food items. In other words the compelling motive is price. Preference for the substituted item on account of its giving greater satisfaction or having a higher food value than the original item, at the same price, is the same motive in other terms. The procedure of increasing consumption of items SUBSTITUTIONS 59 when price falls, and diminishing consumption of other items when price rises, is the application of the housewife's principle of economy in food purchases. Of the many possible sets of quantities that may be substituted for the original set in the numerator of the ratio P 0 , that set should be accepted which gives the smallest total sum and yields the same standard of food consumption as the original set, that is, will yield the maximum savings over the original cost. BASIS FOB EQUIVALENCE A crucial question is the basis for equivalence of food standards, or for determining when the standards of numerator and denominator are equal or equivalent. Two bases may be examined: the nutritive and the economic. The nutritive basis accepts as a test of equivalence the findings of nutrition experts concerning the food values of different foodstuffs in terms of their food elements—calories, proteins, minerals, and vitamins. This can be applied to substitutions of a single item for another, of a group of items for another group, or, with more difficulty, to the substitution of an entirely new set of items for the original set. The economic basis accepts as a test of equivalence the verdict of the individual consumers, as shown by their acts, that one set of items yields more utilities or "satisfactions" than another set. In effect, this question is not put to the test of any individual preferences : the preference is inferred by means of theoretical reasoning. The exact position may be made clear as follows. With a given sum of money in region 0, a consumer will adjust his purchases in such a way t h a t his total "satisfactions" will be a maximum; a t the margin, where specific alternatives are tested, his purchase of any item will depend on whether that item will yield him more satisfaction than the purchase of any alternative item; this depends, therefore, upon the relative marginal utilities, to the individual consumer, of the several items available in the local market, and these marginal utilities of the different consumers are adjusted to the prices prevailing in the local market. When such a consumer with his scale of preferences adjusted to local prices in region 0 moves to region 1 with a different set of prices, he will in general, by changing the quantities, be able to increase his "satisfactions" in expending the sum 2 p x qa which is sufficient for him to purchase exactly the quantities he purchased in region 0. In other words, he can obtain equal satisfactions at a less cost and can therefore maintain the same "standard" of satisfactions as before at less expense than S pi q0. ^ 60 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS Exactly similar reasoning applies to the consumer who has adjusted his food consumption to the prices prevailing in region 1 when he moves to region 0. He also can increase his "satisfactions" by changing his consumption to conform to the new set of prices in region 0, and can do so at less cost than the sum 2 p 0 QiThe points to be noted in this reasoning are (1) the "satisfactions" are based upon "utilities" which are adapted to local prices, in such a way that the marginal utilities to each individual consumer of each "last" item purchased all exceed the marginal utility of their money cost. They are therefore essentially economically determined. (2) When the satisfaction or preference scales of individual consumers from the two markets are compared, there is no basis for deciding whose scale of preferences shall govern. (3) True comparisons of food standards should be based in some way upon quantities consumed rather than upon many values. These points may be made clearer by a specific illustration. If the satisfactions derived from the consumption of 1 kilogram of bread and 1 kilogram of milk and 1 kilogram of oranges are compared, analysis shows that the satisfactions are indicated by the marginal utilities of the different items. If, in one market, prices of 1 kilo, of bread = 1 kilo, of milk = l kilo, of oranges, relative satisfactions or marginal utilities tend to become adjusted to these prices. If then an individual with a preference scale so adjusted buys in another market where z/± kilo, of bread equals \Y¿ kilo. of milk equals Y% kilo, of oranges, he will shift his consumption and his preference scale until his marginal utilities tend to agree with this new set of prices. He will tend to consume more milk and fewer oranges and consider that his "satisfactions" have been increased. On the other hand, the individual whose preferences have been adjusted to the second set of prices will, if transferred to the first region, tend to consume less milk, more bread, and more oranges, and consider likewise that his satisfactions have been increased. Equal "satisfactions" thus appear to depend upon values which vary with prices in the market. As a result of changes in prices in a given market, quantities consumed change. Changes in prices in the same market are relatively easy to follow in their effects on changes in consumption. In the case of comparisons between different markets, the exposition is complicated by the facts that prices are different rather than changed and that quantities consumed are different and may or may not accord with what one would expect if both prices and quantities referred to the same market. Assuming for ease of exposition that prices and quantities in the two markets react as if they were in a single market, and that currencies and commodities SUBSTITUTIONS 61 are identical, then if a price is reduced, the quantity consumed tends to be increased. If more than one commodity is involved, those with lower prices tend to have larger quantities and those with higher prices tend to have smaller quantities. The crucial question concerns the standard of food consumption which depends not on prices but on quantities. If some items have increased and others decreased consumption, how are the different items to be combined ? If the test "satisfactions" is adopted, the different items are combined on the basis of their marginal utilities in the market concerned, which is, at one remove, according to the relative prices of the different foodstuffs. When two markets are involved, as in case of price ratios, the question as to which of the two sets of marginal utilities should govern is left unanswered. If the test "food values" is adopted, the different items are combined on the basis of their respective food elements and a definite answer can be offered to the question as to whether two standards are or are not equivalent. To take a specific case, if two communities are identical in all respects except for their respective prices of milk and bread, and the prices are such that in one community relatively more bread and less milk is consumed, whereas in the other relatively less bread and more milk, the nutritive appraisal would prefer the second, while the economic appraisal, strictly, would appear to adjudge the preference in the light of the respective prices of bread and milk. In practice, the economic test can be utilised only by means of complex mathematical methods for the solution of the problem of food cost ratios. MATHEMATICAL METHODS I t may be worth while, in the search for feasible methods for calculating food cost ratios, to consider the attempts to solve these difficulties by mathematical methods. The underlying assumptions are that all conditions in the two communities compared are identical, except only such changes in consumption as are induced by price differences: tastes, habits, customs, etc., are the same. One of the most interesting of these attempts is Wald's method. 1 He restricts the analysis to the comparison in time of prices in the same community and utilises the demand curves for each item which he considers applicable to the two times compared. This avoids the problem of trying to equate both "satisfactions" derived i A. WALD, "New Formula for the Index of Cost of Living", Econometrica, Vol. 7, No. 4, Oct. 1939, pp. 319-331. 24 62 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS from consumption preference scales in two different markets. Utilising the "Engel curves" of each item as derived from family budget data—showing the total cost of each food item purchased as total expenditure increases—and assuming for ease of computation that all such curves are straight lines, he reaches a formula in which the food cost ratio is / = 2 Pi (g° + X gi) S Pa (go + X 5i) where X is a fraction giving the ratio of the marginal utilities of money in the two situations.1 This result is substantially identical with that of Bowlty's analysis. In this result, however, the values óf the quantities of region 1 are given more weight if they are on the whole larger.2 In commenting on this result, four points may be made. First, though the exact significance of the simplifying assumptions is difficult to appreciate, it appears to give a result which takes account only of price differences rather than one which takes account of all substitutions under the conditions envisaged above. Secondly, the difference in practice between the results of the substitution formula and the average of P0 and f\ depends essentially on the value of X: if X is large the result tends to move towards Pi, if small, towards P 0 , while if X is equal to 1, the result is approximately the average of the two. Thirdly, if "Engel curves" have to be calculated for each food item in each food area, the work of calculating a single ratio on this plan might be so great as to render unfeasible the method as applied to the task of calculating an entire set of ratios between each pair of countries. Fourthly, the method is restricted to cases where data are available for calculating the "Engel curves". Another mathematical approach is Frisch's so-called "double expenditure" method.3 On this basis, the quantities of numerator and denominator of the price ratio fraction are considered equivalent where Q — 1, Q being a quantity ratio of the same type as P is a price ratio, i.e., where i If all the Engel curves are straight lines through the origin, the formula is simplified into the Fisher formula. Ibid., p. 331. 2 See Ragnar FRISCH, "Annual Survey of Economic Theory: The Problem of Index Numbers", Econometrica, Vol. 4, No. 1, Jan. 1936, p. 28; also, A. L. BOWLEY, "Note on Professor Frisch's, 'The Problem of Index Numbers' ", Econometrica, Vol. 6, No. 1, Jan. 1938, pp. 83-84. 3 The criterion is stated by Frisch as Sp 0 qt Spi q¡ = Spi go Spo q<¡. See Ragnar FRISCH, he. cit., p. 29. Also "The Double Expenditure Method", Econometrica, Vol. 6, No. 1, Jan. 1938, p. 85. See also Robert M. WOODBURY, "Quantity Adjustment Factors in Cost of Living Ratios", Econometrica, Vol. 8, No. 4, Oct. 1940, pp. 327-38. 63 SUBSTITUTIONS X Po gì S p i gì = \ S po Ço S p i Co This method, however, for the points to which the criterion applies, i.e., where Q = 1, gives the same ratio as that given by the Fisher formula for this point. This, then, substitutes for an answer to the general question, what effect do substitutions have upon the food price ratio, the specific answer that where Q = 1 substitutions as envisaged by the formula have no effect, or that they have the same effect upon both ratios, leaving the final answer the same as that given by the Fisher formula. PRACTICAL TECHNIQUES The use of the nutritive basis of equivalence seems to offer a practical technique for calculating the effect of substitutions. Under this plan, the different food items can be assigned to "substitution groups", within which substitutions may be made on the basis of approximate equivalence of nutritive elements. For purposes of simplicity of statement, we may consider these substitution groups: I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IX. X. Wheaten bread, rye bread, (flour)1, rice, macaroni. Beef, pork, mutton, veal, etc. Margarine (butter) 2 . Milk, cheese. Fresh (leafy, green, and yellow) vegetables. Other fresh vegetables. Citrus fruits. Other fruits. Coffee, tea (cocoa, chocolate). Sugar, honey. Substitutions may be allowed of one item for another item within the same group, subject to the reservation that in a particular case some extra or supplementary items may have to purchased in order to maintain the standard. For example, if macaroni is substituted for rye bread, a supplementary purchase of tomato sauce or 1 T h e substitution of flour for bread is in part a difference in the degree of preparation, and represents an increase in the home baking of food : to avoid the complication entailed by the difference in the degree of preparation, wheaten flour may be converted into its equivalent wheaten bread (7-10ths of a kilo, of flour—1 kilo, of bread) before testing the amount of saving possible by substitutions. Other differences in t h e degree of preparation may be involved in other cases, e.g., macaroni for bread, b u t these are of relatively small importance. 2 Butter and margarine are obviously not perfect substitutes, since the former has vitamins which t h e latter lacks. 2 4 64 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS cheese may be required to keep food values unimpaired. All such questions must be left to the nutrition expert. For present purposes, to test the importance of substitutions in influencing the food cost ratio, the present scheme of substitution groups may be tentatively accepted, subject however to the reservation that where supplementary items are needed, the saving indicated by the substitution procedure may be too large and overstate the true saving. Having established the groups within which substitutions may be made, the next step is to establish a basis of equivalence within each substitution group. This may be kilograms, as 1 kilogram of wheaten bread = 1 kilogram of rye bread, or calories, as 100 calories of beef = 100 calories of mutton, or in terms of other nutritive elements. The basis of equivalence should take care of the variations in the percentage of waste, as in the proportion of bone in the different cuts of meat, etc. The quantities and prices in each substitution group must then be converted into this new basic unit. The limits to which substitutions are allowed are established by taking the percentages prevailing in the numerator country as limits. For example, in Denmark, as a numerator country, rye is cheaper than wheaten bread and 82 per cent, of the bread consumed in Denmark is rye. Consequently the limit of permissible substitutions of rye for wheaten bread is set at 82 per cent, in all ratios where Denmark is the numerator country. Finally the items are arranged in order of the prices prevailing in the numerator country, and the amount of each item is calculated, beginning with the most expensive, by taking the proportion (of the remaining or unallocated quantity in the substitution group as expressed in the new units) found in the numerator country if less is consumed there than in the denominator country or the proportion found in the denominator country if less is consumed there than in the numerator country. These amounts are then multiplied by the prices as expressed in the new units. The sum of these amounts times prices is then substituted for the somewhat larger original sum in the numerator of the price ratio fraction. 1 In each food ratio the denominator is unchanged. SUBSTITUTIONS AND THE GROUP BASKET M E T H O D The preceding discussion has been in terms of substitutions as affecting the ratio between two countries, when the individual 1 T h e use of t h e average price per new unit in the substitution group, though simpler t h a n the method described above, will not give the same results, since it may require substitutions in some cases where costs are increased by the substitution. SUBSTITUTIONS 65 baskets are used in the calculations. With the group basket method no substitutions are made between countries in the same group, since for these the same basket is used. Substitutions are thus limited to cases arising between countries in different groups, and the amounts of savings are calculated on the basis of the differences between the group baskets in conjunction with the price differences. This simplification effects a marked reduction in the amount of calculation necessary, though it gives a slightly different result than if individual baskets were used. 1 RESULTS Results of substitutions were examined for two cases: namely, that of rye and wheaten bread and that of beef, pork, veal, and mutton. In the case of bread, substitutions are made kilogram for kilogram, since the calorie content per kilogram is substantially the same; whereas in the case of the four meats, "equivalent beef" units were used, based largely upon calorie content: pork was converted into equivalent beef units at the rate of .8 kg. pork equals 1 kg. beef; veal at the rate of 1.2 kg. veal equals 1 kg. beef, and mutton at the rate of 1 kg. mutton equals 1 kg. beef. The net effect of substitutions involving the four meats upon the final ratios was not great. The largest changes (affecting 4 ratios, i.e., two ratios and their reciprocals) were between two and three per cent. ; three-fourths of the changes were of less than half of one per cent.; twenty were between one and two per cent. The possibility of substituting the cheaper for the dearer meats up to the limits set by the proportionate consumption in the country where the substitution is made according to the group basket of that country does not produce substantial changes in the results. The effect of substituting rye for wheaten bread (and vice versa) is more considerable* especially in ratios between rye consuming and wheat consuming countries. Table X I I I gives the ratios for the different countries as calculated following the substitution procedure outlined above. Of the total of 342 ratios, 262 are potentially affected: the rest, besides the.27 intra-group comparisons, are cases where the proportions of the two kinds of bread in conjunction with the price difference do not permit of savings from substitutions. 1 An alternative procedure is also possible, to use the same total quantities in the substitution group in numerator and denominator (as before) but to utilise the proportions of the numerator country basket (instead of those of the group basket corresponding to the numerator country) in calculating the amounts for the numerator. With this procedure, corrections appear also in ratios between countries of the same group. m pi SÎ5SSS N O O O O r-lCOCOOOIN IMCOlO^OO Oi-INr-"^ 8S3S CO I N CO CM. CN SîgSigS "#t~ioiocN o i O H O œ N O O 0 0 H O O M ^ t - IO O i-l 00 *)< • # » "-i oo es os i—i o o o œ o o i o S-s i o i—i co co »o IM OOOOOSTÌ« HMCDOS'* THOOOOt^CO ¿ti O Ol i-H a s e s a r * OS <N I N C O O IO ( D b . C D O M W O O H O O O H O O COCNTtlcNIN o coas as ooooot- IO OS CO CO OOSOSOO Z i U Ì C D H T ) ! CM CD (M CC C O O OOOiHOO oooooosco i-ICNTtHCDCD t * ri* T}I CO Ti* • * C S « w O OS IO CD 00 CO OOPlrtN So-Sgg O—ICO I M O CO CO <N C O O 55- t^-TjHCOOO H H O O ! H O N O oosoooo C M l O i O M * >H i-HCNi-li-l 5 OS CO 00 OS 00 00 CM - H CM. l-l »H rt^^H^CM M O O 0 0 H N O O f O O « » N O N COCOt*.t~0 si ¡SgcSSSg ssssg M O O - # N CDOOOOt^O «'a ssssg §££§§ ^Ht~^HCO00 >o i o co i o oo ^IrtrH-H t~00OSO t > CO CO CO ooooot~© Qg va H IOOST-I OSO « • - H IM CO CO t - 0 0 OS 00 I N H N O H 1 3 - * O S Ó O S 00 C O M r t O N cNosomoo o ^ c o o c o CO CO 00 t*» i-l Oi-lt-OSi-t r - o o oo t - I M S Te ts< pT )o< -s<o0 äSSSS 5Sf£S^ CM (M CM i-l i-l ^H^i-(r-*CN i-l^i-Hi-l • C3 > as Si Ï Ï CS s g E o • a a •ß.3 S ja a 3 Cü 3 N J£ «JfQCQüQ IS ^ ¿IN -S S OJTJ -• rt Cü ri a g u a *» 3 Jâ a S ça n .S t< o t* C Cd 3 tì 0) 0"o ¡nszZfri Sî ö & £¿? TI o c CCOQl-Jp SUBSTITUTIONS 67 Of the 262 cases, 124 or nearly half, involved changes so slight that they did not alter the ratio when expressed to two decimal places, and 55 more altered it only one point in the second place: thus two-thirds of the ratios potentially affected were not altered or were altered in only a negligible degree. Of the rest (83), 25 involved a change of two points, 14 of three points, 8 of four points t and 36 of five or more points. A small number of cases, therefore, involved a considerable change in the ratio. The largest percentage change was 19 per cent. (15 points) in the case of the ratio Estonia/Bulgaria, with 16 per cent. (20 points) in the reciprocal ratio Bulgaria/Estonia. Almost equally large was the change in the ratios between Italy and Estonia: Estonia/Italy 19 per cent. and Italy/Estonia 15.5 per cent. The third largest change was 18 per cent, in the case of the ratio Great Britain/Estonia with a corresponding change in the reciprocal ratio 15.5 per cent. Estonia/ Great Britain. An examination of these large changes shows that the question is of greatest importance when ratios between a wheat-consuming and a rye-consuming country are concerned, and that they are greater when the disparity between the proportions consumed is greater, when the quantity of bread consumed is greater, and when the difference between the rye and wheaten bread prices is greater. An important point is the direction of change in any given ratio. 1 Any given ratio, P , is the average of the two ratios, P 0 and P i , for the two countries concerned : the substitution procedure affects the quantities of one country in P 0 and those of the other country in Pi. In terms of the wheat-rye substitution, assuming that the rye price is less than that of wheat in both countries and that the wheat consuming country is in the denominator, the effect of the substitution is to lower P 0 and leave P i unchanged; the average of the two thus tends to move towards P i since in general P 0 exceeds Pi. If the rye consuming country is in the denominator, P 0 is unchanged while P i is increased, and the average tends to move toward P 0 . 2 8 1 So far as net changes in the aggregate are concerned, since half the ratios are the reciprocals of the other half, a change in one ratio produces an approximately equal (percentage) change in its reciprocal in the opposite direction. 2 This result may be compared with those reached by Bowley and Wald. Wald's conclusion is t h a t the true ratio, when allowances are made for price changes and their consequences upon the demand for the different items consumed, may be expressed : j = 2 Pi (go + X qrQ S po (ç. + X g,) where X is a factor t h a t modifies the q¡'s. This means t h a t where X is greater than » , (continued on next page) 68 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS • SCOPE OF SUBSTITUTIONS As to the scope of substitutions, theoretically, an indefinite number of possible substitutions, each equivalent to the original food basket (or part of basket), may be set up by nutrition experts : of these only those which represent savings need be considered, and in practice, only t h a t one—covering the whole food basket—which represents the maximum savings is important. The analysis made in the preceding section suggests, furthermore, t h a t for practical purposes a particular proposed substitution need be considered only if the savings are substantial, since otherwise the final ratios will not be materially affected. On the one hand substitutions may be limited to the locally available items which offer inexpensive and preferred alternatives in the original food budget, or on the other hand may be extended over the whole range of the food budget, so as to secure 100 per cent, coverage of the food basket by using substitutes for all items 1 the value of 1 moves in the direction of Pi, whereas if X is less than 1 it moves in the direction of Po. In Bowley's formula as modified and interpreted by Frisch, the condition that X is greater than 1 corresponds to the ?i's being greater than the go's and the prices in region 1 lower: in this case the value of the ratio moves towards Pi. In the illustration above, the price of rye bread was lower than that of wheaten bread and more would, therefore, in theory, be consumed in the numerator country: in this case the value of the ratio with substitutions tended to move towards Pi. Though the mode of description of the two cases differs, they appear to correspond in their effects. 3 Reference may be made here to the method of calculating a cost-of-food ratio suggested by the Swedish Social Board for comparing relative costs in Detroit and Stockholm. See INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE: A Contribution to the Study of International Comparisons of Costs of Living. An Enquiry into the Cost of Living of Certain Groups of Workers in Detroit (U.S.A.) and Fourteen European Towns, Studies and Reports, Series N, Statistics, No. 17 (Second revised edition), pp. 69-70. This method proposed that the food budget be divided into the "staple" foods and the non-staple foods, the former including flour, bread, breakfast foods, potatoes, peas and beans, sugar, syrup, and oleomargarine, and the latter all the rest, including the protein-containing foods, the protective foods, etc.; that an average price per calorie be calculated for each group, and that the ratios of these average prices per calorie in each group be weighted by the proportion that each group formed of the total value of the Detroit budget. In essence, this is a procedure of substitutions with two substitution groups, in which, however, substitutions are made not merely when savings can be made, but irrespective of savings the proportions of foods consumed in the numerator community (Stockholm) are substituted for those of the denominator community (Detroit). The calculation was made only for the Po ratio Stockholm/Detroit; this happens to be the one in which large savings appear; and the hew ratio for Po is found to be reduced by 24.1 per cent. This reduction is somewhat less than would have been shown had substitutions been limited to those cases where savings would have appeared (30.0 per cent.). Had the Pi ratio been calculated following the method of the Swedish Social Board, it would have some been 8.1 per cent, below the original Pi; but in theory, Pi is a minimum; following the method of restricting substitutions to cases where savings can be made, the ratio would have been raised 1.4 per cent, above the original P\. No special importance should be attached to these values since the substitution groups were taken with far too wide a range and the basis of equivalence in calories only cannot well be justified. SUBSTITUTIONS 69 not locally available. A broad scope, however, raises difficulties of determining the equivalence of the substituted for the original foods and increases the volume of calculations, especially where special computations have to be made to provide for equivalence by adding in the cost of supplementary items deemed necessary by nutrition experts. A practical compromise to reduce calculations to the minimum is to restrict the scope of substitutions to those which lead to substantial savings. CONCLUSIONS The fundamental assumption of the substitution method is that the substituted foods are equivalent in food standard to the original foods. If this is true, there appears to be no valid objection to accepting the results. If the substituted foods are of equal or superior standard to the original foods and cost less, the substitution ratio would appear to be superior to the ratio obtained by comparing prices. But if the substituted foods are of lower standard than the original ones, the lower cost may be due in part or wholly to their lower standard, and the result of such a substitution can not safely be accepted, even though in a given case it may be possible that the result is better than that afforded by the price ratio technique. The acceptability of the substitution method in its specific applications thus involves the acceptability of the specific substitutions. For example, nutrition experts would probably consider that the substitution of rye bread for white bread improved rather than impaired the diet, and doubt would arise, perhaps, as to the advisability of admitting the substitution of white bread for rye. In regard to the basis of equivalence adopted in the calculations described above for the four meats, much depends upon the actual cuts of the different meats commonly purchased in the different countries and on the proportion of lean and fat ; the calculation was made as a crude test of the importance of these substitutions in affecting the final ratios without implying that the equivalents used were satisfactory from the point of view of nutrition. There remains the question whether any elements not concerned with nutrition must be included in the appraisal of equivalence of food standards. Can the equivalence of food standards be determined on the judgment of nutrition experts, or have utilities, satisfactions, or preferences of consumers also to be considered? There is no problem where nutrition experts and preferences of 2 4 70 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS consumers agree; in such a case, the substitution ratio can be definitely preferred to the price ratio. In the long run they doubtless tend to coincide. Preferences of consumers educated to nutrition values tend towards the purchase of the nutritionally most valuable foods for the money. Tastes and habits of consumers in a particular market are often formed by price conditions; the cheaper foods, preferred at first on account of price, are presently preferred on account of taste. To some extent the reverse effect may be found : foods may be preferred on account of their being expensive, and their consumption favoured because it appears to belong with higher economic status. Difficulties arise, however, in trying to harmonise preferences derived from two different markets in order to derive a satisfactory food price ratio between them. The whole question may be summed up as follows : the classical price ratio technique offers a method of comparing prices in different markets which is for practical purposes substantially valid; in certain cases, where equivalent foods can be substituted for the original foods, the substitution technique offers a ratio that is preferable to that obtained by the price ratio technique, but its acceptability in the given case is dependent upon adequate proof that the condition of equivalent standards is satisfied. As a practical proposal, therefore, its use should be limited to those cases where, on account of special local conditions, large savings can be expected by substituting an inexpensive and good article of food for a general item which in the local market appears to occupy an exceptional position as a luxury item or is not available at all. CHAPTER V CONCLUSIONS In summary, the following conclusions have been reached. (1 ) The group basket method appears to afford a satisfactory technique for international comparisons of food prices subject to a small margin of error. (2 ) A satisfactory technique for grouping countries according to similarity of proportionate consumption is developed. The number of groups should in practice be sufficient to provide representation of the major types of food consumption in the various countries compared. (3 ) A technique is presented for correction factors which substantially reduce errors. (4) The method utilises the cost of the group basket (with correction factors) as the basis of comparison between countries in the same group, and the geometric average of the ratios obtained by using the two group baskets, corresponding to the two countries, when two countries in different groups are compared. (5 ) A technique for extending the results to other cities in the countries included is described. (6) A technique for extending the results to cities in countries not included in the original analysis is presented, provided that the new country or countries can be assimilated to one of the groups already established. If the new countries do not belong to one of the groups already set up, a new group or groups are required. (7) Differences in consumption in different economic groups in many cases do not appear to cause large differences in results. In cases where greater accuracy is required a special technique is suggested. (8) Sources of error in quantities and prices are examined. The need for careful description (qualities, etc.), of articles to be priced, for comparable sources for price data, and for special methods for checking up data for use in international or interregional comparisons is emphasised. The extension of the list of articles to be priced is desirable. 24 72 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS (9) In cases where the prices of particular articles are out of line or where the item is not available, or where a cheap substitute is locally preferred, a substitution ratio may give a more satisfactory result than the price ratio technique. Details for a substitution technique are worked out. It is suggested that the substitutions be limited to cases where large savings are to be expected and where local preferences favour the substituted item; and that they be restricted to such as, in the judgment of nutrition experts, are nutritionally equivalent. All ratios using substitutions should carry notes indicating the exact type and nature of the substitution. (10) Climatic differences in food requirements are neglected on account of lack of data. In general, if differences in food habits and conditions are too great, the food price ratio, the substitution ratio, and the food cost ratio all lose their significance. (11) In using the results, care should be taken not to place too great reliance upon the exact decimals of the ratios, since errors from various sources, up to two or three per cent, or even more, may affect the figures. APPENDIX I RESOLUTIONS ADOPTED BY INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCES, THE COMMITTEE OF STATISTICAL EXPERTS, AND THE GOVERNING BODY OF THE INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE (1) Second International Conference of Statisticians convoked by the Social Science Research Council (U.S.A.) (May 1930). B.—INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF COST OF LIVING. III. In order to see how far different methods of comparing real wages agree with one another, the Committee recommends as desirable: . . . (d) that in view of the fact that cost-of-living index numbers depend more on the prices than on the composition of the budgets, and that retail prices of the same article vary considerably according to quality, precautions be taken with a view to ensure that, as far as possible, the comparability of prices is maintained. It would be desirable before making comparisons that the statistical offices of different countries be requested to furnish detailed information as to the quality of the articles indicated in the budgets, and for any observations to which these budgets may give rise from the point of view of international comparisons. (2) Fourth International Conference of Labour Statisticians (May 1931). (6) The International Labour Office should continue to collect and publish statistics of the retail prices of the articles of food consumed by working-class families in the towns for which 2 4 74 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS particulars as to wages are collected; particulars should also be collected of the prices of fuel and light in these towns. The statistics hitherto published should be extended as far as possible and in publishing the information the Office should give such indications as can be obtained as to the scope of the data. (8) In those countries in which no family budget enquiries have been made during the last ten years, such enquiries should be undertaken at the earliest possible date, on the lines laid down in the resolutions adopted at the third Conference of Labour Statisticians in 1926. (9) The wages and prices information referred to in the preceding paragraphs should be collected and published by the International Labour Office at annual intervals. The Office should address each year to the statistical offices of each contributing Government a questionnaire soliciting the fullest possible particulars of wages and retail prices and rents relating as nearly as possible to the month of October. In view of the fact that there are important seasonal variations in the prices of certain foodstuffs, such prices should be obtained several times a year. (11) Following upon the publication of this volume (Yearbook including statistics of wages, rates of wages, earnings, and retail prices, etc.), there should be prepared and published in the International Labour Review an article in which the data contained in the published volume should be discussed from the standpoint of determining the relative levels of purchasing power of wages in the various countries. In this article the difficulties of the procedure should be fully and frankly disclosed. Indices on various bases should be given, with the purpose of indicating the various points of view from which comparisons can be made and of preventing any one figure being regarded as authoritative for all purposes. In view of the fact that the index numbers of purchasing power of wages serve different national purposes, it is impracticable for the International Labour Office to compute all the comparisons which are possible between a series of countries and between different occupations and industries. The series of index numbers compiled by the Office should be illustrative of the methods by which the data may be used for computing further series. (13) The calculation of these index numbers by the use of information as to working-class consumption furnished by family APPENDIX I 75 budget enquiries should be made not only as hitherto on a fixed international budget but also on the basis of various national or regional budgets. (14) The Conference realises that comparisons cannot usefully be made between countries of widely differing habits and customs ; and that the closer are the consumption habits in different countries, the more trustworthy are the comparisons likely to be. (15) The Conference is unable to recommend the proposal to compare countries of dissimilar conditions by progression through countries with intermediate conditions owing to the lack of information on such conditions at the present time and to the absence of any criterion for measuring the degree of dissimilarity among the intermediate countries. (16) In all comparisons between two or more countries, however, allowance should be made for the difference in articles consumed in each of the countries by basing the calculations successively on the list of important articles consumed in one country and the list of important articles (but not necessarily the same articles) consumed in the others. (17) It is also desirable that as regards certain articles of food for which direct comparison of prices as between one country and another is impracticable, the International Labour Office should explore the question of supplementing the present method of calculation by a method in which account would be taken of the possibilities of comparisons of prices on a basis of nutritive value. R E COMMENDATION The Conference recommends that the Governing Body place the question of the supply of the data required for the purpose of these international comparisons of wages and cost of living on the agenda of a future International Labour Conference with a view to the framing of a Convention binding the Governments which ratify it to collect and supply the information at regular intervals. It recommends that a small committee of experts representing the competent national statistical authorities might be set up. The function of this committee would be to assist the Office in its work of developing and publishing wage and cost-of-living statistics and in preparing for any future international conference which might appear desirable in the near future. 2 4 76 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF POOD COSTS (3) Committee of Statistical Experts (1st Meeting, December 1933). RESOLUTION I (1) As regards the cost of food, the Committee recommends that the International Labour Office continue : (a) its theoretical research, not only on the lines indicated in its memorandum 1 , but also in other directions and particularly from the point of view of physiological standards; (ò) its practical studies, and the periodical publication of international indices of the cost of food. (2) Before indicating some of the principles on which it is possible to express an opinion at present, the Committee recognises that, on the one hand, the absence, in very many cases, of recent enquiries into family budgets classified according to incomes and localities, and showing both the expenditure and the quantities consumed, and, on the other hand, the defects in the statistics of retail prices, present serious obstacles to the application of any method of comparison. In order, however, to enable the International Labour Office to utilise all the data of sufficient value available in the different countries, the Committee recommends that in each case the procedure should be that which is best adapted to the character and the value of these data. It is nevertheless obvious that relatively summary methods can alone be used when the data necessary for more refined calculations are at present lacking. The following principles therefore apply only to comparisons relating to the countries in which the statistical information available enables more elaborate methods to be applied. (3) In accordance with the recommendations of the fourth International Conference of Labour Statisticians, the comparisons should be made on the basis of national or regional budgets of family expenditure; further, indices obtained by different methods should be calculated and published simultaneously. For the purpose of these index numbers, there should be included within the same "region" only those countries, parts of countries, or towns in which the habits of consumption and the price systems are sufficiently comparable; in the first place, the percentage of the total food expenditure represented by the expenditure on articles of common consumption should be sufficiently high; 1 Now published as Part I of International Comparisons of Cost of Living, Studies and Reports, Series N, Statistics, No. 20. APPENDIX I 77 the further criteria suggested in the above-mentioned memorandum may then be applied, and account taken of variations in comparability according to the level of incomes. In principle, "regions" should be formed by towns and not by countries; consequently, they should not necessarily be constituted in such a manner as to cover the whole of a country; they may, for example, include certain towns and exclude others belonging to the same country. When, however, the available data do not admit of the separate consideration of several towns within a country, a single town or an average covering several towns may be taken, and in this case, in default of appropriate data, it will be admissible to utilise, for the purpose of weighting, average quantities relating to the country as a whole. Geographical proximity and comparability from points of view other than that of food consumption may be taken into account in allocating a town to one region or another in those cases in which it is almost or wholly a matter of indifference to which region a town is allotted. It will be expedient to restrict the number of regions as far as possible. In order to reduce the calculations involved, the number of towns should be reduced so far as possible to the capital and, where necessary, some other representative towns in each country. (4) In each "region" a town should be chosen as "regional centre", well comparable with the other towns in the "region". The Office is invited to prepare a primary system of "regions" which will serve as a basis for its calculations. The Office might, in addition, study other systems of "regions" with a view to the ultimate adoption of the system which would yield the best results. (5) For the comparisons within each region, it will be sufficient to calculate one index between each town and its regional centre. (6) For comparisons between the regional centres a formula should be adopted which takes account of the consumption in each of them. Indices of this kind should be accompanied by an indication as to the degree of confidence which can be placed in them so as to avoid any misinterpretations. (7) For the calculation of an index relating to two towns belonging to different regions the Committee is of opinion that it is impossible to formulate a general rule applicable to all cases. If questions of this nature arise, the Office should select in each particular case the method of calculation which appears the most appropriate. (8) The publication should include any necessary reservations, and the Committee expresses the opinion that it should contain not only the computed indices, but also the original data used in the calculations. - , 78 INTERNATIONAL COMPARISONS OF FOOD COSTS (4) Committee of the Governing Body on Cost of Living and Wage Statistics (December 1930). Extract from resolution adopted : (1) The Committee recognises the difficulties encountered in making international real wage comparisons and fully appreciates the work of the International Labour Office in this domain and the successive improvements introduced into the methods employed. It considers however that certain modifications are necessary in order to make those comparisons of greater value . . . (2) . . . (e) To avoid any errors due to differences in the selected qualities of the various commodities, the International Labour Office should ask for a careful description of quality in its questionnaire. (/) In order that the degree of reliability of the indices relative to countries with widely differing customs, needs, and habits may be judged, the index numbers should be computed and published, not only on the basis of an average international budget, but also on the basis of different budgets . . . (3) . . . (j) The method of making comparisons between countries with widely differing conditions of living by progression through countries with intermediate conditions should be examined and introduced into the calculations if it should appear practicable and advantageous. APPENDIX II TABLE 1. CORRECTION FACTORS TO P'„ AND P\ BY COUNTRIES Correction factors Austria Belgium Bulgaria Czecho-Slovakia Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Great Britain Hungary Italy Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden Switzerland Union of South Africa United States 1 Country of denominator. ' Country of numerator. 2 4 c1 Ci« 1.0694 1.0504 1.0237 .9647 1.0984 .9351 .9520 .9769 1.0366 .9104 1.0465 1.0553 1.0967 1.0432 1.0819 .9556 .9476 .9118 .9586 .9243 1.0331 1.0415 1.0402 1.0710 1.0593 .9680 .9602 .9614 .9337 .9440 1.0045 1.0426 1.0464 1.0000 .9956 .9591 .9557 1.0000 —it-ososT* ta m • * ! D M H O t-- I O O S - * IO i-H I - I T - I I - H COT^CCt--* I Û T C OSOCO COTHIOCOCO 1-3 O sì I- II ëî °a iti lì li 05 (>> .ss ss. si <u _i-H —I ^ j - l Ci —i to to to IN 00 C 0 - * T J < i-l OS CO © i—( OS COOOCNCOrH » O r t O l O N CO CO I O CO CO CO I N T h e o -*OSCN00OS IN IN C t o n i o © O S CO —l IO INOOIOOO CO OS 00 I N - * CO Tfl • * (N T(< CDCOOINCO OS IO IO • * CD C N 0 5 C N - * IO 0 0 - * t o t » IN CN —I —I —I ^H W O I O T Ì O CDl-OOt-O T-H t-H i-t i-H H 0 0 O ' * • * H O H liîO—IIN H Ö H O o »o »-i os O O C 5 N © O S OS 00 05 00 IO <N i-H CO CO IO oor-t-co - * O T * © , - ( W O I O O H C S M H O O i—I —I —I —I r lOCOWINN C S O N O l O iOIN-*©CN CO O S © IO CO t-CSt-CO© COCO COCO —I -*IN©t--* lONOiON ooos©cs-* OCNOOCOCD 0>t-0-*CO t-noon oooo—icoos T-H O O I O O CO OS t— O W H H O O O N H O Ü.ÜS §!§§! inoooMo CM — l i O C M H O O O S CSCOt-iO T*-* TJIIO o o en oo ocococo CO CO C O I N - * 00 IO c o t - I N C O O - * lOCO O O H O O H H O C O T H « H M O 0 0 IN l O t - l O I N ©OOtr-00-* ©IOOSCOIN OOSCNCMOO O O W M N I1ISÌ2 IN O S - * — i © IO t o - * 0 0 O •*CNCO—ito •*-*—ioOiO 00 00COO5 TJH N H 0 5 0 t - C O C M 00 H O O » t--(N © - * - * © C O O - * P l f O O N l O H N O t » OOCNtCM CM —< 00 CO CO © C M I N 00 CO i o CM IONCON ©•*CMiO C O - * i o CO t - - * ose»co t - I O CO CO I O IN io osco—< •* o> oo oo t» os — H N ^ H co io co e o o OS t - — 1 0 0 H O H C « oocNcot00 IO I N CM COCMCNf- I N <N I N 1-H 1-1 —1—I.M^HtN CO-*cN00© t»t-OCOco CO b - 0 0 b - I H Tt<l-<O0Tf< TU CO IO CO •*01THOOO) t»lO©COCO - < I N O — I 00 CO 1-1 © I O 0 0 §§§§§ eooioeo-* OSQCOCDH » O H I O O Ì CO i O IO »O OS HOOOr-l<N t-<NOO0OtN H co io oo OSi-iOO-* t-t-t-CO IO t o t o H I N C O t - t - C N CN IO 00 CO CO OS OCOCOCO tOOOO—i CO IO COkO co to co os co i-irtoo^i-i TjHCOr-lrH • * CO CD 00 I-—IOS00CN ©oooot- r- oo os co oo •*—itOtN • * IO IO OS OS 00 OD t - OSINOOSOS 11 rH lOiOCOCOOO H I O H O Ï H •-leOlOIXN —IIOIO-*00 I N CN CO I N © CO CD 00 IO CO I N 00 Til CO CO COCM O S r - i i N t-OioCNtt - C O O S - * ÍO II Qq r-4 i-H i oo CN coco oo c o n t ó o s © C s t - t - < N co T Í i-H,-( a i t-CN COi-H-* O O i O C D N N I-H S ©coio-*co cotrt-ooco N N O t O N ©l-OO-HCM t-ooiooeo cot-cot-t- 8 C00D 0H0C- 0* Ot r —icocot-o CM t - C O CS CO COt--*rtO T U I N <N C O O -*IN O S T - Q K 3 H N O O 00to<NOi-l CO CO CO O OS IOOCN o o <NCSO0t-t> CO IO CO 00 OS T f C N C N IO OS • * OS 1-1 TX 00 r-t>csoocN « M O N O CO ( N O — i 00 I O »-H O O O OS CO IO OS CO 1-1 tv IN—100 IO CO IN CO OS CO CO OS CM 00 t- CO CO OS CO t~ CO OS 00 CO OSO-* i-l-* N O n i O N lOOCOOS-t IO CO 1-1 OS I N 00t~COt>t> •* INCOIO© O S - * C O - * 00 lOtOOCOO t> oo a> oo co CST)<-*CNOS H W t O r t P I ININtNH—I M öS • - > : o • = S 'S O 03 'S.3 3.a S •s .au? 8 a CÎFQ 3 . 3 d 9 »a += d <s Si ? OONt-rtO sss; SoI O H H O I O CO CM CO OS 00 OS t OCMCNCM iHCQOtr O O - i i H O » S tH- tH- t OS- t 1-H r-IHH—I-H —I CM —I —I I N oocot»-* —I HH —I —( ai -0 13 ••2-13 Ih S3 c3 <D O ^ IH N S V OIOTPCOO OOO-ftDOO tOCMCNCSCM CSCN i o t » t » CO -^1 O CO CO osioior-rn 001-Cat--* 00 r i tOCOCO O O O r t C O 00 tO 1-1 O r-l oo oo oo t o t o U5 O i-i 1-1 i—I os «* os t o t o iot--H>ot". to ( N M t O O lOOOOCOH i-i o o - * t o O O O O O O S CO o> t o ó o s OCSOCM O00O00 CO CM »O »O OS rH C D t ~ t ~ - l O ( O H O H H t - CM IO rH CO OOrHOiTfl t - - * CO CO OS OSCNOOOIO OSCO »O CD »O t > O S Ó O S CO f O t i * OOOSCO iHOoooo CM t ^ O S O S OS IO i * CO IO H I lOOOSOOS OS»!* I O C O O CO CO 00 CM IO I O CN r-( CD 00 OOCOCMlN ( N - * lOOSCN t-ooosoocM ©lOCOCM TtiTji r o c o c ò oo c o - ^ i r ^ os cot»t-t»t> 00 rH CO IO 00 ocooo^co rH 1-H OS i—I O ( D O N N O I O CO C O C C O pi» Q O ai W H W S ÏJ H M M œ <! m ¡s co (Ofl'JO ot-œg (NCSOO oooooot» tooio PH p THE CTO BER o «S oœ ir fiO II H Pu H O <! •4 ou P «>, ISsSS O b " * c 9 0 r-i (N i o t o IM t o CM CO t O O t^cO-tfOrH H^lrJIOlO ooosooco OOCOrH C O - * I N OS CO COOCOOOCO >Or-IOOO NOtDMOO 00 C O - * r-l CO - * » 1 C M t o OS N H O O l i J •Ot-OiO-tf CNCO00© © o s o - * OS COCO t - C O f - C O C O rH rH l O O IO t o •>* r i IO CM 00 COOCMlflN. TACO OS 1 * 0 0 rHOOCNlOr-l u r-J H < fl (J CM 00 OS C R N tO r-l 00 CO t o CO CO CM COCO sa C (H SAm O W IOCOTJICOO OCOrH OOS I O OS O O OS o SA <i H mA p «3 COR ÍES H OS U rH W ¡z¡ b N O Q OS FTER KETS < < «¡ « a,^m i*f •3'í 'A LUE ta o O Pu (71 p «•a 0 W «1 ou t» < m CM C O l O O OS CM t O O f > OS OS 00 OtOOOOO OCOt-t-CM O O H O O ooio>oto O H N I Ì O Ì O N O H O !£§<! Nt-CJiOOrH r-l CO CM CM OOOSOO xh.cot-.to r-l CO »O CO OS 3!cB tOncOCOCO 0 > O r - l O O M i t - 0 0 00 00 t^r-lO-*-* Tticgoio-* rHOOO-tft- -*rHOtOCM CO CM CO I O - * I O CO f > t o OS OOOr-l to OS CM tOCC Ttnat»Tîeo rH 0 0 CM CJSOO i f l - N N N Siili O J O K Î C Û to COCO r-l t o r-l i o t o t * t o os t-oo-*-* Ol-OSt-iO S tr »H tl -OcOoSt oO TtlOS00t»CM OSCMOSTflCO -*io>o>ooo 1-1 CM t o t O O coiOCM n o • * 00 OS O S O r-lOSTtllOTH ©CSCO-H-* COOSOiOOO O r i 00 • * 00 •I O C M - * t o >t-oot>.© Si gggl M O J O * omooooo loooioca r-C tO t - • * Tfl n t - . 00 00 OS - * O r i IO00 r—e» i o oo rn r-l IN r i —I 00 t^ooosoo n OSrl IOTH OSOSOCM00 tO-*Or1lO CMt-OCOlO r H 0 0 t » C O OS H I CO CO IO tO NlOQOCON ( N CM CM CO 00 osCMOoOn l O t O N I i 00 CO 00 tO 0 0 r i OSCS r H »O »O tO i o OSOOOSrH lOOOSCOOS • * O 0 0 03 00 00 " 1 IO CO OS t»t~t~(NO CMOSOlOCO OSrHOSrHCM • * i o CM r u t t o t > co t > © C O O C O 00 ot^osco t^t^toto O Os OSOS t » ot»ooioco TtUNgSTH-H t O O O O t CM I N CM rH i-l ooosoosto OS I N 0 0 O tO IN HICOiOrH C O t O r H OS OCMIN-* colloco r i r i r i r i CM ri ri ri ri H O H 8 It ~N 00t - i00O -00* M nooocoto OSOOt~.CN f - C M - i • * »O N 00 Tf 00 T(l 00 COt-lOOOOS CO tO t o t o tO' GO rJ ri (U ( I . O C O O T ) ( OS CM OS OS 00 OO cot-oso-* M o CATI COM ¡3 O S§ mm um t-ooooo<N oot-t-o 00t-OO00 r-l t o iO O tO " * t - l O C O tO i¿ O oO OS r-l C O N iOtOlO-tf to to co io •*-*oto N t D t o IO imu IO*O t o o oooot^t- .' cä W « m < H li Ö •'i :> o .S s a os s . 3 C3J3 a o"3 s N s <¡m«oQ 03 • -o si« 03 -O •Ga ia Sest ìa +» 'a •s .a 2 s a H P H Í ^ Ü Ü 2 4 >> ^-1 • 03 . 03 • fe 03"O J S «'S S 03 CJ O * o ¡S M r « TABLE 4. VALUES OF SUBSTITUTION RATIOS P'o, WITH SUBSTITUTIONS B E T W E E N R CATION OF CORRECTION FACTORS, et, CALCULATED BY THE GROUP BASKET 18 COMMODITIES I N 19 COUNTRIES, PRICES AS OF OC Numerator country Denominator country Austria Belgium Austria Belgium 3.176 Bulgaria Czeeho-Slovakia. Denmark Estonia 1.4741 Finland France Germany Great Britain . Hungary .753 2.057 Italy Netherlands.. Norway 1.299! Poland Sweden Switzerland.. . Union of S.Africa United States. 1.4421 1 Bulgaria CzechosloDenvakia mark 538 1.221 1.500 1.091 Estonia Finland France Germany Great Britain Hungary It .341 492 .714 .956 1.577 .647 .708 2.490 1.928 765 .6 1.529 1.3 1.618 385 1.2 1.4 553 .830 .803 1.132 .394 .646 .912 2.133 2.187 1.761 1.804 1.5 1.761 1.6 7 .843 1.418 1.2 .619 11.021 .616 .567 1.650 1.048 1.319 1. 1.214 1.0 .622 .561 .555 .485 1.6O0 1.442 1.512 1.336 1.352 1. 1.219 1.0 1.218 1.121 1. 950 1.8 1.259 1.237 .996 .9 .791 .944 .854 .856 .791 .972 .765 .783 .632 1.6 In calculating final substitution ratios, if no value for P't is given here, the value in Appendix II, Table 2 is used. . TABLE 5. VALUES OF S U B S T I T U T I O N RATIO P'i, W I T H S U B S T I T U T I O N S B E T W E E N RY CATION OF C O R R E C T I O N FACTORS, ei, C A L C U L A T E D BY T H E G R O U P B A S K E T M C O M M O D I T I E S I N 19 C O U N T R I E S , P R I C E S AS O F OCT Numerator country Denominator country Austria Belgium Bulgaria CzechoDonslomark vakia Estonia Finland France Germany Great Britain Hungary .315 .679 Czecho-Slovakia. 1.860 Estonia France .917 .819 .667 .794 2.866 1.401 1.046 1.547 1.413 2.033 .634 1.002 1.052 .402 1.328 .519 1.306 .654 .618 .722 .644 1.432 .753 .832 .706 1.682 .715 .829 1.521 .750 .555 2.254 1.111 1.014 1.238 1.121 .532 1.607 .792 1.426 .611 .703 Switzerland Union of S. Africa United States. .. 1.359 .670 .645 .713 .533 .437 .4 1.004 1.2 1.0 1.205 1.245 2.541 1.547 .883 1.097 1.6 .9 .808 .469 .457 .554 .631 .715 .671 .935 .705 .568 1.186 .9 .622 1.366 .773 1.044 .908 .731 1.1 .821 .661 .8 1.216 .980 1.5 2.034 .867 .698 .8 .620 .770 .9 .573 .590 Great Britain.... Hungary.. : Italy Netherlands Norway Ita .568 .733 .6 .856 1.171 i In calculating final substitution ratios, if no value for P'i is given here, the value in Appendix II, Table 3 is used. Publications of the International Labour Office Studies and Reports, Series B, No. 33 Studies in War Economics CONTENTS I. E c o n o m i c O r g a n i s a t i o n for T o t a l W a r , w i t h S p e c i a l R e f e r e n c e t o t h e W o r k e r s . By E. F . P E N R O S E . A general introduction to the study of war economics. It discusses the underlying principles involved in changing from a pre-war to a war economy, dealing with changes in productive activities, problems of war finance and foreign trade, and methods of distributing the war burden in the most equitable manner. II. W h o s h a l l P a y for t h e War? A n A n a l y s i s of t h e K e y n e s Plan. By E. J. R I C H E S . A detailed summary and discussion of the proposals put forward in Mr. J. M. Keynes's How lo Pay for the War. Various amendments are suggested and the applicability of the Keynes Plan to other countries is briefly discussed. III. R e l a t i v e W a g e s i n W a r t i m e . By E. J. R I C H E S . An analysis of the nature and causes of wartime movements in the relative wages of different groups of workers, and of the problems involved and safeguards needed in attempts to limit such movements. IV. C o n t r o l of F o o d P r i c e s . By A. S. J. B A S T E R . A discussion of the objectives and limitations of food price control. The problems of administration and enforcement of price regulation and the prevention of profiteering are investigated. V. H o u s i n g P o l i c y a n d War E c o n o m y . By Carl Major W R I G H T . A discussion of the place of housing in an effective defence effort. It examines the ways in which housing policy has been adjusted to new conditions both in belligerent and in neutral countries. VI. T h e Effect of W a r o n t h e R e l a t i v e I m p o r t a n c e of P r o d u c i n g Centres, with Special Reference t o t h e Textile I n d u s t r y . By E d i t h Tilton D E N H A R D T . An analysis of the effect of war on international trade and, through trade, on industry in different countries. The position of the textile industries throughout the world is discussed, as well as the way in which the war is likely to affect the development of these industries. 199 p a g e s P r i c e : $1.00; 4 s . The Labour Situation in Great Britain A SURVKY: M A T — OCTOBER 1940 Studies and Reports, Series B, No. 34 The purpose of this survey is to present a general picture of the manner in which Great Britain adapted its administrative machinery and its labour and social policies and practices to the needs of total war. The survey was prepared in the London Branch of the International Labour Office by Mr. A. D. K. OWEN, Stevenson Lecturer in Citizenship at the University of Glasgow and Secretary of the Civic Division of P.E.P. (Political and Economic Planning), and Mr. Neil LITTLE, a member of the Geneva staff of the International Labour Office. CONTENTS The Political Background The Machinery of Control Economic Policy The Regulation of Labour Supply Employment and Unemployment Wages and Earnings Hours of Work and Holidays Industrial Welfare Industrial Health and the Prevention of Accidents Industrial Relations The Standard of Living 56 p p . P r i c e : $0.25; I s . Industrial Safety Survey (Published quarterly in English) This periodical is intended to act as a link between those in all countries who are interested in problems of accident prevention, and to make international co-operation possible. In addition to articles by experts on specific aspects and problems of accident prevention, the Survey contains notes on the activities of safety associations, new laws and regulations relating to safety precautions, extracts from official reports dealing with accidents, reviews of books and periodicals, and reproductions of new safety posters issued in different countries. 40 p p . P r i c e : $0.25; I s . 2 4 Labour Supply and National Defence Under the title "Labour Supply and National Defence" the International Labour Office has just published a report originally prepared for a meeting of government officials, employers and workers of the United States and Canada held under the auspices of the Office on 12 April 1941. PART I. PROBLEMS OF LABOUR SUPPLY Chapter I : Allocation of Man-power between the Armed Forces and Industry. Reservation of Workers for Production and Release of Key Workers from the Armed Forces in Great Britain, the British Dominions, France and the United States. Chapter II : The Control of Employment. Restrictions on Engagement and Dismissal of Labour in Great Britain, Francei Germany, Australia, New Zealand, South Africa, Canada, the United States and Japan. Chapter III : Vocational Adaptation of Labour Supply. Vocational Training in Schools and Special Centres, Intra-plant Training and Upgrading, Apprenticeship, etc., in Great Britain, France, Germany, Australia, New Zealand, South Africa, Canada, the United States and Japan, with a Section on Arrangements for Training of Indian Workers in Great Britain. Chapter IV: The Mobilisation of Labour Resources. Dilution of Skilled Labour, the Distribution of Experienced Workers and the Mobilisation of Labour Reserves in Great Britain, France, Germany, the British Dominions and Japan. PART II. PROBLEMS OF INFORMATION AND ORGANISATION Chapter V: Information. Inventories of Labour Supply and of Labour Requirements in Great Britain, France, Germany, Canada, the United States and Japan. Chapter VI : Organisation. Administrative Organisation and Special Machinery for Co-operation with Employers and Workers in Great Britain, France, Germany, Canada, the United States and Japan. In conclusion the report contains a series of general principles which the experience of the countries studied has shown should be kept in mind in the interests both of effective policy in the present emergency and of future readjustment to peace economy. ", . . . a useful contribution to the discussion of Canada's war effort. . . ." The Gazette, Montreal. ". . . . the International Labour Office in what is probably one of its most important publications of recent years, has just issued . . . a desirable and informative volume." The Financial Times. Studies and Reports, Series C, No. 23 245 pp. Price: $1.; 4s.