INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE STUDIES AND REPORTS Series K (Agriculture) N o . 11 COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS IN AGRICULTURE GENEVA 1933 Published in the United Kingdom For the INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E ( L E A G U E OF NATLOT^TI •-. '<~,7V.V. By P . S. K I N G & SON, Ltd. ,r,^\-•Lt~¿X'N Orchard House, 14 Great Smith Street, Westminster, Londwi/^SVW.l 'S> IMPRIMERIE ANNEMASSE A. GRANCHAMP (HAUTE-SAVOIE) CONTENTS Page INTRODUCTION 5 CHAPTER I ORGANISATION, HISTORY AND SCOPE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING IN AGRICULTURE I. II. Organisation 1. Parties to Agreements 2. Forms of Collective Regulation in A g r i c u l t u r e . . . . 3. Stability of Collective Bargaining in Agriculture.. History and Scope Austria Czechoslovakia Denmark Germany Great Britain : Scotland Italy Netherlands Poland Sweden CHAPTER 9 9 13 19 25 27 29 31 34 45 46 49 51 54 II CONTENTS OF AGRICULTURAL COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS I. Scope of the Contents of Agricultural Collective Agreements 58 II. Items in the Contents of Agricultural Collective Agreements 64 1. Hours of Work 64 Economic Importance of the Regulation of Hours of Work 64 Ways of Regulating Hours of Work 68 Methods of Calculation; Journey Time 79 Special Regulations for Certain Types of Undertakings and Certain Categories of W o r k e r s . . 82 Agricultural Collective Agreements and the Statutory Eight-Hour Day 84 2. Holidays 89 3. Housing 92 4. Work of Women and Children 94 5. Social Insurance 96 III. Permanent Character of Items 97 CHAPTER III CONCLUSIONS 104 A P P E N D I X A : Principal Agricultural W o r k e r s ' O r g a n i s a t i o n s . . . . APPENDIX B : Annual Hours of Work according to Collective Agreements in Germany in the years 1920 to 1931 A P P E N D I X C : Some Articles in the "International Labour Review" on Agriculture 119 120 121 INTRODUCTION The following Resolution was adopted at the Eleventh Session of the International Labour Conference on 13 July 1928 : Whereas the Labour Part of the Treaties of Peace provides not only for the protection of industrial workers, but also for the protection of agricultural workers, and whereas the International Court of Justice has confirmed this intention of the Treaties ; Whereas social legislation on behalf of agricultural workers appears in many countries to lag behind social legislation on behalf of industrial and other workers ; and Whereas no differences in processes of production can justify such an inferiority of rights for agricultural workers ; and Whereas, until an improved social legislation for agricultural workers can be enacted, collective bargaining may be employed as a preparatory means for regulating labour conditions in a manner conforming to modern principles of the social protection of workers ; The Conference requests the International Labour Office to increase its information on existing systems of collective bargaining in agriculture, to form the basis of a discussion at an early Session of the Conference, and with a view to the rapid acceleration in as many countries as possible of this means of improving the conditions of agricultural labour. This Resolution was submitted by Mr. Hermann Müller, German workers' delegate, in terms identical with those of a motion recently passed by the Executive Committee of the International Landworkers' Federation ; and, with certain textual amendments, itwas unanimously adopted by the Plenary Session of the Conference without preliminary discussion. The Resolution rests on the fact that in many States the social protection accorded to agricultural workers is inferior both in quantity and in quality to that enjoyed by industrial workers. It is not necessary to look beyond international legislation to see that this is so. Although a series of questions concerning agricultural workers was dealt with at the Third Session of the International Labour Conference in 1921, with the result that three Draft Conventions and seven Recommendations were adopted, and although questions of importance for all workers, which means of importance for agricultural workers also, have been regularly raised at the Sessions of the Conference since 1927, nevertheless international legislation on labour conditions in agriculture is less advanced than that affecting — 6 — other groups of workers. Suffice it to point out that there is as yet no international regulation of hours of work in agriculture, that the Recommendation concerning the prevention of industrial accidents adopted in 1929 is limited in its application to agriculture by the words "taking into consideration the special conditions of agricultural work ", and that the Conventions dealing with agricultural questions are among those with the smallest number of ratifications (two similar Conventions, concerning sickness insurance for workers in industry and commerce and domestic servants and concerning sickness insurance for agricultural workers, were adopted in 1927 ; the former has been ratified by twelve States, the latter only by seven). On the other hand, in many States conditions of life on the land have improved considerably since the war, and for this the introduction of collective bargaining into agriculture is apparently partly responsible. The organised landworkers had by 1928 succeeded in many cases in using collective bargaining not only to raise the level of wages, but also to obtain other improvements in conditions of employment — and this they did, it is particularly important to note, at a time when little was being achieved by means of legislation ; in other words, pending better social legislation the collective agreement appeared, for agricultural as for other workers, to be a suitable temporary expedient for the regulation of conditions of employment in conformity with modern principles of labour protection. If this view is right, the obvious conclusion is that the spread of collective bargaining in agriculture should be encouraged by appropriate means. From this it is but a short step to the idea of calling on the support of the International Labour Organisation to secure such an end ; and the International Labour Conference gave its consent in principle by adopting the Resolution quoted above. * * * A study of collective bargaining in agriculture must, of course, be based on the conditions in the individual States. The general structure of the agricultural industry and of agricultural labour, labour legislation, and the point of view adopted by each State on collective agreements in general, — 7 — all these set the bounds within which collective bargaining may develop in agriculture. A detailed study, on the other hand, of the collective agreement system in agriculture in each of the countries considered would overload this report, and a discussion on this basis will not be attempted. A further disadvantage would be the easily made assumption of fundamental differences, for instance between Denmark or Sweden, with their single national collective agreements on the one hand, and Germany with its countless collective agreements on the other ; in actual fact Germany has homogeneous regulation of conditions of employment in agriculture in certain districts comprising quite as many agricultural workers and undertakings as the whole of Denmark. As far as possible, therefore, national boundaries will, be ignored and the subject treated as a whole ; but a conspectus of the history and facts in each country is given in Section II of Chapter I. The extent of collective bargaining, the contents of agreements, and their relation to legislation will be examined. As in a former report on the labour contract in agriculture 1 , which the present study aims at supplementing, an attempt will be made to throw light on labour problems in agriculture, on their many-sidedness and on the opportunities which are open for improvement, and to show to what extent it has been possible, in the present circumstances, to use collective bargaining in order to obtain uniformity in conditions of employment. The report will be limited to those countries in which collective bargaining in agriculture is sufficiently advanced to permit the study of what such a system offers agriculture. The number of such countries is rather small, but this does not mean that in agricultural labour conditions elsewhere are settled only by means of individual bargaining and individual contracts. Other forms of action or regulation on something more than the individual basis can be found ; for example, in the wage board system in agriculture in England and Wales, in the fixation of minimum wages in Hungarian agriculture, in the industrial arbitration systems in Australia and New Zealand, in the working conditions established by local custom on the labour market in many districts in France, in the official regulation of working conditions of national or alien migrant 1 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E : The Law on the Conlracl of of Agricultural Workers in Austria, Germany and Hungary. Series K (Agriculture), No. 10. Geneva, 1930. 63 pp. Employment Studies and Reports, — 8 — agricultural labour in Czechoslovakia and other countries. In several cases these systems m a y bring certain advantages t o the workers. They fall, however, outside t h e scope of the present report 1 , the principal purpose of which is to provide t h e International Labour Conference with practical bases for its discussion of t h e question of collective agreements in agricultura in conformity with the Resolution of 1928 2 . The report was submitted in proof to the Sixteenth Session of the International Labour Conference for its information. The Conference adopted the following Resolution : At its Eleventh Session the International Labour Conference requested the International Labour Office to increase its informtaion on existing systems of collective bargaining in agriculture, to form the basis of a discussion at an early Session of the Conference, and with a view to the rapid acceleration in as many countries as possible of this means of improving the conditions of agricultural labour. A draft report on this matter was accordingly communicated to the present Session of the Conference by the International Labour Office, but it was not distributed in time to allow of a formal discussion for the purposes mentioned above. The Conference re-emphasises the value of collective agreements for improving the conditions of agricultural labour. At the same time the Conference recalls the importance to be attributed to the rights of association and combination of agricultural workers as a condition for the development of collective agreements in agriculture. As the report on the application of the Convention adopted by the Third Session of the Conference concerning the rights of association and combination of agricultural workers is due, in accordance with Article 8 of this Convention, to be laid before the Session of the Conference to be held next year, the Conference considers it desirable that the examination of the report on collective agreements in agriculture should take place at that same Session. The Conference accordingly invites the Governing Body to instruct the International Labour Office to submit to next year's Session of the Conference the final report on this question, account being taken of the observations which may be made by the organisations concerned. In conformity with this decision, the draft report was sent to the Governments and all agricultural employers' and workers' organisations in all States covered by the report for their examination. During its Sixtieth Session in October 1932 the Governing Body approved t h e report and decided to p u t it before the Seventeenth Session of the International L a b o u r Conference. 1 Appendix G includes a list of articles published by the International Labour Office on labour conditions in agriculture not controlled by collective bargaining. 2 The report is based on documentary and other material which the Office has received by the kind co-operation of organisations of agricultural employers and workers and by the taking of first-hand evidence from time to time. In the case of Poland, a detailed memorandum on collective bargaining in agriculture by Mr. GNOINSK!, Chief of Department a t the Ministry of Labour and Social Assistance a t Warsaw, has also been at the disposal of the Office. CHAPTER I ORGANISATION, HISTORY AND SCOPE OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING IN AGRICULTURE I Organisation 1. PARTIES TO AGREEMENTS The first pre-requisite for collective settlement of conditions of employment in agriculture is the existence of agricultural trade unions of a certain size ; the spread of collective bargaining in agriculture is therefore limited to those countries in which the landworkers have combined in associations for the protection of their occupational interests. In a previous report 1 the International Labour Office described the representation and organisation of agricultural workers all over the world and discussed the circumstances which condition the formation of agricultural trade unions. The report showed that there is much greater difficulty in organising agricultural than in organising industrial workers. The trade union movement in agriculture is now passing through a stage which industry has long since left behind, and it has also more technical obstacles to encounter. Agricultural undertakings are scattered and the workers therefore isolated ; really large-scale farming is rare, while there are large numbers of peasant farms, each with a few wage-paid workers ; the line of division between employer and employed is not sharply marked, for the mass of the rural population is engaged in manual work, and members of the farmer's family work side by side with the wage-paid workers, who are treated as members of the household ; finally, a large number of workers 1 INTERNATIONAL of Agricultural Workers. Geneva, 1928. 210 pp. LABOUR O F F I C E : The Bepresenlalion and Organisation Studies and Reports, Series K (Agriculture), No 8. — 10 — are not permanently in wage-paid employment, but are small proprietors or the sons of small cultivators who take service for limited periods only and whose interests do not and cannot coincide with those of the permanent wage-earning workers. On the other hand, it is typical of the unions of agricultural workers that they are all in principle organised on a national basis and that their executive is strongly centralised, the central committee being as a rule represented at all local negotiations of any importance. But while this centralisation aims at the greatest uniformity possible in the regulation of conditions of employment within a country, it is to a certain extent prejudiced by the existence in most countries of several unions, each on a national basis but representing different tendencies in opinion ; and as these opinions have no uniform hold in the different parts of the country, each of the unions inevitably acquires its own local centres of gravity. This combination of different movements of opinion and different degrees of local representation on occasion prevents a complete uniformity in the aims of the unions. However, the report referred to also shows that the agricultural trade union movement has by no means yet reached its widest extension. Even in those countries in which it is furthest advanced, only a fraction of the agricultural workers belong to unions 1 . The membership of an agricultural trade union has an enormous turnover ; large numbers join, but nearly as many leave either because they change their occupation or because they find work in another district where it is hard to keep up relations with the union. The existence everywhere of a large number of formerly organised agricultural workers is not without considerable effect on the spread and importance of collective bargaining. The influence of the unions thus extends far beyond their actual membership, though it does not entail a corresponding increase of financial resources. The influence of the landworkers' organisations is also far from uniform over a given country owing to the nature of their membership. Membership of the unions is practically confined to married workers or unmarried day labourers ; farm servants are nearly everywhere quite unorganised, and the number of women landworkers 2 who join unions is also very small. The 1 Married women and also other members of an agricultural worker's family employed on the land regard themselves as organised if the head of the family belongs to a union. 2 Cf., however, for Italy, p. 46. — 11 — composition of their membership governs the degree of the unions' influence and limits it largely to districts where the nature of the undertakings permits the employment of a permanent staff of married workers, i.e. where large-scale farming predominates ; in districts where farming of a peasant type, whether on an important or a smaller scale, is found, the unions have little voice in the regulation of conditions of employment even where intensive cultivation necessitates the employment of large numbers of wage earners. It is not easy to distinguish here between cause and effect. There are, of course, greater opportunities of organisation among the workers employed in big agricultural undertakings, but one of the reasons why it is easier for the unions to influence conditions of employment on large estates than on peasant farms is just that on the former some general regulation of labour operations is essential, while on the latter each case may be decided as it arises. And then the mere fact of succeeding comparatively easily makes the union more attractive to the workers. All agricultural trade unions 1 are affiliated to the central federations of workers' organisations of their own political tendency, and both the Social-Democratic and the Christian agricultural unions are organised in international landworkers' federations which were founded soon after the war and before long had a considerable membership. A table showing the changes in the membership of these two federations and of the chief national agricultural unions since 1920 will be found in Appendix A. As will be shown, the landworkers' organisations as a whole have made but little headway since the period of rapid growth which followed the war ; an advance in one quarter has been counterbalanced by a falling off elsewhere. The present agricultural depression appears to have encouraged organisation in some countries, but in others the unions have been hard hit, especially where it is the practice to pay the workers mostly in kind, so that they have to sell agricultural produce if they wish to pay their contributions. The organisation of agricultural employers, unlike that of the workers, is not essential to the conclusion of collective agreements. Although farmers in their capacity of employers have long had common interests, which were safeguarded by the ordinary agricultural associations, they acted together 1 exist. However, in Italy no central organisations either of employers or of workers — 12 — not with an eye to the workers, but to the administrative and legislative authorities. In many cases these associations have now also undertaken negotiations with the workers' unions concerning conditions of employment. But it was not until collective bargaining was introduced into agriculture in the form of contracts between individual employers and organised workers that the former found it necessary to protect their interests in this direction by founding real agricultural employers' organisations. The two possible means of protecting these interests — through general agricultural associations or through bodies confined to employers of labour, and through institutions intermediate between these two — have entailed a degree of variety among the different employers' associations which contrasts sharply with the organic uniformity of the workers' unions ; indeed, it is almost impossible to find a formula which will cover all the employers' organisations. There is naturally a wide difference between the cases in which the workers' unions negotiate with an organisation of employers as such, and those in which they have to do with an agricultural association which includes farmers who do not employ outside labour. In the former, it is usually easier to arrive at a true and complete collective agreement, instead of having to be content with the establishment of certain principles. On the other hand, an agreement made with a general agricultural association will usually cover far more enterprises, for the small farmers who do not employ much labour are comparatively seldom members of organisations confined to employers. The membership of the employers' organisations is often extremely low when compared with the large number of agricultural undertakings which employ outside labour. Only the heads of really large estates feel bound, in their own interest, to join such organisations. Many other employers consider it sufficient to make collective agreements on their own estates but are not willing to pay contributions to employers' organisations, and to run the risk of being involved in labour disputes ; they forget that they are thus inevitably and from the outset putting their own — the employers' —- interests in a weaker position. Another characteristic of the employers' organisations is great decentralisation. They are mostly local and often do not even cover a whole economic area. If they are federated at all, the central body does not as a rule do more than undertake — 13 — the business management and watch common interests ; it has no decisive influence on the policy of the affiliated organisations. I t has sometimes happened that collective bargaining in a large area has been simplified by the introduction of a uniform agreement, but that the decentralisation of the employers' organisations has made it impossible to continue this practice and necessitated a return to several agreements. The relations between employers' organisations in agriculture and in industry vary 1 . In Denmark and Germany, for instance, the central agricultural employers' organisations maintain that, in order to be able to safeguard their interests directly and without hindrance, they must remain independent of the industrial employers ; in Sweden the Federation of Agricultural Employers is represented on a joint committee set up by the Swedish Employers' Federation with the employers' organisations not affiliated to it ; on the other hand, the Czechoslovak organisations of agricultural employers are affiliated to the central employers' federations. No international organisation of agricultural employers so far created has shown signs of real vitality. In 1921 an International Farmers' Union was founded with the sole object of representing the interests of agricultural employers in connection with the International Labour Organisation, but this was dissolved in 19302. 2. FORMS OF COLLECTIVE REGULATION IN AGRICULTURE The simplest method by which an employers' or workers' organisation may influence conditions of employment with a view to increasing uniformity is the establishment of " guiding principles " issued without negotiation with the other party and indicating the conditions under which, in the opinion of the organisation, work should be offered or accepted. Such guiding principles have no legal force, and can at the most be cited before a court in case of dispute as evidence of the custom of the country. When issued by a workers' organisation they lay down the least favourable conditions on which a worker — organised or not — should accept employment ; if he can secure better terms, the organisation fully agrees. When issued by 1 2 See footnote p. 11. Cf. INTERNATIONAL Labour Organisation, LABOUR OFFICE : p . 352. Geneva, 1931. Ten Years of the 1 niernational — 14 — an employers' organisation, their character as guiding principles is more precise ; they are meant to be regarded both as maxima and minima. They lay down the wages and conditions of employment which the organisation considers should be offered, but it is not always in its interest for members to regard them only as maxima and to offer the workers such less favourable conditions as they think fit. By so doing they may encourage the trade union movement and thus ultimately have to accept a binding collective agreement instead of having only to observe guiding principles. Guiding principles may be used during a period when no collective agreement is in force, or permanently for districts or groups of workers whose conditions are not regulated by collective bargaining. The wages rates published twice a year by the Danish Agricultural Workers' Union round about the two dates at which it is customary for farm servants to make any change in their employment are an example. It is a particularly interesting one for two reasons : (i) because the collective agreement already contains minimum wage rates for male farm servants, which are well under the rates usually paid, and (ii) because the workers' organisation, in publishing its rates, has in mind chiefly the unorganised farm servants, who form the majority. The Union has of course no means of enforcing these rates. The following table shows the difference between the rates mentioned in the guiding principles and those of the collective agreement (autumn 1931) : Summer wages Winter wages Guiding Collective Guiding Collect! ve principles agreement principles agreement Farm servants over 20 years Farm servants from 18 to 20 years Kr. Kr. Kr. Kr. 500 390 275 210 430 320 235 180 Joint guiding principles may also be laid down by negotiation between employers' and workers' organisations, but do not necessarily thereby take on the nature of a contract. The organisations simply bind themselves to recommend their members to respect the terms of the arrangement made. This is the — 15 — commonest form taken by the collective bargaining principle in Czechoslovak and Scottish agriculture 1 . The collective agreement, the terms of which are binding on the members of the signatory parties, is a document of a very different nature. Yet the difference in value between guiding principles and a collective agreement in practice is not always large, particularly if contracting out of an agreement is not prohibited by statute or legal decision. In countries where contracting out of an agricultural collective agreement is permitted, as for instance in Czechoslovakia, a contract of employment made with an organised employer on less favourable conditions for the worker than those laid down in the collective agreement is nevertheless valid in law. In Austria Federal legislation has protected collective agreements by prohibiting contracting out ; the law in question does not apply to agriculture, but in five of the provinces there is corresponding local legislation2. In the other countries dealt with in this report the principle which forbids contracting out of a collective agreement is recognised without restriction as to occupation. Collective agreements are of different types, and these different types occur with varying frequency in agriculture. While one of the parties to any collective agreement must be an organisation of workers, the other may be either an organisation of employers or the head of a single estate. In the early days of agricultural trade unionism estate agreements played an important part, but their very existence induced employers to organise in order not to allow the workers the advantage of being the only organised party. At present the estate agreement is of minor importance, the workers whose conditions of employment are thus regulated being few in comparison with those affected by agreements between two organisations 3 . In Denmark, however, estate agreements have recovered some of their importance since the dissolution of the Federation of Employers in Agriculture and Forestry, which included employers over a large part of the country. This 1 By arrangement collective agreements are sometimes treated as guiding principles only in reference to certain groups of workers, or undertakings of a certain size. 2 Section 2 of the Agricultural Labour Code of Salzburg, the prescriptions of which are binding, states that the collective agreement may form the basis of an individual contract. Though the contracting out of a collective agreement is not expressly forbidden by the Code, the Federal Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry holds the view that this is in fact the case. 3 In Italy even agreements for specific undertakings are concluded by organisations on both sides. — 16 — state of affairs is particularly remarkable in that it has occurred in a State where the industrial workers are organised to a man, and shows plainly that collective bargaining has reached a far less advanced stage in agriculture than in industry. In other countries estate agreements are as a rule only found in districts where big estates are rare and isolated, or where the agricultural workers are organised on a purely local basis. Further occasions for estate agreements are provided by public undertakings — land in the hands of local authorities, etc. — in cases where the authorities do not consider it advisable for various reasons to be organised as employers on the same footing as private persons, and by agricultural estates owned by industrial undertakings. When such estate agreements occur in districts in which collective agreements between organisations of employers and workers are also in force, the estate agreements often contain more favourable conditions of employment than the current collective agreements. Mention may be made of isolated cases of transition from estate agreements to agreements between organisations — agreements for instance in which one of the parties is a workers' organisation and the other a number of economically independent undertakings which have not formed an organisation on their side. A list of these undertakings is given in the agreement, which is then good as regards each of them for the period of its validity ; there is no possibility of employers evading such an agreement by resigning from such a group or of entering into it by joining one. In two districts in Pomerania agreements are in force to which on the employers' side a given number of undertakings are party ; as these two agreements came into existence as the result of an arbitration award being declared binding, the employers may be described as compulsorily associated for a certain purpose. By this means conditions of employment are uniformly regulated in thirteen and six undertakings respectively. The most important form of collective agreement, that in which both the parties are organisations, becomes possible as soon as the employers organise. This type of agreement, i.e. between two organisations, may again appear in several forms. The simplest is that in which all items are dealt with in one text. This is the usual form in Austria, Denmark, Poland, Italy and the Netherlands, and is also most frequently found in Brandenburg, Mecklenburg-Schwerin, Pomerania, and the Free — 17 — State of Saxony. In other cases the clauses concerning wagerates form a separate part of the agreement ; this is then described as a wage bargain, to distinguish it from the covering agreement which regulates the other conditions of employment (in Baden and Wurtemberg, for instance). The practical advantages of this form of agreement are that under it the two parts may run for different periods of validity and may terminate with different periods of notice. Further, wage rates and other conditions of employment not definitely fixed by the covering agreement — such as hours of work and related questions — may be regulated independently for smaller districts within the area of validity of the whole. agreement. This combination of a covering agreement with several subsidiary agreements makes it possible to introduce collective regulation of conditions of employment for the whole of a large area, yet simultaneously respect local conditions on various heads. An ordinary collective agreement may of course also fix special conditions for certain districts, and once such an arrangement has been made there is no practical difference between it and an agreement on the " covering " system ; but the latter is easier to conclude because the main agreement is not dependent on the settlement of every local detail. The comparative importance of the covering and subsidiary agreements naturally depends on what questions are regulated by each. Usually only wage rates are subject to local variation ; but of course other details can be decided locally within limits laid down by the main agreement. The covering agreement for agricultural workers in East Prussia provides that district agreements may be concluded between the parties to the covering agreement, and that these may in particular regulate wage rates ; nevertheless the covering agreement is supplemented by a general wage bargain, which fixes uniform rates for all districts and special rates only for Königsberg. The agricultural collective agreement in Silesia lays down that organisations affiliated to the signatory parties may only make local arrangements in so far as is explicitly permitted in the general agreement, that is, for the detailed distribution of the 2,856 hours to be worked in the year. At first frequent use was made of this right, and in 1920 as many as sixty-two district agreements were concluded in Silesia ; nowadays they are of rare occurrence. In Bavaria, on the other hand, the subsidiary agreements are a necessary complement to — 18 — the covering agreement because they fix the wage-rates. Further, they repeat all the positive terms of the covering agreement, sometimes adding to them ; some of the district agreements for instance, contain more detailed provisions concerning hours of work than the covering agreement. Anhalt and the Province of Saxony provide perhaps the most highly developed form of covering agreement. Its terms provide that the joint district and regional labour associations shall constitute a central labour association. A collective agreement must be made for every district, and submitted to the Collective Agreements Board at Halle for examination and expert opinion. The Board is required to examine the form and content of agreements and to call attention to any inadequacies. Agreements not in accordance with the terms of the covering agreement are invalid. Where an agreement is outstanding, the Board undertakes to draw up a text. The covering agreement fixes total hours of work for the year for each district, distribution over the separate months being settled by subsidiary agreements. The covering agreement also regulates journey time ; only the urban districts may settle this question, and that of payment in kind, independently. The Swedish national collective agreement for agriculture is also a covering agreement, but is only valid when supplemented by a local agreement. The national agreement is however often concluded for a period of two or three years, while local agreements are valid for one year only. Local agreements contain only stipulations on wages to be taken in conjunction with certain national arrangements concerning payment in kind. The guiding principles laid down for the regulations of conditions of employment in agriculture in Czechoslovakia may also be regarded as a sort of covering agreement within which the local collective agreements may be made. Covering agreements are obviously more important than subsidiary agreements. This does not mean that covering agreements outrank in importance single collective agreements made in districts where a division into covering and subsidiary arrangements does not exist. The area over which a covering agreement is valid is, as its name implies, always considerable, but there are several instances of the conditions of employment of quite as many workers in quite as large an area being regulated by single collective agreements. — 19 — 3. STABILITY OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING IN AGRICULTURE The history of collective bargaining in agriculture shows that, despite their sudden and simultaneous appearance in many countries, agreements have since been consistently renewed or prolonged whenever supported by strong and stable workers' organisations, nor has there been any considerable reduction in their sphere of influence. Initial difficulties in the way of introducing the collective settlement of conditions of employment into agriculture were overcome with comparative ease by reason of the early strength of the agricultural trade union movement and by the fact that the moment was favourable. Collective bargaining is to all appearance now permanently entrenched in agriculture ; this is all the more remarkable in that it has on the whole spread peacefully and caused but few conflicts of any dimensions between the opposing organisations. Apart from the first few years of collective bargaining in the different countries, the negotiations for the renewal and prolongation of agreements have, despite most fluctuating economic conditions, run an extremely peaceful course. True, it has frequently been necessary to call on existing conciliation institutions, and agreements have often only been concluded after an arbitration award. The importance of this should not be over-estimated, for the appeal to such institutions is often nothing but a tactical move. For various reasons agriculture seems to afford fewer occasions for labour conflicts than do other occupations. " Strikes or threats of a strike in agriculture are regarded by the public — including sections which sympathise with us — with feelings different from those exhibited towards strikes in other occupations ; they are to some extent regarded as the most dangerous to the economic health of the nation, and this is an attitude which we have to accept " 1 . Moreover, in agriculture the advantage accruing out of such action to one of the two parties is usually so overwhelming that the other tries to avoid a conflict until the last moment. • The workers have the upper hand in the spring, the employers in the autumn. But in either case the favoured party also is in danger of suffering most heavily through a conflict. Agricultural operations must be done at definite seasons, and days lost through strike or 1 Bericht des Verbandsvorslandes über die Verbandsarbeil in den Jahren 19201922, p. 14. Schriften des Deutschen Landarbeiterverbandes, No. J6. Berlin, 1926. — 20 — lock-out are lost for always. If, for instance, the conditions of employment for beet cultivation are not settled in good time, the fields have to be planted with summer barley or some other crop, and excellent employment opportunities are lost. The employer, for his part, cannot call a lock-out against all his workers, because his animals must be regularly tended ; by calling a lock-out of any sort he runs the risk of so embittering the workers that they may take their revenge by refusing even to perform such essential duties. Another obstacle to strikes and lock-outs is the long contract. These are the rule in agriculture, and they usually expire together on a given day in the spring or autumn, which is thus the only day on which a strike or lock-out can be begun without breach of contract. These hiring days thus also govern the dates of renewal of collective agreements. In Sweden hiring day was 24 October under the old Servants Order of 1833. This Order was repealed in 1926, but had been in existence long enough to influence the newer method of settling employment conditions — by collective agreement. In MecklenburgSchwerin hiring day is also in the autumn, and notice of termination of agreements may be given by either party not earlier than 1 September, to come into force on 1 November. A large number of German collective agreements expire with the calendar year, as do the guiding principles for agriculture in Czechoslovakia ; in these countries the negotiations for renewal often run on a month or two into the new year, and work then continues under the old conditions, differences being made good later if the wage rates are altered. A local leader of the German Landworkers' Federation has expressly declared that the unsatisfactory moment chosen for expiration has made it impossible in recent years to conclude new agreements before March. In Poland agreements run from 1 April to 31 March, their period of validity thus corresponding with that of individual contracts of employment ; originally collective agreements were made for the calendar year. The negotiations take place in the last quarter of the year, so that employers may know the conditions fixed for the next season before expiration of the three months' notice which has to be given to workers engaged by the year. In Denmark agreements run from 1 May to 30 April, with three months' notice of termination, and the Landworkers' Union insists that this should not be altered. In Austria agreements run from the beginning of March to the end — 21 — of February, and in East Prussia, Pomerania and SchleswigHolstein until 1 April. In the Netherlands, too, agreements are concluded in the spring, from March to the beginning of May, with the exception of those for dairy-farming, which are made during May. Agreements are thus in the large majority of cases renewed either at the beginning of the year or in the spring, that is, at times favourable to the workers ; the reason is probably to be found less in the superior strength of the workers' unions than in the fact that the need for a settlement of employment conditions does not make itself felt until the season of sowing and cultivation. The stability of collective bargaining in agriculture only proves that the agricultural workers have been able to exert such pressure on the employers as to compel them to conclude collective agreements without however approving of such a policy in principle. This is undoubtedly the situation in many cases. Employers have a preference for settling employment conditions as far as possible with individual workers. In recent years an influential party in Danish agriculture, not particularly connected with employers, has engaged in a vigorous campaign against all collective bargaining, even in industry. There are, however, many examples of a positive recognition of the principle of collective bargaining to be found in the agreements themselves. These occur in the form of provisions for prolongation and notice of termination. In most cases it is regarded as sufficient to provide that if notice has not been given within a certain period — usually three months, but sometimes more (up to six months) or less (up to six weeks) — before expiration, the agreement is valid in its original form for a further year. Other agreements go further and provide that a new agreement shall be concluded. In Austria collective agreements do not provide for actual notice of termination, but lay down that if no amendment is proposed by one of the parties within a certain period the agreement shall be valid for a further year. The first Swedish national agreement provided that a proposal for a new agreement should be submitted simultaneously with notice of termination of the old ; otherwise such notice was to be invalid. This provision was altered at the first renewal of the agreement, and it is now laid down that if a new agreement is desired notice of termination, to be valid, must be accompanied by a complete draft. Many German agreements define a period within which new negotiations — 22 — must be opened, or require new proposals to be submitted together with notièe of termination. In the Randow district of Pomerania notice of termination must be followed within a month by a new draft agreement or proposal of amendment. In Mecklenburg-Schwerin both parties undertake to negotiate in such a way that the new agreement may if possible be concluded before the notice expires. In Schleswig-Holstein the parties are required to open negotiations for a new agreement within a fortnight after notice. In some districts of central Germany a party giving notice of termination is obliged to submit new proposals within three weeks, while in Baden such proposals must accompany notice. In Bavaria negotiations have to begin in the first half of the period of notice. In Rheinhessen the old agreement is valid during the negotiations but not beyond 31 March. In the Free State of Saxony new negotiations must be opened within four weeks of notice of termination, the old agreement remaining valid until the conclusion of a new one, but only until the available conciliation and arbitration machinery has proved unable to adjust the matter. The recognition of the principle of collective bargaining or of the right of the workers to have a voice in the settlement of employment conditions, which is implied in the above provisions, may also be expressed in special agreements or lead to the establishment of special bodies, such as the joint labour associations encountered in .the early history of agricultural collective bargaining in Germany ; but it has yet to be proved that such bodies are in practice necessary as a preliminary to the conclusion of collective agreements. Collective bargaining appears to be just as stable in the other parts of Germany as in the centre, where the Central German Joint Labour Association and a corresponding body for Anhalt and the province of Saxony are still in existence. It must, on the other hand, be admitted that the explicit recognition accorded to the joint labour associations gives collective bargaining more selfsufficiency than it has, for instance, in Silesia, where it is regularly necessary to call in the conciliation authorities in order to secure renewal of agreements. As long as the convention of 1926 concerning the Central German Joint Labour Association remains in force, negotiations between employers and workers can only relate to the contents of agreements, and not to their existence. The existence of agreements is assured in so far — 23 — as this is possible in view of the fact that the consent of two independent parties is required. The stability of collective bargaining in agriculture is also bound to depend very largely on any difference in the attitude of the State to collective bargaining in general industry and to collective bargaining in agriculture. It has already been pointed out that only in two countries (Austria and Czechoslovakia) is contracting out from collective agreements permitted in agriculture ; in other countries there is a prohibition against contracting out which applies to agreements concluded in all occupations, inclusive of agriculture. Agricultural workers further enjoy the same rights as other workers to bring disputes before the courts, except that in Poland their disputes do not come before the ordinary labour tribunals but are confided to arbitration boards established by special legislation. The simple formal recognition that agricultural collective agreements have the same legal validity as those concluded in industry has apparently not always an equal practical effect in these two branches of production. In many doubtful cases, where the tribunal must rely on the nature of the facts, the custom of the trade, etc., the settlement of disputes in agriculture does not bring the same results as the settlement of those in industry. Collective bargaining is less highly developed in agriculture, and therefore has less influence on labour law in that occupation, so that old individualistic theories, which have not been able to survive elsewhere, still carry weight. Similarly, though in most cases agricultural workers have the same nominal right as industrial workers to use official conciliation machinery for the furtherance of collective bargaining, it is perhaps of less use to them, for an appeal to those institutions can hardly be made unless the dispute is of a certain size and has a certain general economic importance. As a rule, the conclusion of collective agreements is a responsibility of the agricultural organisations and depends mainly on their decisions. The State provides conciliation machinery and interferes on occasions to facilitate agreement, but cannot itself ensure that a collective settlement is made. In Austria, Denmark, Germany and the Netherlands it is the general rule that agreements are only concluded as a result of negotiations between the parties, and the extent and stability of collective bargaining in agriculture depends on the size and comparative strength of the employers' and workers' organisations. — 24 — On the other hand, statutory provisions governing collective agreements and collective labour disputes which directly promote collective bargaining, are probably of .more value to agricultural than to industrial workers. The possibility provided for in German labour law of declaring an arbitration award binding is an instance of this, for though such a step is usually taken on application by the party which accepts the award, the declaration may also be made on the initiative of the conciliation authority if the public interest requires it. An award may be declared binding if, after impartial evaluation of the interests of both parties, it appears that the settlement made is just and its execution for economic and social reasons desirable1. But still more noticeable advantage accrues to agricultural workers out of the provisions which enable a collective agreement to be declared " generally binding ". This is a possible procedure in Germany and the rule in Poland, where it is customary to settle collective agreements by the use of all the available statutory machinery. The importance of such declarations is naturally in inverse ratio to the percentage of organised employers and workers in the occupation affected. Italian legislation gives the most thoroughgoing encouragement to collective bargaining, for the recognised organisations represent all persons employed in the occupations concerned, though collective agreements are not explicitly made obligatory by any Act ; but the Charter of Labour states that the professional organisations have to regulate labour conditions by collective bargaining between the categories of employers and workers they represent, and the agreements are without exception generally binding. Finally, those State measures which deal with agricultural collective bargaining in particular must be considered. It should here be borne in mind that all the countries referred to in this report have ratified the Convention concerning the rights of association and combination of agricultural workers which was adopted at the Third Session of the International Labour Conference in 1921. Although the Convention only ensures that agricultural workers shall have the same association and combination rights as workers employed in industry, this explicit recognition of the right to combine has probably a value of its own. In the dispute in Sweden concerning the introduction 1 Gf. the Conciliation Order of 30 November 1923, section 1, subsection 6, and the Order of 29 December 1923 for the administration of the Conciliation Order, section 23. — 25 — of collective agreements in Södra More, of which mention is made below, the agricultural workers expressly took their stand on the fact that this Convention had been ratified. In Czechoslovakia the practical assistance of the labour exchange authorities simplifies negotiations concerning the guiding principles for employment conditions in agriculture. Polish legislation is also of quite special importance, for it not only provides, as already stated, that collective agreements may be declared generally binding, but also causes representatives of employers and workers to be elected failing sufficient representation through existing organisations. In such cases the proceedings lose part of their character as collective bargaining and resemble the system in force in England, where agricultural wage rates are fixed by joint committees. But neither general legislation on collective bargaining nor particular measures dealing with collective bargaining in agriculture can advance collective settlement if the organisations of agricultural workers do not possess a minimum of strength. Where this is not the case, such legislation is a substitute for collective bargaining rather than an aid to its achievement. II History and Scope It may be said that on the whole collective bargaining in agriculture is a post-war phenomenon. Barring Italy, where the system had entrenched itself in agriculture before 1914, agricultural workers' collective agreements in pre-war days occurred only as isolated cases, of historical interest indeed, but of no final significance because of the absence of agricultural workers' unions of sufficient strength to exert a permanent influence on conditions of employment. It is true that small organisations of agricultural workers existed in the years preceding the war in most of the States where agricultural workers' unions are now to be found ; but it was not until the social unrest of 1919 and 1920 that the membership of these bodies rose to a point which suddenly made them powerful and influential. The development reached its peak with the foundation of the two International Landworkers' Federations (SocialDemocratic and Christian) with 2,100,000 and 1,100,000 members respectively, and was so markedly simultaneous in the different — 26 — countries t h a t there can be no suggestion of imitation. The movement began at the end of the war and, by the time the international federations had been founded, collective bargaining in agriculture was a fait accompli. The process was everywhere so sudden and so rapid t h a t a powerful reaction was inevitable. This reaction was in m a n y cases so strong t h a t the agricultural trade unions either disappeared or shrank to negligible proportions ; but in the countries where the agricultural workers have been able to maintain their organisations and to continue their struggle more slowly, collective bargaining, though so young, has attained p e r m a n e n t importance. In these countries it has been possible t o preserve what the spontaneous vigour of the early days so rapidly achieved, and if there has since been little progress it is probable t h a t steady evolution would not have brought the workers t h e same success in the same period as their one burst of activity gave them. I t is amazing t h a t they should have been able, in such haste, to create collective agreements whose contents have defied economic complications and remained practically unaltered until to-day. But conditions of employment are not collectively regulated in every country where agricultural unions are in existence. In many cases the latter are too small and weak to insist on t h e conclusion of collective agreements, though they m a y be of value to their members in other respects. This applies, for instance, to sundry organisations in t h e Baltic States and to Hungary, Yugoslavia and France ; in the last-named country local agricultural workers' organisations have from time to time succeeded in bringing collective agreements into existence, but these have lapsed, and conditions of employment in agriculture in the countries mentioned are still quite unaffected by collective bargaining. One of the most authoritative writers on French agriculture describes t h e position as follows : In several regions collective agreements have been drawn up between groups of employers and trade unions. A considerable number were concluded after strikes in the vine-growing district of the South and in the Paris district ; there are also agreements among the share farmers of Allier and the share-farming resin collectors of the Landes. The present writer does not think that great importance should be attached to these collective agreements. The parties who discuss and sign them know quite well that they have no real powers and that their signature binds no one ; for that reason they generally prefer to conclude the agreement in the presence of an administrative official, such as the prefect or his deputy, so as to make it appear that his authority is behind the document. But the prefect's chief aim is to restore public order — 27 — as quickly as possible. He has no right and no power to enforce the observance of agreements signed in his presence. Neither the trade union, which often dates only from the first day of the strike, nor the group of employers, which may be merely a group ad hoc of well-known individuals with no real powers, is able to appeal to penalties in case of non-observance. As soon as the economic conditions which gave rise to the dispute have changed, the provisions of the so-called collective agreement are also altered. . . . The utmost value of collective agreements is that they may influence local customs, which serve as a guide for individual arrangements1. In England and Wales, where there are comparatively large agricultural workers' organisations, no collective agreements are made, there being s t a t u t o r y committees charged with the d u t y of fixing minimum rates of wages of agricultural workers. The committees consist primarily of representatives of employers and workers in agriculture, nominated entirely by the respective organisations, b u t comprising also independent members. The S t a t u t e under which t h e committees function is determined by the Ministry of Agriculture, which is also charged with the d u t y of enforcing the observance of t h e minimum rate of wages as fixed by the committees. The National Union of Agricultural Workers itself estimates t h a t to secure voluntary collective agreements has proved to be waste of effort, and considers t h a t the Central Agricultural Wages Board t h a t will legally enforce decisions and the action of a strong trade union are the only safe methods of arranging wages and conditions of employment in English agriculture on a satisfactory basis 2 . AUSTRIA There was in Austria before the war a small Social-Democratic agricultural workers' union, but it was unable to exercise more than a local influence on wages. A Christian agricultural workers' union was founded in 1919. The Social-Democratic union found itself reduced at the end of the war to one-third of its former membership, but within little more than two years 40,000 agricultural, forestry and sawmill workers had joined it. The movement among the workers compelled the agricultural employers to organise on their side ; their principal association is the Central Employers' Association for Agriculture and Forestry (Vienna) ; nearly all its members are to be found in Lower Austria and Burgenland, the only States where large agricultural undertakings are of any importance. Both parties came to recognise 1 M. AUGE LARIBÉ : " Labour Conditions in French Agriculture ", in International Labour Review, Vol. XXV, No. 1. 2 The practice of collective bargaining in Australia and New Zealand, as incorporated in the industrial arbitration systems of these two countries, is governed by special legal principles, the application of which to agriculture is not examined here. — 28 — that it would be more effective to conclude only agreements for large districts or groups of estates instead of for individual undertakings ; and the above-mentioned employers' association was a party to the first wages and employment agreement for estates in Lower Austria, which was signed in July 1919. Burgenland, which was Hungarian territory until the war, was allotted to Austria in 1919, and thus its adaptation to Austrian agricultural conditions took place at the same time as collective bargaining was being introduced into agriculture all over the country. During the first years the workers in the new State imagined that they could immediately obtain the better conditions of employment in force in Lower Austria, and repeated strikes were the result. In July 1922 they succeeded in concluding a State agreement which contained most of the terms of that made three years before in Lower Austria. This result was achieved because several of the Burgenland agricultural employers joined the Central Employers' Association for Lower Austria, and the collective agreement for Burgenland was concluded with this body. The first State agreement in Sty ria was concluded in 1921, but was renewed four times only. It survives, however, with certain alterations, in the estate agreements for various large or medium-sized undertakings. Such agreements occur also in Lower Austria and Burgenland, where they concur on the'whole with the State agreements, and further in Upper Austria and Carinlhia, where there have never been single collective agreements covering all the workers of the State. Upper Austria is the only State where the peasants' organisations and the agricultural workers' union have concluded agreements for farm servants, and of these only one is still in existence : in July 1922 these agreements led to a strike in the district of Steyr which lasted for three weeks. In the Tyrol collective bargaining in agriculture has made less progress than in any other State in Austria. The Lower Austrian agreement, which has been regularly renewed up to date, was valid for all the big estates of Lower Austria with but few exceptions until January 1923 ; but in that year a number of large undertakings, including most of the sugar factories near the Czechoslovak frontier which employed cheap foreign labour, denounced the agreement, founded a new association known as the " Sechs and Laa League ", and succeeded in concluding another agreement less favourable to the workers. This unsatisfactory situation lasted until 1927, when it was ended by a dispute leading in certain undertakings to a strike ; and the agreement between the workers and the new body now coincides with the terms of the State agreement. Since 1926 another agreement has been in force in Lower Austria between the workers' organisation and an agricultural and forestry company running twenty estates ; it provides for payment in cash only. The greatest strike in the history of collective bargaining in Austrian agriculture occurred in 1923 in connection with the renewal of agreements for Lower Austria and Burgenland ; 8,000 workers took part. Since that time strikes have been rare and of small importance. The Social-Democratic Land and Forestry Workers' Union has so far been the only workers' organisation to conclude agreements. The Central Union of Christian Landworkers' simply notifies the employers' association that it proposes to accept as a standard for its members the conditions agreed to with the Social-Democratic union. Uniform regulation, by way of agreement, of conditions of employment over the whole of agriculture has never been attempted in Austria ; but the executive committee of the Land and Forestry Workers' Union in — 29 — Vienna always co-operates in the conclusion of collective agreements, and those in force in Lower Austria and Burgenland are taken into consideration when estate agreements are made. Nevertheless, the members of the Union work under very varied conditions. Agricultural labour law is not uniform in Austria, for each Federal State has its own agricultural labour code, and the differences between these are sometimes substantial just in1 the matters with which collective agreements also deal. These codes , which have taken the place of the earlier domestic and farm servants' codes, were introduced in the years immediately following the war ; they betray the unmistakeable influence of the agricultural trade union movement. Where the codes and the collective agreements still do not directly correspond, the reason is that the former deal principally with conditions on small farms and the latter with those on large estates. In 1928, 8,288 male and 829 female agricultural workers employed on agricultural estates in Lower Austria were organised ; the corresponding figures for Burgenland were 4,772 men and 430 women. Of the organised workers, 75 per cent, in Lower Austria and 80 per cent, in Burgenland were employed by organised employers, but the total number of workers employed in these undertakings cannot be given exactly. In general it may be said that the conditions of employment of nearly all the 34,000 members at present in the Social-Democratic agricultural workers union (40 per cent, of whom are forestry or sawmill workers) are specified in collective agreements, and that at least in Lower Austria and Burgenland the terms of the collective agreements govern conditions of employment also on the big estates where the employer does not belong to an organisation. But estates cultivating more than 100 hectares (about 250 acres) represent only some 6 per cent, of the total arable land of Austria, so that the large majority of the 450,000 agricultural workers are employed on peasant farms where the conditions of employment depend on local circumstances and where all efforts at regulation by collective bargaining have so far been in vain. The influence of collective bargaining among the unorganised employers in Austria is limited to a great extent by the fact that the big estates are crowded together in certain parts of the country and are not to be found at all in some of the States. CZECHOSLOVAKIA In Czechoslovakia there are a number of agricultural workers' unions of different tendencies — National-Socialist, Social-Democratic, Communist and Christian. There is also a " yellow " workers' organisation. The Social-Democratic and Christian movements are further subdivided into Czech and German unions. The interests of agricultural employers are also represented by several bodies, but these are not organisations of employers as such. They are general agricultural associations, for which labour questions are but one small sphere of activity among many. The Agricultural Union has a special employers' committee on which other agricultural organisations are represented ; in addition, they are all directly or indirectly affiliated to the Confederation of Czechoslovak Employers' Associations. The decisive factor in the regulation of conditions of employment in agriculture in Czechoslovakia is not so much the actual collective 1 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Legislative Series, 1921, Aus. 2 (Lower Austria) ; 1921, Aus. 3 (Upper Austria and Carinthia) ; 1926, Aus. 5 (Burgenland). — 30 — agreements made between the local branches of these employers' and workers' organisations as the " guiding principles " for agriculture laid down by the central federations in collaboration with the public authorities. As early as J a n u a r y 1919 negotiations took place between the organisations of agricultural workers and employers of Bohemia in the presence of representatives of the Bohemian Labour Office, and the first guiding principles or conditions of employment in agriculture were agreed upon. Not long after, similar negotiations were opened under the auspices of the Provincial Labour Offices in Moravia and Slovakia, and since t h a t time the initiative in respect of negotiations concerning these guiding principles has been in the hands of the labour exchange authorities — t h a t is, not of the Labour Offices themselves but of the provincial councils attached to each Labour Office to deal with matters relating to agricultural workers. The guiding principles are signed not only by the employers' and workers' organisations concerned, but also by the representatives of other bodies on the council — the Ministries of Social Welfare, Agriculture, and Food Supplies, and the Czech and German Sections of the National Educational Council. The fact t h a t the Labour Offices collaborate in the establishment of these guiding principles is explained by the particular labour conditions in Czechoslovak agriculture. The western part of the country, where the land is worked most intensively, is also highly industrialised. Industry attracts the workers, and agriculture therefore suffers from a serious shortage of labour. In the east, on the other hand, and particularly in Slovakia, there is a large surplus agricultural population, and the Bohemian and Moravian farmers therefore draw on these districts for part of their labour, making use of the official labour exchanges for the purpose. The latter are thus directly interested in the settlement of conditions of employment in agriculture. Despite the regular collaboration of the authorities in the establishment of guiding principles, there is no statutory foundation for such a proceeding, and the Government has no means of bringing guiding principles into existence if the employers and workers cannot agree. The guiding principles are an indication and nothing more ; the employers explicitly object to the term " collective agreement ", and the expression " covering agreement " is used in Slovakia only. The workers have no legal guarantee t h a t the conditions laid down in the guiding principles will be applied, but in practice their acceptance by the central federations on both sides means t h a t they will be widely adopted and t h a t unorganised employers and workers will be bound largely to respect them when giving or accepting employment. The guiding principles have been regularly renewed since 1920, though sometimes the period of validity has been exceeded and an interregnum has occurred. They are either used as a basis for the conclusion of contracts with individual workers, or incorporated in the text of local collective agreements. Generally each individual undertaking concludes with its workers or the competent trade union a collective agreement in harmony with the guiding principles. Since the first renewal of the guiding principles, it has gradually become the practice simply to incorporate their text in the district agreements. In the guiding principles for Bohemia all the organisations represented at the negotiations undertake to ensure as far as possible that the terms are accepted and respected by both parties. Parties concluding individual contracts are recommended to record their acceptance of the terms of the guiding principles by signing on the last page of the latter. — 31 — The guiding principles for Moravia provide that all the workers' and employers' representatives on the provincial council for agricultural labour shall, in the name of their organisations, with a view to peaceful national progress and the orderly conduct of national business, do all in their power to ensure t h a t the terms arrived at by mutual consent are respected and unconditionally applied in agreements concluded with individual proprietors. It is true t h a t actual agricultural collective agreements are also concluded in Slovakia, though no figures concerning them are available ; but the guiding principles laid down with official assistance may be described as the typical method of collectively regulating conditions of labour in Czechoslovak agriculture. DENMARK The first local attempts at collective bargaining in agriculture in Denmark were made during the war. In 1915, the Danish Union of Agricultural Workers was founded, and during the same year it concluded the first local collective agreement with a large undertaking ; in the following years two similar agreements were signed. It was, however, not until 1918 t h a t the Union acquired any great importance. The membership was more than quadrupled in t h a t year and large numbers of agreements were entered into with individual undertakings, although often only after recourse to strikes. The Union as such concluded 234 agreements in 1918, and in 239 other cases its local branches made arrangements with employers. This development was the immediate cause of the formation of the National Federation of Employers in Agriculture and Forestry. Its membership was variously given as lying between 1,400 and 3,000, but in any case most of the large Danish agricultural undertakings were included in it. In the spring of 1919 this body and the agricultural workers' unions concluded an agreement which will be referred to as the " national agreement ". In the same year agreements based on the national agreement were made with the independent employers' organisations on the islands of Langeland and Bornholm, and shortly afterwards the Bornholm organisation became affiliated to the National Federation of Employers. Agreements were concluded for casual labourers and head milkers, as well as for permanent workers, and in 1921 these three were amalgamated in a single agreement, the form and basic contents of which have since remained unaltered. This rapid development was followed by some years of comparatively slow progress, chiefly as a result of the generally unfavourable state of agriculture. In 1921, the renewal of the agreement met with great difficulties. The agricultural workers' union declined to accept the proposal made by the Government conciliator, both sides had recourse to direct action — strikes and lock-outs — and the agreement, which contained a few slight concessions for the workers, was only signed after a conflict lasting eighteen days. These events were responsible for considerable discontent among the members of the employers' federation; many resigned, and the Laaland and Falster organisation became independent, thereby depriving the central Federation of ' some 800 members. In 1922 the depression of the sugar market induced the employers to propose a new method of payment for sugar-beet work ; for the future a fraction of the wage was to vary with the price received by the farmers from the sugar factories, and this fraction could not therefore be paid until the following spring. The agricultural workers' — 32 — union refused to consent to such an arrangement unless all the undertakings growing sugar beet, and not only those which were members of the employers' federation, signed those Articles of the collective agreements which dealt with beet cultivation. Since that time representatives of the sugar beet producers' associations have taken part in negotiations concerning agricultural collective agreements. The original object of these associations was to defend the interests of the sugar-beet farmers as against the sugar factories. The agreement made with them is incorporated in the general collective agreement and is binding not only on members of the employers' federation but also on all the farmers organised in the sugar-beet producers' associations. Further, the agricultural workers' union has concluded an agreement with a co-operative sugar factory, according to which the farmers who have shares in the factory and therefore do not belong to an association of sugar-beet producers undertake to respect the general arrangement for beet work which may at any time be in force. Since 1924 the negotiations concerning collective agreements in agriculture have been carried on in common by all the existing employers' organisations, but the National Federation has been steadily losing its importance. At the beginning of 1930 it had only 150 members, and after a vain attempt to bring the membership back to its old size it was decided to dissolve the Federation. Shortly before, the local federation for the island of Langeland had ceased to function. This meant a fundamental change in the conditions of collective bargaining in Danish agriculture. It was, of course, natural that the organised employers -— very few in numbers outside the islands of Laaland and Falster — should have objected strongly to bearing all the cost of regulating conditions of employment by a system of collective agreements (by which the other employers benefited equally), without being in a position to put up any effective resistance to the demands of the workers' union. It was precisely the fear that higher wages would have to be paid when the agreements were renewed in the spring of 1930 that led to the decision to dissolve the Federation, since the agricultural workers' union would then be compelled to negotiate with the individual employers — naturally a much more involved and difficult process than negotiating with a federation. When the agreement with the surviving employers' organisation in Laaland and Falster was renewed, certain increases in wages were, in fact, introduced. After the dissolution of the Federation, most of the former members continued to act in unison and urged their workers to continue on the same conditions after 1 May (the date on which changes of employment usually take place), notice of termination not to have effect until 1 November. The employers hoped by this means to obtain two advantages, first a supply of labour for the summer and secondly the opportunity to negotiate for new conditions of employment in the winter, a time unfavourable to the workers. The agricultural workers' union thereupon declared that this concerted action was not in conformity with the system under which collective bargaining had been regulated since 1899, brought a plaint against the dissolved employers' federation before the arbitration court and sent strike notices to most of its exmembers who had not in the meanwhile signed agreements with the workers on their respective farms. The arbitration court caused negotiations to be opened, and, with the aid of the Federation of Danish Employers, agreements covering single farms were concluded with thirty-three of the most important former members of the dissolved federation. These included the wage increases already agreed to in — 33 — Laaland and Falster, and were, moreover, valid for two years instead of the one year which had previously been customary. After this success the workers' union opened negotiations with about a hundred other large undertakings, and sixty-two new estate agreements were signed. According to the agricultural workers' union, these methods have led to conditions of employment being collectively regulated in a greater number of undertakings than was the case when the employers' federation still existed. In certain cases employers have been compelled to accept less favourable conditions than those obtained by the local employers' organisation in Laaland and Falster ; but there is no longer a possibility of employers entering an organisation and so protecting themselves from terms which are more unfavourable than those which might have been nationally agreed upon. Apart from the Southern Islands, the collective bargaining position in agriculture is the same as in 1918, when organised workers were opposed to unorganised employers — the very situation which led the employers to organise. The agricultural workers are certainly in a strong position, though the existence of a collective agreement concluded with an employers' federation would ease matters in many ways. The full exploitation of such a situation would imply a state of permanent and undesirable unrest among the workers — a policy likely to prejudice the interests of both parties. Further developments, which will probably lead sooner or later to fresh organisation on the part of the employers, are at present affected by the agricultural depression, and their course cannot therefore be foreseen. As long as the agricultural workers' union was negotiating separately with the existing employers' organisations, the agreements varied on particular points, although the union was succeeding in achieving a more and more uniform regulation of conditions of employment. When the negotiations were carried on between federations, there was only one collective agreement for the whole country and this regulated all branches of farm work. The wage rates, which formerly varied from district to district — even the so-called national agreement contained a number of different rates — are now uniform. In this respect the dissolution of the employers' federation has made no difference. The collective agreement made with the one remaining employers' organisation, that for the islands of Laaland and Falster, now serves as a basis for all estate agreements, so that, in so far as conditions of employment are collectively regulated in Danish agriculture, the regulation is uniform for the whole country. During the summer of 1931 the extent of collective bargaining in Danish agriculture was as follows. Its centre of gravity was on the islands of Laaland and Falster, where occupational organisation on both sides is most highly developed ; here there are also agreements between the Danish Union of Agricultural Workers and the sugar-beet producers' associations, and there are corresponding agreements in Fünen and Jutland, though in the last-named districts the area under beet is small. Further, there are collective agreements with about a hundred estates, almost all on the islands. There are only four estate agreements in Jutland, where the influence of the agricultural workers' union is weakest. Conditions of employment are regulated collectively on an eighth only of all the large farms in Denmark. These agreements cover some 1,500 employers, 1,200 to 1,300 of whom belong to the employers' federation in Laaland and Falster, and 5,000 to 6,000 farmers who are parties to the agreements only in 3 — 34 — respect of beet cultivation. The Danish Union of Agricultural Workers' has some 13,500 members, 500 of whom are women; 1,000 of the men are unmarried day labourers or farm servants, the others married workers. In addition, there are 2,000 women who, though nominally not organised, are married to organised workers and are therefore regarded by both sides as members of the union. These women are occupied mainly in milking and beet cultivation. Some 5,000 to 6,000 of the organised workers are employed by members of the employers' federation or by farmers who have signed estate agreements, and 3,000 to 4,000 (with their wives about 6,000 in all) as seasonal workers with members of the sugar-beet producers' associations. It is difficult to say what proportion of the workers employed by the organised employers are themselves organised. If the wives of organised landworkers are regarded as organised, the proportion of organised married workers employed b y organised employers is between 70 and 80 per cent. GERMANY In Germany both the German Agricultural Workers' Union (SocialDemocratic) and the Central Union of Agricultural Workers, now the Federal Union of Rural Workers (Christian), were in existence before the war, b u t a t t h a t time legislation made it almost everywhere impossible for them to use the strike as a weapon in the struggle for higher wages ; moreover, their membership was far too small to permit the exercise of any real influence on conditions of employment. At the same time, there would appear to have been only a very small number of local employers' organisations which admitted farmers as members. In general, there was a feeling against organisation among agricultural employers, nor was such organisation necessary so long as the prohibition of strikes limited the possibility of concerted action on the part of the workers 1 . As late as 1911 a suggestion concerning the foundation of agricultural employers' organisations was turned down by the Prussian Rural Economic Chamber in order not to encourage organisation among the workers 2 . Even the Social-Democratic Agricultural Workers' Union seems originally to have disapproved of the idea of collective agreements. Nevertheless, the first step towards the introduction of collective bargaining into agriculture was made before the war, the Christian trade unions being responsible for it. The Central Union of State, Municipal, Transport, Assistant and other Industrial Workers, to which many Bavarian agricultural and forestry workers belonged, concluded three estate agreements in 1908, and these were taken over by the Central Union of Agricultural Workers on its foundation in 1912 3 . In the following years the principal efforts of this organisation were directed towards improving conditions of employment in the Rhenish vine country, and it was in this district t h a t the first wage campaign was carried through in J a n u a r y and February 1913. A general and considerable increase in wages, and in certain cases a reduction in hours of work, were the results. On 1 March 1913 a three years' collective agreement was concluded at Niernstein on the Rhine between the 1 A federation of agricultural employers was founded in Schleswig-Holstein in 1912 for the purpose of combating breach of agreement. 2 Dr. Joseph WILDANGEL : Arbeilgeberverbände und Tarifverträge in der Landwirtschaft. Munich-Gladbach, 1920. 3 Max HOPER : Die Löhne und Tarifpolitik des Zentralverbandes der Landarbeiter, p. 7. Berlin 1926. ' — 35 — vinegrowers' associations and the local branch of the Central Union, regulating in great detail piece rates, day wages, hours of work, the period of validity of the agreement and the conditions of terminating it. At Rüdesheim separate collective agreements were concluded with 17 vineyard proprietors. In all, the wage rates and other conditions of employment of over 500 members of the Central Union were collectively regulated during 1913 1 . In April 1914 the vineyard proprietors' association of Neustadt on the Haart made a collective agreement with the Central Union and with the Social-Democratic Agricultural Workers' Union, this being the only collective agreement to which the latter was a party before the war. The development of collective bargaining in the vine country continued during the war. In central Germany a modest beginning in the same direction was made in 1916, but in general the rapid change in values and the rise in the cost of living during the war were not favourable to the conclusion of collective agreements in agriculture. Then came the Revolution of November 1918, which suddenly and completely transformed conditions of employment on the land. As all the old farm servants' codes were repealed on the third day of the Revolution, there was no further obstacle to the spread of the trade union movement among agricultural workers, and the membership of the unions therefore grew rapidly. But agricultural labour law needed immediate completion, for the gap left by the repeal of the old special legislation had to be filled up. Since there was no time to prepare Federal legislation, the Federal Council of Farmers and Agricultural Workers, which had been founded in November, was entrusted with the task. By 20 December a draft had already been agreed on, and this was promulgated as a Provisional Agricultural Code by the Federal Order of 24 J a n u a r y 1919. This achievement of the Federal Council of Farmers and Agricultural Workers is still of great importance for agricultural workers in Germany, since no definitive legislation on the subject has yet been passed. In origin the Provisional Code may be regarded as equivalent to a collective agreement, for it came into existence as a result of discussion between employers and workers and was only subsequently given the force of law. The Provisional Code presupposes t h a t collective agreements will be made, for it provides in section 2 t h a t in undertakings in agriculture and forestry " for which no collective agreement exists, contracts of service shall be drawn up in writing for periods of more t h a n six months". Many of the provisions of the Code have been included textually in subsequent collective agreements. In Anhalt and the province of Saxony the first collective agreement is even called " Agricultural Labour Code for the Province of Saxony " 3 . 1 HAUPTVORSTAND DES ZENTRALVERBANDES DER LANDARBEITER : Zehn Jahre2 christlich-nationale Landarbeiter-Bewegung, 1913-1923, p. 16. Berlin, 1923. Dr. E. MOLITOR : Kommentar zur vorläufigen Landarbeitsordnung vom 24. Januar 1919, p. 3. Berlin 1928. 3 The Order of 23 December 1918 concerning collective agreements, workers' committees, etc., also had much influence on the introduction of collective bargaining •into agriculture in Germany. The workers' committees were instructed to work for the conclusion of collective agreements in those undertakings where they did not already exist. The Order applied to agriculture, and was supplemented by a Decree of the Demobilisation Board on 16 January 1919, which provided that if no other joint organisation of agricultural employers and workers was in existence in a district, the local Council of Farmers and.Agricultural Workers should be competent to conclude agreements regulating wages and conditions of employment on the land. — 36 — The necessity of supplying the people of Germany with food during the Revolution and demobilisation made it essential that conditions of employment in agriculture should be uniformly regulated. Various organisations of agricultural employers, headed by the Farmers' Union, had proclaimed, in the early days of the Revolution, that they were prepared to regulate wages and conditions of employment by means of local committees, whereupon the agricultural workers' organisations had immediately pointed out that this could only be done in conjunction with the workers1. The first agreements were therefore made by the local councils of farmers and agricultural workers which had sprung up on all sides on the Russian model ; but it was recognised by both parties that neither side could use these bodies as permanent agents for collective bargaining. As early as January 1919 district federations of agricultural employers were formed all over the province of Saxony, and on 25 February, forty-eight of these, with some 12,000 members in all, amalgamated to form a provincial association. It is interesting to note that the movement had its cradle in central Germany, where there are both great industrial undertakings and large agricultural estates, and where therefore the introduction into agriculture of a method of labour organisation hitherto confined to industry seemed more natural both to employers and to workers in that part of the country than elsewhere. But the example was quickly followed. Before the end of February district federations had been formed in north Germany, and in the following months employers' federations were founded in all parts of the country except where small holdings are the rule. In the occupied areas of western Germany, the movement started later, because the occupation authorities did not permit concerted action on the part of the workers and there was consequently less need to form employers' organisations. The trade union movement is still less highly developed in the west than elsewhere, and this is certainly due to the hindrances put in the way of an early rapid growth during the Revolution. In September 1919 it was decided to found a national federation of agricultural employers' associations. Not only organisations of agricultural employers but also chambers of agriculture (the Chamber of Agriculture in Halle had collaborated in the foundation of the Federation for the province of Saxony), co-operative societies, the Farmers' Union and other trade associations which had interests in common with the agricultural employers were represented on this occasion. From the very beginning the organisation of German agricultural employers took various forms. On 1 February 1920, ten provincial and State federations — six of whom had 38,000 members in all—were affiliated to the Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations2. The formation of employers' organisations made it possible for collective bargaining to develop freely in agriculture, and during 1919 district agreements were made in nearly every part of Germany. The conclusion of these agreements ran roughly parallel with the foundation of employers' organisations ; they started in central Germany, but were often being signed simultaneously in quite different parts of the country. Towards the end of 1919 the Agricultural Workers' Union 1 Niederschrift über die Konferenz der Gauleiter des Deutschen LandarbeiterVerbandes zu Berlin, am. 3.. 4. und 5 Dezember 1919, p. 16. Schriften des Deutschen Landarbeiterverbandes, Ño. 4. Berlin, 1920. 2 WlLDANGEL, Op. Cit. — 37 — was a party to 268 collective agreements and the Central Union of Agricultural Workers to 177 1 ; but it is impossible to determine to what extent the figures overlap through the two unions signing the same agreements. There is a general lack of information concerning the number of agricultural collective agreements during these first years, and not even the central committees had a thorough grasp of the situation at t h a t time. Most of the so-called collective agreements concluded up to 1920 were in essence nothing but wage bargaining 2 . On the other hand, it is maintained that in the early days a t t e m p t s were made to regulate wages and conditions of employment in far too formal and detailed a way ; the farmers were accustomed to the complete regulations contained in the old farm servants' codes, and tried to use collective agreements as a substitute for them. The first agreements suffered from the fact t h a t sufficient preliminary discussion between the members of each party was not practicable, and thus many of the workers' wishes had to remain unfulfilled. Both workers and employers lacked experience in collective bargaining, and the structure of the agreements made was not satisfactory ; hours of negotiation were often wasted in disputes over unimport a n t details, while matters of real consequence lost the attention they deserved ; neither side really understood what a collective agreement should be 3 . But already in 1920 real collective agreements had been concluded ; and these have in most cases since retained the same general form. The latter part of the inflation period (1921-1923) was of course a difficult time for the agricultural workers' unions. On the one hand, wages rates had to be continuously raised, while on the other there Tas an over-large supply of agricultural labour, since former landworkers were inclined to return from the towns, because food supplies were secure in the country. The agricultural workers had no cash to pay their union contributions, and those which were paid soon lost value. This is the period of struggle in the history of collective bargaining in German agriculture. The contests concerned not the existence of collective bargaining or any other question of principle, but simply increases of wages, sometimes in conjunction with a reduction in hours of work. The causes were often of a purely local nature, and the central committees, which had not always the power to control their members, were a t times compelled to join in strikes which they had not originally undertaken to support. The greatest strike in German agriculture occurred in Silesia in the early summer of 1923. At the end of May in t h a t year a wage agreement had, after negotiation, been agreed to, but it did not satisfy the workers. In some districts the employers paid advances on account of future increases, b u t mass meetings were nevertheless held and it was decided to strike. Without preliminary discussion with the central committee of the Union, work was stopped. According to the German Agricultural Workers' Union, some 90,000 workers were involved — the employers subsequently gave the number as 120,000. They continued to strike for four weeks, practically without strike pay, until the dispute was settled by arbitration. According to the statistics of the German Agricultural Workers' 1 Franz BABILAS : Tarifverträge und Landwirtschaft, p. 8. des Zentralverbandes der Landarbeiter, Heft 12. Berlin, 1921. 2 3 WILDANGEL, op. eil., p. 27. Schriftenreihe Geschäftsbericht des Deutschen Landarbeilerverbandes für die Jahre 1914 bis 1919, p. 53. Schriften des Deutschen Landarbeiterverbandes, Ño. 5. Berlin 1920. — 38 — Union, there were in 1923 over 3,000 wage movements not involving cessation of work, and twelve stoppages affecting in all about 37,000 undertakings and 280,000 workers. In 1924 there were under 500 wage movements, and only nine strikes affecting 2,200 undertakings and 24,000 workers. The biggest strike of the last-named year was in East Prussia, — again contrary to the will of the central committee. There had already been a number of such unauthorised strikes in different East Prussian districts in 1923. At the end of April 1924 the workers, partly under Communist influence, went on strike, and by the beginning of May 20,000 workers were affected, but the strike had eventually to be called off without attaining its object. In the Free State of Saxony also there were a number of strikes in 1924 and 1925. Since t h a t time even the employers admit t h a t only local and easily settled strikes have occurred. But although it has been possible to avoid stoppages of work, it is often very difficult to agree by negotiation alone ; in m a n y cases the conciliation and arbitration authorities are required to give awards, and sometimes the latter must be declared binding before the agreement can be concluded. Nevertheless, agricultural collective bargaining seems to have established itself firmly in Germany. But of late collective agreements have on several occasions been denounced with a view to reducing wages, and most recently for 30 April 1932. By 1 July, however, all the agreements, with a few exceptions, had been renewed, in most cases by mutual agreement between the former parties, and not by arbitration awards declared binding. It is noteworthy t h a t the new agreement for Wurtemberg and Hohenzollern contains no wage rates and only regulates the other conditions of employment. Wages are now fixed by consent between employer and worker. Conditions in Pomerania are exceptional. In the spring of 1919 the so-called land unions (Landbünde) were set up this province ; they soon spread all over the country and the German Land Union was formed, amalgamating in 1920 with the Farmers' Union (founded in 1893) to constitute the Federal Land Union. While the Farmers' Union, as its name implies, was an association of independent farmers, the land unions aimed at realising the ideal of occupational solidarity, i.e. of bringing into one organisation all persons, employers or workers, engaged in a single occupation, in this case agriculture. In accordance with this policy, the land unions object to the formation of employers' federations. " We cannot afford to indulge in such conflicts as are carried on in industry, and so we have no need for class-war organisations; we must therefore oppose the creation of such organisations among the employers and among the workers. W h a t we need is economic peace, and this is the watchword of the Pomeranian Land Union. " 1 At the same time the first a t t e m p t was made in Pomerania to form a non-militant or "yellow" labour organisation, a workers' group of the Pomeranian Land Union being founded in July 1919. The same form of organisation was subsequently adopted in Mecklenburg-Strelitz,but in the other parts of the country the yellow workers' organisations were not so closely connected with the respective land unions. In 1920 all these workers' bodies amalgamated to form the Federal Land Workers' 1 Cited in Julius SCHMITT: Tarifverträgenn der Landwirtschaft, p. 17. Schriften des Deutschen Landarbeiterverbandes, No. 13. Berlin, 1922. — 39 — Union, which is in its turn affiliated to the Federal Land Union 1 . These non-militant organisations are not recognised by the authorities as competent to conclude collective agreements, and this means, among other things, that an agreement made with them has not the legal effects of collective agreements proper. In a few cases the courts, and also the Federal Labour Court, have deemed the agreements concluded by non-militant organisations to be genuine collective agreements. It is nevertheless a fact that the workers' group of the Pomeranian Land Union has been largely responsible for the development of collective bargaining in that province. The German Agricultural Workers' Union had established itself in Pomerania before the foundation of the non-militant organisations, and after the Revolution there were also employers' federations in ten districts of the province, but even in 1919 it was impossible to arrive at a collective agreement, because the employers wished to include the yellow organisations and the workers would not agree. An Order issued by the Prussian Minister of Agriculture in J u n e 1919 made the conclusion of collective agreements compulsory, and this policy was continued by Order of the provincial administration in 1920. In the following years the non-militant workers' organisations gained the upper hand, collective agreements between the workers' and employers' groups of the Land Union being in many cases declared binding on members of-the German Agricultural Workers' Union. The latter is a party to agreements in a few districts only, though the number of direct agreements between it and the employers' groups is on the increase. The National Union of Agricultural Workers is a party to only one agreement 2 . The present position of collective bargaining in agriculture in Germany is as follows : there are two workers' organisations — the Social-Democratic and the Christian agricultural workers' unions — which extend to all parts of the country. They are both parties to all the agricultural collective agreements of any importance, the only exceptions being the provincial agreement in Schleswig-Holstein and the agreement of Brunswick to which the Social-Democratic union alone of the workers' organisations is a party. In Pomerania and the neighbouring country the non-militant workers' organisations are of considerable importance. All the organisations representing the interests of agricultural employers are affiliated to the Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations, save only the Agricultural Employers' Federation for Bavaria, which has left the central body 3 . In 1926 the Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations joined the above-mentioned Federal Land Union as an independent body dealing with all questions affecting agricultural wages, conditions of employment and social policy, and the result was that all the employers' groups attached to the Federal Land Union or its affiliated State, provincial and district land unions, in particular those of Pomerania, the Free State of Saxony and Mecklenburg-Strelitz, came under the control of the Union. Further the Union took over the representation of employers' interests in all those districts where land unions existed, but where 1 Dr. Constance VON SCHWERIN : Die Landarbeiterorganisationen Ostdeutschlands2 und ihre klassenmässige und ständische Struktur, p. 29. Langensalza, 1928. Dr. F. HERING : Die Landarbeiter und ihre Gewerkschaften, p. 34. Schriften des Deutschen Landarbeiterverbandes, No. 24. Berlin, 1929. 3 The Agricultural Federation for Wurtemberg and Hohenzollern was also independent for a time. — 40 — employers' groups had not been founded because of the prevalence of small peasant farms 1 . The Federal Union admits t h a t the varying structure of the employers' organisations in the different States and provinces makes a uniform representation of agricultural employers a very difficult matter ; it never itself concludes collective agreements, and the bodies which compose it have a free hand in the settlement of wages and other conditions of employment. On the other hand, the fact t h a t general associations of persons engaged in agriculture frequently act as employers' organisations has probably contributed to the progress of collective bargaining in districts where empjoyers' associations pure and simple could hardly have gained a foothold. But this spontaneous and unsystematic growth of employers'organisations would now appear to be giving rise to certain difficulties. In Germany only the so-called " economic associations " of employers and workers are competent to propose and designate representatives on social insurance institutions, labour exchanges, unemployment insurance institutions and institutions for the settlement of labour disputes. Exactly what the term " economic associations " means is not laid down, but legal decisions have gradually established certain principles in accordance with which an organisation which wishes to be regarded as an association of employers is required to fulfil the following conditions. It must comprise employers only ; and the economic purpose of the organisation must be the regulation of conditions of employment. These requirements have only gradually been clearly established, and in many parts of the country no difficulties are yet raised with regard to organisations which do not fully accord with them (land unions, peasants' associations, etc.) ; but the authorities are now requiring more and more exact conformity with their definition. One cause of this attitude is the steady growth among the workers of a trade union movement of a Communist type which has been refused recognition by the labour courts as having political rather than economic objects. As a result of this stricter attitude a number of agricultural associations, which until recently had been readily recognised as employers' organisations, have suffered the same fate, and if the process continues it will apparently be necessary to reorganise the representation of agricultural employers in many parts of Germany 2 . Agricultural collective agreements are common in almost every part of Germany. In Pomerania and Brandenburg conditions of employment 1 Annual report on the work of the National Union for 1926. The Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers is now organised on the following lines. In Anhalt and the province of Saxony, Silesia, Schleswig-Holstein, Brandenburg, Thuringia, Hanover and the Rheingau the agricultural employers have largely formed associations to protect their interests purely as employers of labour on the model of the industrialists' organisations, some even relying on the latter for support. The members are in part individual employers, in part agricultural and forestry organisations founded for economic purposes which watch their members' interests as employers in exchange for an agreed sum. Moreover, in Hessen and the Rhineland the chambers of agriculture are at the same time the offices of the local federations. In East Prussia, Brunswick, Nassau, the two States of Mecklenburg, Pomerania and the Free State of Saxony, employers' groups have simply been founded as branches of the land unions ; they are supported out of the ordinary land union contributions and have no individual members." The Agricultural Federation for Wurtemberg and Hohenzollern, the employers' committee of which is affiliated to the Federal Union, belongs to the Federation of German Peasants' Associations. 2 " Der land- und forstwirtschaftliche Arbeitgeber ", Nachrichtenblatt des Reichsverbandes der deutschen land- und forstwirtschaftlichen Arbeitgebervereinigungen, 12th year, No. Il ,28 Nov. 1931. — 41 — are regulated by district, and, in these provinces only, some districts have collective agreements only with non-militant workers' organisations, In the Rhineland and the other frontier lands of north-west Germany collective bargaining is less firmly entrenched than in other parts, and here too the number of agreements varies. The north-west, and above all Westphalia, where peasant farming is overwhelmingly prevalent, is the only part of Germany where collective agreements are practically nonexistent. In 1919 the first collective agreements were concluded in that province, some with individual employers, others with district employers' federations ; in 1924 the latter bodies disbanded in order to prevent collective agreements being made, and in 1929 only six agreements with individual employers were in force ; but it is probable that, under the influence of the Federation of German Peasants' Associations, some form of organisation to represent the interests of agricultural employers will be formed in Westphalia. The area covered by collective agreements in German agriculture varies considerably, depending largely on the form of association adopted by the employers ; but organisation on their part is so widespread that very few agreements are now concluded with individual undertakings. Agreements covering districts only occur most frequently in Pomerania and Brandenburg, and are accounted for by the decentralisation of the land unions. In the Rhineland and central Germany (including the Free State of Saxony) the agreements cover a considerably larger area. Apart from the local subsidiary agreements which regulate wage rates and occasionally hours of work within the limits laid down by the covering agreements, and which occur chiefly in Anhalt, the province of Saxony and Bavaria, conditions of employment are uniformly regulated in the following large areas : the Prussian provinces of East Prussia, Silesia, Saxony and Schleswig-Holstein and the States of Baden, Bavaria and Wurtemberg. Much of the importance of collective bargaining in Germany is due to the possibility of declaring agreements generally binding. The Federal Minister of Labour is empowered to declare agreements which are decisive factors in the conditions of employment of any occupational group in a given area to be generally binding within the area covered by them. They are then binding, within the area which they cover, in respect of all contracts concerning the same type of employment even if neither the employer nor the workerwas party to the original collective agreement. Such a declaration can only be made on application by one of the parties to the agreement or by an organisation of employers or workers the members of which will be affected by the declaration1. Naturally, in occupations like agriculture where both employers and workers are only partially organised, such a possibility is an enormous support to collective bargaining. In certain cases — in the province of Saxony, for instance — the text of the collective agreement provides that application shall be made for such a declaration. At the end of 1931 the covering agreements for agricultural workers in Bavaria, Wurtemberg and Baden, Rheinhessen and Kurhessen, Brunswick, Anhalt and the province of Saxony2, Silesia, Schleswig-Holstein, and in one district each in Brandenburg and Pomerania, were declared generally binding. 1 and 3. Order of 23 December 1918 concerning collective agreements, sections 2 2 The covering agreement is generally binding ; but this does not apply to all its subsidiary agreements. — 42 — The frequency of this declaration and the extent to which agricultural employers are organised make the question how far unorganised employers apply the terms of collective agreements to their undertakings of less importance. According to the workers' unions there are, in East Prussia for instance, practically no unorganised employers, and the few who exist accept the terms of the agreements. In MecklenburgSchwerin the few unorganised employers pay the agreement wage-rates and, in some cases, even more. It is reported from other parts of the country also t h a t unorganised employers accept the terms of collective agreements. The following figures may illustrate the extent of agricultural collective bargaining in Germany ; they are taken from the collective agreement statistics 1 . NUMBER OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS ON FOR 1 JANUARY AGRICULTURAL WORKERS 1929 Number of agreements Number of undertakings Number of workers Single estates One locality One district 28 4 84 55 74 189,320 1,712 3,296 1,393,997 1 undertaking 2-20 undertakings 21-100 undertakings Over 100 undertakings Not known 19 16 15 65 1 19 105 776 188,549 740 3,682 34,667 1,359,916 Up to 100 workers 101-1,000 1,001-10,000 „ 10,001-100,000,, Over 100,000 „ 25 14 37 37 2 64 259 10,509 140,787 37,830 902 5,577 147,133 839,393 406,000 116 103 115 189,449 172,256 169,982 1,399,005 1,591,806 1,363,937 Agreements valid for Total 1929 : 1928 : 1927 : Note. — In the first years after the war it was not regarded as sufficient in Germany to establish independent workers' and employers' organisations and to have them brought into the position of contracting parties through the collective agreements which they signed ; it was considered necessary to create permanent bodies to which both these parties might belong ; and it was even declared that the most important part of a collec1 " Die Tarifverträge im Deutschen Reich am 1. Januar 1929 " (bearbeitet im Statistischen Reichsamt), Reichsarbeiisblatt, 55. Sonderheft. Berlin, 1930. — 43 — tive agreement was t h a t which established a " joint labour association " composed of equal numbers of employers' and workers' representatives 1 . The German legal definition of a joint labour association is a joint trade body founded by voluntary agreement to protect the interests of the persons represented. The first joint labour associations were set up during the war as a result of exceptional circumstances, and conditions during the following years greatly favoured their development. In 1919 the Central Joint Association of Industrial and Handicraft Employers and Workers of Germany was founded and its creation officially announced. The need for such an association in agriculture was then generally recognised, but very different ideas were held concerning the form which it should take. Some considered that it should be a permanent institution composed of representatives of employers and workers for the purpose of maintaining and extending collective bargaining and deciding on the correct interpretation of agreements in cases of dispute ; while others believed t h a t labour questions could not be isolated from other economic problems in agriculture and therefore regarded it as necessary for employers and workers to have a common policy on matters of production and technique. The employers' federations had come into existence locally and subsequently amalgamated, but the joint labour associations were developed, so to speak, from above downwards. As a result of negotiations set in motion by the Federal Ministry of Economic Affairs (now the Federal Ministry of Agriculture and Food Supplies) and concluded on 20 February 1920, the Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations on the one hand and the German Agricultural Workers' Union and the Central Union of Agricultural Workers on the other entered the Federal Joint Association of Employers and Workers in Agriculture and Forestry. Each side had equal rights and obligations, the principal objects of the new organisation being : (a) to encourage the conclusion and application of collective agreements ; (b) to make proposals and to give expert advice to the authorities and legislative institutions. The formation of State and provincial joint labour associations in the Federal States, in Prussia and also in the provinces was to be encouraged 2 . In its first years the Federal Joint Labour Association was very active, although it confined its attention to the development of collective bargaining, while the Central Joint Association for Industry dealt also with all economic questions of occupational interest. Very soon, however, the Federal J o i n t Association, like the corresponding industrial body, lost much of its importance. From 1923 onwards its activity was restricted to more or less desultory collaboration between the member organisations, though the Association did not actually cease to exist until 1926. Its formal dissolution was occasioned by the secession of the Federal Union of Agricultural and .Forestry Employers' Associations, which had come to the conclusion t h a t the German Agricultural Workers' Union did not wish to collaborate further within the Association. Of the local joint labour associations the most highly developed was t h a t for Anhalt and the province of Saxony, which not only met 1 2 W l L D A N G E L , Op. Cil. Dr. W. v. ALTROCK : Die Organisation der deutschen Landwirtschaft, Berlin, 1921. p. 108. — 44 — regularly but also set up a permanent Collective Agreement Office which still exists. After the conclusion of the first covering agreement in the province of Saxony in 1919 the contracting parties formed a joint labour association 1 , and set up the following bodies to ensure the general application of the agreements : (a) district joint labour associations ; (b) the Agricultural Collective Agreement Office for Anhalt and the province of Saxony at Halle. The district joint associations were composed of from two to five employers and the same number of workers, representing the parties to the covering agreement. Since 1926 an arbitration committee has been set up as part of each district joint association. But the foundation of the Collective Agreement Office is of greater practical importance. Its duties are : (a) to examine every part of the wage and labour contracts made in agriculture, forestry and related occupations in order to supply the district joint associations with the necessary d a t a on which the collective agreements to be concluded b y them may be based ; (b) to further uniformity in collective agreements ; (c) to guarantee the observance of the rights and obligations laid down in agreements ; (d) to secure as far as possible a uniform regulation of wages and conditions of employment for the whole area with which it deals ; (e) to further the development of separate departments agricultural workers at public labour exchanges. for The board of the Collective Agreement Office comprises two full-time officials, one appointed by the employers, the other by the workers. The district joint associations are competent to settle any disputes concerning collective bargaining in the place of the official conciliation and arbitration bodies. If the district association can neither mediate nor make an award the matter is decided by the Office. The Collective Agreement Office also acts as secretariat to the Central Germany Joint Agricultural Association, which was formed in 1926. Its founders were the employers' associations for agriculture and forestry in Brunswick, Kurhessen, the Free State of Saxony, the province of Saxony, Southern Hanover and Thuringia (Federation of Central Germany Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations) on the one hand and the Social-Democratic and Christian Federations of agricultural workers' unions on the other. The object of the Association is to settle questions affecting wages and conditions of employment in as uniform a manner as possible. The conclusion of collective agreements for the various areas is left to the competent district joint associations, so t h a t due account may be taken of local conditions. If an agreement cannot be so concluded, the matter is decided b y a special ad hoc committee of the Central Germany Joint Association, composed of five employers' and five workers' assessors and an impartial chairman with the right to vote. The committee's first task is to a t t e m p t mediation ; if this is not success1 The term " Collective Agreement Association " was in subsequent agreements substituted for that of Joint Labour Association, but this was a change in name only. — 45 — ful the award given is an award within the meaning of section 1 of the Conciliation Order of 30 October 1923, and is immediately binding on the parties if such has been agreed on for the case in question before the award. Decisions made by majority vote of the assessors are immediately binding under similar conditions. In order to facilitate uniform regulation of wages and other conditions of employment, the parties are entitled to request members of the board of the Collective Agreement Office at Halle to attend negotiations in an advisory capacity. The convention by which the Central Germany Joint Association was set up can only be terminated at the end of a calendar year with three months' notice. GREAT BRITAIN: Scotland The Scottish Farm Servants' Union was founded in 1912 and the National Farmers' Union for Scotland was set up a year later ; the latter organisation is a general agricultural association of farmers. The agreements concluded between the Scottish Farm Servants' Union and this association, or its local sections, are not collective agreements in the strict sense of the word. They only stipulate the working conditions which the organisation recommend to its members as a basis for individual labour contracts. They can therefore only be characterised as guiding principles. The general practice followed is to print the agreement on the back of the engagement form, the terms of the agreement thus becoming part of the individual contract. Even where no individual written contract has been drawn up, however, the agreement is accepted as an implied condition of employment, unless an employer is able to prove that he has contracted out of it. The first collective agreement in Scotland was signed in 1915, and covered only a small district in the county of Ayrshire. In 1916 a Joint Wages Committee was established with the National Farmers' Union for the districts covered by the Glasgow hiring area, Renfrew, Dumbarton, Lower Lanark and West Stirling, but only that for the Glasgow area is still in force. The Committee meets every six months to adjust wages for the following half-year. During the war agricultural committees of the local authorities were recommended to arrange for meetings of farmers and farm servants for the purpose of electing representatives who would form a joint committee to discuss from time to time the necessary adjustments of wages and conditions of service. These district agricultural committees had already been set up in several counties in 1917, and in the Lothians the first agreement concerning wages was concluded during this year. In the three following years this method of collective bargaining was extended to about half of the counties of Scotland. After the first year the representatives of these joint committees were nominated by the National Farmers' Union and the Scottish Farm Servants' Union respectively. Ón the other hand, the work of the statutory wage committees, which were set up between 1917 and 1921 under the Corn Production Act, was of limited practical importance. By means of the voluntary collective bargaining carried out by the joint committees, it was generally possible to obtain higher wages than the minimum rates fixed by the statutory committees. In the year 1922 the growth of collective agreements concerning wages in Scottish agriculture reached its high water mark, and most of the counties had agreed as to the general principles to be observed. — 46 — Since then, however, there has been a marked failure to reach agreement on this question, although here and there progress has been made. In 1930 the only wage agreement concluded was that for the Glasgow hiring area, although in 1931 agreements were also drawn u p in Midlothian, West Lothian and West Fife. In February 1919 a conference was held between the National Farmers' Union and the Scottish Farm Servants' Union to regulate the question of hours of work in agriculture, at which a resolution was adopted recommending to farmers and agricultural workers t h a t the hours of work should be laid down on the basis of a 50-hour week. This was the first attempt made to draw up an agreement for the whole of Scotland on working conditions in agriculture. Difficulties of interpretation arose, however, and the agreement was not finally accepted by the national organisations. In practice, however, it formed the basis of local agreements between the two parties in all counties except one, although certain difficulties were experienced when it came to be carried out in practice. After 1923 the representatives of the National Farmers' Union tried, in several counties, to alter the working conditions laid down by the 1919 agreement. They succeeded in doing so in some counties, though the main principles adopted remained in force for some time longer. In other counties the agreements ceased to exist. In many cases the workers succeeded in maintaining the old conditions of work, in spite of the fact t h a t the formal agreements had expired. For the past eight years no new agreements concerning conditions of work have been made, with the exception of t h a t for the Glasgow hiring area, which is thus the only existing agreement on this subject. ITALY Italy is the only European State which had really developed a system of collective bargaining in agriculture before the war. Agricultural workers' unions appeared towards the end of the nineteenth century, the movement beginning in the valley of the Po, where agricultural work is done largely by day labourers and permanent workers, subsequently spreading to districts where share farming is the prevailing system. In every village each category of workers formed its own " league ", and these bodies concluded collective agreements with the individual employers. The latter were well-nigh powerless to resist them, and therefore began to organise on their side, first in committees formed for the conduct of negotiations and then in permanent associations. Collective bargaining has since that date always taken place between the organisations on either side. The next step was the amalgamation of the local associations into provincial federations and the consequent suppression of the principal variations between the many agreements. A collective agreement at this time usually covered the area of a whole province. As early as 1901 the agricultural workers' organisations founded a national federation. In 1907 the agricultural employers set up a inter-provincial federation in Bologna which comprised several provinces and regions of Northern Italy. In 1910 this federation was transformed into a national organisation, but its field of activity remained practically the same. After the war the National Agricultural Secretariat succeeded in forming, out of this federation and other associations which it had set up in Central and Southern Italy, a real — 47 — national federation, i.e. the General National Federation of Agriculture. After five years of activity this organisation was absorbed by the National Fascist Confederation of Agriculture. The Social-Democratic Agricultural Workers' Union was followed later by the establishment of Republican and Catholic workers' federations. In some provinces all the workers' unions were parties to the same collective agreement, while in others they negotiated separately with the employers 1 . The SocialDemocratic Federation, comprising some 850,000 members, affiliated itself to the International Landworkers' Federation. The Fascist trade union movement has profoundly modified this situation. From the very beginning the idea of an intimate collaboration between employers and workers played an important role in the development of occupational representation in Fascist Italy. Originally attempts were made to combine both parties into one joint organisation. This idea was successfully carried out as regards agriculture, but not in the manufacturing industries. Even in agriculture, however, this procedure, met with resistance on the part of the workers. In 1924 all joint organisations of agricultural workers and employers had ceased to exist and only separate organisations remained. Subsequent legislation on occupational representation has maintained the principle of separate organisation. The importance of the Act of 3 April 1926 on the legal regulation of collective relations in connection with employment lies in the definite framework which it supplies for a system of occupational organisation, officially recognised and placed under the control of the State. Occupational organisations are public institutions possessing the rights and duties attached to such bodies ; but in the execution of their tasks, as set forth in their statutes, and above all as regards the conclusion and terms of collective agreements, they enjoy complete autonomy. According to the principles laid down in the Act, the formation of occupational organisations shall be carried out on voluntary lines, no one being compelled to join, but only one such organisation in any occupational group can obtain State recognition. To this end certain stipulations must be fulfilled. A workers' organisation must comprise directly, and an employers' organisation indirectly, at least one-tenth of the workers engaged in a particular occupation. Such associations may cover a commune, a district, one or more provinces or regions, or the whole State. The associations may unite to form federations, and the federations again to form confederations. The federations and confederations are designated as organisations of higher grade, and the associations as organisations of inferior grade. National confederations may be officially recognised both for employers and workers for each of the following industries : the manufacturing industry, agriculture, commerce, marine and aerial transport, transport by land and inland navigation, banking and insurance. There is further a national confederation for persons belonging to the liberal professions and for artists, making altogether thirteen national confederations. On their recognition as occupational organisations depends the right of such bodies to represent employers and workers within a district and to conclude collective agreements, to which all local individual labour contracts must conform. In this way every collective agreement becomes generally binding. There is no strict obligation to conclude collective agreements, although the Labour Charter of 1927 declares, 1 " Collective Labour Agreements in Italian Agriculture ", in Labour Review, Vol. XIV, No. 5, Nov. 1926, p. 676. International — 48 — t h a t it is the d u t y of the occupational organisations to conclude them. Theoretically it is conceivable t h a t the necessary organisations may not exist in a given district and t h a t therefore no collective agreement can be concluded. The idea to which consideration was first given of prescribing collective agreements in every part of the country was abandoned, owing to the rapid and spontaneous growth of collective bargaining. Strikes and lock-outs are prohibited. Disputes concerning collective agreements, their introduction or renewal, are settled by the labour courts. The awards of the courts are binding and have the same legal power as collective agreements concluded voluntarily. When necessary, the Ministry of Corporations acts as conciliator. In accordance with a recommendation of the Central Committee of Trade Unions, collective agreements hitherto ruling remain in force until a new agreement has been concluded. A collective agreement is not valid until it has been deposited with the public authorities and approved and published by them. It is their d u t y to ascertain whether such agreements are in accordance with legislation, and an agreement cannot be published unless it contains in full the statutory provisions and regulations concerning the following : employment of workers during their period of probation, wage rates and payment methods, hours of work and the weekly rest, annual holidays with pay in the case of continuous undertakings, arrangements in case of sickness or death, of dismissal without fault of the worker, of change of management, and of calling up for military service. Exception is made for agreements which do not regulate certain of these points provided the latter are covered by legislation, or are not important in the particular case, or if it is stipulated in the agreement t h a t they will be settled by the parties within a certain period. Occupational organisations shall not only seek to regulate labour conditions from the point of view of the employer and of the worker, b u t shall also take the higher interests of production, and consequently the interests of the whole nation, into consideration. Thus the " corporative idea " exercises influence over the activity of occupational organisations. The legislation of 1926, however, also created the possibility of instituting special organs to bring about more intimate collaboration between (employers' and workers' organisations. Such liaison bodies may be established by the Ministry of Corporations. They are designated as corporations, and are not legal personalities but organs of the State administration. To them is confided the task of settling disputes between their constituent organs, the drawing up of certain general regulations with regard to labour, the encouragement and support of measures for the co-ordination and improved organisation of production, the setting up of employment exchanges where necessary, and the regulation and superintendence of apprenticeship. In all matters relating to the conclusion of collective labour contracts, however, the occupational organisations retain their competence. In the meanwhile such corporations were not set up, but first the National Council of Corporations, already announced by Order of J u l y 1926, was created under an Act of 20 March 1930. The National Council of Corporations was instructed to keep watch over the activities of every factor of economic and social life and to bring them into harmony with one another. It is also the duty of the Council to further uniformity in collective agreements. Besides representatives of employers' and workers' organisations, the Council includes representatives of the co-operative societies. The Council is divided into sections corresponding to the above-mentioned occupational confederations. A Decree provides — 49 — t h a t the duties and rights of the above-mentioned corporations can be entrusted to the corresponding sections of the National Council of Corporations. This was done under the Decree of 27 J a n u a r y 1931, the function of conciliator being reserved for the Minister of Corporations. In everyday language these sections are spoken of, though incorrectly, as corporations. According to the strict sense of the Act, however, there is only one corporation properly so called, i.e. t h a t of the theatre. The Agricultural Section of the National Council of Corporations has dealt with such questions as methods of fixing wages for workers occupied in soil improvement work, the valuation of the live stock of share farmers, and the liquidation of credits of share farmers in cases of change of proprietor. The section is working on a " Charter of Share Farming ". This problem is not one of tenancy only, b u t is rather a labour question of the greatest social importance. The structure of agricultural occupational organisations, which has been changed several times, is actually as follows : the National Fascist Confederation of Agriculture comprises agricultural associations of the higher grade, national confederations of special categories, and certain other agricultural associations and institutions. Associations of the higher grade are again divided into section for agriculturists who do not themselves engage in manual work but superintend an undertaking (estates and large peasant farms) ; section for landowners who lease their land ; section for leaseholders ; and section for owners and tenants who themselves share in the manual work. In accordance with a Decree of J a n u a r y 1931, tenants who themselves do manual work belong either to the organisation of employers or to t h a t of the workers, according to the size of their holding. The determining area is fixed by the two organisations in agreement for each province or part of a province. Out of a total of 2,700,000 farmers, 465,000 are members of the abovementioned Confederation. The Federation of Fascist Agricultural Trade Unions is formed by provincial agricultural workers' organisations. These again are subdivided into sections for the different categories of agricultural workers. The Federation has at the present time about 1,400,000 members, of whom 1,035,000 are permanent and day labourers, while 208,000 are share farmers and 89,000 small tenants. It is estimated t h a t about onehalf of the persons eligible for membership belong to the Federation, while about two-thirds of the permanent and day labourers are members. On 31 December 1931, 4 agreements covering the whole of Italy, • 2 regional agreements, and 375 provincial agreements were in force, besides 207 agreements existing concerning only one commune or a single undertaking. The number of collective agreements in certain provinces has fallen, owing to the amalgamation of several minor agreements to cover a whole province. In other provinces several agreements still exist both for different classes of agricultural workers and for different districts of the province. NETHERLANDS The representation of agricultural employers and workers in the Netherlands is extremely decentralised. There are a Social-Democratic, a Protestant and a Roman Catholic agricultural workers' union, and each enters into collective agreements with the general associations of agricultural employers. Local collective agreements have been in existence since 1908, but the movement was not of real importance until the last 4 — 50 — years of the war. Negotiations for the conclusion of collective agreements have on several occasions caused strikes of considerable gravity, one declared by the Social-Democratic union in 1930 affecting 3,000 workers and continuing for as long as five and a half months. The following table 1 shows the position in June 1930 in respect of collective agreements in agriculture and horticulture. Separate data for stock-raising and crop production are only available on the totals. Number of undertakings Number of workers 11 53 66 78 79 91 742 3,864 3,810 3,519 3,891 4,252 1,492 11,948 15,185 18,861 15,753 21,252 1930 valid for : one undertaking one locality one district 31 100 15 31 4,027 2,005 663 13,815 12,001 Total For agriculture proper only 146 82 6,063 3,902 26,479 18,186 Year 1918 1920 1922 1924 . 1926 1928 Number of agreements As the table indicates, most of the agreements are valid for a small area. The few district agreements have only recently been concluded, and there are none with a really wide — i.e. provincial or national — validity ; in several cases wage rates for larger areas have been collectively settled by the employers' and workers' organisations, but this has been done by means of correspondence, and no actual collective agreement has been made. Since 1919 the Netherlands Catholic Farmers' and Market Gardeners' Federation and the Catholic Land Workers' Union have maintained joint councils similar in character to the German joint labour associations. Their object is to encourage the spirit of occupational solidarity in agriculture and market gardening and to ensure a maximum of economic peace ; they are composed of equal numbers of employers and workers, and represent not individual undertakings but areas of a considerable size. Their duties include acting as arbitration boards when a conflict appears imminent, drafting collective agreements and securing their conclusion, and safeguarding the rights of the workers to a voice in economic policy in each district. There are three such local councils and one for the whole country. 1 STATISTIEK VAN NEDERLAND : Overzichl van den Omvang en den Voornaamslen Inhoud der Collectieve Arbeidsovereenkomsten op I June 1930, table p. 29. Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek, Dec. 1930. — 51 — POLAND It was not possible to set up agricultural trade unions for the whole of Poland before the foundation of the Republic. All combination was prohibited in Congress Poland 1 , there were no agricultural workers' organisations in Galicia, and the unions formed in the former Prussian territory in connection with the movement then developing in Germany were the only agricultural workers' organisations in existence in Poland before 1918. As many as five agricultural workers' unions were subsequently formed, the Social Democratic, National and Christian being the most important. The interests of the agricultural employers are represented not by federations of employers of labour as such, but by general agricultural associations, and these may be divided into two groups, that of the large estate owners and t h a t of the independent farmers in general. The following review will show t h a t in many parts of Poland the employers are represented by several different organisations. ( 1 ) In the five central provinces agricultural employers are represented by the Landowners' Association (Warsaw). (2) In the provinces of Poznan and Pomorze the Federation of Agricultural Associations (Poznan) represents the independent Polish farmers, while the Federation of Employers in German Agricultural Undertakings (Poznan) and the Federation of Farmers in the Vistula Valley represent German agricultural employers in Poznan and Pomorze respectively. (3) In the provinces of Lwow (Lemberg), StanislawówandTarnopol the Federation of Landowners of the East-Galician Provinces (Lwow) and the Federation of Galician Farmers (Lwow) represent respectively the Christian and Jewish agricultural employers of the area. (4) In the province of Krakow agricultural employers are represented by the Association of Landowners (Krakow). (5) In the Eastern provinces of Wilno, Nowogrodek and Polesie by the Federation of Landowners of the Frontier Provinces (Warsaw). (6) In the province of Volhynia by the Federation of Landowners (Luck). While most of these organisations are content to be represented by ad hoc delegates at negotiations concerning collective agreements, the organisations in the five central provinces and in Poznan and Pomorze have set up special departments for labour questions, and maintain permanent delegations, which constitute a Committee of Employers, for negotiations on agreements. These institutions are a considerable aid to the uniform settlement of labour questions. Special services of the Central Council of Landowners' Organisations, to which all the above bodies are affiliated, have as their chief duty to assist in the conclusion of collective agreements all over the country and to give advice to various employers' organisations. When the present Polish Republic was founded, the agricultural population was in an extremely unsettled state, and with the first months of independence came a dangerous strike among the agricultural 1 This includes only the former Grand Duchy of Poland and not the Eastern Provinces, which were part of Russia proper until 1918. — 52 — workers. Popular land movements had taken place before the war, and during the Revolution of 1905 widespread strikes had broken out in Russian Poland. In October 1918 a strike occurred on certain estates in t h e former Government of Lublin, and quickly spread over the whole southern part of Congress Poland. This movement, which was encouraged by Communist agitation, compelled t h e Minister of Labour to send into the strike area so-called Agricultural Delegates, whose duty it was to a t t e m p t mediation on individual estates. The Delegates, following the instructions of the Ministry of Labour, attempted to make settlements for several estates a t once. Eventually their efforts were successful and the strike ended. This was the beginning of collective bargaining in Polish agriculture. It was considered necessary to give the Delegates' work a statutory basis, and' on 28 March 1919 the Act concerning the settlement of collective disputes between employers and workers in agriculture was passed. Additional provisions became law on 1 August 1919 and 11 March 1921 1 . The Act 2 has two objects: (1) to facilitate and ensure the conclusion of collective agreements in agriculture ; (2) to provide for decisions in case of disputes concerning the application and interpretation of such agreements (the arbitration boards instituted by t h e Act function as labour tribunals for agriculture, but have no power themselves to enforce their decisions). Collective disputes m a y be settled in three ways : (1) with t h e assistance of the labour inspectorate, which was created by Order of 3 J a n u a r y 1919; (2) by conciliation b o a r d s ; (3) by arbitration boards. The conciliation boards established by the supplementary Act of 1 August 1919 are not of great importance, for the disputes are usually either so inconsiderable t h a t the labour inspector can settle them, or so serious that application must be made to an arbitration board. The employers and workers are represented on the conciliation and arbitration boards through their occupational organisations established in the district in question and registered in accordance with t h e regulations. If there are no such organisations, the authorities arrange for the direct election of employers' and workers' representatives. The labour inspector may refer a dispute, on his own initiative, to conciliation, but application by one of the parties and agreement in advance, by both parties, to accept the award are necessary before the matter m a y be brought before an arbitration board. The settlements made with t h e aid of t h e conciliation board and awards issued by the arbitration board are binding for the period laid down in the collective agreement or in the award, but in no case for longer than one year. The regulation of wages and conditions of employment made by means of such a settlement or award is binding on all agricultural employers and workers in t h e district concerned ; individual contracts which contain conditions less favourable to the workers are invalid. The Act thus ignores the comparative importance of the occupational organisations which conclude agreements by means of the machinery it sets up, and its insistence on t h e generally binding force of all agreements so concluded is its most essential feature. It has become t h e universal practice for the public authorities to collaborate in the drafting of collective agreements ; the labour inspector invites the parties in good time to a meeting to negotiate on the renewal of the agreement, which is then concluded either with the aid of a conciliation board or 1 2 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Legislative Series, 1921, Pol. 2. The text of 1921 was amended by the Act of 25 February 1930, but the alterations affect only the duties of the arbitration boards as agricultural tribunals. — 53 — by the decision of an arbitration board, and is therefore binding on all agricultural employers and workers in the district. In t h e early part of 1919 large numbers of collective agreements, based on the legislation of that year, came into existence in the provinces of Poznan, Warsaw, Kielce, Lublin and Bialystok, and in 1919 occupational association was so far advanced t h a t it was possible to conclude an agreement for the whole of Congress Poland. In December of t h a t year representatives of the central committees of the employers' and workers' organisations m e t for t h e first time t o discuss this possibility. The Act of 1919 had prescribed district collective agreements, so t h a t only these could be given binding force ; and the central committees had therefore to undertake to induce their district committees to ratify t h e general agreement. This was speedily and easily done and the agreement remained in force until t h e end of March 1921. In t h a t year the employers' organisations of the five central provinces refused t o negotiate with the workers' unions on account of the latter's alleged Communist attitude. The Act of 1919, which does not provide for the issue of a binding award by t h e authorities, was not sufficient to meet t h e emergency, and t h e Government was compelled to introduce new legislation. The old Act, which was valid for a year and applied only to Congress Poland, was renewed several times and extended in 1922 to Galicia ; b u t finally in July 1924 a new Act was passed with unlimited temporal validity and applying to the whole of Poland except Upper Silesia 1 . The Minister of Labour and Social Welfare is hereby empowered to convene a special arbitration board in cases in which it is impossible to settle a collective dispute in agriculture by t h e procedure prescribed in t h e Act of 1919, or if the parties refuse to submit voluntarily to the arbitration board to which they appealed. The Minister appoints t h e chairman of t h e board, on which the Ministry of Agriculture and State Lands, the Ministry of Justice and the organisations of agricultural employers and workers are also represented. If t h e parties refuse to appoint representatives, the latter are no longer elected, and t h e board then consists only of t h e three Government representatives. The board lays down the conditions under which contracts of employment may be concluded in agriculture, and its decisions are binding for not more than one year. If, after a decision by this special board, a collective agreement is concluded b y friendly negotiation between employers and workers, its provisions are substituted for the relevant decisions of t h e board. The Act makes it possible for t h e authorities to intervene in cases where t h e workers are not organised — where, for instance, a dispute has arisen between t h e workers on a single estate and t h e employer, or where a collective demand for higher wages is made b y workers not supported by an organisation ; it has thus enabled collective agreements to spread in areas where the workers were comparatively poorly organised. On t h e other hand, in the opinion of the workers it has prevented them from using their advantage to t h e full where their organisations are strongest. In 1922 collective agreements for Congress Poland were again voluntarily concluded, and in t h e same year t h e first agreement for Pomorze was made. Collective bargaining then spread over the whole country, and by 1927 every province had its agreement. The instability of the currency, however, made it extremely difficult to regulate wages, 1 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR »OFFICE : Legislative Series, 1924, Pol. 4. — 54 — and 1925 saw the third strike in the history of collective bargaining in Polish agriculture. It was not of long duration, for the majority of the workers did not take part, and its result was a slight improvement in conditions of employment, though many of the strikers were dismissed at the end of the year. In the last few years collective agreements have been concluded in Poznan and Pomorze only by means of binding arbitration awards. Collective agreements are in principle valid for all agricultural undertakings, but in practice they apply mostly to the larger estates. The statistics of 1920 show t h a t there were then 16,713 large estates (i.e. estates of a total area of more t h a n 50 hectares — about 125 acres) in Poland, employing 620,000 workers in all ; in view of these figures, the following table will give an idea of the extent of collective bargaining in such undertakings 1 : Year Number of undertakings Total area (hectares) Number of workers employed 1920-1921 1921-1922 1922-1923 1923-1924 1927-1928 1928-1929 1929-1930 5,917 10,717 12,121 13,652 16,873 16,873 16,873 2,878,278 4,447,543 5,236,783 6,314,598 9,765,706 9,765,706 9,765,706 122,517 318,825 396,414 412,832 520,365 454,318 520,365 The agreements are in most cases valid for several provinces, the geographical arrangement corresponding with t h a t of the employers' organisations outlined above. SWEDEN By 1904 the trade union movement was strong enough among agricultural workers in Scania to compel organisation on the part of the employers and to force through the first collective agreements ; in many cases the latter process was only completed after long and stubborn conflicts, for the employers refused to accept the principle of the collective regulation of conditions of employment. The pre-war movement reached its zenith in 1908, when the conditions of some 2,000 workers in ninety undertakings were regulated by collective agreements. In t h a t year the local employers' associations, which had by t h a t time appeared in several provinces, formed a central organisation entitled the Representative Committee of the Swedish Agricultural Employers' Associations ; in 1910 this body had 1,800 members, farming 215,000 hectares (about 550,000 acres) of arable land and employing 26,000 workers. Subsequently, however, the union movement among the agricultural workers suffered a decline. Better wages having been obtained, interest was lost. The Swedish Union of Agricultural Workers, which was founded in 1907, wasted its strength in two serious local conflicts and in the general strike of 1909. The trade unions lost nearly all their 1 Zarzad GLOWNY : Sprawozdanie Z dzialalnosci Zwiazki Zawodoweqo Robolnikow Rolnych Rzeczypospolilej Polskiej 1919-1928, p. 65. Warsaw, 1929. — 55 — importance, and collective agreements again ceased to exist. It was not until 1918 that the unions were reorganised and again obtained a considerable membership. The employers' central body was extended and put on a firmer basis in 1920, when it was transformed into the Central Federation of Swedish Agricultural Employers. It has now twelve local sections, with 1,100 members cultivating 160,225 hectares of land. There is also a provincial employers' organisation, which is not affiliated to the Central Federation. Since 1912 the latter has been represented on a joint committee of the General Federation of Employers' Associations and some other employers' organisations not affiliated to it. In the early summer of 1919 the agricultural workers of several districts made proposals to employers on the subject of collective agreements, and, since the employers of Uppland did not seem disposed to negotiate, the workers of that province went on strike. Similar strikes being imminent in other parts of the country, it was considered necessary to nominate a State conciliation board, the authorities only undertaking mediation on the condition that both the parties accepted the principle of the collective regulation of conditions of employment. The workers naturally agreed. The employers followed suit, work was recommenced, and negotiations lasting for three weeks led to the conclusion of a national agreement providing for general rules for the regulation of wages and other conditions of employment, and of local agreements settling wage rates and hours of work in detail. The national agreement was to run for three years, the local agreements — which applied to eight provinces in 1919 — for one year only. However, the workers were not satisfied with the conditions; and in the summer of 1920 fresh local strikes broke out, in some cases in violation of existing agreements. Once more a State conciliation board was set up, and on this occasion local agreements were entered into in nine provinces, estate agreements being concluded in others. While the local agreements of 1919 provided that the hours of work hitherto in force should be maintained and only prescribed that in the summer work should not continue after 6 p.m. on Saturday evenings, those of 1920 fixed the daily hours for the different months of the year1. In the autumn of 1924 attempts to renew the various agreements ended in failure and the Agricultural Workers' Union called strikes in Scania, the Malar Provinces and Ostergotland which lasted until January and February 1925. New agreements were then concluded. On the other hand the workers in Uppland who were organised in a provincial union not affiliated to the National Landworkers' Union, stayed at work despite the expiration of their agreement and did not go on strike until July ; this dispute, affected from 2,500 to 3,000 workers, but only lasted for a short time, and in August a fresh agreement was made. September 1925 saw the conclusion of a new national agreement with three years' validity, and this was subsequently renewed and is still in force. It regulates hours of work, although these vary with the provinces, and wage rates are thus now the only matter regulated by the local agreements. These too have been annually renewed since 1925, so that Swedish agriculture has been under unchanged conditions for the last seven years2. However, the principle of collective bargaining in agriculture, which is a recurring source of dispute in practically every country, has again 1 Sodala Meddelanden, 1919, pp. 638-645, and 1921, pp. 5-8. Stockholm, 1919-1921. 2 In the summer of 1932 both parties denounced the local agreements, claiming modifications of the wage rates. — 56 — been a cause of conflict in Sweden. An attempt on the part of the Swedish Landworkers' Union to introduce a collective agreement into the Södra More district in July 1929 was met with stubborn resistance on the part of the farmers. The workers therefore called a strike, which lasted for nearly two years. The conflict became extremely violent and though it directly affected only a small number of undertakings its peculiar character caused considerable feeling. A special State conciliation board attempted in vain to make a settlement in 1929, and it was not until August 1931 that the strike could be brought to an end. The arrangement made between the workers' union and the farmers affected by the strike provided that all belligerent action was to cease at once ; that the strikebreaking workers were to remain in their employment ; that twelve married strikers were to be reinstated ; that a joint committee was to set about finding work for the other strikers 1 ; and that negotiations concerning arrangements and terms were to be carried out voluntarily by employers and workers. A further clause provided that hours of work, procedure in case of sickness, etc., were to remain as before the strike. The principal object of this arrangement was undoubtedly to end the dispute. Although this agreement does not fulfil the conditions laid down by the legislation on collective bargaining, in respect of the agreements covered by its provisions, the labour tribunal, in a decision given in June 1932, stated that it was impossible to deny that the agreement in question partook, in a certain measure, of the character of a collective agreement. It is in any case an interesting incident in the history of agricultural collective bargaining, and shows how firmly some agricultural employers are convinced that they are bound to oppose that principle. The following table shows the number of strikes and lock-outs which have occurred in Swedish agriculture since the war : Number affected Employers Workers Year Strikes and lock-outs 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 10 14 13 12 400 237 18 15 7,824 4,985 767 671 6 3 6 6 9 8 8 205 170 6 6 37 44 178 3,090 • 3,080 170 92 327 398 726 There are at the moment some ten local agreements connected with the national agreement ; the latter is only valid in conjunction with such local agreements, but the provincial agricultural federations are not formally obliged to conclude collective agreements. If they d so, the agreements must be submitted to the central organisation for examination, 1 The total number of strikers was about eighty. — 57 — and are not valid without its approval. Officials of the central organisation are in practice present at all negotiations, and the requisite uniformity in the contents of the agreements is thus achieved without great difficulty. The independent provincial employers' federation has also used the national agreement as a basis for its arrangements with the workers' union. Some 800 employers and 15,000 workers — i.e. about one-seventh of those engaged on farms with more than 100 hectares of land — are directly affected by collective agreements 1 . Besides the provincial agreements, estate agreements are also conducted with individual employers, in some districts very widely, but collective bargaining is limited to central and southern Sweden, small holdings being the only form of agriculture to be met with in the north 2 . 1 According to data supplied by the Swedish Social Board there are eighty agreements in agriculture and the fishing industry in Sweden, and these concern 934 employers and 16,706 workers. 2 Sodala Meddelanden, 1929, pp. 982-85. Stockholm, 1929. CHAPTER II CONTENTS OF AGRICULTURAL COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS I Scope of the Contents of Agricultural Collective Agreements The aim of agricultural collective agreements is to bring about collective regulation of the conditions of employment of agricultural workers, and since the agreements are the fruit of trade union effort, it may be assumed that the aims envisaged include an actual improvement in conditions. However, the degree to which such regulation can be carried through, and the net result which may be gained thereby, depend on more than one factor. The decisive factors are naturally the strength of the trade unions and the opposition displayed from the employer's side to collective agreements as a whole and to their individual provisions. Further, in Scotland and Pomerania the agricultural unions have to content themselves with a very simple regulation of wage rates and hours of work. Thirdly, the contents of collective agreements depend upon the actual existing organisation of labour in agriculture ; for only on the basis of such existing organisation has it been possible to establish a collective system of regulation. Hence, the contents of collective agreements do not always represent the desires of the agricultural workers. The agreements regulate many practices which the workers look upon as out of date, and consequently demand their abolition or replacement. Among the most important of such practices are those inherent in and indeed peculiar to agricultural work. For instance, most of the agricultural trade unions, although on this point there is not absolute uniformity, aim at abolishing wages in kind wherever — 59 — this is possible. Another example is furnished by the dwelling and the plot of land that the worker receives as part of his wages. By this arrangement he is the tenant and the employer the landlord, and, consequently, any question, involved in a landlord-and-tenant relationship can arise between employer and worker, and indeed assume a special character owing to its close connection with conditions of employment. The aim of the worker is to separate this existing relationship from employment conditions and convert it into a purely landlord-and-tenant relationship. The agricultural unions are also attempting to abolish the "Hofgänger" system and the obligation of the agricultural worker's family to work for the employer. But only gradually and to a certain extent have collective agreements been able to contribute to the transformation of this state of affairs into something more modern. Hitherto, the workers have often been compelled to accept a provisional regulation of questions in collective agreements. The historical background of present conditions in agriculture in various districts will, for a long time to come, be reflected in the contents of agricultural collective agreements, and in general retard wished-for improvements. Finally, the contents of agricultural collective agreements are partly conditioned by the social legislation for agricultural workers. The lack of social legislation for agricultural workers in Poland, more than the strength of the agricultural unions, contributed to the fullness of the contents of Polish collective agreements. The Italian legislation, which makes approval of collective agreements dependent upon acceptance of a whole series of conditions, naturally exercises a great influence on the contents of such agreements. Owing to these circumstances alone, partly legal, partly practical, the contents of the many agreements now in force are extremely diverse. Any attempt to survey the contents of agreements is further made difficult by their diversity of structure. From district to district, even if the districts are adjoining, collective agreements disclose wide differences both as regards general structure and the terms of the individual provisions. Even the two Austrian collective agreements, for Lower Austria and Burgen land respectively, which were drawn up by the same parties on either side, vary widely both in their structure and their contents. — 60 — From the structural point of view, agricultural collective agreements assume countless forms. Some agreements begin with questions with which others end ; some treat a question as an independent matter, others as an exception to a general rule ; others again fix the working conditions of the general body of agricultural workers by means of special rules for certain classes of workers, or even for each class quite separately, so that actually the collective agreement consists of several agreements applying respectively to the various classes of workers. This is the form taken by collective agreements in Italy, Poland, Czechoslovakia, etc. 1 Even the separate questions are very variously dealt with ; regulation of hours of work, for example, generally constitutes a separate Article of the agreement. On the other hand, provisions concerning overtime are frequently contained in the wages agreement. Again, breaks for workers in the employer's household are regulated in still another Article. True, most collective agreements deal with holidays as a separate matter, but, here again, in some of them holidays are an exception to the general rule that only time actually worked is paid for. The same may be said of the way in which the workers' rights in the case of illness are dealt with. Some collective agreements go into great detail and are carefully framed ; but others are too short, so that it is difficult for outsiders to appreciate the exact meaning of the provisions. For instance, the provisions regulating the most important item in a collective agreement, namely wage rates, vary from simple stipulations that the worker shall be boarded and lodged and receive a monthly or yearly wage in cash, to comprehensive provisions concerning hourly rates of pay, piece rates, payment for overtime and Sunday work, extra allowances for special work, regulation of wages in kind including quality, calculation of wages, calculation of journeys to the workplace, method of paying wages, etc. In this respect many agricultural agreements are hardly less complicated than industrial agreements. These variations are explained to some extent in the local origin of collective agreements, which are influenced by local manners and customs, and by the whole organisation of agriculture and its attitude to the collective regulation of 1 In Italy, certain social welfare questions affecting agricultural workers are regulated by special agreements between the employers' and workers' associations. — 61 — working conditions. Here t h e decisive factor is whether the contracting parties desire to frame an agreement as comprehensive as possible or as brief as possible. The local origin of agreements also makes it clear t h a t a question is often settled in quite different ways because it is considered from quite different standpoints. Of t h e m a n y theoretical aspects of a labour problem, here one and there another has been given pre-eminence and so has conditioned the settlement. There are, for example, provisions ensuring compensation for holidays n o t taken, so as n o t to give t h e employer any interest in refusing holidays. B u t there are also provisions ruling out such compensation so as not to make it possible for the worker to derive any financial advantage from his holidays. Working conditions in agriculture and accordingly the contents of collective agreements m u s t necessarily depend upon the stage of economic development attained. This is also true of social legislation. B u t it is the very aim of social legislation to establish certain minimum conditions by freeing working conditions from economic limitations and their a t t e n d a n t fluctuations, and by establishing a fixed basis to the extent t h a t this is possible. The purpose of the present enquiry is to examine to w h a t extent agricultural collective agreements contain provisions which afford the workers protection either in the place of or supplementing statutory protection, and which, in view of their unaltered character from year to year, represent such a degree of independence from economic conditions t h a t they may rightly be considered as a provisional substitute for statutory provisions. Looked a t from this angle, the question of the regulation of wage rates by agricultural collective agreements loses its importance for the purpose in view. S t a t u t o r y regulation of wage rates in agriculture comes into consideration only where there is some doubt as to whether wages are falling or t h r e a t e n to fall below a certain minimum, considered b y society as a whole as essential to the bare existence of agricultural workers. In England the question of a minimum wage in agriculture has been settled by the creation of an official agricultural wages committee in each county. The workers of some other countries are unanimous in thinking t h a t some such regulation is desirable. So far the general body of organised agricultural workers has opposed such a solution, and has taken the view — •62 — that wages should be settled on purely economic lines, through collective agreements 1 . The Draft Convention on the creation of minimum-wage-fixing machinery, adopted by the International Labour Conference at its Eleventh Session in 1928, and the Recommendation concerning the application of this machinery, do not extend to agriculture. Actual conditions have hitherto been such that the question whether collective agreements can provisionally make good any deficiencies in legislation as regards minimum wages in agriculture cannot arise in practice, although continuation of the present depression may completely alter matters. Consequently, for the purposes of this report, it will not be necessary to go into the question of regulation of wages by agricultural collective agreements. The following section will deal with such provisions of collective agreements as fall within the domain of general social legislation, consideration being given to their form, frequency and permanency. In this connection attention will be paid only to such provisions as recur more or less generally in collective agreements. Isolated and special provisions of agricultural agreements will not be mentioned, although they are often not devoid of interest in that they suddenly flash a light, as it were, on a social problem that otherwise would remain unnoticed. Before turning to the individual provisions of agricultural agreements, consideration must be given to another question. The importance of the system of regulation embodied in collective agreements depends not only on their area of application but also on the classes of workers covered. It is naturally outside the task of a trade union to concern itself with the working conditions of unorganised workers2. In practice, however, the beneficiaries of a collective agreement do not always coincide with the organised workers. The employer is usually not in a position to discriminate between organised' and unorganised workers. On the other hand, certain classes of workers be may affiliated to a union without its being possible on this 1 In Italy conditions are somewhat different, because the Charter of Labour states that the adjustment of wages to the normal requirements of life, the possibilities of production and the output of labour shall be ensured by means of trade association action, the conciliation work of corporative organs and the awards of the labour courts. A Decree of 1928 stated that the fixation of minimum wage rates is a compulsory function of collective agreements. 2 In Italy, the occupational organisations represent all workers, both organised and unorganised. — 63 — account to pay regard to their special circumstances in the collective agreement. Estate officials and other salaried employees, who in several States have their own organisations, are usually not covered by the collective agreements here examined ; but apart from this, these agreements mostly group all categories of agricultural workers, though exceptions exist. In Italy, the relations between land proprietors and share farmers and other small tenants are regulated collectively. In Germany separate agreements are often concluded for special classes of workers, such as farm handicraftsmen and milkers. Hence, other agreements exclude these classes. In Poland the collective agreements do not apply to agricultural casual workers. Particularly important is the position of workers in the employer's household. Usually this class is covered by agreements. There are, however, special agreements for agricultural domestic servants. In Czechoslovakia the guiding principles provide that special rules shall be drawn up for domestic servants ; but no agreements on this point have so far been concluded. . With regard to age, too, the scope of collective agreements is sometimes limited. In no case do they cover child work properly so called, but in the German collective agreements there are special wage rates for juvenile workers and these are explicitly included in the scope of the agreement. Only in Sweden are workers under eighteen years of age totally excluded from collective agreements. What is the significance of the fact that some classes of workers are not covered by collective agreements, or, if they are, that their working conditions are incompletely regulated ? It might be expected that such classes would be preferred by employers and, in some countries, this is actually thought to be the case. The Austrian Agricultural Workers' Union claims to have proved that some undertakings employ large numbers of socalled independent day labourers who receive no députât, and whose wages were not originally regulated by collective agreement. The Union later succeeded in incorporating provisions concerning the working conditions of these classes in the agreement. Consequently, the matter would not appear to be of any great practical importance. From certain German districts, it is reported that a similar state of affairs is to be found. Such districts, however, are scattered among others where the practice in question is inexistent. Where the employer — 64 — does follow it, he usually replaces fully qualified workers by juveniles and married workers by domestic servants. It is reported from Schleswig-Holstein that since wages for married workers have increased, juveniles are being substituted for them. It is likewise reported from Poland that the employers are trying to find cheaper labour. This example shows how important it is that collective regulations in agriculture should embrace as many classes as possible of agricultural workers. II Items in the Contents of Agricultural Collective Agreements 1. HOURS OF WORK Economic Importance of the Regulation of Hours of Work Every one of the agricultural collective agreements which come within the scope of this report contains some regulation, simple or detailed, of hours of work. Four States have, in addition, passed legislation on the subject, thus fixing a limit above which independent negotiation may not go. In some cases the collective agreements merely refer to this statutory regulation or incorporate it in their own text, while in others they supplement it by going into greater detail. In general, however, the terms of collective agreements are more favourable to the workers than the statutory regulations. In another of its publications 1 the International Labour Office has made an exhaustive review of the statutory regulation of hours of work in agriculture and also discussed the treatment of the subject in collective agreements ; the principal purpose of the present Chapter is to show what are the different ways in which this regulation can be effected and the relation of provisions on hours to the other parts of agreements. Agricultural workers desire shorter hours and object in particular to an over-long working day. The German agricultural labour movement, for instance, aims at establishing 1 " The Present Regulation of Working Hours in Agriculture ", International Labour Review, Vol. XXV, No. 1, Jan. 1932. p. 79. — 65 — the ten-hour day as a maximum. Where the worker has his own piece of land or livestock to attend to, he is especially interested in shortening the working day, even if this entails lower earnings. But the limitation of hours of work is often merely a question of wages ; when normal hours are exceeded overtime must be paid at higher rates and the worker's earning capacity is thus greater. It is a fact recognised by the workers themselves that many whose usual earnings are small voluntarily offer to do overtime. This reduces the hours of work question to one of wages only. The connection between hours and wages is perhaps most clearly displayed in the working of the British Agricultural Wages (Regulation) Act of 19241. This Act provides for the establishment of an agricultural wages committee in each county or combination of counties in England and Wales to fix minimum rates of wages for workers employed in agriculture : " Any such minimum rates may be fixed by a committee so as to apply universally to all workers employed in agriculture in the county for which the committee act, or to any special class of workers so employed, or to any special area in the county, or to any special class in a special area, . . . and so as to vary according as the employment is for a day, week, month, or other period, or according to the number of working hours, or the conditions of the employment, or so as to provide for a differential rate in the case of overtime. In the exercise of their powers under this subsection, the committee shall,so far as is reasonably practicable, secure a weekly half-holiday for workers." In practice, all the committees have fixed weekly wage rates for male workers and laid down the number of working hours per week on which the rates are based. Any time worked beyond this number must be paid for at overtime rates. Women workers are usually paid by the hour, and it is therefore less necessary in their case to fix normal hours of work. During the period between the first application of this Act and September 1930, wages and other working conditions (the latter in so far as they are indirectly settled by the committees) were comparatively stable and any alterations tended to benefit the workers ; but owing to the steadily increasing gravity of the agricultural depression the committees have latterly had to deal with employers' demands for wage reductions. In most 1 In Legislative Series, 1924, G.B. 5. 5 — 66 — cases the committees, instead of reducing the minimum rates, have merely increased the number of hours to be worked for the weekly wage, and have thus enabled the employers to save on overtime pay. Between October 1930 and September 1931 nine of the forty-eight committees increased the number of working hours and four reduced the minimum wage rate, while one committee both lowered wages and lengthened working time. All agricultural collective agreements proper regulate payment for hours of overtime, but in no case do they limit the number of such hours. The influence of regulation on the actual time worked therefore depends very largely on the amount by which the overtime rate differs from the normal rate of pay. In the earliest collective agreements the supplement for overtime was usually very high, but there has since been a tendency to reduce it. The economic effect of regulating hours appears also in another way. The number of hours per year prescribed in a collective agreement may be taken not only as the maximum which must be worked in exchange for the normal wage, but also as the minimum for which the workers are entitled to remuneration. The difficulties which may here arise will be due to the long contracts customary in agriculture and to the methods of remuneration. A worker engaged for a year puts his labour at the disposal of his employer for that period, and the provisions on the length of the working day decide the number of hours during which he may be called upon to work. If more is required of him, more must be paid. The regulation of hours of work has usually no further significance, since the worker is likely to be employed up to the maximum, first because of the general shortage of agricultural labour, and secondly because there is always work to do on a farm. Indeed, provisions which appeared in the first German collective agreements show that the prescribed hours were regarded by the employers as an absolute minimum, the workers being in many cases obliged to do as many as 200 so-called emergency hours in the year over and above the regulation time. Provisions on emergency work have since totally disappeared from collective agreements, with the result that in some cases the actual time worked has decreased, while in others the emergency hours have been added to and included in the regulation time. — 67 — It now sometimes occurs that the latter is not fully utilised — a well-run farm, for instance, often does not require a ten-hour day in summer ; nine and a half hours suffice. Such reduction is very popular among the workers ; but if in a time of depression the employers incline to economise on labour and, above all in winter, do not make full use of the workers in their employment, the] latter may find themselves in a difficult situation, for their cash wages in winter are in any case on the low side by reason of the shorter regulation hours. Further decrease or the suppression of whole days of work may entail such a reduction in earnings that the workers begin to wonder whether after all they cannot claim full occupation for the number of hours mentioned in their agreements. The question is so new that its legal aspect is not yet clear ; but an attempt has been made in certain German agricultural collective agreements not simply to limit normal hours of work, but also to guarantee a minimum of occupied hours to workers with long contracts. The collective agreement for Kurhessen explicitly provides that the working year is equivalent to 2,800 hours of duty (Pflichtstunden), a term which is so interpreted that the employer is obliged to pay workers engaged by the year for that number of hours. A district agreement in Pomerania obliges employers to provide work during the whole year for workers engaged by the year, and in several parts of the Province of Saxony an eighthour day is prescribed as a minimum. Another Pomeranian district agreement provides that, as far as possible, not less than eight hours shall be worked daily between 1 December and 28 February. The Bavarian covering agreement lays down that the average working time over a period of four months shall not be less than eight hours per day, and that, if for several days together the daily hours of work are to be shorter than those prescribed in the agreement, the workers are to be informed of the fact in sufficient time for hardship to be prevented. One of the district agreements in the Free State of Saxony provides that workers who put the whole of their labour at the disposal of their employer must be given occupation if they require it. Other agreements take the contrary view and state that only the hours actually worked are to be paid for. If an agreement contains no provision on this point, ambiguity arises and the solution will probably have to take account of the method of payment in the district. In northern and eastern Germany — 68 — payment in kind (the députât) is given for the whole year, whatever work is actually done ; in the south and west, where it is incidentally of much smaller importance, it is correspondingly reduced if the working time prescribed in the agreement is not fully occupied. In the opinion of the Federal Union of Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Associations the number of hours prescribed in a collective agreement is as a rule the maximum which may be required by the employer, and can only be regarded as the minimum during which the worker is entitled to occupation if this is explicitly provided for. The collective agreement for Silesia gives 2,856 hours as the annual working time at normal rates, and it is assumed that the employer is not obliged to provide work for all the agreed hours, nor the worker entitled to claim payment for those in which he is not occupied1. This opinion is not shared by the workers, who maintain that in the case of agreements for a year or an unspecified period the worker has the right to payment for the regulation number of hours whether or not he is given work to do. It is of course easy to draft the provisions concerning hours of work in such a way that the question does not arise, but this does not cause the problem to disappear. If agricultural workers are not occupied for a sufficient number of hours, their position becomes economically impossible ; they need not only protection against excessive hours but also a guarantee of permanent occupation, unless agricultural work is to develop into seasonal employment with correspondingly higher remuneration. Ways of Regulating Hours of Work The practical value of the regulation of hours of work in agriculture naturally depends on the way in which this regulation is arranged, and particularly, as far as the workers are concerned, on the distribution of the annual working time over the various seasons of the year. The greater the difference between the length of the working day in summer and in winter, i.e. the more closely the regulation follows natural conditions, the smaller is the advantage obtained from it by the workers ; on the other hand, the closer the working day approaches the 1 FEIGE : Schriftenreihe des betriebswirtschaftlichen Aasschusses beim land- und forstwirtschaftlichen Arbeitgeberverband für die Provinz Schlesien, Vol. 9, p. 44. — 69 — average over the year, the more easily will regulation achieve its object. Provisions on the calculation of working time, the jobs to be done before and after regulation hours, and the extent to which journey time is to be included are also of importance ; and among the most decisive of all is the question of time spent in tending livestock, for on this depends the possibility of regulating hours on peasant and other small farms. With the exception of arrangements for certain categories of workers, which will be discussed later, the regulation of hours of work in agriculture by collective agreement is direct — that is, the number of hours to be worked at the ordinary wage rate is exactly fixed either for the whole year or per day for a specified period ; in the latter case the average or the maximum day may be prescribed. In Czechoslovakia and Italy the statutory eight-hour day applies to agriculture as well as to other industries, and, as far as hours of work are concerned, collective agreements do little more than give effect to this principle with the exceptions allowed. Conditions in these two countries will be discussed separately. Of the other countries with which this report deals, it may be said that collective agreements are the decisive factor in the regulation of hours of work. Austrian and German legislation has very little to say on hours. The Agricultural Labour Codes of Burgenland and Lower Austria merely lay down that working time is to average ten hours per day over the whole year. The German statutory regulations are fuller — section 3 of the Provisional Agricultural Labour Code provides that the maximum daily hours of work shall average eight over four months, and ten over four months, and be eleven for the remaining four months, but it must be remembered that the Provisional Code was originally a collective agreement ; and the daily maximum of eleven hours for four months — not simply an average as during the other periods — is so high that in most cases a collective regulation is more advantageous to the workers. In the winter, working days of less than eight hours may be agreed if occasion demands, though the Committee of the German Agricultural Workers' Union objects to the inclusion of such arrangements in collective agreements, as occurs in some districts, and regards them as contrary to the terms of the Provisional Code. The actual text of the Code hardly lends itself to the objection of the Union, which is prompted by the desire to limit the span between working hours in summer and in winter. It is also frequently stated — 70 — that hours of work in agriculture in Germany are fixed by law at 2,900 in the year. This figure is reached by reckoning twenty-five working days to the month and multiplying by eight, ten and eleven respectively for the three four-month periods prescribed in the Provisional Code. The figure is not to be found in the Code itself, and an exact calculation based on the calendar gives a somewhat larger number of hours ; when, therefore, collective agreements prescribe this figure and refer at the same time to the Provisional Code, as some do, there is ambiguity unless the text of the agreement explicitly states that this number of hours per annum may not be exceeded. Methods of regulating working hours by collective agreement, additional to statutory provisions, are as follows in Austria and Germany. The German agricultural collective agreements are instances of the simplest method of regulating hours of work. A number of agreements merely fix a total of 2,900 hours per annum ; in various agreements for the Marches the figure is 2,800, while others go as low as 2,700. The distribution over the months of the year is left either to local subsidiary agreements (covering agreement for Anhalt and the Province of Saxony, for instance), to estate agreements, or simply to the employer. In such cases the length of the working day is only limited by the maximum of eleven hours laid down in the Provisional Code. Some of the agreements which regulate hours of work by fixing a total for the whole year also provide maxima and minima for the day. The Silesian collective agreement, for instance, provides that 2,856 hours are to be worked annually and that their distribution over the year is to be in the hands of the employers unless district arrangements are made on the subject ; but employers may require a ten and a half hour day only during a period of four months, and this must fall between 15 April and 30 September. The covering agreement for Anhalt and the Province of Saxony fixes the normal annual hours of work for each district on the basis of 300 working days in the year, and leaves it to the district joint labour associations to regulate the distribution over the different months The subsidiary agreement for the district of Jerichow, for instance, lays down that the management of each undertaking may make its own arrangements on the point, provided that not more than'ten nor less than eight hours are worked on any one day. In the Free State of Lippe the distribution of the 2,700 annual hours over the months may be settled by arrangement — 71 — with the workers or their s t a t u t o r y representatives, provided t h a t not less t h a n seven hours per day are worked in the winter nor more t h a n ten in the summer. Other German agreements follow t h e Provisional Code and fix either the absolute or the average length of the working day for periods of a certain duration, b u t without indicating when these periods are to fall. All these agreements divide the year into three periods, each having a working day of a different length. The periods are not bound to coincide with calendar months or weeks, or to be continuous ; the four m o n t h s ' period of ten hours is usually divided into two sections between the eight-hour and eleven-hour periods 1 . Some of these agreements simply refer to the Provisional Code or repeat its terms ; b u t most of t h e m contain a more advantageous regulation for the workers, either by reducing the number of months during which t h e eleven-hour day is to be worked, or even by abolishing it, in which case ten hours becomes the maximum. The following table gives an idea of the various regulations : Hours per year (25 working days per month) Area covered by agreement Baden, Usedom-Wollin in Pomerania Wurtemberg and Bavaria Anhalt Erfurt Brunswick Saale district. Dresden Leipzig Magdeburg Bautzen 2,900 2,875 2,800 2,775 2,750 2,750 2,725 2,725 2,700 2,700 Number of months when hours per day are 11 10 9 8 4 3 — 4 5 5 6 5 4 5 4 6 4 5 3 4 6 3 5 3 4 4 4 2 3 3 2 4 3 3 4 — In all these cases the individual undertaking is allowed considerable freedom in the distribution of t h e annual t o t a l over the different months. Perhaps the agreement for Kurhessen is the best illustration of the consideration given to individual conditions. It provides t h a t the distribution of the 2,800 hours 1 MOLITOR, op. cit., p. 27. — 72 — of duty (Pflichtstunden) should be settled by the employer after consultation with the workers' representatives, for instance on the following lines : ten hours daily from 16 March to 15 November and eight hours daily from 16 November to 15 March ; but adds that such regulations should not be applied rigidly, but should be adapted to the particular nature of the undertaking, the early or late start of the crops, the climate and essential seasonal work. In this way a seven-hour day may be worked for a definite period (not on separate days) in the slack season, and in the busy season, also for a fixed period, a ten-hour day may be extended over more than its normal eight months (speaking in terms of the above example) in compensation, provided always that the grand total of 2,800 hours be not exceeded ; but the shorter time worked during the eight-hour period may only be compensated during that same period, and not during the normal ten-hour period. The regulation is more exact when the agreements themselves determine the number of hours to be worked in each month. Here there are great possibilities of variation. A few agreements provide for only two types of working day, while others — obviously modelled on the Provisional Code — divide the year into three sections, and determine also the number of hours to be worked in each month. Others again contain a still more detailed regulation, which may go so far as to make a difference of four and a half hours between the summer and winter working day — in East Prussia, for instance, an eleven-hour day is worked in summer and a six and a half hour day in December and January — so or as to provide for twelve or fourteen changes of daily hours during the year. The changes usually take place at the beginning or in the middle of a month, but also occur at other dates, and are commonest in the spring and autumn, when hours of work do not remain the same for more than a fortnight together. It is impossible to make an exhaustive survey of the stipulations of this sort, and the following table merely gives some examples of the simplest and of the most complicated of them : — 73 — District covered (hours per day) Period East Prussia SchleswigHolstein Borde Kurhessen Hours per day 1 - 15 16 - 31 1-15 16 - 28 1 - 15 16 - 31 April January January February February March March 7 7 8 8% 9% 10 io y2 May ii June July August 1 - 15 September 16 - 30 September 1 - 1 5 October 16 - 31 October 1 - 1 5 November 16 - 30 November December ii . ii ii io y2 10 10 9 8 8 6% 7 7% 8i/, 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 sy2 8% 7 8 8 8 8 9 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 9 9 8 8 8 8 8 8 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 8 8 In many cases the agreement permits the use of a different method of distributing the annual hours than that which it prescribes, if employers and workers agree on the subject and provided that the contractual number of hours per year is not exceeded. Sometimes a limit is set to such rearrangement ; in one district in Pomerania the employer may, with the consent of the workers' statutory representatives, shorten working hours by half-an-hour daily, but the hours thus carried over may not be worked off on Saturdays nor between 1 April and 31 August. In another district hours of work during December, January, and February should, as far as possible, be not less that eight per day. In many cases it is arranged that the workers may be employed in one spell during the winter months if the employer so instructs, and the result is often a slight shortening of hours for the workers. In most of the German agreements it is left to the employer to determine the daily time-table though in many cases he must consult the workers on the subject ; but some contain provisions concerning the length of the rest periods, and these indirectly determine the limits within which work may be performed. — 74 — A glance at the geographical distribution of the various methods of regulating hours of work in German agriculture so far described, shows that all over southern Germany — in Baden, Wurtemberg, Bavaria and the Bhine country — and in Hanover and nearly every district of the Free State of Saxony the system defined in the Provisional Code is prevalent ; in other parts of central Germany, too, the year is divided into three. sections, though here the number of hours to be worked in the different months is often given. Scattered over the centre and in part of the east are to be found agreements which simply prescribe the number of hours to be worked per annum and leave the distribution to estate agreements or to the employers alone. Agreements providing for working days of more than three different lengths occur only in East Prussia, Pomerania, Brandenburg, Silesia, Mecklenburg-Schwerin and SchleswigHolstein. The largest number of hours per annum is worked in the south and north of Germany, that is, in the markedly peasant districts with difficult soil conditions, great fragmentation and resulting unsatisfactory distribution of cultivations ; and in the east with its large and less intensively cultivated estates. The shortest hours occur in the Rhenish wine country, where one agreement, for instance, provides for an eight-hour day, and in the intensively cultivated estates of the centre. An eleven-hour day is the normal only in south Germany and in East Prussia, Pomerania and Brandenburg. In the last two provinces eleven hours are even worked for more than four months in the year ; this is made possible by the fact that the Provisional Code prescribes only an average for the two periods of eight and ten hours respectively and not a maximum as for the eleven-hour period. For the rest of Germany the maximum day is ten hours, except in two central German districts where it is as Iowas nine and a half hours. The workers'organisations report that the agreed ten-hour day is not fully exploited on many of the large estates in the centre and that only nine and a half hours are required. The hours worked vary remarkably from district to district. In Pomerania, one district may work 2,950 hours per annum and another, bordering on it, only 2,850. In Brandenburg the figure varies between 2,825 and 2,912, and in the Province of Saxony between 2,750 and 2,848. This is all the more extraordinary in that a uniform system for large areas, such as is — 75 — to be found in other collective agreements, seems perfectly practicable ; the same hours are, for instance, worked over all Bavaria and over all Mecklenburg-Schwerin. In the Austrian States of Lower Austria and Burgenland, too, the agreements specify the exact distribution of hours of work over the various seasons of the year, the length of the working day changing three and four times respectively. The following table shows the distribution in these two States : Daily working hours January - February . . . March - April - May - June July - August - September October November December jower Austria Burgenland 8 10 10 10 9 8 8 10 11 10 9 8 The Burgenland Code is somewhat harder on the workers, who have an eleven-hour day for three months of the year. In Lower Austria, too, the workers are obliged, at the request of the employer, to work an eleven-hour day from 15 July to 31 August without special remuneration, but in this case they receive compensation in the shape of a corresponding shortening in the winter. In Austrian agriculture wages are paid by the day ; in both the States mentioned work stops at 12 noon on Saturdays during two months of the winter without reduction of wages. This arrangement brings the number of hours per year down to 2,816 in Lower Austria and 2,875 in Burgenland — figures well below those prescribed in the respective Agricultural Labour Codes. In the other countries which come within the scope of this report the system is that of exact distribution of hours over the seasons of the year and frequent change in the length of the working day. This is natural inDenmark and Sweden, whose northerly position makes the day very long in summer and short in winter and compresses agricultural processes into a comparatively short period. This last circumstance is also of importance in Poland with its markedly continental climate, and the fact that the north and east are the only parts of Germany where such — 76 — detailed distribution is to be found is accounted for by similar reasons. In Sweden, the covering agreement for the whole country regulates the hours of work in various provinces as shown in the following table : Scania Province of Kalmar V ârmland. Uppland province and of Örebro, Province province Ö stergo tof of land, Vastman- Söderman- Elvsborg land land Hours per day January 1 - 15 February 1 6 - 2 8 February 1 - 1 5 March 16 - 31 March 1 - 15 April 1 6 - 3 0 April May June July August September 1 - 15 October 16 - 31 October 1 - 15 November 16 - 30 November December . 8 8 8 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 9 9 8 Total hours per year 1 2,700 8 8 8% 9 9% 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9% 9 8% 8 2,700 8 sy 2 8% 9 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 8 8 7% 2,650 8 8% 8% 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 8 8 'V, 2,650 8 8 8 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 8% 8% 7 2,650 After deduction of days of rest laid down in the agreements. Individual employers are entitled to arrange with their workers for a further hour per day during two months or halfan-hour during four months, but not during the months when the ten-hour day is already in operation. In this way the annual total may be increased by fifty hours, which must be paid for at special rates fixed in local agreements. The employer is entitled to fix the daily time-table, as a rule on condition that the actual agricultural work does not normally begin before 7 a.m. or end after 7 p.m. (6 p.m. on Saturdays). — 11 — In Denmark, hours of work are uniformly regulated as follows: Date _ . 1 January - 28 February 1-15 March 16 - 31 March 1 April - 31 October 1 - 15 November 16 - 30 November . 01 _, 1 - 31 December Hours no . . . . Between o f 7.30 a.m. and 4.30 p.m. 8 > o r g 0Q a m a n d & Q0 p m 9 6.30 a.m. and 5.00 p.m. 9% 6.30 a.m. and 5.30 p.m. 10 6.00 a.m. and 6.00 p.m. 9 6.30 a.m. and 5.30 p.m. 8y2 6.30 a.m. and 5.00 p.m. f 7.30 a.m. and 4.30 p.m. Q 8 Qp g 0 0 a m a n d 5 Q0 p m The remarkable feature of this scheme is that it exactly determines the hours at which work is to begin and end. Local arrangements may be made to settle at what time breaks shall be taken, but in no case prolong working hours. The midday break lasts for at least one hour. During harvest the employer is entitled to shift working hours so that they fall between 8 a.m. and 8 p.m., but only in order to carry out harvest operations in the best possible way. This shifting of hours can therefore take place only on days when either reaping or bringing in crops is on hand, and only for a maximum of five weeks ; if the harvest is finished before the expiration of the five weeks, the rearrangement of hours must cease. Workers must as far as possible be warned a day in advance. On days when such rearrangement of hours is prevented, for example owing to rain, work stops at the usual hour of 7 p.m. In sugar beet districts working time can — from 15 November to 1 December — be prolonged by half-an-hour, on condition that a corresponding shortening of hours takes place in the first half of January. In Poland, the regulation of hours of work in the central provinces serves as a model for other parts of the country. It is very exactly worked out and determines the time at which work shall begin and end and the length of breaks. The annual working hours amount to 2,800, i.e. a daily average of nine hours twenty minutes over the year. The difference between hours of work in summer and winter is very great, at one point as much as six and a half hours, the longest working day in summer being almost twice as long as the shortest in winter. The length of the working day changes three times in the month. — 78 — Working day Working DD Midday Working hours AfiereooD hours in Morn' break break in the afternoon Break the morning Period Hours 6% 8 9% 10 11 1 /* IIV3 liVt 10% 10% 82/3 7 8 /4 614 a.m. January February March I 1-10 11-20 ! 21-31 April I 1-10 11-20 ' 21-20 May ( 1-10 11-20 ( 21-31 June 8-12 7.30-12 Hours — Hours iy 2 1% ) ) % 1% ( 1.30-6.40 ) ] 1.30-7.00 [ ' 1.30-7.20 1 % 6-12 % 1% ( 1.30-7.30 J I 1.30-7.50 [ ' 1.30-8.00 ) 6-12 % 2 ( 2.00-8.20 / j 2.00-8.20 [ ( 2.00-8.30 ) % 6-12 % 2 ( 2.00-8.30 J | 2.00-8.30 [ ! 2.00-8.00 I y2 6-12 % 2 ( 2.00-7.50 ) I 2.00-7.30 | ' 2.00-7.00 1 y2 6-12 y2 1% I 1.30-6.40 ) j 1.30-6.20 [ ' 1.30-6.00 ! — 7-12 — 1% 7.30-12 8-12 — — lX/2 ) ) j 11-20 [ ! 21-30 1 July I 1-10 ) 11-20 ' 21-31 ! August I 1-10 Ì 11-20 ! 21-31 1 September I 1-10 ) 11-20 ( 21-30 ) October t 1-10 Ì j 11-20 ' 21-31 > November December 1.30-4.00 1.30-5.00 I 1.30-5.30 ] j 1.30-6.00 | ( 1.30-6.30 ) / 7-12 Hours 1% ) 7-12 p.m. 1% Í 1.30-5.30 ) | 1.30-5.20 [ ' 1.30-4.50 ) 1.30-4.50 1.30-3.45 — — — On the whole the various stipulations on hours of work to be found in agricultural collective agreements are respected, although the smaller the undertaking is and the more the owner shares in the work, the more frequently do departures from the rules occur. Conformity with stipulated hours is naturally less exact in agriculture than in industry ; and it is equally natural that compliance with such a detailed regulation as the Polish leaves something to be desired, for agricultural workers — 79 — in Poland are in a less favourable position than those in the other countries where there are collective agreements, and their organisations are weak in comparison with the number of workers they represent. The somewhat unsatisfactory observance of the agreements on hours of work in Poland has been explained as follows. It is much more difficult to check what hours are worked in agriculture than in industry, because a large proportion of the workers are scattered over the fields, often far apart, and because the variations in the length of the working day make the agricultural worker less conscious of his rights. Noncompliance with the contractual time-table is most common in summer ; being accustomed to start workat 5 a.m., the workers tend to ignore the fact that the agreements prescribe 6 a.m. in order to shorten working time ; habit is strong, and when the employer calls on them to start at 5 a.m. in summer they often do not like to stand on their rights and refuse. The breaks and knocking-off hours are on the whole respected. The time-table is usually so arranged that the latter hour coincides with sunset and the worker is thus practically never obliged to work overtime. Methods of Calculation; Journey Time In order to form an opinion on the value of agricultural collective agreements in the regulation of hours of work it is most important to know how working time is calculated and when and where work begins and ends. All collective agreements assume that certain preparatory work, in particular the tending of draught animals, e.g. their feeding, is excluded from regular hours ; but it is rare for such work to be exactly defined. Duties of this sort count neither as normal working time nor as overtime, and are often unpaid. Most of the German agricultural collective agreements repeat the terms of the Provisional Code to the effect that the time spent in looking after draught animals, e.g. feeding them, is not to count as regular working time. In Denmark, male farm servants are obliged to do halfan-hour's stable work before the regulation working time begins, without extra remuneration ; if this work is done by workers of other categories, special payment is given. In Sweden, the workers are bound to attend to not more than three horses or oxen and clean their stables before working hours. If this work does not take up the time provided for it in the agreement, the time saved can only be used for other work at special rates. — 80 — In Lower Austria, the collective agreements provide that a driver's working time begins with the harnessing of the horses. The calculation of journey time is of great importance in agriculture. In districts with large estates, or where the land is highly subdivided and the fields of a farm are widely scattered, the time spent going to and from work is often considerable. The various journeys may be grouped as follows : (1) between the farm and the place of work (a further distinction must be made here between the morning and evening journeys on the one hand and those at midday on the other) ; (2) between the worker's dwelling and the farm (with a further distinction according as the worker lives in his own dwelling or in one supplied by the employer). Despite the complicated nature of the question, the collective agreements which regulate it at all usually do so in a very simple manner. In Poland, the time required by the worker to cover the distance between his dwelling and his place of work is included in working time. In Denmark, workers may not knock off until the end of the normal working time, even if employed in the fields, though drivers are permitted to begin the journey back to the farm in time to have finished not less than twenty minutes after the close of the normal working time. In the Italian Province of Matera, the collective agreement states that work starts and ends on the field only. When the distance from the dwelling of the worker exceeds 4 kilometres and conveyance is not furnished, every additional kilometre is counted within the working hours. The time allowed for each kilometre is fifteen minutes. Other agreements confine themselves to considering as actual hours of work only the time required to go from one field to another, or include the time taken by a worker to lead draft animals in his charge from the stable to the fields and back again. In Lower Austria, working time begins and ends at the farm ; the Agricultural Labour Code provides that the time spent on the way from the worker's dwelling to his work is not to be counted as working time if less than one hour ; any time spent over one hour is to be so counted or specially paid for. Ini?ur#en/and,thecollectiveagreementcontainsthesame provision, but adds that at noon the time spent going from and back to work is included in the midday break ; if more than half-an-houris needed, the employer is bound to have the worker's — 81 — midday meal sent out to him, and if this cannot be done, the journey is counted as working time. If the midday break is spent at the place of work, the employer may require it to be shortened by an hour. In Germany the Provisional Agricultural Labour Code prescribes that the journey time between the farm and the place of work is to be included in working time. This regulation is repeated in all collective agreements for the country east of the Elbe and in the district agreements for the Province of Saxony and for the whole of south Germany. The East Prussian collective agreement adds that working time ends at the farm if the latter is not more than 1 kilometre from the worker's dwelling. The State covering agreement for Bavaria formerly prescribed that in the case of fields situated at a great distance from the farm only one hour of the time spent on the way might be deducted from working time ; the remainder was to be worked off later and paid at the ordinary hourly rates. This provision now appears only in the Upper Bavarian district agreement, and the State agreement merely repeats the Provisional Code on the point. In central Germany, where working hours in agriculture are shorter than in other parts, schemes different from that of the Code are in many cases in operation. Instead of the farm buildings, another place is often appointed as rendezvous, and working time usually ends at the workplace unless it lies more than 2 kilometres — in some cases 2% or 1% kilometres — from the farm ; time spent on journeys in excess of these distances is either counted as working time or specially paid for. These arrangements are against the letter of the Provisional Code, but it should not be forgotten that the worker whom his duties do not compel to return to the farm after knocking off may well find it nearer to go straight home ; as long as working time is not more than that laid down by the Provisional Code, such a method of calculation is permissible. Some collective agreements determine how long certain distances should take, the large estates in the east giving fifteen minutes per kilometre, while in central Germany only twelve minutes are allowed. Other German collective agreements provide that journey time at noon is to be counted in working time, and that if the midday meal must be taken in the fields, the worker is entitled to have it sent out to him or, alternatively, to a cash compensation. The Schleswig-Holstein collective agreement contains the fullest regulation of journey time. It provides that working 6 — 82 — time shall begin at the appointed hour at the farm and end at the place of work, whatever the distance from the worker's dwelling to the farm may be. If the worker's dwelling is further from the farm than from the morning workplace, the employer may arrange that working time shall begin at the workplace, provided that warning is given a day in advance ; and if the evening workplace is further from the farm than from the worker's dwelling, the worker may go straight home if he has no further occupation at the farm (bringing back team, harness, etc.). If the workplace is more than 2 kilometres from the farm, time spent in the evening in covering the excess is deducted from working time. The distance from the farm of any fields to which this stipulation may apply should be determined as soon as possible, and 12 minutes per kilometre be allowed. The daily time-table, including breaks, is settled by the employer, after discussion with the workers' representatives, if any exist. The time spent in covering distances up to 2 kilometres at breaks, particularly the midday break, is not counted as working time ; the following provisions regulate the point in greater detail : (a) the time spent going to and from the farm at noon by men working with horses does not count as part of the midday break ; (b) other workers are obliged to remain at the place of work until the beginning of the midday break and to be back by the time the break ends ; (c) individual undertakings are free to settle any difficulties which may arise out of the above by agreeing on a new stipulation on the subject, provided that the contractual number of hours per annum is not affected and that no arrangement made before conclusion of the agreement is amended to the workers' disadvantage. The exactitude with which hours of work are often regulated is sometimes reflected in special arrangements concerning methods of payment, which occasionally allow the workers to knock off earlier on pay day. Special Regulations for Certain Types of Undertakings and Certain Categories of Workers A few German collective agreements regulate hours of work on peasant farms separately. According to the SchleswigHolstein agreement, the hours of work on peasant farms of less than 100 hectares may if necessary be prolonged for half-an-hour — 83 — daily ; while a district agreement in Brandenburg provides that on farms where most of the workers Uveas members of the farmer's household — that is to say, peasant farms — the regulation contained in the agreement does not apply and the time-table may be settled by the employer according to need ; even on these farms, however, it is not allowable to exceed the total number of hours fixed for the year. The Silesian collective agreement provides that on peasant farms the hours of the workers living in depend on the working day of the stockmen, which may not normally exceed the regulation time of other (day) workers by more than three and a half hours daily. It may be taken as a general rule that the hours of work of persons living as members of the farmers household cannot be exactly defined, for their work usually includes looking after livestock and various preparatory and accessory duties outside the normal hours, and work on Sundays and public holidays ; a special regulation of the hours of work of this category of workers is therefore rare. The Bavarian system is particularly interesting, for the State covering agreement provides that the district agreements shall fix for farm servants a nightly rest of a certain length, which amounts to an indirect limitation of working time ; the district agreements lay down that the hours of these workers depend on the season and on the pressure of work ; that they should as a rule have eight hours' rest at night for eight months of the year and ten hours for the other four months ; and that the four months must lie between either 1 November and 1 March or 15 November and 15 March. Several district agreements provide that, if economic conditions and the weather make it necessary, the nightly rest may be shortened to seven hours between 15 May and 15 September ; in some cases the employer may make such a regulation unilaterally, in others he must arrange with the farm servants or the workers' representative. This indirect method avoids the necessity of calculating hours. In fact, the collective agreement explicitly states that there can be no question of special rates for overtime in the case of farm servants and that regulations concerning journey time do not apply to them. On the other hand, there are often special regulations for stockmen, their most noticeable point being the attempt to limit the amount of work per worker rather than the number of working hours. When this amount is exceeded, the employer is obliged to increase his staff. — 84 — In Denmark, stockmen's hours of work are regulated as follows. They are not entitled to overtime pay as long as their hours do not exceed sixty-six and a half in the week or ten in the day. Each stockman must milk up to eighteen cows twice daily, provided that the maximum week mentioned is not thereby exceeded. In Austria, horsemen and cowmen must attend to and feed the animals and milk the cattle within the time needed for the purpose, but if the milking staff is required to fetch the fodder from the fields, they are entitled to extra pay. Both in Lower Austria and in Burgenland the agreements assume that a man can attend to fourteen cows and a woman to eleven. In Sweden, working hours for stockmen are those necessary in order reasonably to tend and look after the animals ; but hours must not as a rule exceed ten per day. For milkmaids the hours are those necessary for milking work, but where milking machines are not used women cannot be obliged to milk more than 150 litres of milk per day in three milkings. In Germany, hours of work for milkers are widely settled by the special collective agreements concluded by the independent organisations of skilled milkers. These agreements are in some cases attached to those for ordinary agricultural workers in the same area, in others independent ; they fix the milkers' hours by defining the amount of work and many explicitly state that the working time cannot be subject to limitation. Twenty head of milch cows or young cattle is the usual number taken in the case of grass-farming and in breeding-sheds, while in mixed sheds the number is twenty-seven and in milking-sheds twenty-five. Breeding-sheds are those in which at least onethird of the cattle are not full-grown, mixed sheds those in which there are a few cows and where a number of calves are brought up, or where a number of store cattle are kept, and milking-sheds those in which there are no young cattle. Agricultural Collective Agreements and the Statutory Eight-Hour Day In Czechoslovakia, the Eight-Hour Day Act was promulgated on 19 December 1918 ; with certain necessary exceptions it applies to agriculture as well as to other industries. A Decree of 11 January 1919 authorised the distribution of working hours in agriculture in a different way provided that they do not exceed 192 in four weeks ; but this does not provide for seasonal varia- — 85 — tions proper. Further, when extra work is necessary owing to force majeure or to accidents or in the public interest, hours of work may be increased during not more than four weeks of the year by not more than two hours a day ; under this provision permits are issued to agricultural undertakings by the communal authorities. Overtime, which must be specially remunerated, may be allowed for a further sixteen weeks in the year, but permits from a higher authority are required, except in the case of particularly urgent work or of subsidiary work in the household, such as the feeding of stock. A Circular of the Ministry of Social Welfare to the administrative authorities dated 21 March 1919 instructed them, when examining demands for permits for extension of working hours, to pay special attention to this point in agriculture and mining. Although the eighthour day applies only to persons employed regularly in agriculture who live outside the employer's household and receive daily or weekly wages, the working time of other workers is also regulated under the Act, which states that persons employed in the household of the employer and living there and engaged for more than one month shall be allowed a twelve-hour period of rest in every twenty-four hours, eight of which shall be uninterrupted night's rest ; the same applies to persons engaged in irregular services that involve little exertion, such as the supervision and watching of premises and undertakings and looking after animals. The Circular interprets the first group to comprise among others resident farm servants and farm hands paid partly in kind (députât workers), and the second group night watchmen and special watchmen in stables. Large numbers of agricultural workers may therefore be called upon to work a twelve-hour rather than an eight-hour day. No stipulations are laid down as to the working day of day labourers engaged for less than one week. Practical life has considerably modified the working of the Act in agriculture. It was the principle of the Act that, where an aggregate of 192 hours was allowed to be spread over four weeks, the number of hours exceeding forty-eight in one week should be compensated by corresponding rest periods in the following three weeks ; but both employers and workers agreed that such an arrangement was not possible in agriculture. The employers argued that work must be dependent on weather conditions, while the workers had no interest in obligatory rests during the summer ; they depended for their living almost entirely on their — 86 — summer earnings and wanted these to be as large as possible. A public enquiry undertaken in December 1920 proved that by that date the compensatory rest period had already been abandoned in agricultural practice. The same was the case with the demand for advance permits to work overtime. Here also the conditions which make overtime necessary cannot be foreseen early enough to allow for previous authorisation. The negotiations undertaken by the Provincial Auxiliary Councils for Agricultural Labour Questions, with the object of • establishing guiding principles for agricultural employment, have provided the required additions for applying the eight-hour day principle to agriculture. The hours of work of both day labourers and députât workers are dealt with. For day labourers there is a tendency to lengthen the working day, for it is laid down that the ninth and tenth hours, although overtime in the eyes of the law, are to be paid at the same rate as the first eight hours ; only the eleventh and following hours are to be paid at a higher rate. At the time when the EightHour Day Act was passed wages in agriculture were paid by the day, the length of which was undefined. The Act introduced the notion of overtime and secured to the workers that extra payment should be given for it, but there was no specific provision in the Act that this payment for overtime should necessarily be at a rate higher than that for ordinary work. Consequently, when the method of payment was altered throughout from a daily to an hourly rate, there was nothing in the text of the Act to make it necessary to pay higher overtime rates. These were introduced only by the collective agreements. For députât workers the guiding principles have tended to reduce the working day. For those employed as drivers the number of hours in the twelve-hour day to be spent on driving proper, counted from the departure from the farm, are : Hours . Hours January - February . . . 8 October 9 March - May 9 November - December . 8 June - September . . . . 10 If necessary these hours may be otherwise distributed for individual districts or estates, or a nine-hour average day may be agreed upon for the year. The remainder of the twelve hours is to be spent in auxiliary work (cleaning, feeding, putting the horses to, attending to harness, etc.). In the busy season in the fields or when the horses are required on long trips the — 87 — députât driver is required to work the extra hours fixed during such periods and is paid the normal wage of his category for every hour of such work. In the same way the stable staff are entitled to pay if required to work for more than twelve hours. In Italy, hours of work in all industries are regulated by a Legislative Decree of 15 March 1923, which lays down that the normal maximum daily hours of all workers shall not exceed eight a day or forty-eight a week. The Decree does not apply to persons engaged in domestic work. Regulations for its application to agriculture were issued on 10 September 1923. The Decree applies only to day labourers in agriculture, leaving other categories to be dealt with by Regulation. The Regulations state that the Decree shall apply to share producers employed as casual and permanent workers on agricultural work exclusive of work executed by them under a share-produce contract ; persons in large and medium-sized undertakings who have charge of the technical and administrative direction of undertakings and who only occasionally take part in manual work are excluded. At all periods of the year, if bad weather conditions prevent the full utilisation of the hours planned, the employer may, where workers are paid by the day, make up the time lost by increasing the hours of work in the course of the week up to a maximum of ten, without paying any extra wage. The Decree also states that the eight-hour day or the forty-eight hour week may be exceeded on account of technical or seasonal requirements during a specified period, provided that the average duration of work during that period does not exceed the limits fixed by Royal Decree or by an agreement concluded between the parties concerned. In the case of agriculture the specified period may not exceed three months in the year. Except where agreements to the contrary have been concluded between the parties, the hours of work may not exceed ten in the day or sixty in the week during this period. In addition, overtime may be added to the normal working time of eight hours a day or forty-eight a week, but must not exceed two hours a day nor twelve a week ; it must be agreed upon by the parties, and must be paid at a rate 10 per cent. above that for ordinary work. Working hours do not include breaks ; time spent in going to and from the fields or workplace and in resetting scythes is reckoned in accordance with local — 88 — custom in default of any agreement to the contrary. Further, agreed exceptions may be permitted for preparatory and accessory work which must be performed outside the normal hours. Finally, work may be prolonged beyond the limits laid down in the Regulations in case of force majeure or when cessation of work at the normal hour would entail risk and damage to human beings or to production. It will be seen that the Italian legislation itself opens wide possibilities for extending working time in agriculture beyond eight hours in the day or forty-eight in the week, and gives the organisations of employers and workers power to act in the same direction by means of agreements. Moreover, a Decree of 30 June 1926 provides that until further notice, and in spite of anything specified to the contrary in the Legislative Decree of 15 March 1923, all industrial, commercial and agricultural undertakings are authorised to increase their daily hours of work by one hour. A Decree of 11 January 1927 states that this extension to a nine-hour day is permissible only by agreement between the competent organisations of employers and workers and subject to the approval of the competent public authorities. The ninth hour must be paid for at a rate 10 per cent, above that for normal hours. The collective agreements are usually content to distribute working time over the year within the limits laid down by the Act, i.e. so as to obtain an annual average of eight hours a day, and to define the months in which the different maxima apply. In some cases, however, shorter hours are agreed on. The following table gives examples of the various systems : Area covered by the agreement Region Piedmont Lombardy Liguria Emilia Latium Apulia Calabria Sicily Sardinia Province Novara Mantua Spezia Parma Piacenza Viterbo Brindisi Catanzaro Trapani Nuoro Number of months in which maximum hours per day are : 6 6y2 2 7 8 9 10 4 2 8 8 12 4 6 5 1 1 2 3 2 1 3 2 3 1 2 1 1 4 2 1 3 2 • 7 7 6 5 3 3 3 — 89 — 2. HOLIDAYS Almost all agricultural collective agreements make provision for annual holidays, a fact to which attention may be drawn. The prevalence of the long contract, on which a claim for holidays may be based, is undoubtedly responsible for their definite introduction into agriculture. Holidays are frequently used not so much for rest as for personal business, which takes up more time in the country than in the towns because of the greater distances. The collective agreement for the district of Hildesheim is typical ; it provides that all days granted off for other purposes — slaughtering of animals, carriage of wood, visits to the annual market, etc. — shall be deducted from the annual holiday. In the same way, Polish agricultural workers are reported to use their holiday for personal business or for shopping. The Danish agricultural collective agreements are the only agreements which make no provision whatever for annual holidays. This is all the more remarkable in that the Act concerning the legal relations between master and servant lays down that a servant living in, who was engaged or who has been employed for a half-year shall be entitled to leave on 3 working days, and a servant who was engaged or who has been employed for a whole year shall be entitled to leave on 6 working days, during the term of service. Agricultural workers living in their own homes do not, however, benefit by this provision, nor have collective agreements yet succeeded in securing annual holidays for them. It may be remarked in this connection that even in Danish industry, where the workers are in other respects so well-situated, the question of holidays is still unsettled, and the position in this respect is less advanced than in other countries. Many of the Netherlands collective agreements contain stipulations on annual holidays. The Italian Labour Charter states that workers are entitled to holidays with pay after one year's employment, and the length of such holidays is regulated in many of the agricultural collective agreements. In the other countries with which this report deals the agreements, as a rule, make some such provision, the only exceptions being certain districts in Pomerania and Brandenburg. Naturally, only those workers who have been in the service of the same employer for a considerable period are entitled to — 90 — holidays. This period is usually one year, but in the Rheingau and Wurtemberg it is two years. In Sweden and Poland only workers engaged by the year, and in Austria and Germany only permanent workers who have been employed in the same undertaking for at least a year, are entitled to holidays. In Czechoslovakia, the députât workers who have been in the service of the same employer for at least a year without interruption are allowed holidays. It is not always necessary for the workers to have been fully occupied during this period. In some of the wage agreements in the Free State of Saxony 200 days' work during the year, and in one only 150 days' work, suffices. In Thuringia, no distinction is made between permanent and non-permanent workers, all those who have worked for a certain number of hours — in the case of men 2,600, in the case of women 2,000 — in the undertaking during the year being entitled to holidays. Permanent women workers — those who are regularly at the employer's disposal — have always the right to a proportionate holiday. In some German collective agreements certain categories of workers are excluded from the right to holidays, although permanently employed. Examples are farm servants in Bavaria and in Silesia men and women day workers and women députât workers not contractually bound to a six-day week. In East Prussia, the holidays for ' ' Hofgänger ' ' (additional labour employed on sub-contracts by permanent workers) and farm servants are shorter than for députât workers. In many cases the length of the holiday depends on the age of the worker. In the district of Hildesheim, workers of under 21 years of age are not entitled to any holiday ; in those of Magdeburg, Halle and Erfurt, workers from 16 to 20 years of age are entitled to 3 days', from 21 to 23 to 4 days', from 24 to 25 to 5 days', and from 26 onwards to 6 days' holiday. In Kurhessen, workers under 18 are entitled to 3 days' holiday, and those over that age to 6 days. In general, the length of the annual holiday varies with length of service, and differs largely from country to country. Holidays are apparently shortest in Italy and Germany. In the province of Piacenza, they are fixed at 2 days, in Mantua and Parma at 3 days, in Brindisi at 4 days and in Spezia at 6 days. In Bavaria, the workers are entitled to 2 days' holiday, in Silesia to 3 days', and in East Prussia to 5 days' (" Hofgänger " and farm servants to 3 only). In the other German collective agreements the length of the holiday increases annually, usually by — 91 — 1 day, but in Pomerania by 2 days, to a maximum varying between 6 and 9 days. In Sweden, workers employed by the year are entitled to 7 working days' holiday. In Czechoslovakia députât workers have the right to 6 days', after ten years' service to 7, and after 15 years' service to 8 days' holiday. In the last-named country religious festivals falling on weekdays and taken as free time are deducted from the annual holiday,, three such festivals counting only as two full days for this purpose if the worker feeds his own team. In Poland, the regulation of holidays in the different collective agreements varies ; in three localities 8 days are allowed, in twelve 9, and in four 10. The holidays of agricultural workers in Austria are relatively long. The Lower Austrian Code provides for a holiday of 8 days after an uninterrupted employment of one year in the same undertaking, and according to the Burgenland Code the holiday amounts to up to two weeks according to the period of service with the same employer. The collective agreements in these two States provide for still longer holidays. In Lower Austria, the agreement states that workers are entitled to 10 days' holiday after one year's service, and to 14 days after three years, in both cases exclusive of religious festivals, while that for Burgenland allows a holiday of 7 consecutive days to workers who have been in the service of the same employer for a year without a break, the number of days increasing to 14 after five years, to 18 after ten years and to 21 after fifteen years' service. The date at which holidays are taken is fixed by mutual agreement, and must as a rule fall in the slack season. In Czechoslovakia, holidays, apart from religious festivals, may only be taken in the winter. In Sweden, holidays must be divided into two instalments and may not be taken during the sowing or harvest season. As a rule workers are entitled to remuneration during holidays, payment for 8 or 9 hours being allowed in case of hourly wage rates. In parts of Germany where payment in kind is given only for work actually performed, it is in certain cases provided that such payment is to be made for the period of the holiday. In some Brandenburg and Pomeranian districts no cash wages are paid during holidays. In order to ensure that the holidays are actually used for rest or private affairs, it is provided in some agreements that work for other employers — 92 — is not permitted during holidays, or that, if such work is done, wages for the period of the holiday are forfeited. It is occasionally provided that no special compensation is payable for unclaimed holiday rights, so that workers shall not be tempted to prefer an economic gain to a rest. On the other hand, it is in some cases stated that compensation must be paid if holidays are not taken, the object here being to deprive the employer of any interest in refusing to allow his workers their full right to holidays. 3. HOUSING The provision made in collective agreements for the housing of agricultural workers naturally concerns service dwellings only — that is, dwellings provided by the employer as part of the worker's wages. As has been mentioned, the result of such arrangements is that employer and worker stand, one towards the other, in a relation resembling that of landlord and tenant. Besides settling the legal position which thus arises, collective agreements also lay down minimum requirements to be fulfilled by the employer in respect of such dwellings. These usually concern the size of the accommodation, and only in exceptional cases its quality. It is noteworthy that some agreements require a higher standard for buildings about to be erected than for dwellings already in existence. Stipulations concerning agricultural workers' dwellings are but rarely to be found in Italian and German collective agreements. In Italy it is simply laid down that dwellings must be of adequate size and in a habitable state. The German Provisional Agricultural Labour Code provides that dwellings should be free from objection with regard both to morals and to health, and, in the case of married people, of adequate size in respect of the number of children and of the sexes. Such German collective agreements as do not themselves regulate the question of dwellings are content to refer to this provision, and minimum requirements on the size of the dwellings are only occasionally to be found. The agreement for the district of Schlawe, for instance, states that large families are to be given dwellings of sufficient size ; in Silesia, it is laid down that dwellings shall contain at least one living room, one bedroom and some additional space ; and in the district of Leipzig, that married men workers shall have free lodging, including living room, bedroom, kitchen, loft or shed, and stabling. In Austria, too, the Lower — 93 — Austrian and Burgenland collective agreements provide only that every permanently employed worker on an estate is entitled to accommodation free from objection from the point of view of health requirements and corresponding to the size of his family ; the employer is required to bring this accommodation into a state consistent with health and sanitary requirements. In Burgenland, it is prescribed that the floors of such dwellings must be of wood. In. both States representatives of the workers' organisations or of the staff of the undertaking are required to inspect dwellings, by agreement with the employers, and to encourage the workers to keep them clean and in order. The Czechoslovak guiding principles state that each married députât worker should have a dwelling of adequate size, free from objection from the point of view of health requirements and consisting of living room (fully equipped if possible), bedroom, loft, cellar, pigsty, wood-shed, etc. At least 12 sq. m. space must be reckoned for a married couple, and 2sq. m. extra for each child. The Polish collective agreements, on the other hand, deal very fully with the question of lodging. Deputat workers' dwellings must include at least one wooden-floored living room and one bedroom. The rooms must be whitewashed and absolutely clean, with airtight doors and windows. The path leading to the pump must be paved, and there must be a supply of clean and healthy drinking water. Sufficient sanitary conveniences must be available near the dwellings. In buildings with sufficient space and in all buildings to be erected bath accommodation must be provided. On some estates the employers are obliged to have a bathing establishment fitted if there is any possibility at all of doing so. In Denmark and Sweden dwellings should as a rule contain at least two rooms and a kitchen, though in the latter country one room and a kitchen, with a total surface of 35 sq. m., is sufficient. If dwellings of this size are not available, compensation amounting to 10 kr. per annum for every 3 sq. m. less than the prescribed surface must be paid. Necessary additional space — cellars or other winter storage room for potatoes, wood-shed, wash-house, pigsty, etc. — should also be provided. The Danish collective agreements contain similar provisions concerning additional space, and lay down further that at least one good usable stove must be provided (two in dwellings with more than two rooms), that if a dwelling comprises three rooms they shall — 94 — all be made over to the worker, and that any dwelling erected or adapted after the agreement has come into force shall contain at least three rooms. Only the Danish and Swedish agreements deal with the question of accommodation for unmarried farm servants. In Sweden each such worker is entitled to a separate bed with bed clothes in a warm and decently furnished room. In Denmark, the collective agreement states that farm servants' rooms must comply with the minimum requirements contained in the Act concerning the legal relations between master and servant, and that if the farm servants' bedrooms are not heated by a stove or other means, a sufficiently warm and lighted room must be provided for use in their spare time. 4. WORK OF WOMEN AND CHILDREN Special provisions for the protection of certain classes of workers, in particular women1, juveniles and children, are extraordinarily rare in collective agreements. In Denmark children under fourteen may lead horses only occasionally ; and they may not be employed on agricultural machines, for example, they may not lead the horses working horse-driven machines. This provision goes beyond the statutory regulations. Some Dutch agreements shorten hours of work and prohibit employment on certain classes of work for young persons and women. In Poland women may not be employed in spreading certain kinds of artificials. The collective agreement for the Province of East Prussia lays down that women may not be employed without their consent four weeks before and eight weeks after childbirth. The collective agreement for Lower Austria lays down that pregnant women may not be employed on heavy work from the fifth month of pregnancy onwards. In Germany several agreements in the Eastern districts provide that the wives of députât workers or other women workers who manage households shall have shorter working hours than the men, so that they can go home one hour before the principal meal. This is in conformity with a provision in the Provisional Agricultural Labour Code, and the agreements only exceptionally go beyond it. As an example of 1 In Italy special national agreements deal with the women working in the ricefields. — 95 — provisions supplementary to the Agricultural Labour Code can be mentioned the right of women workers in Mecklenburg-Schwerin to stay away from work on the days before Christmas, Easter and Whitsun. In a Brandenburg district a woman who takes the place of a " Hofgänger " is entitled to remain at home at least one day a week for her household duties. In the Dresden district women workers may not be employed against their will after 6 p.m. Among the provisions protecting the wives and children of agricultural workers may be included those provisions of collective agreements cancelling or at least limiting the obligation to work on the part of members of the family. This obligation originates in the desire to obtain the services of as many as possible of the persons living in service dwellings. In large undertakings it has been customary from time immemorial to oblige the members of the worker's family to work on the employer's estate. Adult or even juvenile members of the family who do not seek employment on the estate are often refused the right to live in service dwellings. In districts where a large part of the women's time is taken up in making use of the comparatively high wages in kind, it had become customary for the worker to have to place another person at the employer's disposal. This person, the worker had to board and lodge, but received correspondingly higher wages in kind for him. He was the so-called " Hofgänger " and might be a member of the worker's family. If, however, no one of suitable age was available, the worker was obliged to find an outsider. The obligation to work on the part of the worker's family, and in particular the obligation to furnish a " Hofgänger ", has been more and more looked upon as an evil by the workers, and they have gradually succeeded in inserting attenuating clauses in the collective agreements. As a result, the German collective agreements no longer contain a general obligation to provide " Hofgänger ", as was the case in the earliest collective agreements. But in concluding individual contracts of employment, many employers still insist on the furnishing of a " Hofgänger ", and, indeed, many Pomeranian collective agreements still require inhabitants of service dwellings to furnish a " Hofgänger " when household conditions make this possible, and especially when there are children able to work. In many districts the employer has to house the " Hofgänger " when the — 96 — worker cannot provide a member of his own family and there is no room in the dwelling for outsiders. In Poland, where similar conditions prevailed before the war, the members of the family are no longer required to work, and where members of the family are employed by the same employer they have quite independent contracts of employment. 5. SOCIAL INSURANCE The provisions of collective agreements concerning the workers' rights in the case of illness or accident depend on the scope of the legislation in force. In general, it may be said that in the past sick or incapacitated agricultural workers have been looked after to some extent by the employers ; but as social insurance has developed this practice has tended to die out and most collective agreements merely aim at eliminating the simultaneous furnishing of benefits by the undertaking and the insurance scheme. It is, however, still very frequently laid down that notwithstanding the receipt of sick benefit, for instance, wages in kind shall be continued for a certain time. Special mention should be made of certain regulations in collective agreements that take the place of social insurance or secure greater advantages to the workers. In Italy, all collective agreements stipulate either that sickness funds, with contributions from employers and workers, shall be established, or fix directly on employers an obligation in the case of sickness of the worker. In agriculture, the employers' and workers' organisations have agreed to set up a national association of sickness funds for agricultural workers which shall promote the establishment of provincial sickness funds and co-ordinate their activity. In Poland accident insurance exists only for workers employed in undertakings exceeding 30 hectares in area ; and the sickness insurance scheme is only in force in the former Prussian and Austrian territories. Consequently, in Congress Poland the collective agreements lay down that the employer shall provide medical aid for the workers and pay their wages during illness. The employer is also required to pay for the coffin in the event of a worker's death and to make a small payment to the family. There are similar provisions concerning workmen's compensation for accidents on undertakings of less than 30 hectares. — 97 — In Sweden the workers are not insured against sickness, but the covering agricultural agreement lays down that every worker whose contract of employment is for not less than one month shall be entitled to medical treatment in the event of sickness. Workers engaged by the year and living in a house owned by the estate, are entitled to not more than three months' hospital treatment at the employer's expense ; and the wife or housekeeper and children of such workers are entitled to free medical treatment. In Denmark the collective agreement requires the employer to pay the workers a daily wage for the first thirteen weeks following an accident at work, during which period the compulsory insurance scheme furnishes no benefit. For this supplementary insurance the workers themselves pay part of the contributions. Ill Permanent Character of Items The value of collective agreements in agriculture as a substitute for social legislation is mainly determined by the degree to which their provisions are permanent. It is of little use for the workers to be able to wrest great advantages when the season is good if they lose all or a substantial part of them in harder times. Rates of wages will always be subject to fluctuations and it is not to be expected that the remaining provisions will be absolutely permanent, seeing that a large proportion of them are more or less of an economic character. Consequently, no more than comparative permanency can reasonably be required, so as to give the provisions of collective agreements a value approximating to statutory regulations. Thus permanency should not be formally insisted upon, for not every alteration in the text of an agreement means a betterment or worsening of working conditions ; many are only matters of drafting. The question of permanency sometimes involves the whole agreement and sometimes only individual provisions. In the first years of agricultural collective agreements there were very extensive alterations. This was the period of transition from estate agreements to agreements between organisations, and from simple wage bargains to complex collective agreements. But in an astonishingly short time the present forms of collective — 98 — agreement came into quite general use. The fact that agreements were usually concluded without the accompaniment of labour disputes may serve to indicate that no great alterations have taken place. In Denmark both the form and the substance of the agreement concluded in 1920 have remained unchanged, even the number of paragraphs being still the same. Most of the small changes introduced date from 1922 ; for instance, abolition of the workers' right to leave the fields half an hour earlier on pay day. In 1929 the employer's obligation to insure his workers against accident was extended beyond the statutory requirements. In Germany the first collective agreements in the south were drafted in great detail, whereas in the remaining districts agreements, and especially those concluded in 1919, were essentially confined to matters of wages. Since 1921, however, both form and substance have practically everywhere remained unchanged. Only in the province of Saxony and Anhalt was the evolution somewhat slower ; up to 1923 the covering agreement contained only general principles concerning the contents of district agreements, and not until the last few years has it provided any detailed regulation of working conditions. In Mecklenburg-Schwerin, as early as 1920 provisions concerning the obligation to provide "Hofgänger" disappeared from the collective agreement. In the following year a provision concerning paid holidays was introduced. On the other hand, provisions guaranteeing the worker's collective rights have been struck out, and provisions concerning illness have been altered, with the effect that cash wages are now only paid for days actually worked. In Schleswig-Holstein the 1920 agreement laid down that for all small undertakings employing less than ten permanent workers a local committee should be set up, representing all such undertakings in the localities concerned and consisting of one employer and one worker. This provision, however, was rescinded as early as 1921. In Silesia, a provision was introduced into the agreement that every permanent worker was entitled to two half-days off ; this was altered in 1921 to two days, and in 1923 to three days, the present figure. On the other hand, sick benefits have been somewhat reduced in the course of time. In Bavaria the covering agreement of 1922 laid down that provision should be made in the district agreements for the grant of reasonable holidays to the permanent workers. As a rule, the district agreements — 99 — allowed two days. In 1929 the provisions of the covering agreement were made more precise, and holidays were graduated according to the number of years of service. Provision is now made for the regulation of the matter uniformly over the whole country, instead of on a district basis. In 1927 a provision concerning the period of notice for permanent workers was introduced into the covering agreement. In Wurtemberg also the provisions concerning holidays have been repeatedly altered, the last alteration being to the workers' detriment. The following table shows how matters have gone. NUMBER OF D A Y S ' HOLIDAY After employment of at least 1921 1922 1923 1924 1 year 2 years 3 years 4 years 5 years 6 years 2 2 2 3 3 3 2 4 4 4 3 4 4 5 4 6 6 6 6 7 7 8 In the province of Saxony and Anhalt the question of holidays was originally dealt with in two different ways in the district agreements, some calculating holidays according to the worker's length of service, others according to his age. Since 1922 the covering agreement has laid down that after one year's service all permanent workers shall be entitled to leave, the amount varying with their ageIn Italy the provisions of agricultural collective agreements have become steadily more complex, an evolution to which the promulgation of the Labour Charter has particularly contributed. The principle of paid holidays for agricultural workers was adopted in 1928, and in the same year compensation for dismissal was introduced. As regards Austria special consideration may be given to the collective agreement for Burgenland. This has been considerably modified in the course of its existence. The original wording of the agreement drafted in 1922 remained in force until 1927, when it was completely remodelled in much greater detail. Noteworthy is the fact that provisions which were originally modelled on the agreement for Lower Austria have — 100 — been replaced by others, although the original provisions in the Lower Austrian agreement have remained unchanged. In 1926 the Burgenland Agricultural Labour Code provided for the introduction of workers' representatives in the larger agricultural undertakings. The regulations, however, are not very detailed, and have been supplemented by provisions in the Burgenland collective agreements. In Poland, up to 1925-1926, the collective agreements tended to improve working conditions in agriculture, but since then their provisions have undergone practically no change. In Sweden the first collective agreements closely resembled one another, but the agreement concluded in 1925, after an interval of some years, revealed not inconsiderable changes. The regulation of hours of work was transferred from the district agreements, and new provisions concerning holidays for workers on time rates and sick benefit — which was formerly granted only in connection with industrial accidents — were added. Since 1925 this agreement has remained in force unchanged. Special attention must be given to fluctuations in the regulation of hours of work. In Denmark, the estate agreements concluded in 1918 regulated hours of work very diversely. If the month is reckoned at 25 working days, the number of working hours per year varies from 2,800 to 2,950. The first national collective agreements shortened hours of work, but in 1921 they were increased by 150 hours, and in the following year there were further changes to the workers' detriment. Since then the hours have remained unchanged ; but their distribution over the year has been more closely adapted to the demand for labour and to the season. This adaptation in fact has been in evidence since 1920, despite the shortening of hours of work. Whereas in 1919 hours were altered only twice a year, now they are altered six times. In order to make it easier to follow the fluctuations in hours of work in the German agricultural collective agreements, the number of hours per year as laid down in agreements in various parts of the country are shown in the table of Appendix B. The districts quoted which are not entire provinces or States are those whose conditions of work represent the average for the States in which they are situated. In all cases the calculations have been made in accordance with the Prussian State Calendar. — 101 — In the first years of agricultural collective agreements hours of work were shortened very considerably, but the present annual hours of work show an increase over 1923. Not until 1929 are there fresh instances of hours being shortened. The fluctuations in hours of work in the first years after the war may be illustrated by the following considerations. In East Prussia, as in many other parts of Germany, compulsory overtime was introduced in 1920, and since 1924 this overtime has been incorporated in the normal working hours. In MecklenburgSchwerin originally only eight and ten hour working days were provided for, but in 1922 the agreement prescribed that for one summer month eleven hours a day should be worked. This provision, however, does not seem to have come into force before 1923. Since 1925 in the cultivating season ten and a half hours must be worked during four consecutive weeks, and in the harvesting season eleven hours during six weeks. In Schleswig-Holstein hours of work were originally fixed at 2,700 per year, but ten hours a day had to be worked for six months. Later alterations increased this period of six months to seven and a half. In Silesia the number of hours per year has remained constant ; what fluctuations there are in the regulations concern the maximum working day. In 1921, as a general rule not more than ten hours a day were to be worked, but where a ten and a half hour day was the practice, it was to be confined to four months in the year at the most. In 1922 it was laid down that the daily hours of work should not be exceeded for more than three months in the year. In 1923 a working day of ten and a half hours was allowed between 16 May and 31 August. In 1924 eleven hours a day could be worked during the six weeks of the harvesting season. In 1925 eleven hours a day might be worked on undertakings where this number had been worked in 1924. Since then, the agreement has contained no provisions concerning an eleven-hour working day ; the workers may be required to work ten and a half hours for four months only during the period 15 April to 30 September. In the province of Saxony and Anhalt, hours of work were regulated very diversely in the first district agreements. Some of the 1919 agreements reproduced the stipulations of the Provisional Agricultural Labour Code, but others provide for much shorter hours of work. In the following year shorter hours became the general rule. The number of hours per year fell to 2,650, although occasionally overtime had to be worked. — 102 — In the next years hours were increased a little, but since 1923 they have remained stationary almost everywhere. In Austria, Czechoslovakia, Poland and Sweden hours of work have remained stationary or have undergone only trifling changes since collective agreements were first concluded. The general evolution of hours of work may, then, be summarised as follows : in the first years after the war collective agreements were able to curtail hours substantially. Then a reaction set in and in many cases a not inconsiderable lengthening of hours had to be accepted. Simultaneously there was a movement to distribute hours of work over the year in closer harmony with natural conditions, and consequently the regulation of hours of work lost some of its value to the worker. Since 1923-1924 hours have everywhere remained unchanged. The evolution of the general contents of agricultural collective agreements may be similarly summed up. Some of the provisions included in collective agreements in the first years were too radical for permanent retention and had to be dropped. But since 1923-1924 it has proved possible to maintain intact all provisions of practical value for the agricultural worker, though very few new provisions have been added. Of particular importance in judging of the permanency of individual provisions in agricultural agreements is, naturally enough, the question of the extent to which the latest renewals of agreements have been detrimental to the workers by reason of the agricultural depression. It was only to be expected that the heavy fall in agricultural prices would entail a fall in wages ; but there remained the question whether, and if so to what extent, other provisions only indirectly bound up with wages would change for the worse. In England, the agricultural depression has for two years exerted a marked influence on hours of work. In many cases where the employers have demanded a lowering of the minimum wage rates, their demands have been refused by the agricultural wages committees, but the number of hours to be worked a week before overtime can be paid has been increased. On the other hand, in Austria, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Poland and Sweden collective agreements or guiding principles have been renewed without any alterations except as regards rates of wages. In Germany the employers were driven by the economic position to demand both a reduction in wages and a tightening up of other working conditions. The most important point was the — 103 — reduction in wages, and apart from one or two exceptions their demands for other alterations in the collective agreements were rejected. An enquiry into alterations in the provisions relating to hours of work in the German agricultural collective agreements of 1929-1931 even shows that improvements predominate ; both in Wurtemberg and Bavaria, for instance, the number of hours of work per year has been reduced by twenty-five. Consequently, it may be said that on the whole the agricultural depression has so far not had any considerable influence on the regulation of working conditions by way of agricultural collective agreements. CHAPTER III CONCLUSIONS I The information presented in the first two Chapters of this report suffices to prove the existence of collective bargaining in agriculture in a number of countries and shows that this system has enabled large numbers of agricultural workers to secure effective collective regulation of their working conditions. We are now in a position to discuss the problem which constitutes the real aim of our enquiry. To what extent and in what way does collective bargaining replace in agriculture an inadequate social legislation ? The suggestion that collective bargaining can replace social legislation depends on certain assumptions. In the first place, the geographical extension of social legislation normally covers the whole national territory of a given country and normally includes in its scope either all workers in the country or all workers falling under a given definition : the question has to be raised whether collective agreements have a similar universal application. In the second place, social legislation, by its very character, secures for the workers positive improvements in their working conditions : the question has to be raised whether collective agreements have a similar ameliorating character or whether they are limited to securing merely a status quo. In the third place, social legislation ex hypothesi can embrace any and every factor which bears on working conditions, wages, hours, protection of the worker in every direction even up to and including such forms of insurance as secure him in illness, accident, invalidity, old-age, and unemployment: the question has to be raised whether collective agreements can in any way rival social legislation in the largeness of the subject matter to be dealt with. A theoretical answer to these questions is of minor interest for our present purpose. The Resolution accepted in 1928 — 105 — by the International Labour Conference was the outcome of a definite actual situation ; it amounted to a recognition of the unsatisfactory progress which is at the present time being made by social legislation on behalf of agricultural workers. It is with this situation in front of us, namely, with our eyes on the gaps and deficiencies in protective Acts on behalf of agricultural labour, that we have to answer the questions put, and to try to realise both the present function of collective bargaining in agriculture and its future possibilities. There is first the question of the geographical and national extension of collective bargaining. Here we must admit that the limitations are very great. True, agricultural workers are such an enormous group of the world's working population that even on its present modest scale collective bargaining may be estimated to cover 5,000,000 agricultural workers. But 5,000,000 workers are only a tiny fraction of the agricultural workers of the world. Perhaps a truer estimate is obtainable if we confine our attention definitely to those more advanced countries where the system might reasonably be supposed to apply under present conditions. Even here we find that in many countries the agricultural trade unions essential to the conclusion of collective agreements simply do not exist, while in others, where they do, there are noticeable gaps, with the result that whole districts and whole groups of agricultural enterprises are quite untouched by the collective bargaining idea. Nowhere have the agricultural workers' trade unions been strong enough to influence working conditions throughout a country. Indeed, the actual geographical extension of collective agreements in agriculture is noticeably greater in proportion as the basic principle of direct negotiation between the two parties is relaxed in favour of that of State intervention. But, if the extension of collective bargaining in agriculture is limited geographically, it is also limited in regard to the type of enterprise to which it applies. It was noted in the first Chapter of this report that the agricultural trade unions recruited their membership principally from the workers who work on large-scale farms. The character of existing agricultural employers' organisations also contributes to this tendency to concentrate on large-scale farming conditions. It is natural that where negotiations are carried on with persons representative of these particular conditions — and the employers' associations in agriculture draw their membership from occupiers — 106 — of large enterprises — the contents of collective agreements should be suited to the interests of the negotiating parties. Thus the prevailing tendencies in organisation, both on the workers' and on the employers' side, combine to confine collective bargaining largely to workers on large-scale farms and to prevent the working conditions of those groups of workers who are principally or exclusively employed on smaller or on peasant holdings from being regulated by collective bargaining as completely as is done in large-scale farming. Formal exceptions in the texts of agreements are perhaps rare, though smaller farms are occasionally treated as though they were exceptional, special terms being made for them, while certain groups such as artisans or servants forming part of the farm household are sometimes specifically excluded. But the terms agreed upon are such as have little application to workers living at the farmhouse, or else different conditions are deliberately mentioned in their case, e.g. the number of their working hours is fixed on quite a different basis. It is also characteristic that rates of wages for farm servants are often left to be negotiated between master and man or else are put so low as to be mostly meaningless. This state of affairs is quite natural. The large-scale enterprise is bound to be more rigid in its labour arrangements than the smaller peasant type of farm ; any uncertainty or indefiniteness in the conditions to be observed will interfere with its efficiency. The small occupier has little to fear on this score, and adapts his orders to circumstances. At any rate the pressure of the agricultural trade union movement is seldom intense enough to induce him to join his district employers' association. It is, in fact, difficult to maintain such associations in regions of peasant farming or smallholding. It must consequently be counted as a considerable step forward when general farmers' associations which include all types of farmers are induced to take part in the collective bargaining process. Incidentally, owing to the wide membership basis of such associations, the rather curious situation may arise that the total number of negotiating employers may exceed the total number of negotiating workers. But the fact remains that collective bargaining in agriculture is possible even in peasant farming ; the conclusion of collective agreements in south German agriculture is a proof. On the other hand, as is shown by the history of such bargaining in — 107 — Scotland and by the way in which working conditions have been settled in Danish sugar-beet farming, collective bargaining cannot be carried so far when negotiations are with general farmers' associations as when they are carried on with organisations properly and exclusively representative of agricultural employers only. Undoubtedly it is in large-scale farming that collective negotiation has its most significant application, and, while this must be recognised as a limitation, it also shows the great significance of the collective bargaining principle for agriculture, seeing that it is in this type of farming that we find the ordinary agricultural labourer, who remains a general worker throughout his life and is for that very reason peculiarly in need of securing regulated working conditions. Our second question concerned the ameliorative character of the two methods of regulating working conditions in agriculture, namely, social legislation and collective bargaining. The question may be simply put. Have collective agreements brought improvements in the working conditions of agricultural labour ? Are such improvements comparable to what can be secured by legislation ? The answer is yes, but it must not be given too unhesitatingly. The mere fact that his working conditions are laid down in a collective agreement implies a great deal for an agricultural worker. He is thereby supplied with precise information about those conditions and can estimate his rights much more accurately in case of dispute, a point in which he is otherwise habitually at a very great disadvantage owing to the frequent want of any written contract in his industry. But collective bargaining has also given the agricultural workers more direct material benefits, even apart from the bargains struck about wages rates, which of course constitute the chief objective of the whole system. Terms as favourable to the workers as those elsewhere laid down in legislation, or even more favourable, are found in collective agreements on a variety of points. A perceptible shortening of the working day has been obtained throughout, while the grant of paid holiday leave is generally admitted. As regards the length of the working day, it may be claimed that there is no agricultural labour legislation in existence which approaches the most favourable of the solutions laid down by collective negotiation between employers and employed. It may therefore be taken as proved that collective bargaining is a suitable way of dealing with problems which belong to the — 108 — field of agricultural social legislation and that it has an ameliorative effect on the worker's conditions. The limits of this suitability must, however, be examined. There are two main limitations on the usefulness of collective bargaining in agriculture. In the first place its results are uneven, and in the second place they are incomplete. Collective bargaining in agriculture is in direct contrast to social legislation in respect of the marked local variations and differences between the terms of the regional agreements. In a few countries, e.g. in Denmark and Sweden, and also throughout a few more extensive regions of Germany, it has proved possible to obtain uniform working conditions, but in many other parts of Germany and also, for example, in the Netherlands, the size of the district covered by any one agreement is very restricted. This means that great attention is paid to local conditions, with the result that elements of merely historical interest, which need not have been safeguarded, become stabilised in an agreement. Careful consideration of local conditions is undoubtedly necessary if practical solutions are to be arrived at, but some of the differences between the terms laid down for adjacent districts point to a certain capriciousness in the results obtained. The situation has unquestionably been influenced by the present state of organisation among agricultural employers. The marked decentralisation of their associations has on more than one occasion hampered efforts made on the workers' side to obtain uniform conditions over the widest possible area, and constitutes one of the principal causes of the frequent occurrence of agreements covering very small districts. Local employers' organisations aim above all at concluding an agreement which shall fit their local needs. To this unevenness in the results of collective bargaining in agriculture is added a considerable incompleteness as regards the topics dealt with. Chapter II of the present report shows that while such questions as wages, hours, and, frequently, paid holiday leave are included for settlement in agricultural collective agreements, many other topics, which might naturally form the subject matter of a settlement, are not mentioned ; in fact, comparatively few of the many questions arising out of the agricultural labour contract are included. In some cases such matters may already have been settled by legislation ; or local custom on the point is fixed and mention is not .thought neces- — 109 — sary ; or else the workers have simply failed to get the point included. But certain other topics which have no direct importance in an individual agricultural labour contract, though they are a matter of general advantage to the whole body of agricultural workers, especially topics which include an element of social risk and one therefore normally dealt with by means of social insurance legislation, are also seldom mentioned in agricultural collective agreements. Such agreements are, moreover, mostly silent on the subjects of women's labour and child labour 1 . This brings us face to face with our third question, which indeed is already hereby in part answered. The contents of collective agreements do not extend much beyond those elements which form the basis of the individual employment contract. The organised workers have not been able to press collective bargaining much further than this, even on their own behalf. In view of the limited extent to which agricultural employers have at present troubled to organise themselves, the agricultural workers' organisations are by contrast the stronger, but the decisive factor is not so much the actual as the potential strength of parties. Further concessions might frequently have been obtained from the employers' organisations as at present constituted, but the wisdom of doing so could be questioned. It is universally admitted that, where a collective agreement has been concluded, its terms are mostly observed even by the unorganised employers ; evidence to this effect is supplied not only by the representative organisations on either side but also sometimes from official sources. It may at first sight appear curious that the organisations of the agricultural workers should have been able to spread their influence far beyond the immediate circle of the negotiations ; the explanation appears to lie in the fact that by thus accommodating themselves to the present contents of agreements the agricultural employers are able to call a halt to the organisation movement among agricultural workers. Any offer of less favourable terms, which would often not be at all impossible in view of the state of the labour market, would evoke more organisation among the workers. 1 Many workers' organisations consider that any mention of child labour in a collective agreement implies a formal justification of such labour. A mention is therefore refused, the demand here being for legislative intervention to prohibit the employment of children. — 110 — The present restricted contents of agreements reflect the present strength of the negotiating parties. On the workers' side organisation is sufficiently good to enforce the terms as they stand even among unorganised employers ; but any extension of contents would jeopardise the currency of the agreements as more or less practised to-day. The whole system might then possibly be threatened. Where the contents of agreements no longer coincide with the contents of the individual employment contract, but are extended to deal with social problems proper, the likelihood is that the unorganised employer will not pay too much attention to them, and that the worker himself will not lay a great deal of stress on stipulations which may never come into play in his own case. While it is universally admitted that employers abide in general by the terms of agreements, such complaints as are occasionally raised on this head have reference precisely to the stipulations on general social questions. Here the organised employer discovers that he has put himself at a disadvantage as against his unorganised colleague by the fact of being bound by an agreement, and asks himself whether he should not free himself of such obligations by resigning from his organisation. On one occasion a stipulation in an agreement designed to meet a social obligation — the promise of an extra voluntary payment additional to an obligatory insurance premium — was not taken over by the unorganised employers, with the result that the organised employers dissolved their association. Another point which must be noticed in regard to the contents of agreements is that agricultural collective agreements have remained very stationary. The original framework has hardly anywhere been touched. The system has crystallised into the forms which were adopted at the outset ; neither the areas in respect of which agreements were to be current nor the technical character of the agreements have been modified ; very few new clauses have been added. Some very desirable simplifications have failed to take place because negotiations have been limited to the strictly necessary amendments. Nor, in fact, are any developments likely until the agricultural workers' trade unions are as important as they were just after the war, when they first became parties to agreements. With these facts in mind we must now give our verdict on the value of collective bargaining in agriculture as a means of — Ill — replacing social legislation. Looking at the question quite generally, and bearing in mind the present restricted use of collective agreements in agriculture and the small hopes of their immediate extension, we are compelled to deny that collective bargaining is sufficiently important in the agricultural industry to be reckoned as a means capable of replacing an inadequate social legislation. This, in fact, is the view of all agricultural workers' organisations. One and all sent a negative answer to the question put to them by the International Labour Office : " In your opinion, may the stipulations in agricultural collective agreements be considered adequate to replace social legislation ?" It is clear that it was more especially questions concerning social insurance, workers' protection and women's and children's labour which influenced the answers. The achievements of collective bargaining on these heads are insignificant compared with even the minimum results of legislative intervention. Though from the workers' side an effort must needs be made to secure attention to such problems in cases where legislation is wanting, no collective regulation can be expected to prove on these points any sort of adequate substitute for the law. Parliamentary action is the only means of dealing with this part of the worker's conditions. II Are there then no problems in agricultural labour which have been regulated by collective bargaining with results at least as satisfactory as those induced by legislative action ? Undoubtedly there are, for, as already indicated above, all those employment conditions which have a permanent and direct interest for the individual worker have been submitted to collective regulation with results which may challenge what can be obtained by legislation. True, not every problem of this kind is commonly dealt with in this way, but the existence of comprehensive stipulations on some of them shows that they can suitably be dealt with by collective negotiation. Thus within a limited field (but one of primary importance) collective bargaining may fill up the gaps in legislation. This, however, does not exhaust the significance of collective bargaining in agriculture. Social legislation may not be so much replaced as completed by collective bargaining, and this — 112 — possibility is particularly important in agriculture. We have already mentioned variation in local conditions as a characteristic of the carrying on of the agricultural industry, and we have drawn attention to the unnecessary observance of such local variations. Indeed, a great risk lies here, especially in regard to the fixing of wages rates ; there is every danger that, by the system of separate local agreements, the backward parts of the country may not be compelled to level up their rates sufficiently to catch up current wages in more progressive areas, and may remain permanently behindhand. National agreements and even national legislation do not always surmount this difficulty, which can only be dealt with by considerable pressure from a central authority, whether that authority be a Government one, or the workers' central executive, or the combined workers and employers. But while stressing the importance of not overestimating the need for local variations, not only in the direction of wages but also in many other directions, it must nevertheless be admitted that there is a point up to which local variation is peculiarly necessary in agriculture. It only needs to be pointed out that different types of agricultural industry are carried on in different parts of a country and that stipulations which are required, e.g. on sheep farms, are totally without application for workers in crop cultivation. In fact, agriculture is not one but many occupations, and these occupations are often strongly localised. It follows that legislation has to be drafted in rather general terms in order to cover such varying conditions, and it is precisely here that collective bargaining can be useful in filling in those details which have to be accommodated to the current organisation of the agricultural industry and the natural conditions which govern agricultural effort. There exists unquestionably a type of problem which is more easily handled by collective negotiation than by legislative decision. The workers' organisations justly observe that collective bargaining is a means of clothing the guiding principles laid down in an Act with the necessary meaning and the necessary obligatory force. Indeed, collective regulation, while it hesitates to deal with problems of a wide social bearing like social insurance, is able, in other directions, to go further than the law. The President of the Danish Agricultural Workers' Federation has stated this idea at length in a communication addressed to the International Labour Office : — 113 — Collective bargaining in agriculture must show a certain elasticity and a certain capacity to adapt itself to economic and social circumstances. Alterations in production processes require to be rapidly noted. This is best and most regularly done at the annual negotiations for the renewal of agreements, where the demands made on either side are discussed before debaters perfectly experienced in every practical detail of agricultural processes and agricultural labour. Professional knowledge is brought to bear on every argument on either side. Collective regulation then emerges as the result of pooled knowledge, of the relative strength of the parties, and of the nature of the subject matter handled Previous experience has also shown that the agricultural legislator has less understanding of labour questions than the employers' representatives, who are in much more direct touch with the circumstances, and that it is easier to come to an agreement by friendly negotiation with practical farmers on points which no legislator would ever put into an Act. Add to this that employers show far less hesitation in accepting a point in an agreement whose validity runs only for a year, which gives them a chance of re-negotiating at the end of that period, than a legislator, who cannot foretell for how long an Act will remain in force and only knows that amendments are difficult to secure. The organisations representing the negotiating parties are in a much better position to make experiments. The writer points out t h a t it was fifteen years before the Danish legislature abolished a Master and Servants Act which had been recognised on all hands as quite out of date ; meanwhile, already two years before this abolition, collective negotiation had secured for Danish farm servants, in despite of existing legislation, improved and more acceptable wages, housing, and working conditions which on really i m p o r t a n t points still go much further even t h a n w h a t the new Act provides. Similarly, on housing the first collective bargaining of the agricultural workers' federation secured clauses on the size, arrangement and sanitary sufficiency of married workers' accommodation which revolutionised housing standards. Legislation has here hardly intervened a t all—only a few regulations of 1902 and an old Order of the middle of the nineteenth century a b o u t notice and eviction are in force. Were t h e law merely to confirm the housing clauses which have been incorporated for the last ten years in the t e x t of t h e collective agreement, it would be a great step forward. In other States it may also be observed t h a t legislation has only touched on the fringe of questions which are of t h e first importance to the worker. Indeed, legislative intervention is sometimes of a quite negative character, consisting in a mere abolition of out-of-date enactments ; t h u s t h e Swedish Master and Servants Act of 1833 was simply rescinded in 1926, as were a number of German F a r m Servants' and Servants' Codes during the 1918 Revolution. By such action the conditions formerly 8 — 114 — regulated by law have been left to the free decision of employers and workers, a process which has given increased importance to the collective agreement system. In one other way collective bargaining offers greater advantages than social legislation. One of the principal difficulties of this type of legislation is, in agriculture, the enforcement of decisions. The number of enterprises in question and their topographical distribution demands a staff of inspectors which has to be much larger than for any other industry if control is to be exercised at standards as effective as those in urban manufacture. In Poland special inspectors are appointed for agricultural labour conditions, but their number proves insufficient to cope with all the duties which are assigned to them. In England also the inspection of the payment of the minimum wage rates laid down by the wages committees has always been a difficult business. In spite of increased inspection, the number of cases of underpayment does not diminish. Here collective negotiation offers decided advantages, the many small branches of the organisations on either side providing an easy check on the loyalty of members. In any case collective agreements bear witness to a certain collaboration between the two sides, their very existence implying relations of loyalty and confidence between the organisations, confidence, in fact, that either party has a real intention to abide by the negotiated terms and to see that their members do so too. Where such confidence gives out, the conditions making collective bargaining possible also disappear. The organisations are therefore opposed to unconstitutional behaviour on the part of their members, and where such behaviour is noted, attempt a reprimand. When agreements are unconstitutionally abandoned, their restoration is required, and legal action instituted should warnings prove insufficient. Finally, it must not be forgotten that the use of collective bargaining in manufacturing industry to deal with conditions of employment entails a corresponding necessity for agriculture to adopt the same methods. In the degree in which strong trade unions of industrial workers are able to exercise their influence on working conditions in the factories, the occasions for adopting factory legislation are likely to be much restricted. The trade union movement in industry is often in a position to forego legislation and deal directly with the employers, e.g. on the important questions of wages and hours. Agricultural — 115 — workers must follow this general policy, as they can seldom hope to obtain separate legislation on their own behalf, although, objectively considered, their situation might sometimes seem to call for it. In the absence of legislation, they will be left unprotected, unless they manage to imitate their comrades in industry and secure collective negotiation. There is also the rather different situation where legislation exists on behalf of the industrial worker which is specifically exclusive of the agricultural worker ; here the agricultural worker can have recourse to collective bargaining to make good at least in part the inequality between himself and the workers in the towns. Collective bargaining is necessary in agriculture if only in order to prevent the widening of the gap between industrial and agricultural working conditions. Ill The contents of collective agreements in agriculture may be considered to have an independent positive value ; they extend to topics where legislation is negative or non-existent. Yet in the present state of collective bargaining in this industry it is obvious time and again that unless those contents are ultimately supported by legislative action, the usefulness of the collective bargaining process is soon threatened. The workers' action becomes more and more difficult should the legislator fail to adopt at least some of the advances which have been current for years and which lend themselves to legislative definition. It is nevertheless very difficult to quote specific instances where clauses in collective agreements have provided a basis for later legislation. In fact, in addition to the German Provisional Labour Code, which resulted out of negotiations between employers' and workers' organisations and was given legal force, only one really good instance of this has been brought to our notice. The careful stipulations laid down in the earliest Danish national collective agreement in agriculture on the accommodation of farm servants have plainly been incorporated in the text of the 1921 Act in that country on the relations between employers and their assistants. The text of the later agreement therefore merely states that accommodation must conform to the standard laid down in the Act. — 116 — All the more important therefore are the various systems which, while not incorporating in formal legislative Acts the positive contents of agreements, nevertheless continue to give value to those contents by attributing to the agreements themselves something of the force of law. The various systems by which the texts of collective agreements can be declared " binding " on non-signatory parties when living within a specified area are of material assistance to agriculture. Nevertheless, even in this system, when the intervention of the State seems so direct, nothing is added to or subtracted from the contents of agreements ; these are and remain a matter solely for the bargaining power of the two parties. Even the Polish system maintains this, the true principle of collective bargaining, for though on occasion the Polish Governihent representatives may lay down the terms to be observed, sitting as sole adjudicators, nevertheless this is only by exception and the assumption is that the parties will meet and will bargain. In fact, the Polish system illustrates well one marked difficulty in collective bargaining in agriculture —• it is usually difficult to get negotiations started ; once started, they are apt to continue, as observed above, more or less smoothly. Here a good deal of stress must be laid on the novelty of collective bargaining in so conservative an industry as agriculture. It is therefore often practical, according to the circumstances of the particular country in question, to back up at any rate the initial stages of negotiation by some measure of compulsion. The ideal system would then be to leave the parties to work out the terms which they think the industry can carry, only withdrawing from collective negotiation certain unsuitable topics such as social insurance, negotiators being unlikely to deal adequately with such large general interests, and also very distinctly reserving the right of the State to protect by quite other means certain weaker groups of workers, especially children. Whether collective bargaining is a good means of dealing with the housing problem is a rather disputable point ; there is some reason for stating that it is apt to break down. On the other hand, collective bargaining has held its own very well during the recent severe agricultural depression on the basic subject of wages rates, while on the almost equally important subject of working hours it has, as was pointed out above, secured terms for the workers quite noticeably superior to anything attempted by legislation. — 117 — A further ideal would be, when the collective bargaining process has been carried on some time, to carry over for legislative action selected topics on which discussion has reached a settlement of a kind which has proved acceptable to both sides over a term of years. Such legislative confirmation of terms agreeable to both parties should not come too late, or doubt and difficulty may arise on the mere excuse of a passing economic situation. Legislation, moreover, is necessary in order to bring to heel certain backward areas where collective bargaining is unable to surmount the difficulties created by historic or other special circumstances. That the workers on their side are in favour of collective bargaining hardly requires statement. Nor does it require argument to show why the employers' attitude is bound to be somewhat different. When collective bargaining first started in agriculture, between 1918 and 1920, employers were quite favourable ; they believed collective negotiation to be possible, indeed necessary, in order to secure social peace and avoid great social unrest. In many cases employers still remain of this opinion. Their own advantage out of the system lies in the stabilisation of labour conditions which it secures and the elimination of competition for labour between one employer and another. More particularly is it stated that this result of collective bargaining is appreciated in peasant farming, where farm servants are very scarce. While the Danish agricultural employers' organisation declares that collective bargaining, if not greatly to be desired, is necessary, and while the Swedish agricultural employers' organisation does not wish for any extension of the system but would prefer to see continued, as far as possible, the old arrangements for individual labour contracts, the General Secretary of the Federation of German Agricultural and Forestry Employers' Organisations states in a communication to the International Labour Office that the members of his Organisation are " altogether in favour of " collective bargaining and recognise its importance as a basis for the individual labour contract in agriculture ; they protest, however, against any tendency on the part of Government authorities to force collective negotiations into certain channels without sufficient regard for local agricultural situations. Whatever the form of collective bargaining adopted, the size and strength of the organisations on either side is the determining factor. The results achieved will always be the — 118 — expression of the relative strength of the negotiating parties. The function of the State in regard to collective bargaining is confined above all to recognising the organisations, to facilitating the work of the negotiating parties and to enforcing if necessary the results of negotiation. APPENDICES APPENDIX A PRINCIPAL AGRICULTURAL WORKERS' ORGANISATIONS Country Austria: Social-Democratic Czechoslovakia : Social-Democratic : Czech language German language National-Socialist Christian-Socialist Denmark : Social-Democratic Membership Founded in 1920 1911 60,000 1921 1919 1920 1925 1924 44,000 6,000 — 1927 1930 34,000 32,000 37,000 3,000 23,000 12,000 7,000 4,000 1915 25,000 13,000 15,000 15,000 1908 1912 680,000 89,000 180,000 78,000 153,000 77,000 162,000 Greaf Britain: Social-Democratic : England and Wales 1906 1912 Scotland 150,000 23,000 30,000 15,000 1901 1926 846,000 15,000 1900 1914 Prewar 16,000 Germany : Social-Democratic Christian-Socialist Italy: Social-Democratic Fascist Netherlands : Social-Democratic Christian-Socialist Roman-Catholic Poland : Social-Democratic ) Post Christian Socialist [ war National Socialist ) Sweden : Social-Democratic • 1908 — |E 10,000 10,000 35,00o 1 5,000 700,000 1,320,000 6,000 7,000 6,000 16,000 — 7,000 — 50,000 — 47,000 21,000 86,000 46,000 5,000 10,000 1 Further, the agricultural sections of the Transport and General Workers' Union groups 10,000 members. APPENDIX B ANNUAL HOURS OF WORK ACCORDING TO COLLECTIVE A IN THE YEARS 1920 TO 1931 Hours of work as laid down in Districts 1920 1921 Province of East Prussia Province of Pomerania Free-State of Mecklenburg-Schwerin Province of Brandenburg Province of Silesia Province of Hanover Province of Schleswig-Holstein Province of Saxony Free State of Anhalt Free State of Saxony Free State of Thuringia Province of Hesse-Nassau Province of Rheinhesse Province of Westphalia Free State of Wurtemberg Free State of Bavaria 2,788 — 1 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 2,788 3 2,788 s — — 2,788 2,900 2,895 2,900 2,895 2,900 2,90 2,96 2,800 — 2,850 — 2,764 2,700 2,850 — 2,802 2,700 2,840 2,850 2,870 2,850 2,857 2,775 2,870 2,850 2,856 2,750 2,88 2,85 2,85 2,75 2,700 — 2,650* — 2,800 — — — 2,900 2,900 2,725 — 2,775 2,675 2,675 2,675 2,750 2 2,750 2,750 2,725 — 2,725 2,800 2,800 2,800 2,800 — 2,800 2,800 — 2,799 — — 2,675 2,9004 2,9004 2,900 2,900 2,900 2,900 2,834 2,750 2,800 2,725 2,800 2,800 2,799 2,675 2,900 2,900 2,834 2,750 2,800 2,725 2,800 2,800 2,799 2,675 2,900 2,900 2,83 2,75 2,80 2,72 2,80 2,80 2,83 2,67 2,90 2,90 — 2,700 2,836 — In addition there are 150 supplementary hours I " " 50 " " / for which an extra payment must be g a >. .. ,. .. \ 100 4 If eleven hours are worked, extra payment must be given for the eleventh hour. 2 APPENDIX C SOME ARTICLES IN THE " INTERNATIONAL LABOUR REVIEW ' ON AGRICULTURE O N COLLECTIVE BARGAINING IN AGRICULTURE, OR MAKING R E F E R E N C E TO A POLICY OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING Conciliation in Agriculture A New Policy for Agricultural Labour Agricultural Conditions and Labour Agreements in Denmark and Sweden Collective Labour Agreements in Italian Agriculture : I II The Effects of Collective Agreements in Silesian Agriculture Collective Agreement Wages in Silesian Agriculture Agricultural Wages and Labour Conditions in the Netherlands Agricultural Wages in Australia Vol. VIII XXV No. 1 2 II XIV XV 1 5 2 XVIII XXI 3 4 XVIII XXV 6 6 DESCRIBING OR MAKING R E F E R E N C E TO LABOUR CONDITIONS IN AGRICULTURE N O T CONTROLLED BY NATIONAL OR RECOGNISED SYSTEMS OF COLLECTIVE BARGAINING (a) General1 The Present Regulation of Hours of Work in Agriculture The Housing of Agricultural Wage-Paid Workers . . . . Some Forms of Inspection in Agriculture Unemployment in Agriculture. Cf. the relevant section of the Grey Report on Unemployment Insurance presented to the Seventeenth Session of the International Labour Conference. (b) By XXV XXV VIII 1 3 4 Countries1 Algeria: The Problem of Agricultural Labour Algeria Brazil: Agricultural Wages in Brazil Cuba: Labour in the Cuban Sugar Industry in XXII XXII XX 1 The general articles mentioned deal simultaneously with conditions subject to collective bargaining and with conditions uncontrolled by such bargaining; the articles on the separate countries include information on some countries where certain elements of collective action already exist. — 122 — Vol. Estonia: The Position of the Agricultural Labourer in Estonia France: Labour Conditions in French Agriculture. . . . The Housing of Agricultural Workers in F r a n c e . . . Hungary: The Agricultural Labour Situation in Hungary (Cf. also Studies and Reports, Series K, No. 10 : The Law on the Contracts of Employment of Agricultural Workers in Austria, Germany and Hungary.) Japan: Conditions of Agricultural Workers in J a p a n . Kenya: Aspects of Agriculture in Kenya Latvia : Social Aspects of Agrarian Reform in Latvia . Palestine: Rates of Wages and Hours of Labour in Palestine in 1929 .' Rumania: Land Reform in Rumania South Africa : Native Labour in South Africa Spain : The Agrarian Problem in Spain Switzerland : Working Conditions of Agricultural Wage Earners in Switzerland U.S.A. : Allowances in Kind Given to Farm Labourers in the United States of America No. V XXV XVIII 5 1 6 XXV 5 XVI XXII XX 5 2 1 XXIII XXII XVI XI 2 4 1 6 XXIV 2-3 XX 4 Labour Conditions in the Timber Industry in the Argentine, Brazil and the Dutch Indies XVIII 4-5 (c) More than One Country