INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE THE COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS WITH SPECIAL REFERENCE TO REHABILITATION AND RECONSTRUCTION GENEVA, 1955 STUDIES AND REPORTS Series H (Co-operation), No. 5 First Printed, Montreal, 1945 Second Impression, Geneva, 1955 PUBLISHED BY T H E INTERNATIONAL LABOUR O F F I C E , G E N E V A , SWITZERLAND Published in the United Kingdom for the INTERNATIONAL LABÓUB OFFICE by Staples Press Ltd., London PRINTED BY " LA TRIBUNE DE GENÈVE " , GENEVA, SWITZERLAND CONTENTS Page Introduction 1 Part I. Restoration of Basic Economic Functions 5 CHAPTER I. 7 Food and Agriculture Means of Agricultural Production 7 Rural Supply Co-operative Organisations Feeding Stuffs and Fertilisers Seeds Farm Implements and Machinery Livestock Miscellaneous Requisites Agricultural Credit 18 Rural Credit Co-operatives in Europe Their Chief Characteristics Rural Credit Co-operatives and the State The Finnish and French Systems Organisation of Agricultural Marketing 19 20 22 24 27 Types and Number of Rural Co-operatives Marketing Agricultural Products Co-operative Marketing of Specific Agricultural Commodities Grain Livestock and Meat Eggs and Poultry Dairy Produce Fruits and Vegetables Textiles and Other Products Restoration of the Fishing Industry 27 30 30 32 34 36 40 44 47 Fishermen's Co-operatives: Numerical Data Some Problems An Experiment CHAPTER II. 9 10 12 13 16 16 Transport, Power and Housing Fuel Transport.. Electric Power 48 51 54 56 56 60 63 5 ¡i CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS The Housing Problem Necessity for Collective Action Co-operative Activities Distributive Co-operative Societies Housing Co-operative Societies Housing Co-operative Societies and Housing Policy Reconstruction Co-operatives CHAPTER III. Inter-Co-operative Relations Page 67 68 69 70 70 73 74 78 Advantages of Direct Inter-Co-operative Relations 79 Some Instances of Inter-Co-operative Relations Inter-Co-operative Relations within Countries International Inter-Co-operative Relations within Europe Inter-Co-operative Trading through International Co-operative Agencies 82 83 88 Nature of Inter-Co-operative Relations 93 Comparison of Different Forms of Inter-Co-operative Relations... A Considered Policy Part II. Social Problems of Rehabilitation CHAPTER IV. Employment Co-operative Forms of Employment of Industrial Workers 92 95 98 101 103 104 Co-operatives among the Unemployed 106 Building and Public Works 108 Workers' Productive and Labour Contracting Co-operatives.. . . 109 Forms of Scattered Industry 112 Cottage Industry and Home Work 113 Handicrafts 114 Workers' Productive Societies 116 Application of the Forms of Scattered Industry to Rehabilitation 117 Industrial Decentralisation 120 Co-operatives and Employment on the Land 123 Access to the Enterprise 124 Co-operative Forms for the Organisation and Operation of Agricultural Holdings under Individual Control 127 Co-operative and Collective Forms of Farming 128 The Co-operative Economy and the General Level of Employment.. . . Stability of Employment in Co-operative Enterprises Disturbances of Economic Equilibrium CHAPTER V. Improvement of the Standard of Living Influence on Real Income from Work 136 137 139 149 149 CONTENTS Hl Page Mode of Life Environment Leisure Health Nutrition 151 152 152 153 153 Social Security Insurance Credit 160 161 162 CHAPTER VI. Democratic Management of the Economy A Sector of Democratic Economy Co-operative Democracy and Political Democracy Part III. Conditions and Forms of the Co-operative Contribution to the Rehabilitation and Reconstruction Effort CHAPTER VII. Conditions of Co-operative Action 164 164 169 173 177 Teaching and Training 177 Legislation 182 Co-operative Legislation Fiscal and Economic Legislation 182 183 Co-operative Institutions and the Planning of the Economy 186 Co-operative Institutions and the Public Authorities 188 CHAPTER VIII. Forms of the Co-operative Contribution Consultation and Representation 198 198 Price Regulation, Rationing 198 Organisation of Production and Marketing 199 Representation of a More General Nature 201 Place of Co-operation in the Permanent Machinery of Government 203 Representation in International Economic and Social Organisations 205 Assignment of Public Utility Functions 207 Mandates and Delegation of Functions Co-operative Organisations and Public Bodies Linked in Joint Service Undertakings 209 216 Conclusion 222 Index 227 2 7 * 5 L INTRODUCTION It is proposed in the following chapters to examine the role of the different types of co-operative organisation in the work of postwar rehabilitation and reconstruction. The present study therefore forms a sequel to its predecessor in this series1, which sought to define and measure the possible contribution of the co-operative movement to the task of immediate relief in the countries devastated by war and occupation. Besides being a continuation, it combines in several ways with the earlier study to form a single whole. First, as the countries requiring relief have also to pass through a period of rehabilitation and reconstruction, the two studies overlap each other, just as the problems of relief, rehabilitation and reconstruction form an unbroken chain. Second and more particularly, it is obvious that in some of its aspects the role of co-operative organisations with distributive functions will be much the same in rehabilitation as in relief operations. For rehabilitation may be regarded as the continuation or the accompaniment and consolidation of the work of relief; conversely, though the latter represents a transitory effort, primarily inspired by the urgent needs of the moment, it is from the beginning mingled with considerations affecting the immediate future and gradually extends into an effort at economic, moral and social rehabilitation. It has therefore been thought unnecessary to repeat in this study the description of the co-operative distributive network given in the preceding volume. It will be enough to complement it where necessary, for instance, to show some affinity between a particular aspect of the activity or functioning of consumers' co-operative organisations and this or that feature of some of the problems of rehabilitation or reconstruction. Lastly, the first two parts of the preceding study, containing a general survey of the co-operative movement, of its principles and methods, of its various forms, and of its distribution throughout the world, may be regarded as common to both studies. For without these general data and this comprehensive survey, it would be difficult to form a sound idea of the place of co-operative institutions in the post-war effort in general—in rehabilitation and 1 I.L.O.: Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief (Studies and Reports, Series H (Co-operation), No. 4, Montreal, 1944). 5 2 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS reconstruction as well as in immediate relief operations, since the nature and extent of their role clearly depend on their particular character, on their fitness for certain functions, and on their degree of development and geographical distribution. The task of rehabilitation is even greater and more complex than that of relief. It comprises a much larger number of problems. It concerns many more countries: not only those requiring relief, but, to some extent, all, or nearly all others. It covers a far longer period of time, as the work of rehabilitation extending and accompanying relief measures prepares the way for long-term programmes which must try to inaugurate a new stage in human progress in a world already psychologically, socially and economically transformed by the war. Neither rehabilitation nor reconstruction means a complete restoration of the past, and it is in the first effort of rehabilitation that the relationships, habits, outlook, methods and institutions of the future will be formed and established. No attempt, of course, is made here to tackle the whole complex of problems which constitute the task of rehabilitation and reconstruction. But to a still greater degree than in the organisation of immediate relief, any recovery programme must count, for the solution of certain problems, on the responsible collective effort of the organised elements of the population represented by the people's voluntary institutions. T o the solution of some of these problems co-operative organisations of many kinds offer necessary, useful or possible forms of help. The present study is limited to a study of such problems under those of their aspects which lend themselves to co-operative action. In this confronting of co-operative methods with some major problems, reference will not be confined to the types of co-operative organisation which have already attained a high degree of development and are prepared to make an important contribution. Mention will sometimes be made of less known and even less developed types, where these seem to contain a new idea in harmony with what can be discerned of the economic tendencies or social aspirations of t h e modern world. Only the future can tell whether these beginnings will prove fruitful. But what was the co-operative movement a century ago, and, in most countries, as little as twenty-five years ago ? The problems of rehabilitation and reconstruction are not always the same, in all their features, for every country. Obviously, too, the nature or importance of the contribution that co-operative organisation can make to their solution varies in the same way. Some of the matters dealt with in this study concern all countries indiscriminately. Others are of interest rather to countries of a INTRODUCTION 3 particular category or categories: countries which have taken an effective part in war operations, countries which have considerably altered or intensified their wartime agricultural or industrial production, countries which have been a theatre of war, countries which have been subjected to blockade or counter-blockade, even countries which, though not involved in the struggle, have felt many repercussions from it in their economic life and perhaps in their social development. Some of the chapters are more specially directed to the problems peculiar to the industrially backward countries, but not every factor in their situation has been considered. This study, like the preceding one, is mainly documentary in character and does not attempt to lay down a plan for the future. It is confined to providing material for the elaboration or execution of whatever plans are made. The facts and evaluations making up this material have been derived from the observation of recent events. Besides reflecting the state of affairs at a given moment, they reflect the information currently available to the International Labour Office. In other words, they are only partly complete. As regards certain points and certain countries, they could not be completed because of present circumstances; in other cases, they could only have been completed by excessively long and problematical research. It seemed better to have some gaps in a documentation which was otherwise generally sufficient than to have a more perfect documentation too late to be of use. While the study does not claim to put forward a solution to every problem, it is not limited to providing facts and figures. When occasion arises, the opportunity is taken to describe briefly some solution that has been attempted with success or to call attention to attitudes or tendencies that seem significant, or even to plans and projects, if they help to throw light on future possibilities. The study, so conceived, deals with three classes of problem. Part I analyses the possibilities of co-operative action in the restoration of basic economic functions: agricultural production, fisheries, housing, transport, power, etc. Part II is devoted to some of the social problems of rehabilitation: employment, improvement of standards of living, democratic management of the economy. The third and last part examines the conditions under which and the forms in which the co-operative movement can most effectively contribute to the solution of some of the problems of the present and of the immediate future. A simple index, mostly of countries and forms of co-operative, has been added for purposes of easy reference. 5 PARTI Restoration of Basic Economic Functions 5 CHAPTER I FOOD AND AGRICULTURE Means of Agricultural Production From the task of relieving famine and disease and of supplying the most urgent needs for clothing and shelter, it will be necessary to pass—even before that task is accomplished—to the replenishment of Europe's farms with the requisites of agricultural production: feeding stuffs and fertilisers, seeds, tools and machinery, livestock, fuel and other commodities. Before the war, Europe (including the U.S.S.R.) was estimated to be responsible for 46.2 per cent, of the world production of foodstuffs and 24.2 per cent, of that of textile fibres. But the domestic production of food and other farm products has fallen off in a number of European countries as a result of war conditions, and in some instances the reduction is serious. It was estimated that Belgium, Greece, and Norway were unlikely to achieve more than two fifths of their normal volume by the time the war ended, and that production in France and the Netherlands would have been reduced by almost a half. This falling off is due to a number of causes: lack of labour (even, in certain cases, the physical weakness of the workers), transport difficulties, destruction of buildings .and machinery, shortage of agricultural requisites, etc. Among all these factors consideration will be given here only to the shortage of requisites, including machinery. Everywhere, and particularly in countries which had a highly specialised agriculture dependent on large imports of feeding stuffs and fertilisers, there will be a pressing need for these commodities if production is to be rapidly increased and brought to the highest possible level. An indication of the extent of the deficit is given by the considerable decline which has taken place in the volume of trade of the Co-operative Fertiliser Supply Society and the feeding stuffs societies in Denmark. These societies, supplying as they do a large number of agriculturists and holding an important place on the market, have always provided an excellent means of measuring the country's agricultural activities. The 5 8 CO-OPßRATION AND PRßSENT-DAY PROBLEMS volume of trade of the Co-operative Fertiliser Supply Society fell from an average of 274.9 million kg a year in 1936-1940 to not much more than half that amount, i.e., 157.6 million kg in 1942; that of the feeding stuffs societies fell still more spectacularly, from 783.2 million kg in 1936-1940 to only 92.4 million kg in 1941-42. This experience, easily measurable in the case of Denmark, has been shared by many other countries of Europe, neutral as well as liberated. In regard to seeds, the Technical Advisory Committee on Agriculture of the Inter-Allied Committee on Post-War Requirements has reported on the probable post-war seed requirements of the Allied countries of Europe, considered from the point of view of helping Europe to feed itself. It has recommended that provision should be made for a probable deficit of rather over one million tons of seed, including cereals, seed potatoes, pasture and garden seeds. The situation is particularly serious with respect to livestock: Occupied Europe already has lost one third of its horses, one fourth of its cattle, almost half its hogs, one third of its sheep. Moreover, the stock that survives is diseased and malnourished—unfit for breeding. The decline will continue to the end of the war.1 It is estimated that it will take five or six, or even as many as ten years to restore herds to their pre-war level. Owing to shortage of shipping space, the possibility is being investigated of speeding recovery through improved veterinary services, the import of breeding animals, and the extensive use of artificial insemination. The Technical Advisory Committee has also given consideration to the provision of agricultural implements and machinery. In addition to feeding stuffs, fertilisers, seeds, and machinery, there will be a need for minor requisites, such as packing materials, binder twine, and insecticides, and also for certain less specifically agricultural items, namely, petroleum products, coal, cement, and timber. The Inter-Allied Committee on Post-War Requirements has reported to the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration (UNRRA) that in addition to over 9J4 million tons of food, it will be necessary to ship more than 41 % million tons of coal, metals, oil, animal feeds, fertiliser; and clothing to nine newly liberated countries alone over a six months' period. It is suggested that this amount of supplies, together with a year of normal crops, should suffice to set Europe on its feet again. With the agricultural 1 Herbert H. LEHMAN: "Agriculture's Postwar Job", in Country Gentleman (Philadelphia), June 1943. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 9 requisites, as with food, clothing, and medicaments, the question arises how they may be distributed to those needing them in the most rapid, efficient, and economical way. RURAL SUPPLY CO-OPERATIVE ORGANISATIONS One appropriate channel will clearly be the organisations of farmers themselves, more particularly those which have been established expressly to effect the distribution of farm supplies. Beginning in the 1880's, the agriculturists of Europe have gradually built up an extensive network of rural supply co-operatives. This network is their own and under their direct management, and therefore stands available to meet their requirements exactly. The network comprises a number of highly specialised cooperatives dealing with particular agricultural requisites. For instance, in 1942 there were in Denmark 1,567 societies for the supply of feeding stuffs and 1,516 societies for the purchase of fertilisers. And before the war, there were in Europe at least 7,818 societies1 for the selection and supply of livestock, as well as 4,465 societies2 for the purchase (for sale or hire to members) of machines. However, the most widely distributed type of agricultural cooperative society naturally adapted to playing a part in the distribution of agricultural requisites is the non-specialised purchase and sale co-operative. 3 According to pre-war statistics there are more than 44,500 such co-operative societies serving rural areas in Europe (excluding the U.S.S.R.). This estimate may be regarded as low, since the figures refer only to federated societies. In 1937 there were altogether over 46,000 non-specialised purchase and sale co-operative societies in Europe (excluding the U.S.S.R.). 4 In addition, about one third of Europe's 65,775 rural credit co-operative societies and one half (24,000 out of 42,325) of the specialised marketing co-operatives render their members an additional service by making available to them such supplies as seeds, feeding stuffs, fertilisers, and some implements. Altogether, therefore, there are in Europe (excluding the U.S.S.R.) somewhere in the region of 107,000 agricultural cooperative societies with distributive functions in regard to agricultural requisites, that is, well over half the total number (188,000) 1 land. 2 In 6 countries: Finland, Germany, Latvia, Luxembourg, Sweden, Switzer- In 9 countries: Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Latvia, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Yugoslavia. 3 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., p. 68. 4 Cf. I.L.O.: Co-operative Societies throughout the World: Numerical Data (Geneva, 1939), p. 42. Reprinted from International Labour Review, Vol. XL, Nos. 2 and 3, Aug. and Sept. 1939, pp. 254-271 and 375-419. 5 10 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS of European agricultural co-operatives (excluding rural insurance societies). To these must be added some 2,000 rural consumers' co-operative societies in Hungary, over 400 consumers' societies affiliated to the Finnish Co-operative Wholesale Society (S.O.K.), and some 260 rural consumers' co-operatives in Switzerland, all of which supply their members with agricultural requisites (and also articles of domestic consumption), as is also done by a considerable number of consumers' co-operatives active in the rural areas of other European countries. 1 Including such consumers' co-operatives, there are perhaps some 109,660 societies in Europe with distributive functions in the field of supply. In the U.S.S.R. 2 , there were 28,000 rural consumers' co-operatives, with a membership of more than 36,000,000, in 1940, serving the needs of almost the entire rural population. No doubt the European network of rural supply co-operatives as a whole, built up through persevering efforts over a long span of years, is susceptible, in some countries, of fresh development, in the direction either of geographic extension or of improved service. Nevertheless, the few figures given in the foregoing paragraphs show that it has already attained a considerable density. The network, in addition to being a fairly close one, is effective in operation, and the data given below testify to the large—and sometimes very large—part that the rural supply co-operatives of various kinds have played in the agricultural requisites trade. Feeding Stuffs and Fertilisers It is not possible to determine the exact proportion of the trade in feeding stuffs and fertilisers handled by co-operative organisations in each one of the different European countries. Nevertheless, the following table, which gives such data as are available, sufficiently indicates the importance of co-operative trade in these two fields. Except for Great Britain, where the agricultural co-operative movement is far less developed than the consumers' movement is, or than the agricultural co-operative movement in most other European countries, between 40 and 80 per cent, (and in two instances as high a proportion as 90 and 100 per cent.) of the national trade in one or the other commodity is in co-operative hands. It is not unlikely that in most of the other European countries the co-operative organisations would be found 1 Consumers' co-operatives functioning in rural districts could also, as an emergency measure, undertake the distribution of agricultural requisites even where they do not normally deal in them. In some countries consumers' cooperative wholesale organisations have entered the rural supply field, often in order to dispose of by-products of the milling of grains and oils. 2 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 108-109. 11 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE to control a similarly high proportion of the supply of feeding stuffs and fertilisers. In all instances the figures relate to the years before the present war. TABLE I. PERCENTAGE OF NATIONAL TRADE IN FEEDING STUFFS AND FERTILISERS HANDLED BY CO-OPERATIVE ORGANISATIONS CountryDenmark Estonia Finland Germany Great Britain5 Latvia Lithuania Netherlands Sweden Switzerland 1 Of imports. Feeding stuffs Fertilisers 67' 80' 40-60 13 80 40 80' 40-60 61.3 40 so 6 90 100 64.6 40 60 ' England only. In Denmark, feeding stuffs and fertilisers are distributed by specialised organisations dealing in each of those products. The 1,500 Danish feeding stuffs societies hold registrations for 762,500 cows, representing more than 50 per cent, of the total number of cows in the country; a similar number of fertiliser societies had a volume of trade in 1940 of nearly 290 million kg, which was, however, reduced to 157.6 million kg in 1942 owing to the cutting off of imports and other wartime difficulties. Before the war (1938), the five unions of the Netherlands co-operative agricultural associations supplied farmers with 898,000 tons of fertilisers and 783,000 tons of feeding stuffs; one of them, the Co-operative Supply Society of the Dutch Co-operative Agricultural Associations (Centraal Bureau) in Rotterdam, was the largest importer of maize, of which .it imported some 200,000 tons annually, and one of the chief importers of artificial fertilisers, with an annual turnover of 100,000 tons of potash and 150,000 tons of nitrate. In Norway, where between 50 and 60 per cent, of all farmers are members of general agricultural co-operative societies, the Felleskjöpet Wholesale Society, the most important of the district wholesale societies of the agricultural co-operative movement, supplied its members with 74,000 tons of fodder and 62,000 tons of fertiliser in 1941. The Union of East Switzerland Co-operative Agricultural Societies, which has at times accounted for as much as 50 per cent, of the fertiliser business in Switzerland, supplied fodder to the value of 10 million francs1 and fertiliser to the value » In 1942, 7.7 million francs. 2 8 12 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS of 4 million francs in 1941. Some 80 Swiss pasture co-operative societies also contribute t o the supply of fodder. In regard to the activities of consumers' wholesale societies in the feed and fertiliser business, mention may be made of the poultry feeding stuffs plant of the Danish Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society (F.D.B.) ; of the oil mill for pressing cattle food of the English Co-operative Wholesale Society, which in 1937 supplied 150 affiliated associations with farm and farm home supplies valued at £2J^ million; and of the oil refinery and feeding stuffs factory of the Swedish Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society (Kooperativa Förbundet). The Acid-Fodder Association set up by the Swedish Co-operative Union has recently made contracts with the Swedish cellulose factories for the supply of cellulose fodder, in view of the shortage of imported feed and the reduced output of the Union's productive works. Since 1929, the Union has also owned a superphosphate plant near Stockholm, with a pre-war production of half a million bags annually, representing one quarter of the country's demand. The plant was leased by the Co-operative Union to the National Union of Swedish Farmers. In order to alleviate the wartime scarcity of fertilisers, the Union has recently established plants for the production of phosphate and nitrate fertilisers. In Switzerland, an association (formerly a department of the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society of Switzerland) dealing with the purchase of agricultural products, fertilisers, and fodder had a trade of 22.6 million francs in 1942, 4 million francs of which were for fodder. The consumers' co-operative movement in Finland owns a fertiliser plant. Seeds It may be assumed t h a t practically all non-specialised rural supply co-operatives and rural consumers' co-operatives furnish their members with seeds, most of which would be selected or improved seeds. Sometimes the co-operatives are big suppliers: in Finland, for instance, 75 per cent, of the demand for seed was met by co-operative organisations in 1937; in the same year local purchase associations in the Netherlands supplied over 15,250 tons of seeds and plants. The demand for high-quality seeds has led co-operative organisations in a number of countries to enter the field of seed production. Thus, in Czechoslovakia, there was a seed association {Selecta) with its own testing and experimental services and a network of seed-raising stations; in Denmark, a seed production and marketing society (with a trade of more than 20 million crowns in 1942); in Finland, the Hankkija Agricultural Co-operative Wholesale POOD AND AGRICULTURE 13 Society before the war operated the only selected seed production centre in the country; in the Netherlands, the Centraal Bureau had its own station for the cultivation of seeds. From Great Britain has come the suggestion 1 that British farmers can help to meet the post-war demands of the continent for seeds, seed corn, and seed potatoes, and that British agricultural co-operative societies should be organised and equipped in advance to carry out this important work. There are six co-operative seedgrowing societies a t present established in Wales. 2 Farm Implements and Machinery There has been a heavy loss of machines on European farms, due to a number of causes, including military destruction, confiscation, removal, lack of replacements, non-repair, abnormal deterioration through shortage of lubricants. Parallel with this loss of machines there has been a loss of draught animals, which will often be more readily replaced by machinery than by other animals. The war will also have occasioned a serious lack of manpower on European farms, through war casualties, deaths from disease, loss of physical strength and efficiency among the population generally, and other causes. Part of the rural population is also likely to be engaged for some time on urgent works of reconstruction (rebuilding of roads, bridges, railways, houses, etc.). If production is not to be hampered, machines will have to replace the missing men. This shortage of farm machines may even be intensified by certain projects for the reorientation or improvement of agriculture aiming at or entailing a more intensive use of mechanisation than heretofore. These considerations suggest the necessity of making the best possible use of the machines that are available. It is unlikely that the supply will equal the demand for a considerable time, and some form of rationing will be necessary. Individual use of machines in a time of scarcity means that they stand idle; their collective use, on the other hand, under a planned system of rotation, brings them into full productivity. Apart from this practical physical advantage, it is desirable, in the difficult period of restoration, to avoid a situation in which there would be privileged individuals enjoying a priority in the purchase or use of machines that are necessary to all or nearly all agri1 Cf. J. W. HEWITT: The Co-operative Supply of Agricultural Requirements. Paper read at a Conference on Co-operative Systems in European Agriculture, held by the British Association for the Advancement of Science, in London on 16-17 April 1943. Reprinted in Year Book of Agricultural Co-operation 1943-44 (Manchester, 1944), pp. 26-30. * Two for seed potatoes, two for seed oats, and two for red clover seed. 5 14 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS culturists. The collective use of farm machines was already firmly established before the war, and in many countries organisations for this purpose exist, together with organisations which aim at making machinery available on an individual basis to small agriculturists (who would otherwise be unable to obtain it). The provision of agricultural implements to make up for losses suffered during the war has been considered by the Technical Advisory Committee on Agriculture of the Inter-Allied Committee on Post-War Requirements. 1 While in countries which normally produce their own machinery the main necessity will be to restart the industry, there are other countries into which all but the simpler implements had to be imported before the war. It is frequently the case that in these countries the loss of draught animals may necessitate a great increase in the use of mechanical cultivation. In this connection the Committee has considered the co-operative use of machinery to get small farms into full production as quickly as possible, on lines suggested by the experience of the British war agricultural committees with the operation of farm machinery on a collective basis. The Governments of Czechoslovakia, France 2 , Greece, Poland, and Yugoslavia, in submitting to the Inter-Allied Committee their estimates for the number of tractors and other machines required, all stated their intention to use them either on a collective or on a co-operative basis. An American writer has made the suggestion that the military vehicles known as "jeeps", when no longer required for military purposes, should be used by European farmers to help to solve problems of transport and haulage. 3 According to the manufacturer, however, the vehicles would have to be geared down for civilian use. Many of the 46,000 rural co-operative supply societies not only buy feeding stuffs and fertilisers to meet their members' needs, but also purchase ordinary agricultural implements and machinery for sale to individual members or for hiring out to the membership on a collective basis. In a good many countries this function has grown so much in importance that the machine departments of the general rural co-operative societies have become detached and constitute distinct societies, or special machinery co-operatives have been established. The following table gives the most recent data available on such specialised societies alone, in European countries. 1 1 Cf. International Labour Review, Vol. XLVIII, No. 1, July 1943, p. 68. Cf. André DuLiN: Systems of Co-operation in Pre-War France and their Post-War Expansion. Paper read at a Conference on Co-operative Systems in European Agriculture, held by the British Association for the Advancement of Science, in London on 16-17 April 1943. Reprinted in Year Book of Agricultural Co-operation 1943-44, pp. 43-51. * Bertram FOWLBR: "Food, Jeeps and Co-ops", in Common Sense (New York), June 1943. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 15 TABLE II. MACHINE CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES IN NINE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Country Estonia Finland France Latvia Germany Lithuania Netherlands Switzerland Yugoslavia Year Number of societies 1937 1937 1939 1938 1936 1939 1937 1942 1933 283 450 1,850 236 800 125 258 399 64 4,465 Total In certain countries these societies have even developed special federations. This has been the case, for instance, in Estonia, in France (where the National Federation of Threshing Associations and Co-operative Societies had 670 affiliated societies in 1937), and in Germany. In Hungary, the Co-operative Wholesale and Productive Society of the Farmers' Union (Hangya), and in Finland, the Hankkija have special sections for machinery. A further stage is the co-operative manufacture of machinery for agriculture and the dairy industry. In Denmark, for instance, there is a Co-operative Dairy Societies' Joint Purchase and Engineering Works, with over 1,500 members (societies and individuals) and a turnover of more than 10 million crowns. Agricultural machinery is also manufactured by co-operative organisations in Estonia (Wholesale Society E.T.K.), Finland, and Great Britain (Engineering and Dairy Equipment Factory of the Co-operative Wholesale Society). In Sweden, the Co-operative Union acquired an agricultural machine factory in 1943, in which year its sales of agricultural machinery doubled, from 500,000 to 1 million crowns. Outside Europe, mention may be made of the National Farm Machinery Co-operative Inc., comprising co-operative organisations in the United States and Canada, which could perhaps make some contribution to Europe's need for tractors and other farm machinery. The available information does not permit of anything like a complete picture of the role of co-operative organisations in the agricultural machinery trade in many countries. The following data, however, relating to Finland and the Baltic States only, tend to show that, in certain countries at least, co-operative organisations occupied an important place in the trade in agricultural machinery: Estonia, 50 per cent, of total imports; Finland, 75-90 per cent, of total demand ; Latvia, 65-70 per cent, of total demand 2 8 * 5 16 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS (85-90 per cent, for dairy machinery); Lithuania, 80 per cent, of total demand. Livestock A contribution to the task of replenishing European livestock can bt expected from the co-operative stock-breeding societies or associations whose object is to place at the disposal of smallholders high-class sires too expensive to be acquired by most individuals. Such co-operative organisations are numerous and wellestablished in the principal stock-raising countries, particularly in Finland, Germany, Latvia, Luxembourg, Sweden, and Switzerland. 1 The activities of these organisations are assisted by their own or public veterinary services2 or, in the dairy countries, are closely associated with the work of the milk-testing societies or associations. It is likely that the stocks of these organisations are practically exhausted or in bad condition. Nevertheless, it would seem that the rebuilding of these collective stocks with the least possible delay would be the most efficient means of replenishing European livestock herds, and would certainly be superior to any attempt at replenishment on an individual basis. Possibly these co-operatives, or some of them, could be converted into artificial breeding co-operative societies, on the model of the associations of this type which have sprung up, particularly in the United States, in the course of the last few years. Indeed, the suggestion has been made in the co-operative press in the United States' that such co-operatives could despatch semen to Europe by aeroplane. Should this suggestion prove practicable and be carried into effect, with European co-operative organisations as the receiving agencies, this novel form of inter-co-operative relations would do much to hasten the process of re-establishing the much needed production of milk in European countries. 4 Miscellaneous Requisites Less important than feed, fertiliser, and seeds, but nevertheless worthy of brief mention, are cement and minor agricultural requisites, such as binder twine and straw board used for packing. 5 1 1 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., p. 71. The Yugoslav health co-operative societies, which from 1934 onwards undertook the organisation of veterinary sections, began in 1938, in collaboration with stock-breeding co-operatives, to establish special veterinary co-operatives. * Cf. Pennsylvania Co-operative Review, June 1944. ' Similarly, it has been suggested that hatching eggs might be shipped by boat or aeroplane from the United States to European agricultural co-operative organisations which would serve as centres for the establishment of co-operative hatcheries. 6 In view of its importance and special characteristics, the problem of supplying the countryside with fuel and motive power requires separate treatment and is not dealt with here. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 17 The following examples illustrate the part of co-operative organisations in providing these requirements. In Denmark, the Co-operative Cement Works normally supplied 680,000 bags of cement annually to its 1,400 member societies, while in Lithuania nearly 60 per cent, of the demand for cement was met by the Central Union of Agricultural Co-operative Societies before the war. The Co-operative Wholesale Society of Danish Distributive Societies (F.D.B.) was producing 1,000 tons of binder twine annually before the war, and though this amount represented less than 20 per cent, of the country's requirements, the Society controlled the price of binder twine in Denmark; the Society also owns a tannery and a harness factory. There is a rope and twine works among the numerous productive enterprises of the English Co-operative Wholesale Society. The Netherlands possessed 9 co-operative straw-board factories that together accounted for about 60 per cent, of the national production of straw board, most of which was exported, especially to England. As already observed, the various types of rural supply co-operative organisations in Europe were equipped for and accustomed to the handling of import business. Some of them, indeed, were by far the largest importers of agricultural requisites in their respective countries. A number of co-operative organisations in countries outside the European continent are in a position to participate in the rehabilitation of agricultural production in Europe and may be all the more inclined to do so if their contribution passes through European co-operative channels. Mention has already been made of the possibility that British agricultural co-operatives might help to meet demands for seeds, seed corn, and seed potatoes, while some rope and twine might be contributed by the English Co-operative Wholesale Society. Some assistance might also be expected from agricultural co-operative organisations in Ireland. 1 But it is from co-operative organisations overseas, more particularly those in the United States and Canada, that the major contribution can be looked for. Farmers' marketing organisations could supply seeds, seedlings, and livestock, while the regional co-operative wholesale associations (which mostly serve the farm population) could supply fodder, fertilisers, implements, insecticides, twine, and so forth. These societies and the National Farm Machinery Co-operative Inc. 2 could contribute agricultural machines, including tractors. 1 Co-operatives in continental countries relatively less affected by the war, such as Sweden and Switzerland, may also perhaps be able to contribute agricultural requisites to countries having a greater need. 1 See above, p. 15. 5 18 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS The 108,000-110,000 European co-operatives dealing in agricultural requisites are widely dispersed and can therefore reach even remote villages and districts. At the same time they themselves are easily accessible through the various federations or central organisations in the different countries. The process of fédéralisation has also been carried into the international field. Since 1929, the central organisations of rural purchasing co-operatives in Belgium, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Estonia, the Netherlands, and Sweden have been associated in an International Co-operative Agricultural Purchasing Society (Intercoop) with headquarters in Rotterdam in the Netherlands. This system of co-operative organisation, made up of numerous and geographically well distributed entities, has in many instances achieved a high degree of technical development. Built up over a long period of years, it did not reach its present position without difficulties and sacrifices or without good reasons. European agriculturists set up for themselves co-operative supply societies in part to reduce their costs of production and often because they mistrusted the quality of the goods supplied through ordinary commercial channels. Mutual association was their defence against fraud and also their means of access to technical progress. The same motives which prompted the establishment of these organisations suggest t h a t they should be used in the tasks of rehabilitation, and also that measures should be taken to extend the network wherever that seems necessary. Agricultural Credit In order to obtain the means of agricultural production and to bridge the gap between planting and harvest, farmers and peasants will need credits. Particularly well suited to the provision of such short-term credit are the rural credit co-operative societies, though this is not the limit of their usefulness, as they also have a part to play in the provision of medium-term credit. Attention was drawn to their indispensable role as far back as 1927 by the World Economic Conference held by the League of Nations in Geneva. A special resolution of the Conference defined this role in the following terms: The increase of agricultural production is intimately bound up with the organisation of agricultural credit, which will place at the disposal of agriculturists the necessary capital on favourable terms. . . The first condition for surmounting these difficulties [of making adequate provision for agricultural credit) is the organisation of suitable credit institutions in those countries where they do not yet exist and their development where they 19 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE are already in existence. The best form of institution appears t o be the co-operative credit society operating by means of resources which the very fact of association enables it to procure and to increase with or without the assistance of the public authorities. It is, moreover, by the co-operation of national organisations t h a t the effective guarantees for appeals for credit, whether national or international, can be most easily procured. 1 RURAL CREDIT CO-OPERATIVES IN EUROPE The rural credit co-operatives are extremely well distributed over Europe. There are more co-operatives of this single type than of any other and they account for more than one third of the total number of agricultural co-operative societies of all types in Europe. The rural credit societies today cover more than 8J^ million holdings in some twenty-five European countries. The following table gives the number and membership of such societies in 1937.2 TABLE III. NUMBER AND MEMBERSHIP OF EUROPEAN RURAL CREDIT SOCIETIES Country Austria Belgium ;. .. . Bulgaria Czechoslovakia Danzig Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland (including Northern Ireland) Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Netherlands Poland Rumania Sweden Switzerland Turkey Yugoslavia Total No. of societies Membership 1,839 1,165 1,899 6,080 51 100 242 1,179 10,550 18,121 4,327 1,008 90 2,372 325 268 71 1,299 3,736 4,638 816 640 663 65,762 4,283 315,535 98,492 216,538 1,440,784 3,357 21,356 105,443 147,500 586,372 1,997,382 193,901 421,507 8,899 481,742 130,275 94,607 8,576 214,001 816,007 905,420 93,200 59,509 107,324 8,882,372 414,645 1 LEAGUE OF NATIONS: The World Economic Conference. Final Report (Series L.O.N. Publications, 1927, I I . 46(a), Geneva, 1927). * Cf. I.L.O.: Co-operative Societies throughout the World: Numerical Data (Geneva, 1939), op. cit. 5 20 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS These figures relating to the pre-war period are sufficient to give an idea of the European network of rural credit co-operatives. More recent figures are available for a few countries, but do not always apply to the same political divisions, making comparison difficult. However, such figures as are available point to a decrease in the number of rural credit co-operatives. It is known, for instance, that the number of such co-operatives has decreased in Germany (17,442 in 1942), apparently through a process of consolidation of societies which has been instituted since the outbreak of war. There also seems to have been a slight decrease in the number of credit societies in Ireland (81 in 1940), the Netherlands (801 in 1940), Sweden (748 in 1941), and Turkey (523 in 1944). However, the membership of the societies in these countries has grown. The number of societies increased in Bulgaria (2,117 in 1941), and both the number of societies and membership increased in Switzerland (704 societies with 66,149 members in 1941). T H E I R C H I E F CHARACTERISTICS The recent tendency exhibited in Germany towards amalgamation of rural credit co-operatives in order to form larger units is exceptional. Normally, the credit societies are quite small, with an average membership of from 130 to 140. Their small size, so far from being a sign of weakness, is generally regarded as one of their principal virtues and as a condition of their successful operation. It keeps them close to the people whom they serve and allows a simplicity which makes for very modest overhead expenses, easy administration and ready participation of the members in the conduct and supervision of the business. It must also be remembered that these are not ordinary credit institutions organising the provision of credit as they would any other business run to earn a living or to make profits. Credit cooperatives are at the service of their members, to meet their legitimate credit needs by the granting of loans which will bring them real and permanent advantage. Like any ordinary credit institution, the committee of a credit co-operative, when deciding whether to grant a request for a loan, must of course take every precaution and require full guarantee of its repayment. But the ordinary credit institution does not feel it has any responsibility towards the borrower; it can strictly limit itself to securing regular payment of interest and repayment of the principal, even if repayment should lead to the borrower's ruin. A credit co-operative, on the other hand, if it discharges its functions faithfully, will see that repayment is made possible by an improvement in the position of FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 21 the borrower resulting from the loan made. Thus co-operative credit, so far from being a factor in rural indebtedness, is the best protection against it. The careful examination of requests for loans has a further consequence: the advice given on such occasions and the special conditions sometimes imposed on the borrowers regarding their methods of cultivation constitute effective means of education and technical progress. Moreover, in all countries, and particularly in those where there is rural poverty, the rural credit societies have been valuable agencies for education in thrift and for the collection and utilisation of peasants' savings. In Czechoslovakia, for instance, the 6,000 pre-war rural credit co-operatives with nearly one and a half million members held about one third of the total savings deposits in the country. Through the rural credit co-operative societies the patiently gathered savings of the rural community are used within the community itself for its own benefit and under its own control. The savings deposits of the credit societies, coupled with their borrowing power based on the joint responsibility of their members, serve to satisfy the need for short-term credit, and, in part, that for medium-term credit (mostly by borrowing from higher institutions), among the rural population. The extent to which they satisfy this need may be gauged by some figures relating to the pre-war period. For instance, in Bulgaria 28 per cent., in Czechoslovakia 65 per cent., in Poland 25 per cent., in Rumania over 50 per cent., and in Yugoslavia 36 per cent, of the demands for agricultural credit (either short-term or as a whole) were met by co-operative organisations. It should be borne in mind that within each country the credit societies form an organised system through federation. Central banks, which serve as clearing houses for the transactions of the societies, provide medium-term and, to a fairly large extent, longterm credit. It is difficult to say to what extent the upper stories of this financial structure are still everywhere at the disposal of the local credit societies in certain countries. Nevertheless, it is the very simplicity of this machinery for credit, particularly in the basic lower units, which makes it so durable and constitutes the best guarantee of its power to remain in operation. There is no doubt, therefore, that it will be found worth while to take the necessary measures to set the rural credit societies firmly on their feet, so that they may be in a position to make the maximum contribution to the speedy restoration of European agriculture. 5 22 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS RURAL CREDIT CO-OPERATIVES AND THE STATE In assessing the measures necessary to restore to agriculture this essential instrument of its rehabilitation and organisation, regard must be had to the limitations imposed on the activity of rural credit co-operatives by the very conditions in which they operate. It is equally or perhaps even more important to consider the financial position in which many of them will be placed as a result of the war. The conditions under which local rural credit co-operatives operate "are such that they must generally confine themselves to the provision of short-term credit and, to a less extent varying with each country, of medium-term credit. It is to be anticipated that for a fairly long period the agriculture of certain countries will have a great need of medium and long-term credit, whether for the restoration of war-devastated holdings (dwellings and other buildings, soil, livestock, implements), or in order to carry out, with some chance of success, the long-term transformation (shift from one type of production or system of cultivation to another, mechanisation, agrarian reforms) implied in the plans of agricultural reorganisation contemplated for certain regions. It is not even sure t h a t rural credit co-operatives will be ready immediately, in every European country, to satisfy the short-term credit needs of their members out of their own resources. It is indeed likely that these resources will have been more or less seriously impaired by outright or disguised depredations, by repercussions of the economic situation, inflation, and so on. It will clearly be for the State to use its political and administrative resources to help the rural credit co-operatives to recover the funds and other property taken from them. It is to the State, too, that they will probably turn for the advances they require, as it is doubtful whether they will be able to get them from the general banking system, which has itself been badly shaken and will have many heavy calls upon it. In France, for example, the Provisional Government 1 has already decided to extend financial assistance (up to 3,000 million francs) for the restoration of agricultural and rural undertakings, in the shape of loans to agriculturists, agricultural co-operatives and other agricultural associations, and rural artisans. However, the advances are not made directly to the individuals or bodies concerned, but are placed at the disposal of the central organ of the credit co-operative movement in France, the National Institute for Rural Credit, which is responsible for their distribution. 1 Journal officiel de la République française, 17 Oct. 1944. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 23 Such a procedure was not uncommon before the present war and it will very probably continue in the future. A varied and long experience has shown that the State, while able t o assess general needs and situations, is badly placed for making direct loans to individuals. It lacks the machinery (or has to build up a cumbersome and costly machinery) for judging accurately the real needs of each applicant and the urgency of his claim vis-à-vis the others, for forming an estimate of each borrower's solvency, for controlling the use to which each loan is put, and for fixing or varying judiciously the date of its repayment. If the loan granted is not large enough, it may be without real utility. If it is too generous, it will do harm by weighing too heavily on weak shoulders. Large or small, it will be harmful if in the long run it leaves the borrower poorer and less capable of obtaining credit than before: overindebtedness is often the result of a faulty extension of credit. Finally, if the loan is not repaid, the State will have the politically embarrassing choice either of distraining upon its debtor or else, if it neglects to do so, of perhaps demoralising conscientious debtors and giving encouragement to the habit of non-repayment. On the other hand, the small rural credit co-operatives are excellently placed for forming an exact estimate of requirements, for exercising proper control and for distributing credit prudently and with a full knowledge of the facts,, since they are close to the needs to be satisfied and since the members of a society all know each other and are jointly responsible for its debts (which more often than not are secured on the whole of their property). It is for this reason that in a large number of countries the State passes through them the permanent credits (especially for a long term) and the occasional credits (to deal with a crisis or to serve some particular project) which it extends to agriculture. The efforts of the State to organise agricultural credit and those of the rural co-operatives are often so closely linked that they meet in a common institution that is at once a public body and the national centre of the credit co-operatives. The structure of such institutions may be even more complicated, since it may comprise other agricultural and credit co-operatives, handicraftsmen's co-operatives and even consumers' co-operatives in addition to the State and the rural credit co-operatives. The State participates either directly or through the bank of issue or in some other indirect manner in the setting up of the share capital or in the maintenance of the working capital of the institution. It also has a share in its management. These mixed credit institutions were found before the war under S 24 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS widely varying forms, in the following European countries: Bulgaria, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Lithuania, Poland, Rumania, and Turkey. There were also examples of them in places outside Europe, among others in Algeria, Iran, Japan, Madagascar, Mexico, Morocco, and the Union of South Africa. The Finnish and French Systems While there is no need here to go into details of structure and function, it may perhaps be useful to describe briefly two systems of agricultural credit organisation, those of Finland and France, which differ quite widely from each other and are at the same time typical enough to give an idea of how there may be a conjunction of the resources and methods of the State and those of co-operative organisation to meet the credit needs of European agriculture during the rehabilitation period. The Finnish system of agricultural credit has been organised from the top downwards and, a t the beginning, without any collaboration by rural people, who were too poor to start local credit co-operative societies themselves. The first step was the creation, in 1902,.of a Central Bank of the Co-operative Agricultural Societies, for which the initial capital was found by a group of private persons interested in the future formation of local credit societies. In addition, the Bank received from the State an advance of four million Finnish marks at a low rate of interest and an annual grant of Fmk. 20,000 for a period of 10 years. The first intervention of the State thus took place before the existence of any local credit co-operatives, but with a view to their establishment. During the ten-year period 1902-1912 local credit co-operative societies developed satisfactorily in the most depressed districts. From 1920 onwards, the local societies, having been granted permission to receive savings from non-members, multiplied their deposits many times over. 1 After 1925 the main activity of the societies was the granting of long-term loans out of a fund of Fmk. 103 million granted to the Central Bank by the State for that purpose. The intention of the founders of the Central Bank was that their financial aid and that of the State should only be temporary. Its by-laws accordingly provided that shares subscribed by private persons should be progressively redeemed by the local credit societies in proportion to the amount of the loans granted to them by the Bank. This redemption was completed in eight to ten years, but towards the end of this period the State began to be a shareholder in the Bank along with the local credit societies. However, 1 Between 1915 and 1920 they multiplied nearly 25 times; between 1915 and 1930 more than 1,100 times. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 25 the share of the State decreased as that of the societies grew larger. By the end of 1938 the credit societies had contributed Fmk. 15,000,000 against the State's Fmk. 25,000,000. In 1943, the State's share was still Fmk. 25,000,000 but the capital of the Bank had risen to Fmk. 90,000,000. Apart from share capital, the resources of the Bank consist of deposits of the credit societies (11.5 per cent.), loans from the State's Public Treasury a t a low rate of interest or free of interest (20 per cent.), and loans from the Bank of Finland and the Postal Savings Funds and State-guaranteed short-term foreign loans (68 per cent.). In view of this direct or indirect financial dependence of the Central Bank on the State, the latter exercises a certain amount of influence on the Bank's management, but has been careful not to invade it unduly. It has retained only a limited internal control; it has power to appoint three members of the board of directors, but it has only six votes in the general meeting—the maximum any shareholder may hold. External supervision, on the contrary, is fully exercised : auditing of the credit societies was done by the Central Union of Finnish Co-operative Societies until 1939, and since that date has been in the hands of special auditing officers appointed by the Government. The Central Bank, though strongly supported by the State, is therefore not a purely State agency, but an institution of mixed character, in which the State and co-operatives collaborate until the latter are in a position to manage it entirely themselves. In France, agricultural credit has been organised from the bottom upwards, so as to be in close contact with agriculturists requiring loans, which are granted chiefly in consideration of the character and professional ability of the borrowers. At the same time it enjoys some financial support from the State and is subject to a certain degree of State supervision. This combination of influences explains the three-storied structure of the French rural credit system. This characteristic feature consists of private bodies on the two lower levels and a public institution a t the top, viz.: (a) local societies, (b) regional funds, and (c) the National Institute for Rural Credit. Members of local societies must be either individual agriculturists or agricultural associations (collective members). They supply the share capital. Most of the societies have limited liability, but some have unlimited liability, which the law allows. They accept savings deposits from any person, whether a member or not, and use these and other resources to make loans to their members for agricultural purposes. Applications for loans beyond their means are forwarded by them to the regional funds. The local societies are managed by an elected board of directors who receive no remuneration for their services. 5 26 CO-OPBRATION AND PRESBNT-DAY PROBLEMS The regional funds, which numbered 98 in 1938, are essentially associations of local societies, but individual agriculturists and agricultural groups or associations may also be affiliated. By law two thirds of the shares of regional funds are reserved to local credit societies. When set up, their capital may not be reduced below the original amount at foundation nor below the amount on which any advance received from the State has been calculated. Advances obtainable from the State are in proportion to the paidup capital of the regional fund. In the regional funds the number of votes of a member at a general meeting was equal to the number of shares held, but with a maximum of 4-5 votes for any shareholder (mostly collective members). Regional funds had power: (a) to grant advances to their affiliated credit societies to set up or supplement their working capital; (b) to discount notes subscribed by members of the local societies and endorsed by the latter; (c) to receive deposits in the form of current accounts and issue bonds (to a value not exceeding three fourths of the bills in hand) ; (d) to invest in stock (under strict regulations) or deposit in postal savings banks the unused part of their resources; (e) to supervise the operations of the local credit societies connected with them. Regional funds receiving advances from the State had to keep their books in accordance with very detailed regulations issued by the Department of Agriculture and to submit to supervision by inspectors of finance. At the head of the system was the National Institute for Rural Credit, which was an administratively independent and financially autonomous public institution. It was administered by a board of seven directors (at least two of whom represented the regional funds) elected by the Plenary Committee of the Institute from its members. The Plenary Committee was composed of members of parliament (one fifth), high officials of the Departments of Finance and Agriculture (two fifths),and members elected by regional funds (two fifths), and had the task of supervising the work of the Board of Directors. The General Director of the Institute was appointed by the Minister of Agriculture and could not be removed from office except a t the request of the Plenary Committee and the Board of Directors. Though the Institute was financially autonomous and operated in accordance with banking procedure, it possessed some features of a central public administration. For instance, it did not issue a balance sheet, its budget was subject to ministerial approval and, like the institutions to which it lent, it was supervised by the Inspectorate-General of Finance and the Inspectorate-General of Agricultural Associations and Credit Institutions. However, its 27 POOD AND AGRICULTURE banking procedure enabled the Institute to handle agricultural credits more expeditiously than it could have done under administrative procedure. The Institute made its advances and loans out of resources consisting of a State subsidy, special credits allocated to it by various Acts, deposits made by the regional funds, reserves, and the rediscounting of its securities by the Bank of France. The Institute also had the function of supervising the rural credit co-operative societies and other collective borrowers. Organisation of Agricultural Marketing European agriculturists have not only organised co-operatively to procure high quality requisites as cheaply as possible, but also for the sale of their products. For they work, buy, and borrow in order to produce; and they produce to sell. The marketing of produce is not merely the final act in a series, but the one which governs and directs every activity throughout the year. By the grower's success or failure in marketing his produce is measured the success or failure of all the preceding efforts of the series. It is therefore not surprising that agriculturists should have tried to gain control of so decisive a process. This the small and medium agriculturists have sought to do, not by individual means, but through organisation and the adoption of co-operative methods, designed to obtain a regular and assured market for their wares at reasonably stable prices related to the costs of production. Co-operative organisation enables the host of little producers to assemble their individually small crops of varying quality for pooling with those of others, to enjoy the advantages of standard grading and large, uniform lots, and to have the produce shipped to market in response to real demand. In short, they are enabled to secure marketing advantages which, without such co-operative organisation, would remain the privilege of the big landed proprietors. Furthermore, just as the rural supply co-operatives have been instruments of technical progress in production, so too, cooperative marketing organisation, particularly in its more highly developed forms which impose the most discipline and responsibility on the producers, has done much to improve methods of cultivation, harvesting, breeding, and so on. TYPES AND NUMBER OF RURAL CO-OPERATIVES AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS MARKETING The need for adjusting production as closely as possible to marjcet conditions has favoured the development of marketing co2 9 5 28 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS operatives organised on a commodity basis, particularly in the case of export products. But so anxious are European agriculturists to control the marketing of their produce that in the absence of a specialised co-operative they often entrust this function, either temporarily or permanently, to the first co-operative which happens to have been established in their village. This may be a rural consumers' co-operative society. Very often it will be a multi-purpose or "village co-operative"—the most widespread form of rural cooperative in Europe—which supplies agriculturists with their domestic and farm requirements and at the same time effects the sale of their produce. In 20 out of the 24 European countries where such general agricultural co-operatives were reported before the war, these co-operatives performed thefunction of sale as well as that of purchase. Selling is sometimes even entrusted to the rural credit co-operative society, which in many cases is the oldest among the co-operative institutions of the village. Before the war, more than a third of the European rural credit co-operatives were engaged in marketing their members' produce. According to the very incomplete information available, the function of marketing agricultural produce was performed in Europe before the war by about 77,000 rural co-operative societies, divided as follows: Marketing co-operatives specialised by products. . Non-specialised agricultural purchase and sale cooperatives Rural credit co-operatives Total 42,326 11,829 22,596 76,751 The number of these co-operatives was really much greater than the figures indicate, particularly as regards the rural credit and the non-specialised purchase and sale co-operatives, for which two groups the statistics show the marketing activities only where the societies' accounts were sufficiently detailed Jo enable the distinction to be made. This explains why the figures include the rural credit co-operatives of only three countries (Bulgaria, Germany, and Greece), and the non-specialised purchase and sale cooperatives of only 11 out of the 20 countries where co-operatives of this kind are known to have marketed their members' produce. It is at any rate clear that the co-operatives of the three categories mentioned played an important part in the marketing of agricultural produce, a part meriting closer examination. No more need be said about the rural credit co-operatives, the known sales business of which seems to have represented only some 2.5 per cent, of the total sales of rural co-operatives. But before examining, POOD AND AGRICULTURE 29 product by product, the marketing activity of the rural co-operatives as a whole, it may be well to glance at the role of the nonspecialised purchase and sale co-operative societies in certain countries. For the sales business of such co-operatives represents about 12 per cent, of the total figure for the co-operative marketing of agricultural produce. In Bulgaria, for instance, the sales business of the non-specialised purchase and sale co-operatives was more than three times their trade in supplies; in Iceland and Poland sales slightly exceeded purchases; in Germany 1 sales represented 86 per cent., and in Sweden 82 per cent, of purchases. In Switzerland, where a t least 60 per cent, of the general agricultural co-operative societies sell their members' produce, these societies' sales amounted to rather more than one third of their purchases. In Great Britain, however, purchases were at least seven times more important than sales. More recent data are available for some of the countries mentioned. Thus in Bulgaria, the General Union of Agricultural Cooperative Societies, with some 1,600 affiliated societies (mostly of the general purpose or rural credit type) and an aggregate membership of 250,000, representing more than 35 per cent, of the rural population, had in 1940 a total turnover for marketing and supply of 1,162 million leva, 71 per cent, of which was for marketing. In England, 93 requirements societies reported a combined turnover in purchases and sales in 1942-43 of £12.4 million, 27 per cent, of which represented sales.* In regard to Iceland, it may be mentioned that the Federation of Icelandic Co-operative Societies is responsible for 80-90 per cent, of the country's exports of agricultural commodities. From the figures available it would appear that there has been a considerable development of purchase and sale co-operatives since the outbreak of war, at least in certain countries. This is so, for instance, in Sweden. Although it is not possible to distinguish between selling and purchasing activities, it is worth remarking that the total trade of the general societies affiliated to the National Union of Swedish Farmers rose from 127.1 million crowns in 1938 to 203.4 million crowns (for a volume of 928,600 tons) in 1941, and 218 million crowns in 1942. These figures, of course, reflect a certain rise in prices, as well as an increase of trade. More significant, perhaps, is the growth in membership, from 44,600 in 1937 to 75,000 in 1942. And it should be noted that in Sweden these non-specialised societies are found side by side with federated societies of the 1 According to recent reports it would appear that in Germany about one half of all agricultural produce is placed on the market by agricultural (nonspecialised or specialised) co-operative societies. 1 Compared with 16 per cent, in 1940-41. 5 30 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS specialised type dealing in dairy products, meat, eggs, and other commodities. Switzerland offers a clear instance of an increase in the marketing activities of non-specialised purchase and sale or rural consumers' co-operatives: the Union of East Switzerland Co-operative Agricultural Societies, one of seven such federations in the country, increased its volume of sales from 3,266 carloads (of 10 tons each) in 1938 to 9,209 carloads in 1943, or by 280 per cent. Agricultural products marketed accounted for 22.1 per cent, of the total trade of the Union in 1938, for 29.6 per cent. in 1941, and for no less than 38.7 per cent, in 1943. The value of such produce amounted to 35 million francs in 1943, not including wheat to the value of 17.5 million francs delivered to the Federal Government. CO-OPERATIVE MARKETING OF SPECIFIC AGRICULTURAL COMMODITIES Some attempt at definition of the place held by rural co-operatives before the war (or at present) in the collection, processing, and marketing—at home or for export—of the main agricultural products is perhaps the best way of assessing the role that such co-operatives can play in the post-war organisation of the European agricultural market. GrainCereals figure quite frequently among the products collected, stored, and marketed by the general (or non-specialised) purchase and sale co-operatives. Co-operatives specialising in the sale of cereals are a comparatively recent development in Europe, and they are generally found in association with some official or semiofficial institution for the marketing of grain. Such was the case, for instance, in France and Yugoslavia. In France, a large part of the 1,205 wheat marketing co-operatives in existence on 1 July 1937 were the outcome of the establishment in August 1936 of the InterOccupational Wheat Office1, a body set up to regulate the wheat market. By July 1937, these co-operatives had handled 36 million metric quintals, or five sixths of all grain placed on the market. 2 In Yugoslavia, 169 wheat marketing co-operatives and a number of general agricultural co-operatives were in contact with the Company for the Export of Agricultural Products (which enjoyed practically a monopoly in the export of wheat) ; 28 per cent, of all the wheat purchased by the Company for export was obtained from these co-operatives. However, the existence of a central 1 2 Its name was later changed to National Inter-Occupational Cereals Office. In addition, there were in France 117 milling, and milling and baking, co-operatives, as well as some 600 rural co-operative bakeries. 31 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE body regulating the market does not necessarily lead to the establishment of specialised co-operatives. In Czechoslovakia, for example, the general agricultural co-operative societies acted as the agents of the Czechoslovak Wheat Company, which was managed jointly by representatives of the agricultural co-operatives, the consumers' co-operatives, the processing industries, and the wheat merchants. Under State control it exercised a monopoly in the purchase and sale and in the import and export of cereals and the principal feeding stuffs. Even in less important grain-producing countries the general agricultural co-operatives occupied a considerable place in the grain market. In Finland, for instance, the societies affiliated to the two unions of consumers' co-operatives (K.K. and, more particularly, Y.O.L.) were the largest grain purchasers in the country until the State took over the national grain supply. Even in small Lithuania, for example, the Central Union of Co-operative Societies {Lietükis), which owns two flour mills, in 1938 exported 129,308 tons of wheat and other grains. In Sweden, cereals accounted for 40 per cent, of the sales of the Swedish National Union of Farmers, whose members in 1938 cultivated 27 per cent, of the country's total arable area on farms of more than 2 hectares. The following table gives a more precise indication, for a number of countries, of the role of co-operative organisations—general or specialised—in the marketing of cereals. TABLE IV. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE IN GRAIN TRADE IN SIX EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Country and type of society Year 1939 1937 1940 1939 1938 1939 Czechoslovakia: general. France: special Germany: general Poland: general Sweden: general Yugoslavia: special 1 Of grain and seed exported. a Percentage of national grain trade 87 80 50 701 40-50 28* Of all exported grains. For lack of precise information many countries find no place in the table, including such large producers and exporters of wheat as Hungary and Rumania. However, this does not prevent an estimate of the importance of co-operative organisations in the grain market in some of the omitted countries. During the years immediately before the present war the problem of marketing wheat and cereals in general had become a major preoccupation of European Governments, and in a large number 2 9 * 5 32 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS of countries the public authorities found it necessary to intervene in the market. Such intervention assumed many varied forms, but nearly always involved some kind of joint* action with cooperative organisations—especially agricultural co-operatives. Mention has already been made of France and Czechoslovakia. In Greece, the efforts of the State to regulate the market took the shape of purchasing wheat through the agricultural co-operatives of the wheat producing districts. In Hungary, all the 2,000 or so village consumers' societies affiliated to the Co-operative Wholesale and Productive Society of the Farmers' Union (Hangya) are of the purchase and sale type (and even include the word "marketing" in their name), and they all act as collecting agencies for the more or less specialised central marketing organisations set up by and attached to Hangya. In particular, they collect wheat for the Trading Company of Hungarian Co-operative Unions (Futura), which directly and indirectly derives a large part of its capital from the State and plays or used to play a predominant part in the purchase and export of wheat (and of some other agricultural products) as agent of the Department of Foreign Trade. In 1942, purchases of grain for Futura made by Hangya from its affiliated societies amounted to 35.4 million pengös. Before the war 75 per cent, of the Hungarian wheat export quota to Italy was assigned to co-operative organisations. Precise and up-to-date information is lacking for Rumania. But there is no doubt that the numerous agricultural co-operative societies (207 wheat-marketing co-operatives and 1,699 non-specialised purchase and sale co-operatives before the war) were closely associated with the handling of wheat in what is one of the major wheat-producing countries of Europe, and where the co-operative movement is highly centralised and closely controlled by the Government (especially since the establishment of the National Cooperative Institute by the Act of 23 June 1938).l Livestock and Meat The great majority of the co-operatives engaged in the marketing of livestock and meat are specialised. In certain countries cooperatives of this type have attained a high degree of development and possess slaughterhouses of the most modern design. Owing to the conditions of the trade, they generally cover a considerable territory and have a fairly large membership. The number of such societies is therefore relatively low; altogether there were about 3,500 in Europe before the war. Nevertheless, they stand second (after co-operative dairies) both in number of societies and in 1 A number of European co-operative organisations—agricultural and consumers'—also offer facilities for the milling of grain and baking of bread. 33 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE membership (about 730,000) among the specialised marketing co-operatives. Before the war, livestock and meat-marketing co-operatives were to be found in at least 17 European countries: Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Danzig, Denmark, England, Estonia, Finland, Germany, Hungary, Lithuania, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Sweden, Switzerland, and Yugoslavia. Sweden (217,000) and Denmark (191,000) led in membership, followed by Germany (142,000), Norway (82,000), and Switzerland (50,000). Denmark and Germany came first in order of trade, with Sweden and Norway following. Co-operative organisations also played quite an important part in some other countries. For instance, the Federation of Icelandic Co-operative Societies handled the whole of Iceland's export of frozen mutton, and in Estonia the Meat Export Company, an institution established and managed with State support, was granted (by the Act of 12 February 1937) a State monopoly for export. In Hungary, the societies selling livestock were centralised in the Hangya co-operative for the marketing of cattle. The following table gives an idea of the part played by co-operative organisations in the marketing of meat and bacon in certain countries before the war. TABLE V. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE IN MEAT AND BACON MARKETING IN EIGHT EUROPEAN COUNTRIES National trade Country Bulgaria Denmark Estonia Germany Iceland Latvia Sweden Yugoslavia Measured by Exports of live pigs, cattle, poultry and lard Entire production of bacon and other pork products Meat and cattle exports Exports of pigs and pig products Meat production Total meat exports Exports of frozen lamb Bacon exports Pork marketed Meat marketed Bacon exports Live cattle exports Exports of livestock and poultry Co-operative percentage 16 86 39 100' 7.4 90 100 100' 70 60 89 85 40 i Through a State monopoly granted to co-operative organisations. Recent data show that development has continued during the last few years, at least in certain countries. Thus in Germany the number of societies for the sale of cattle and meat rose from 619 in 1937 to 648 in 1940; during the same period the membership of 5 34 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS the Norwegian Central Union for the Marketing and Export of Bacon increased from 82,900 to nearly 84,500, while the trade of its affiliated societies grew from 42.5 to 50.5 million crowns. In Sweden, the Federation of Co-operative Meat Marketing Societies increased its membership from 207,000 in 1937 to more than 250,000 (with a volume of trade of 159,700 tons) in 1941 and 259,000 in 1942. Membership of the Federation of the Danish Co-operative Bacon Factories, which normally slaughtered and processed over 334 million pigs annually, increased from 191,000 in 1937 to 193,500 in 1940 and 194,000 in 1942. Over the same period membership of the 18 societies affiliated to the Federation of the Danish Co-operative Cattle Export Societies rose from 16,680 to 29,390.l The smaller Danish Farmers' Meat Supply Organisation has also increased the number of its members in recent years. Eggs and Poultry Poultry products, of which eggs are of course the chief, occupy a considerable place in the agricultural production of certain countries. It has, for example, been estimated that in Germany, some years ago, the value of poultry products represented between 6 and 8 per cent, of the value of all agricultural production (and equalled that of wheat). And Germany, besides being a large producer, was along with Great Britain a great importer of eggs; 43 per cent, of German egg imports and 52 per cent, of British egg imports were derived from three European countries: Denmark, the Netherlands, and Belgium (where the value of poultry products was normally equal to about half that of all the coal mined in the country). The egg trade is traditionally handled by dealers collecting from farm to farm or from the local markets. Sometimes these dealers work on their own account or else they work for commercial firms. Under such a system the producers are entirely at the mercy of the middleman unless they are able to form a federation to maintain prices on the more important local markets or unless there happens to be stiff competition between the dealers. To remedy this situation, various forms of co-operative began to participate in the egg trade: consumers' co-operatives in rural areas (which bought eggs from members and then placed them on the market), general agricultural co-operatives, and, generally at a later stage, specialised egg-marketing co-operatives. When eggs are handled by non-specialised co-operatives, there is a tendency towards specialisation at the top, for example, the establishment of a special department of the Supply and Marketing Organisation of the Farmers' League (Boerenbond) in Belgium. 1 In 1943, 29,950. 35 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE A few figures may be given to .show that, in certain countries at least, the co-operative trade in eggs was of considerable importance. In Denmark, for instance, the two co-operative organisations engaged in the export of eggs, the Danish Co-operative Egg Export Society and (less extensively) the Federation of Danish Co-operative Bacon Factories, had an average combined trade in eggs during 1936-1940 of more that 36 million crowns a year. 1 Before the war, the Egg Export Society alone handled about 20 million kg of eggs annually. In Germany in 1936, 369 societies2 collected eggs to a value of 78,676,000 marks. In 1938, the Central Union of Co-operative Dairies in Lithuania exported nearly 86J^ million eggs, purchased through 325 co-operative organisations. The Association of Swedish Co-operative Egg-Marketing Societies, comprising 42,000 members, marketed more than 7,500 tons of eggs in 1941. Before the war, the Supply and Marketing Organisation of the Belgian Farmers' League and the Hungarian central co-operative organisation for the marketing of eggs and poultry were both rapidly developing their trade in eggs. The egg auction co-operatives (41 in 1942-43) are an interesting feature in the Netherlands. Specialised poultry-marketing societies (4 with 55,150 members in 1942) are found in Denmark. For certain countries data are available showing the relative importance of co-operative organisations in the national production and export of eggs before the war. TABLE VI. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE IN EGG PRODUCTION AND EXPORT IN TEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Percentage of national output Country Bulgaria . . . Denmark . . England . . . Estonia. . . . Finland.... Germany . . Latvia Netherlands Poland . . . . Sweden.... 25 8 70-75« 7.1 34 35-40' Percentage of national export 17 301 100» 184 1002 50 5 46 1 Represents the share of the Danish Co-operative Egg s Export Society alone. The co-operative bacon factories also made considerable exports of eggs. Through a State monopoly granted to co-operative organisations. 3 Of the 14.9 million kg of eggs placed on the homeand foreign markets. * By the Central Co-operative Egg Export Association Murta alone. 6 Of the quantity of eggs wholesaled in the country. 1 Less than 23 million crowns in 1942. In 1940, 298. T h e reduction in the number of societies is probably due to the measures of rationalisation and reorganisation which have been applied to the agricultural co-operative movement in recent years. 2 5 36 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Dairy Produce Co-operative organisations have penetrated more deeply into dairying than into any other agricultural processing industry. Co-operative dairies, whether they merely handle liquid milk, or, as is most often the case, also manufacture butter, cheese, condensed or powdered milk, and milk by-products, are also by far the most widespread of all the specialised marketing co-operative societies. Before the war they represented more than 62 per cent, of all European specialised marketing co-operative societies and are to be found in almost every country. For 22 countries of Europe data on the number of societies are available, relating either to the years 1940-1942 (table VII) or to the pre-war period, in most cases 1937 (table V I I I ) . TABLE VII. CO-OPERATIVE DAIRIES IN TWELVE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, 1940-1942 Country Czechoslovakia1 Denmark Finland 1 Germany Great Britain' Hungary Ireland (including Latvia4 Netherlands Norway Sweden Switzerland Total Year 1942 1942 1940 1940 1940 1941 1940 1941 1940 1940 1942 1942 Number of societies 211 1,384 677 9,744 14 1,079 215 175 475 464 756 2,946 18,140 Membership 188,639 80,404 987 158,621 53,015 85,352 221,000 — 1 Bohemia and Moravia only. * Probably includes Sudetenland and Austria. * England only; there are also five or six dairy societies in Wales. * Affiliated to Titriba. In 1939, there were 192 societies with nearly 101,500 suppliers, of whom 18,370 were members. The lack of recent information about co-operative dairies in 10 countries (table VIII) does not entirely preclude an approximate estimate of their present number. Though there may have been changes during the last few years, these will have been slight and in both directions, judging by what has happened in countries for which more up-to-date information is available. In Finland, for example, the number of co-operative dairies increased from 670 in 1937 to 677 in 1940, while in Latvia there has apparently been a decrease. Normally the changes would have been small in most of the countries concerned, as the number of co-operative dairies was nearing saturation point. It does not seem that war events have greatly altered the picture, except for some destruction of 37 FOOD AND AGRICULTURE TABLE VIII. CO-OPERATIVE DAIRIES IN TEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, 1937 N u m b e r of societies Country Italy Lithuania Luxembourg Poland 3 Rumania Yugoslavia 169 262 2,213 77 3,130 196 268 1,560 267 200 Total 8,342 Belgium Estonia Membership 35,142 30,000 280.0001 843 240,000* 14,836 11,819 642,118 30,000 17,081 1,301,839 > For 1,480 societies. • In 1935. • In 1938. premises and, here and there, suppression or interference with the activities of the dairies. Therefore, with due reservations' and for want of a better method, it will not be improper to use the prewar figures as resembling closely those of the present time, and to add together the totals of the two tables, giving an approximate grand total of 26,000 co-operative dairies in the 22 countries considered. Most of the co-operative dairies were federated, either in general or in special central organisations. In both cases, but particularly in that of the specialised organisations (found chiefly in the exporting countries), there was a high standard of equipment. The figures given below give some notion of the volume of trade of the cooperative dairy organisations. Denmark, with some 4 million inhabitants, comes first, as the world's largest butter-exporting country, supplying from 38 to 40 per cent, of the total net exports of all countries. The attainment of this position and the technical achievements which made it possible must be ascribed largely to the co-operative organisation of the Danish agriculturists. Deliveries of milk to the Danish cooperative dairies, which represent 75 per cent, of all the dairies in the country, totalled some 4,500 million kg annually; their normal annual butter production was 189.4 million kg and their cheese production 33.4 million kg. The trade of the dairies averaged 626.6 million crowns annually in 1936-1940, while that of the butter export societies was 187.1 million crowns annually in the same period. While the trade of the dairies increased to 782 million crowns in 1942, that of the export societies declined to 151.9 million crowns, as a result of war conditions. In Hungary, deliveries of milk to the co-operative dairies 5 38 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS in 1940 amounted to 195 million litreSj of which the central association handled 102 million litres. However, in 1941, owing to shortage of fodder, these amounts declined to 147 million and 86 million litres respectively. Regional associations of co-operative dairies in the Netherlands sold 35,877 tons of butter, 27,416 tons of cheese and casein, and 6,644 tons of other dairy products in 1940. Before the war the Norwegian co-operative dairies, comprising from 80 to 90 per cent. of all milk producers, normally handled some 662,800,000 litres of milk a year and had an annual butter production of about 36 million lbs. In Switzerland, the members of the societies affiliated to the Central Union of Dairy Farmers before the war owned some 730,000 cows on 125,000 holdings; the regional federations of the Union manufactured butter on a large scale. In the three tables IX—XI data are given showing the cooperative share of the milk, butter, and cheese trades in a number of countries. The figures, which relate for the most part to the pre-war period, are to be regarded as approximations. Furthermore, it is to be observed t h a t the tables are not mutually exclusive. The first, concerning milk in general, contains some figures which are the same as or include some of those given in the other two. Nevertheless, despite possible repetition and overlapping, they enable some idea to be formed of the economic importance of cooperative organisations in the field of dairy production. TABLE IX. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE IN MILK EUROPEAN COUNTRIES TRADE IN TWELVE National output Country Denmark France Germany Hungary Iceland Latvia Luxembourg Netherlands Norway Sweden Switzerland Yugoslavia2 ' 1942. » Croatia only. Measured by Co-operative percentage Total milk delivered to dairies Total dairy production Milk supplied to market Total dairy production Milk sold Total number of milch cows Total number of milch cows Total milk production Milk powder produced Condensed milk produced Milk producers members of co-operative dairies Milk delivered to dairies Milk marketed Milk handled (collection and processing) 90 15-20 70 20 70 38 53 76.7 67.5 34.4 80-901 93.4 90 46.6' 39 POOD AND AGRICULTURE As regards butter and the butter exporting countries, it must be pointed out that not all co-operatively produced butter is cooperatively exported. Where it is, this is sometimes due to the existence of a co-operative monopoly granted by the State, as in Latvia (butter, cheese). In Denmark, as the following table shows, only 50 per cent, of butter exports was handled directly by cooperative organisations; large quantities of co-operatively produced butter were exported through other channels. TABLE X. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE OF BUTTER OUTPUT AND EXPORT IN SIXTEEN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Country Austria Czechoslovakia Denmark Estonia Finland Germany Hungary Ireland Latvia Lithuania . . . . Luxembourg . . Netherlands . . Norway Poland Sweden Switzerland . . . Percentage of national export Percentage of national output 92 9 90 85-90 94 70 42.5' 35 95 85-90 53« 82 40 SO« 100» 88 52 100» 95 100 100 99 93.5 95 1 By 10 co-operative butter export societies, to which 49.5 per cent, of the co-operative dairies are affiliated ( 1942). * Through State monopoly granted to co-operative organisations. » Of factory butter production. * Of the total number of milch cows. TABLE XI. CO-OPERATIVE SHARE IN CHEESE PRODUCTION AND EXPORT IN NINE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Country Percentage of national output Czechoslovakia Estonia Finland Hungary: cheese cream cheese Latvia Netherlands: cheese 10 70 55.8 40 Poland Sweden 99.8 73.4» Percentage of national export 7 65 58 1001 75.5 58.3 * Through State monopoly granted to a co-operative organisation. in dairies, 100 1 Cheese manufactured 40 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Fruits and Vegetables The organisation of the market in fresh fruits and vegetables, which play quite an important part in the European dietary, is chiefly determined by the perishable nature of the produce and by transport conditions. A large part of the total production is consumed on the spot by the producers themselves (or their immediate neighbours) or sold nearby in a multitude of small local markets, or else disposed of directly by the growers in some large city close to their establishments. Sale in distant markets affects only a relatively small proportion of the total output and is of fairly recent origin. The co-operative marketing of fruits and vegetables, therefore, is a more complicated and delicate matter than that of cereals and dairy produce, for instance, and is, for the reasons stated above, a comparatively late development. As a result, many fruit and vegetable-marketing co-operatives are not yet federated regionally or nationally, and there are central organisations for the sale of fruits or fruits and vegetables in only eight European countries (France, Greece, Hungary, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Turkey). In certain countries, too, co-operatives for marketing fruits and vegetables are found affiliated to general federations of agricultural co-operative societies. Owing to this imperfect development of the federal structure, it is difficult and at times impossible to obtain precise and complete data concerning fruit and vegetable co-operatives. Subject to this reservation, the information available shows that before the war there were at least 1,300-1,400 specialised fruit and vegetable-marketing co-operatives, spread over no less than 20 European countries: Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Danzig, Estonia, France, Germany, Great Britain, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Rumania, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, and Yugoslavia. This figure does not comprise general purchase and sale cooperatives collecting fruits and vegetables on behalf of some specialised central co-operative organisation. Nor, except in a few, mostly unimportant cases, does it include either the vinegrowers' co-operative societies or other agricultural co-operatives carrying out industrial processes (such as oil-pressing societies, potatostarch works, potato distilleries, sugar refineries, etc.). Co-operatives engaged in the production of canned fruits and vegetables are mostly a wartime development, stimulated by difficulties in transporting fresh produce. Some idea of the part played by co-operative organisations in the marketing of fruits and vegetables may be gained by a brief FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 41 consideration of some of the countries where co-operative marketing of these products has attained a certain importance. Such a survey will cover fruit-marketing co-operatives (including those for dried fruits and nuts), vegetable-marketing co-operatives, and those marketing fruits and vegetables together. For the moment it will leave out of account the vinegrowers' co-operatives and the industrial processing co-operatives, other than the recent wartime developments referred to above. In Bulgaria, there has been a considerable wartime development in the export of fruit and vegetables. Owing to transport difficulties, these perishable products have been largely turned into preserves: dried fruit and vegetables, jam, and similar products. Co-operative organisations rapidly gained an important place in the preserves industry, covering 22.3 per cent, of the production and export in 1939-1941. In 1941, a third of the strawberry-collecting centres belonged to co-operative organisations, and two co-operative organisations together held first place among strawberry exporters. Co-operative canning factories cover 37 per cent, of the total production of tomato pulp and jams; 13 out of 18 undertakings for drying fruit and vegetables belong to cooperative societies. Out of 12 cold storage installations, five, with a capacity, during 24 hours, of 49 five-ton wagons, and representing almost 50 per cent, of the total storage capacity, are co-operatively owned. Before the war there were 23 fruit and vegetable growers' co-operative societies reported in Czechoslovakia. In France, a start was made with the establishment of fruit growers' co-operatives shortly after the war of 1914-1918 and a more substantial development occurred around 1930-31. But these co-operatives were unconnected with one another, and it was not until the creation, in 1933, of the Federation of Fruit and Vegetable Growers' Co-operative Societies, that they were able to influence the market. The statistics available for Germany do not permit the necessary distinction to be drawn between the marketing and the industrial processing societies. Before the war, the two groups together comprised some 1,300 co-operatives with an aggregate membership of 140,000. It included a fairly large number of distilleries and potato-drying plants. At the end of 1940, the German Union of Agricultural and Raiffeisen Co-operative Societies had 214 fruit and vegetable-marketing co-operatives proper affiliated to it. In Great Britain, in 1942-43, sixteen fruit and vegetable-marketing societies made sales of these products totalling £878,691. In Greece, all the citrus fruit producers of the island of Crete were compulsorily members of the Union of Citrus Growers, to which 5 42 CO-OPERATION AND PRBSENT-DAY PROBLEMS they delivered their whole crop. The Union thus exercised an export monopoly. In Hungary, the network of co-operatives affiliated to Hangya collects fruits and vegetables in common with other products. And, as with other products, Hangya set up a central co-operative for the marketing of fruits and vegetables, which grades and sells them, and also plays an important part in their exportation. Italy, a great producer of fruits before the war, was one of the best organised countries for the marketing of fruits and vegetables, ever since the creation in 1927 of the Department for Collective Marketing of Fruit and Vegetables (Fedexport) of the Federation of Agricultural Co-operative Societies. This Department, comprising 102 local societies, rapidly extended its field of action to the whole country; it undertook both collection and marketing, and did much to develop export business. In 1936 its volume of trade was 40,000 tons. In Lithuania, there were 12, and in Luxembourg 44, fruit and vegetable growers' co-operatives. Norway before the war had 202 co-operatives for the collection of berries, which were then marketed through a central co-operative organisation. In the Netherlands, co-operative auctioneering societies (Veilingen) play an important part in the marketing of fruits and vegetables; as much as 96 per cent, of the vegetables grown for the market are sold through the co-operative auctions. 1 In Rumania, the National Co-operative Institute controls jam factories with an annual production of 500 tons, and also drying plants for vegetables. In 1942, it was reported to be building two fruit-refrigerating plants with a capacity of 50 tons each. Before the war, there were 21 fruit-marketing societies in Sweden, with 18,000 members; the societies were grouped in a federation. Switzerland before the war had some 200 fruit and vegetable-marketing co-operatives, with a membership of about 13,750. In addition, at least five out of the seven regional federations of agricultural co-operatives were also concerned with the marketing of fruit. One of them, the Union of East Switzerland Co-operative Agricultural Societies, which has equipment for storing fresh fruit, for drying fruit, and for producing apple juice and cider, sold over 2.0002 carloads (of 10 tons each) of potatoes and 1,700 carloads of fruit in 1941. Before the war, there were 20 fruit and vegetable growers' cooperative societies in Turkey and at least 40 in Yugoslavia. The co-operative trade in dried fruit is mostly in Greece and 1 2 There were 180 such co-operative auctions reported in 1942-43. In 1942, 2,378. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 43 Turkey. In the two main currant-growing regions of Greece, between 40 and 65 per cent, of the growers were co-operatively organised before the war. In Turkey, 25 per cent, of the national output of figs was handled by co-operative organisations; the Union of Fig and Raisin Growers of Izmir included over 20,000 growers in 1941. There are also regional marketing co-operative unions of hazel-nut growers and of pistachio-nut growers. More than 38,750 hazel-nut growers were organised in 15 societies in 1941. At one time, 15 per cent, of the nut crop was co-operatively handled. The commodities principally handled by the industrial processing co-operatives are grapes, potatoes, beets, and olives. The vinegrowers' co-operative societies are chiefly for the manufacture and marketing of wine; a few also engage in the sale of table grapes. These societies are both more numerous and older than the fruit-marketing co-operatives proper. Before the war, there were more than 2,000 of them, spread over at least 11 European countries: Bulgaria, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Luxembourg, Rumania, Switzerland,Turkey, and Yugoslavia. France had the largest number of societies, followed by Germany, Italy, Greece, and Yugoslavia, in that order. The French vinegrowers' societies possessed a storage capacity of 10 million hectolitres, equivalent to 20 per cent, of the average production of France. In Germany, vinegrowers' co-operative societies1 before the war accounted for 13 per cent, of the annual production of wine. Cooperative organisations in Bulgaria handled as much as 21.5 per cent, of the national export of grapes; the central organisation of the wine and grape growers' co-operatives acts as authorised exporter under the control of the Department of Foreign Trade. Fifteen per cent, of the Turkish grape crop was marketed by cooperative organisations for some years before the war. Co-operative grape distilleries have been developed in France (350) and in Switzerland (about 50). In a number of countries the growers of potatoes have set up various co-operative processing plants. Thus there were co-operative potato distilleries in Estonia (80), Germany, Latvia (13), and also Czechoslovakia, where at one time co-operative distilleries supplied 22.7 per cent, of the total production of alcohol for agricultural and industrial needs. There were co-operative factories for the manufacture of potato flour in France, Norway, and the Netherlands (where at least 80 per cent, of the output was cooperative). In Czechoslovakia, before the war, there were about 30 co-operative societies for the desiccation of chicory. 1 In 1940, 561. 3 0 5 44 CO-OPSRATION AND PRBSBNT-DAY PROBLEMS Co-operative sugar-beet distilleries were set up in several regions of France, more particularly in the north, where beetroot is an important rotation crop. Before the war, there were about 60 of these societies, 45 of which belonged to the Union of Agricultural Beet Co-operatives. In Bulgaria, the Central Union and Wholesale Society (Napred) participates with other co-operative organisations, including the Co-operative Society of Bulgarian Sugar Beet Growers, in a large co-operative enterprise for the manufacture of sugar. In Sweden, co-operative associations of beet growers comprised over 22,000 members and had a trade of 82,400,000 crowns in 1942. In the Netherlands, six co-operative sugar-beet factories normally used to handle 65 per cent, of the total output of beet sugar. Olive oil is manufactured and marketed co-operatively in France (72 societies with 15,000 members), Greece, Italy (20 societies), and Spain. Textiles and Other Products Co-operative marketing of cereals, livestock, dairy produce, and fruits and vegetables is of considerable importance, sometimes exceeding other types, in many European countries. But cooperative marketing has not achieved a role of the same dimensions in the case of the other products of farming and stock-breeding. Nevertheless, there are some other products, notably textiles, tobacco, and honey, which should not go entirely without mention in this survey. 1 The textile chiefly concerned is, of course, wool; but, in eastern Europe, flax and, in the Mediterranean, silk are of some importance. In addition, there is some production and co-operative handling of cotton in Bulgaria and Turkey. In Turkey, for instance, there were two unions of cotton growers in 1941, comprising seven societies with 5,666 members in all. Co-operative marketing of wool has been developed in Bulgaria, France, Great Britain, and Iceland. In 1940, Bulgaria had 164 wool marketing co-operatives, with an aggregate membership of nearly 10,000; in the previous year these societies supplied the textile industry with about one third of its requirements. In France, wool is co-operatively marketed both by general and by specialised marketing societies. In regard to Great Britain, where large numbers of sheep are still kept, it may be said that in 1941 English wool marketing (and a few supply) societies sold wool to the 1 The various types of forestry co-operatives, which play an important part in Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Finland, Rumania, Sweden, and Switzerland, also perform certain marketing functions (timber for building purposes, wood for fuel, etc.). FOOD AND AGRICULTURA 45 value of £206,000. In Iceland, the Federation of Icelandic Cooperatives normally handles 75-80 per cent, of the country's export of wool and sheepskins. Flax used to be co-operatively marketed on a fairly large scale in Estonia, Latvia, and Poland. Co-operatives also shared in the flax trade in Czechoslovakia, where co-operative flax mills at one time accounted for 10 per cent, of the national export of flax, and in Lithuania, where the co-operative wholesale society Lietükis in 1938 reported sales of flax amounting to 6,870,000 lits. There are a number of co-operative linen works in France. The co-operative marketing of silk is of some importance in Bulgaria, in France, which possesses a number of sericultural cooperatives, in Italy, where there were about one hundred co-operative establishments for the drying of cocoons before the war, and in Turkey, where four societies with a membership of 2,169 formed the Union of Co-operative Cocoon Marketing Societies of Bursa. Tobacco is co-operatively marketed in Bulgaria, Italy, and Turkey. At one time nearly a quarter of the national output of tobacco was handled by the Bulgarian tobacco growers' co-operative societies; these societies now act as agents for the State-controlled Agricultural Co-operative Bank, which enjoys a Government monopoly for the purchase of tobacco. Italy had 45 co-operative societies of tobacco growers a few years before the war. In Turkey, the Hasankeyf Tobacco Marketing Society, with 250 members, markets a special kind of chewing tobacco mostly used for medicinal purposes. Honey is marketed co-operatively to some extent in quite a number of European countries. In Hungary, for instance, the beekeepers' co-operative societies used to account for over 60 per cent, of the total honey exports of the country; in recent years Hangya has set up, as for other products, its own specialised central co-operative organisation for the marketing of honey. The Central Association of Latvian Milk Producers had the exclusive right to export honey (5,000 kg in 1938). In Lithuania, the Sodyba Union of Co-operative Societies for Horticulture and Gardening used to buy honey (as well as fruit and herbs) from its affiliated societies. There is also some co-operative marketing of honey in Sweden and in Yugoslavia, where 125 beekeepers' societies were reported just before the war. This brief and necessarily incomplete review will perhaps have served to give some idea of the place of the various European co-operative marketing organisations in the marketing of the principal agricultural products. By reason of their number, their wide distribution, and, often, their high degree of technical 5 46 COOPERATION AND PRBSBNT-DAY PROBLEMS development, these organisations (especially when welded into federations or centrals) are often quite irreplaceable agencies for the marketing of certain products. Their role cannot, however, be adequately indicated by purely numerical data. For they do not just market the products of the agriculturist or stock-breeder at as fair a price as possible. When they function successfully, they also serve the community at large, by introducing order into the market for the products most necessary to life. Their beneficent activities include grading, standardisation, correlation of supply and demand, and so forth. And apart from their action on the market, these co-operatives exercise a reflex action on the mode of production itself, through the technical and moral education which they give to the producers who are their members. They help the agriculturists in their choice of land and its proper maintenance, in the selection of the best vegetable or animal species, in suggesting appropriate procedures for cultivation or harvesting, and in matters of animal care and nutrition. The best measure of their irreplaceability is that, despite the war, they have almost nowhere been dispensed with. The available reports indicate that they were suppressed in certain parts of Poland during the German occupation, only to be replaced by imitations. In certain places their use has been made obligatory, which is at once a homage to their efficiency and an assault upon their liberty. Even if not everywhere respected, they have practically everywhere been left in existence. Indeed almost all the data recently received point t o a growth in the number of such societies and in their membership. It is permissible, then, to conclude that as soon as conditions of production and exchange return to normal, these various cooperative bodies will be able to resume their habitual functions, not only as a vast mechanism of orderly marketing, but as guides and regulators of production. This is the role that they filled in the ten years of agricultural crisis that preceded the war. Their place in plans of rehabilitation and reconstruction is likely to be still greater. Lastly, it is to be noted that the agricultural marketing co-operatives, though chiefly concerned with organising the sale of their members' products, are not and cannot be indifferent to the final phase of the economic process in which these products are conveyed to the consumer. Some of them have even assumed this function themselves and have set up their own organs of distribution, though this is exceptional. But if they wish to ensure this distribution and to keep an eye on it, the agricultural marketing co-operatives can utilise the huge network of urban and rural con- FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 47 sumers' co-operatives which has been described elsewhere.1 It may be useful to recall here that the consumers' co-operatives, besides their apparatus of distribution and transportation, also possess plants for the processing of agricultural products: flour and flour products, including alimentary paste products, in Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain, Lithuania, Norway, Poland, Sweden, Switzerland; sugar in Bulgaria and Lithuania; jams in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, Finland, Germany, Great Britain, Netherlands, Poland; cocoa and chocolate in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, France, Germany, Great Britain, Norway, Switzerland ; canned vegetables or fish in Belgium, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Estonia, Finland, France, Great Britain, Netherlands, Poland; milk products in Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, France, Germany, Great Britain, Netherlands, Yugoslavia; margarine or lard in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Great Britain, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland ; edible oils in Netherlands and Sweden ; soap in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Estonia, France, Germany, Great Britain, Iceland, Lithuania, Poland, Sweden; meat products in Austria, Czechoslovakia, Germany, Great Britain, Latvia, Lithuania, Sweden; various spices in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland, Great Britain, Hungary, Switzerland; textiles, cloth and garments in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Great Britain, Netherlands, Sweden; footwear in Belgium, Denmark, France, Great Britain, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland. The effectiveness of both agricultural co-operative marketing organisations and consumers' co-operative organisations as rationalising factors in the economy will be further enhanced in proportion as the two groups are able to increase the number and strengthen the closeness of the direct economic relations which they were increasingly tending to develop with one another before the war.2 Restoration of the Fishing Industry Brief consideration should also be given to the fishing industry, first in its immediate bearing on the feeding and rehabilitation of the countries which have suffered most directly from war devastation and enemy occupation and then under its general aspects, which are practically universal and, up to the present, permanent in character. The latter concern almost all countries with a fishing population. It is to be feared that in the countries where the pasture land 1 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., Parts II and III. Cf. Chapter III: Inter-Co-operative Relations. 5 3 0 * s 48 CO-OPERATION AND PRESBNT-DAY PROBLEMS and stock have been damaged, the national dietary may be deficient in meat and other proteins of animal origin for a considerable period. Fish and other sea, lake and river products can make up for this inadequacy to some extent. They merit attention more especially as they represent a net addition to the amount of foodstuffs available, while stock and poultry are in competition for their food with other animals and men. For both these reasons it seems desirable that the place held by fish in the feeding of the countries under review should be rapidly restored and even enlarged. 1 It appears likely that an effort will be made in this direction unless the obstacles are found to be insuperable. This probability is confirmed by the fact that the consumption of fish has increased in countries where fishery, though restricted, has been maintained. In Sweden, for example, the Stockholm Consumers' Co-operative Society in 1943 bought a fishcanning factory near the city in order to meet the increased demand of its members for fish products 2 ; it is now distributing fish through 35 special shops and a score of simply equipped kiosks designed to replace the sales vans used in normal times. To meet this demand, attention will have to be given in the period of rehabilitation and reconstruction to the problem of restoring as completely and quickly as possible an industry that is a source of employment as well as an abundant and immediately available source of foods with a high nutritive value. But just as the restoration of agriculture calls for the assembly and distribution of a large quantity of means of production of various kinds, so fishermen must have boats, gear, fuel, engines, bait and also credit if they are to resume and if possible develop their useful calling. For fishermen as for agriculturists the question arises whether it is not possible, and indeed preferable, for supplies of occupational requisites to be distributed by organised bodies capable of reaching the largest number of persons in an efficient and orderly way rather than that they should be available only to favoured individuals. FISHERMEN'S CO-OPERATIVES: NUMERICAL D A T A Such organised bodies existed before the war in the shape of the fishermen's co-operatives and they still exist, though some have had temporarily to suspend their activities. Actually, in 1 In certain European countries, for example, the annual consumption of fish2amounted to 40 lbs. and even as much as 60 lbs. per person before the war. Consumption of fish also increased in Sweden in the latter part of World War I: in 12 Swedish towns it rose from 71 grams daily in June-July 1917 to 139 grams daily in June-July 1918. FOOD AND AGRICULTURB 49 most countries, fishermen were less highly organised than agriculturists. Nevertheless, all the countries of Europe with a sea coast had fishermen's co-operatives. They were mainly fishery requirements and credit co-operatives, and, more rarely, marketing co-operatives; some of them had attained a high degree of development and efficiency. There were also a number of freshwater fishermen's co-operative societies. Being less fully organised, fishermen's co-operatives had no great means of making themselves known through the usual channels of information (reports, periodicals, etc.) and figures relating to them are therefore incomplete. Nevertheless, it was possible to list more than 600 societies with a total membership of over 83,000 in Europe (excepting the U.S.S.R.) 1 , in statistics published in 1939, even though no mention was made of Belgium, France, Germany and Sweden, all of which have some fishermen's co-operatives. Before the war there were 36 fishermen's co-operatives in Denmark, with an annual trade oi about 10 million Danish crowns, and 28 in Estonia. In France, there were well-established fishermen's co-operatives in Brittany, and on the west and south-west coast. Those on the Atlantic coasts, if not others, were grouped in a federation. 2 In 1943, Great Britain had 45 local fishermen's cooperatives with a combined membership of 1,500 and sales amounting to £102,000; the societies were affiliated to a national Fisheries' Organisation Society which seeks to promote co-operation in the fishing industry. In Greece, there were 37 fishermen's co-operatives reported in 1936, but only one of these seems to have been of much commercial importance. In Iceland, societies affiliated to the Federation of Icelandic Co-operatives operate fishing stations, a fish-meal factory and a cod-liver oil refinery. Italy, before the war, had over a hundred societies with a membership of 15,000 fishermen. There were 30 such societies in Latvia, 18 of them for sea fishermen and 12 for freshwater fishermen. The central organisation, Zvejnieks, to which all primary societies had to belong, supplied gear and fuel costing 19 per cent, less than those obtainable through ordinary trade channels, while its marketing operations brought fishermen higher prices than they could get before. In 1939, the central organisation was given a monopoly of the wholesale trade in fish within Riga, the capital. Norway had four fishermen's co-operative societies in 1940, with a total membership of 21,000 and a trade of 52.5 million Norwegian crowns; membership in1 I.L.O.: Co-operative Societies throughout the World: Numerical Data (Geneva, 1939), op. cit. 1 There were also some fishermen's co-operatives reported in Algeria and French Morocco. 50 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS creased fivefold since 1937. Spain had an extensive network of societies known as pósitos marítimos, which enjoyed a large measure of State support and embraced practically the whole life of the fishermen and their families (education, old-age and other benefits, etc., as well as provision of fishing requisites and other economic functions). In 1934, there were 400 of these fishermen's societies, with a total membership of 50,000, organised into nine regional federations which covered the whole Spanish coast and the Balearic and Canary Islands. They owned 116 buildings and operated 53 large fishing craft. Their economic enterprises included co-operative stores, co-operative fish markets and sales organisations, cooperative savings and loan banks and mutual insurance. They also had 118 schools of their own, where 9,440 children and 4,720 adult fishermen were taught general subjects, mutuality and co-operation. There is at least one large fishermen's co-operative in Sweden —the Association of West Coast Fishermen. A few years before the war Yugoslavia reported 58 fishermen's co-operative associations. The most important fishermen's co-operatives, however, are found in the U.S.S.R., where practically all the fishermen—96 per cent, in 1936—are organised in co-operative societies. At that time there were 830 local co-operatives for sea fishermen and 810 for freshwater fishermen. The co-operatives for sea fishermen alone had about 150,000 members. The local societies were the owners of fishing boats and gear valued a t 70 million and 45 million roubles respectively in 1935. Part of the fleet was motor-run; the total strength of the motors amounted to 19,556 hp. in the same year. In addition, the State in 1936 placed 578 boats with a total motor power of 15,000 hp. a t the disposal of the co-operatives through the medium of "machine-stations" (similar to the "tractorstations" of agriculture) 1 , which rent out machines in return for a cash payment. The co-operative societies make over their catch, by previous arrangement, to the local organisations of the Commissariat for the Foodstuff Industry. In 1935, the catch of all the co-operatives together amounted to 8,000,000 tons, or more than 60 per cent, of the country's total production. The wartime dislocation of European (and Japanese) fisheries has given added importance to fisheries in the Americas and Asia. The two leading regions in North America are the North Pacific coasts of Canada and the United States (including Alaska) and the North Atlantic coasts of Labrador, Newfoundland, Canada and the United States. There are also fishing grounds along the coasts of Mexico and Brazil, and along the coasts of India. In Canada, there were more than 100 fishermen's co-operative i Cf. p. 132. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 51 societies reported in 1943-44. No indication is available regarding their membership or trade, but in 1940-41, the 91 societies then existing had a total membership of 6,438 and a total volume of business close to $3,000,000. Since the co-operative shipment of fish was adopted in Newfoundland in 1938, some 1,200 fishermen have been organised in marketing societies, which have marketed lobster to the value of about $350,000 since their inception. In the United States, according to a survey made in 19361, some 60 co-operative associations, comprising 12,500 fishermen either as members of the co-operatives or as personnel on members' vessels, marketed fish with a value of about $9,000,000, representing about 24 per cent, by weight of the fish produced by the fisheries of the United States. Fishermen's co-operative societies are also reported in Brazil (36), Mexico, and, outside America, in India, where 120 societies, with over 6,000 members, are to be found in Bengal alone. SOME PROBLEMS Fishing populations are generally poor and their co-operative organisation by itself will rarely be able to solve all the problems connected with the restoration of fisheries, especially sea fisheries. Intervention by the public authorities will be indispensable, but such action will find in the fishermen's co-operatives the requisite channels and points of application. The first and financially the biggest problem will often be the rebuilding of the fishing fleets which have suffered heavy losses in some countries. In France, for instance, according to a report of the Minister of National Economy, the steel fishing fleet was reduced from a total of 150,000 tons in September 1939 to only 8,500 tons in August 1944, or 5.7 per cent, of the pre-war tonnage. In some countries the advances required to build new vessels will be provided by the maritime credit institution, which is often organised along the same lines as those for agricultural credit. But, as in the case of the latter, the advances made can usefully be sifted and controlled by being passed through the fishermen's organisations. And if the dilapidated state of the fishing industry necessitates subsidies (or priorities) for the construction of vessels and the purchase of gear, these can be allotted to the fishermen's co-operatives, as has recently been done in Croatia under a plan for the restoration of fisheries. But the problem of the fishing industry contains other elements besides those derived from the war period. It has economic and social elements that are older and of a more general nature. The 1 By the Fish and Wildlife Service, U.S. Department of the Interior. 5 52 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS post-war reconstruction programme, extending and consolidating rehabilitation measures, can be the occasion for providing a lasting solution to this problem. Such a solution is probably not possible without the intervention of the public authorities, but equally requires the organised action of the parties concerned, so that the two spheres of endeavour may support and complete each other. The fishermen's fundamental problem at many points resembles that of the agriculturists in its economic and social aspects; in certain respects it is more serious and is perhaps less generally known. Its degree of complexity and acuteness varies from country to country. But it is essentially the problem of the so-called independent producer's relations with the market—the money market, the market for occupational requisites, the consumer goods market, the market for the sale of the product of his labour. The fisherman is only really independent if he controls his relations with the market and, if he is not really independent, his position is generally less enviable than that of wage-earning workers with equal professional qualifications. Actually his whole economic situation and, in varying degree, his personal status depend on the intermediary organs commanding the approaches to the market. The less he has direct relations with the market, the more complete is his dependence. In extreme and by no means exceptional cases, one and the same intermediate body (generally a powerful company) occupies a central position through which the fishermen have to pass in order to obtain, usually on credit, their fishery requirements and household goods, and, at the same time, to get the remuneration for their toil and risk. Such a situation easily degenerates into a truck system that imprisons the weaker partner in a complicated network of indebtedness, obligations, and, eventually, economic exploitation. In many countries the fisherman has partially freed himself, through co-operative action, from the toll levied on his way to credit, fishery requirements and consumer goods. It is harder for him to retain or regain mastery of the crowning act which must recompense all his efforts—the marketing of his catch. Sea products are even more perishable, often incomparably more perishable, than the products of the soil. Even more than a bumper crop a heavy catch can be a calamity for the producer. Neither fresh fish nor shellfish lend themselves to orderly marketing which exactly relates supply to real demand. Lacking their own preserving facilities, the fishermen are a t the mercy, on the sales market, of the companies with canning plants or, at the least, and in the majority of cases, of transport concerns. The situation is aggravated by the fact that the special means of transport and the preserving facilities are often in the same hands. FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 53 Unless this problem of transport and preservation can be overcome, it is generally recognised that the fishermen's social problem cannot be solved and that as a consequence the fishing industry itself is in serious jeopardy. The fishermen can hardly solve this problem on their own. Though they have been able, to a certain extent, to organise for their short and medium-term credit needs, for their fishery requisites, and, sometimes, for the provision of consumer goods, they do not normally have the necessary financial means for the purchase o r construction of canning factories or even, in most cases, of trucks or wagons specially equipped for the transportation of their catch. They therefore have to receive external aid. In Belgium, for some years shortly after the last war, the fishermen of the Ostend coast succeeded, with the help of the trade unions, in setting up a large organisation known as the Armements ostendais, with three subsidiary societies: one {La Marée) for the sale of fish, another (Pescator) for the utilisation of by-products, and the third for preservation (Frigorifiques du littoral). The fishermen's cooperatives could advantageously establish firm relations with the consumers' co-operative wholesale societies, since the latter generally have large financial means at their disposal and their huge distributive network would become available as a market for the co-operative catch. It may be noted here that some of the European co-operative wholesales have fish-preserving plants (salt or oil) ; the English, Estonian, French and Scottish co-operative wholesale societies even have establishments of this kind on the seacoast, and the Swedish Co-operative Wholesale Society, during the war, set up the first fish-oil factory in Sweden. The Swedish co-operative movement has approached the problem of marketing fish along the lines suggested above, by the creation, in 1939, of the Cooperative Fish Marketing Society (Svensk Andelsfisk), which is jointly financed and managed by the Swedish Co-operative Wholesale Society and the Association of West Coast Fishermen. More recently, the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society has extended its aid to a population that includes fishermen; it decided to take a half share in the financing and management of a co-operative in the Island of Skye and undertook to absorb or dispose of the goods produced by members of the society, including fishery products. Elsewhere aid is given by the State, as for instance in Latvia, where the fishermen's co-operatives transported their fish in trucks belonging to the State. 1 Sometimes State intervention and its 1 As before the war, the fishermen in Latvia are grouped in co-operatives which appear to comprise more than 2,000 members at the present time. Plans provide for the rebuilding of the equipment of these co-operatives through the State network of "motor and equipment stations for the fishing industry . 5 54 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS dovetailing with co-operative action assume more complex forms, as was the case with the Spanish pósitos already mentioned. The following example, drawn from the Canadian Province of Quebec, is recent and covers every aspect of the fishermen's economic and social problem; it shows very clearly how, by judicious division of tasks, State and co-operative action can be co-ordinated. ' An Experiment For a number of reasons the years 1931-1937 were the darkest period in the history of the fisheries of Quebec. The fishermen, who were without resources, unorganised, and dominated by powerful companies, got excessively low prices for their fish (one fifth and, in certain cases, one tenth of the price paid by consumers) or else lived by running into debt and depending on an unemployment benefit which, though small, brought more to the home than the proceeds of fishing. In the course of a few years the situation was entirely changed. In 1938, the creation of a Superior School of Fisheries gave the industry an instrument of technical research (in collaboration with experimental stations established on the coast) - and also a training centre for the corps of engineers, inspectors and master-fishermen required. In addition, the School itself, some months after its establishment, set up an extension department which initiated a successful programme of adult education through lectures, meetings, fêtes, radio broadcasting, pamphlets, and, especially, study circles, and sponsored the establishment of co-operatives among fishermen. Adult education among fishermen receives a subsidy from the federal Government ($12,000) and the provincial Government ($15,000). Short and mediumterm credit needs were met by a large increase in the number of credit unions. In the Gaspé peninsula, the region principally concerned, their number rose from 19 on 31 May 1937 to 40 on 30 April 1944, and their membership grew from 3,184 to 8,188. A dozen consumers' co-operatives were established to supply household goods and some occupational requisites. Finally, fishermen's co-operatives proper were set up. Their principal function is to prepare, grade and pack fish, but they also generally supply fishery requirements. By 1943-44 there were already 23 such co-operatives with a membership of 2,388, compared with eight co-operatives and 1,503 members in 1939. Since the latter year the fishermen's co-operatives have been grouped in a federation known as the United Fishermen of Quebec, which is an industrial organisation, an organ of technical, economic and co-operative education and also the central economic organisation of the fishermen's co-opera- FOOD AND AGRICULTURE 55 tives. In 1942, this federation opened a wholesale and retail sales agency in Montreal, obtaining the capital required from the Federation of Credit Unions, with a provincial Government guarantee. The establishment of agencies in other towns is contemplated. As a result of this technical and co-operative effort, the conditions of production have been radically altered to meet the needs of consumers. Up to 1932 only 3 per cent, of the production was marketed fresh or frozen, while 80 per cent, was salted or dried. Consumer demand for fresh fish steadily rose. In 1942, 52 per cent. of the production was absorbed by the fresh fish trade and the percentage had risen to about 69 in the financial year 1943-44. But the programme of research and technical training and of cooperative education and organisation would not have been sufficient of itself to put things right. The transport problem, and, most of all, the preservation problem had to be solved. As its contribution the State subsidises transportation by truck in areas without railway service. But its chief intervention has undoubtedly been its construction of 37 refrigeration plants all along the coast. 1 Two engineers, paid for by the Government, are stationed a t each of these—one for day and one for night duty. The plant facilities are for the use of the neighbouring communities and, more particularly, of the fishermen's co-operatives. The co-operatives pay a fee of 25 cents for each 100 lbs. of fish refrigerated 2 , and a rental of 15 cents per 100 lbs. a month for fish kept in storage. The refrigerating plants generally also include a large chamber or individual lockers for the use of local agriculturists. The experiment has been a great success and, allowing for its brevity, is quite conclusive. There are special features to it connected with local circumstances and, in particular, with the nature of the fish handled; cod accounted for more than 85 per cent, of the total catch in 1943-44. But it also has a general value as far as its principle and results are concerned. It illustrates the necessity of attacking all elements of the problem at once and makes it possible to discern which among those elements lend themselves to co-operative action and which require external assistance, that, for instance, of the State. In its general form the solution reached is adaptable to other local circumstances. 1 Construction costs ranged from $8,000 for the smallest unit to $100,000 for the J largest. 75 cents for the refrigeration of superior varieties of fish (salmon, smelt, halibut) and of lobsters. 5 t CHAPTER II TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING A number of factors will combine to make the problems of supplying fuel (coal, petroleum products, peat, wood), transport and power of tremendous urgency and importance in the immediate post-war period. These include the enormous destruction and disorganisation of the means of communication, the need for restarting production of the most immediately essential articles of daily life, even by improvised means, and the fact that recourse will probably be had, temporarily and in some cases perhaps permanently, to forms of decentralised industry. From this standpoint, it can truly be said that "if European rehabilitation could be summed up in one word, that word would be fuel".1 Ingeneral, co-operative organisation can make a much less important contribution to the solution of these problems than it can to those of providing credit and the means of agricultural production, of marketing farm produce and distributing foodstuffs, and of building dwellings. T h e contribution varies, moreover, even within the problems considered, depending on whether coal, petroleum products, means of transport or motive power are in question. Nevertheless, in certain fields it is already of importance, while in others it is potentially by no means negligible. Fuel As regards solid fuels, it can first of all be said that the most developed co-operative organisations—urban and rural alike— occupied a considerable place in the distribution of coal ; in the case of Great Britain and Switzerland they handled as much as 20 per cent, of the total trade. In the Netherlands, more than 1,500 cooperative societies included the supply of coal among their activities. In Denmark, there are even two central organisations specialising in the purchase of coal, and one of these comprises more than 1,000 co-operative societies to which it supplies more than 250,000 tons of coal a year. Under a different form of organisation, the British 1 Hiram MOTHBRWBLL: "Three R's of Post-War Europe", in Harper's Magazine, Dec. 1943. TRANSPORT, POWBR AND HOUSING 57 consumers' co-operatives dealing in coal are grouped in a special Co-operative Coal Trade Association; in 1941, there were 767 societies affiliated to it, with acombined membership of 7,661,115, and a coal distribution amounting to 6,765,949 tons. 1 Co-operative organisations have only rarely engaged in the raising of coal. Since 1916, however, the English Co-operative Wholesale Society has owned and developed a coal mine at Shilbottle, Northumberland, which in 1942 provided work for 721 employees 2 ; it also possesses two workshops for the repair of railway coal wagons. A few coalmining workers' productive co-operative societies were to be found in Hungary and Rumania. As to secondary fuels, mention may usefully be made of the peat co-operatives which developed in a number of countries, such as Germany, the Baltic States, Finland, Ireland, Sweden, and the U.S.S.R. In Estonia, for instance, there were 906 such societies, with 2,862 members, in 1937; in Sweden, 83 in 1936. Irish rural supply co-operatives in 1941 bought turf (and timber) for fuel, owing to wartime coal shortages, and quite a number secured bogs and engaged extensively in turf production; peat co-operatives in the U.S.S.R. produced one million tons of peat in 1943. Something should also be said here of the considerable part played by forestry co-operatives in the working of European forests, as regards the production both of firewood and of timber for building purposes. These co-operatives were found principally in the following countries (arranged in order of membership strength in 1937): U.S.S.R., 370,000 members; Rumania, 25,062; Bulgaria, 21,576; Sweden, 19,300; Switzerland; Finland; and Czechoslovakia. There is little recent information on these co-operatives, but what there is suggests that wartime necessities have given an additional impetus to their development (beyond normal growth), and these or similar necessities are likely to continue in the immediate postwar period. In Sweden, for instance, the societies affiliated to the Union of Co-operative Forestry Societies had a membership of 21,800 in 1938 (an increase of more than 10 per cent, over the previous year's figure), and at that date the members already owned altogether 1,941,300 hectares of forest, or 20 per cent, of the national forest stand. Four years later, in 1942, the number of members had more than doubled—to 53,000. Between 1940 and 1942, the trade of the Federation increased from 44 million to 1 In 1943, consumers' co-operative societies in the United Kingdom supplied 2 } ^ million houses and other premises registered with them under wartime rationing provisions with more than SJ^ million tons of coal. 1 A similar enterprise has also recently been developed in the United States, where the Indiana F a r m Bureau Federation has acquired an interest in a bituminous coal mine, with an option to purchase the whole business after three years. 5 58 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS 109 million Swedish crowns. This extraordinary growth is ascribed to the fuel crisis in Sweden and to the Federation's activity in the collection and distribution of firewood; in 1942, it marketed 70 per cent. (11 million cubic metres) of the 16 million cubic metres of firewood used for private consumption. Co-operatives in the U.S.S.R. produced 4 million cubic metres of wood in 1943. In regard to emergency measures and substitutes, which will probably continue to be necessary for some time after the close of hostilities, reference may be made to the initiative taken by the Swedish Co-operative Union (K.F.), which decided, as soon as war broke out, to build a factory for the production of charcoal for gas producers, in order to overcome the shortage of petrol (gasoline) for motor vehicles. In 1942, this factory delivered 197,000 hectolitres of charcoal for gas generators, 902,000 kilograms of wood tar, and 140,000 hectolitres of wood alcohol. European co-operatives enter the market for petroleum products to satisfy either their own operational needs or else their own and their members' needs, when the latter (agriculturists, owners of motor vehicles, etc.) are purchasers of fuel oils and lubricants. Though there are not the complete and accurate data for estimating what these needs may amount to in the near future, it is known that already in 1938 the co-operatives of the United Kingdom, Sweden, Denmark and Norway alone had an annual consumption of some 62 million gallons of petrol. This estimate—incomplete, inasmuch as it covers only four countries—and the likelihood of increased use of the petrol engine in both transport and agriculture together warrant the assumption that there will be a considerable demand for fuel oils and lubricants by co-operative organisations of all categories in all European countries. If this is so, there will probably be an effort to organise this demand, and, in particular, to satisfy it from a co-operative source, in accordance with the tendency already noted. 1 This source exists in the shape of co-operative petroleum supply associations in the United States and Canada. Since 1935, and particularly since 1937, one such association, the Consumers' Co-operative Association of Kansas City (C.C.A.), was making shipments of petroleum products to co-operatives in England, Scotland, France, Estonia, Belgium, the Netherlands, Bulgaria (and Canada). 2 The patronage refunds due on these deliveries were converted into shares, so that co-operative wholesale societies in some of these countries are now 1 2 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., p. 12. In addition, shortly before the war, co-operatives in Australia and Ireland showed their interest by enquiring about the prices and conditions of delivery f or C.C.A.'s petroleum products. TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 59 even members of the American co-operative organisation which supplied them. These shipments to European co-operatives were not very large and they were interrupted by the war. But they were a beginning and are an indication of possible developments in the future. The rural purchasing co-operative associations in the United States were still young at this time—Consumers' Co-operative Association was only eight years old—their purchasing power was just starting to develop, and they owned no oil wells, no pipeline and no refinery. During recent years the situation has considerably altered. According to an estimate made by the Farm Credit Administration of the United States Department of Agriculture, these co-operatives distributed 650 million gallons of fuel oil to farmers in 1942, or 22 per cent, of farmers' total requirements in that year. In 1944, they owned nine gasoline (petrol) refineries, one lubricating oil refinery, more than 360 producing oil wells and more than 1,000 miles of pipeline. An additional gasoline refinery of considerable importance is owned by Canadian co-operatives. Probable increased and organised demand for petroleum products by European co-operatives 1 , and, at the supply end, the position gained by co-operative organisations in the United States and Canada in the production and refining, as well as in the sale of these products, are the underlying factors in plans now being studied for the correlation of European co-operative demand and co-operative supply from the North American continent. Certain instruments of international co-operative trade and even of international co-operative production have already been elaborated. There are the Scandinavian Co-operative Wholesale Society (Nordisk Andelsforbund), which dates from 1918, the International Co-operative Wholesale Society, effectively established in 1929, the International Co-operative Agricultural Purchasing Society (Intercoop) of the same year, the International Co-operative Electric Bulb Factory (1931), and the International Co-operative Trading Agency (1937). These instruments have not yet all taken final shape or attained full efficacity. Nevertheless, their existence, and, in the case of some, their experience, pave the way for fresh developments. According to plans recently published, a place for international co-operative trade in petroleum products is envisaged among such developments in the future. The Committee on International Co-operative Reconstruction (established by the Cooperative League of the U.S.A. in 1942) has drawn up plans which 1 The large Swedish co-operative organisations most concerned with the distribution of petroleum products have just set up (1945) a National Federation of Petrol Consumers (Sveriges Oljekonsumenters Riksförbund). 3 1 5 60 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS define the structure and scope of an international trading and manufacturing association, which would be established either through amalgamation or federation of existing international cooperative agencies or else in collaboration with them. The plan, which in principle covers every continent and a large variety of commodities, would be carried out by stages. The stage regarded as most urgent and, in some respects, most important, is that concerned with petroleum products. It provides for the establishment of a fund of from 6 to 12 million dollars for the setting up of enterprises (wells, pipelines, refineries) capable of handling from 10,000 to 15,000 barrels of crude oil daily. Two thirds of the necessary financial resources would be furnished by contributions from the principal co-operative organisations of Europe and North America, and the remainder by means of a loan. It is impossible a t this juncture to say if the plan will be carried into effect, and, still less, what form it will take. Yet it merits attention, first of all for its boldness, and also on account of the interest which it aroused both a t the Conference on Co-operative Reconstruction at Washington in January 1944, and among European co-operative organisations informed of it. Transport In most European countries the joint transport of passengers or freight is generally regarded as a public service, whether this is directly administered by the public authorities or merely operates under the control of and upon conditions agreed with the latter. The contribution t h a t co-operative action can make to the solution of the transport problem in the rehabilitation period must not, therefore, be exaggerated. There are, however, instances of cooperative action in the transport field, which, though not directly connected with post-war problems, are suggestive in this regard. From time to time co-operative institutions have had to undertake the organisation of public services, as their principal or else as their subsidiary purpose. This has been the case, for example, in isolated areas or in large territories with a scattered population, and, speaking more generally, in places where the costs of establishing and maintaining the service seem disproportionate to the probable number of its users, e.g., co-operative post-offices in India; credit co-operatives laying on water and electricity supply in rural districts of Bulgaria; water supply co-operatives in Germany and Switzerland; rural telephone co-operatives in Finland, Canada and the United States; and a co-operative forest fire insurance association in Norway which maintains its own fire pre- TRANSPORT, POWBR AND HOUSING 61 vention posts to help prevent the spread of fires and so contributes to the protection of the common national heritage. Similarly, there are co-operatives that undertake the building and maintenance of parish or other rural roads and of the bridges on them: in some cases these are special co-operatives for the purpose, in others they are societies with a different original and chief function (often rural credit co-operatives). Finally, there are instances of bus and lorry (truck) and of ferry and boat transport services organised on a co-operative basis. Sometimes these enterprises are in the nature of consumers' co-operatives, in which case the members of the association will be those who require to travel or to move their goods, and sometimes they are workers' productive or labour-contracting co-operatives set up and operated by workers who find in them a means of livelihood. They can also combine the characteristics of both the consumer and the producer types in varying degree. Co-operatives of the consumer type generally meet local needs not otherwise satisfied, while those of the second type can grow to large dimensions and operate over long distances. Interesting examples of transport co-operatives of the consumer type are found in Canada: in British Columbia, there are seven transport co-operatives with a total of 1,835 members and owning 83 vehicles of various sizes, which take their members, who are employed in mines and smelters, to and from their work; in Quebec, the inhabitants of the Magdalen Islands in the Gulf of the St. Lawrence have recently established a sea-air transport co-operative to connect them with the mainland. In Finland, where means of communication are difficult, bus and ferry services have been organised on a co-operative basis. Along with transport co-operatives of this type, mention m a y b e made here of a class of enterprises half-way between co-operative and public action, which may be termed "public co-operatives". 1 These co-operatives have an affinity with co-operative action, in that they are managed by their users (direct or indirect) in association and by them alone, that the number of the members of the society is not limited in advance, and that eventual surpluses return in one form or another to their users. They are related to public action by the facts that membership in the association is confined to bodies corporate and that the creation of such enterprises depends, at least in part, on a decision of the public authorities. In the transport field, this formula has produced successful results which have not perhaps received the attention they deserve. 1 In French "régies coopératives". Cf. Bernard LAVBRGNB: L'ordre coopératif (1926) and Les régies coopératives (1927). See also Les régies coopératives et leur aptitude à résoudre la question sociale (Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society of Switzerland (U.S.C.), Basle, 1940). 5 62 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Examples of this type of enterprise are the Interdepartmental Transport Syndicate in the French Jura, and the National Society of Local Railways in Belgium, which, founded in 1884, operated some 2,500 miles of railroad before the war. I n a rather wider field, mention may be made of the co-operative society of municipalities recently established in the Department of Antioquia, Colombia. More than 60 out of the 90 municipalities in the Department belong to this society, which in 1943 built 13 aqueducts, 15 electric power houses, 27 schools, 3 abattoirs and 2 telephone exchanges throughout the wide area of its activities, as well as undertaking numerous repairs to existing buildings. 1 Transport co-operatives of the workers' productive or labourcontracting type have developed chiefly in Italy, Mexico and Palestine, and there were some ten of them in Hungary before the war. The Italian transport co-operatives numbered 380, with 20,000 members, in 1937, most of them affiliated to the central co-operative federation of the country. They included a railway co-operative owning a short stretch of railway, a navigation co-operative owning boats and barges, a boat-building co-operative, as well as co-operatives providing taxi and lorry (truck) transport service. In Mexico, according to statistics prepared by the Department of Co-operatives of the Ministry of National Economy, there are 265 transport cooperatives (with a total membership of 9,730), and 170 of these are affiliated to one or other of the 17 statutory federations of transport societies. Most of the societies operate road freight or passenger transport services, while a few run small-gauge railways or river or sea shipping enterprises. The majority are quite small, with from 10 to 50 members, but there are 12 with 100 or more members, and one, engaged in river transport, has over 900. The bus services in the Federal District are co-operatively controlled. Transport co-operatives are also an important element among workers' productive and service co-operatives in Palestine. Of the 23 societies reported, 14 are for carriage of freight and 9 (with some 2,000 member-employees) carry probably the greater part of the country's urban and inter-urban passenger transport. The passenger societies have a capital of £ P 600,000 and an annual turnover of £ P 1,500,000. A central purchasing agency has been established for the supply of spare parts, accessories and other requisites to all these societies. Under the impetus of war needs the Hamgapor cooperative in Haifa has retreaded 20,000 tires and has become the chief rubber manufacturer in the country. 2 All these organisations 1 The society's programme of works for 1944 included the erection of 44 aqueducts, 18 power stations, 5 hospitals and other important structures. * The Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society of Sweden (K.F.) also manufactures tires for motor vehicles (and bicycles). TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 63 have been able to make an appreciable contribution to the war effort and have been awarded contracts to the value of £ P 750,000 by the military authorities, for the carriage of goods and passengers. Their central purchasing organisation has collaborated with the Government in the collection of tires and spare parts. After the war they will probably be able to continue providing services which, at the time that they were established, had no attraction for profit enterprises. These few examples serve chiefly as a reminder of the fact that co-operation springs from necessity and the maxim of "self-help". They are purposely drawn mostly from experiments made in isolated areas or new territories, since in transportation, public service, and some other fields such regions are in much the same situation as the war-devastated areas. During the immediate postwar period, so many and great will be the needs in some countries that the public authorities cannot reasonably be expected to satisfy them completely and a t once (and profit enterprises may find that their satisfaction is not a paying proposition). Sometimes the needs will be so pressing that they must be satisfied by resourceful improvisation of a temporary nature, and co-operative action is essentially organised collective self-help. Such collective action in transport matters can be either encouraged or discouraged, depending on the nature of the regulations made in this field, or simply on the operation of priorities for materials, vehicles, fuel, and so on. While co-operatives do not as a rule ask for special privileges, nevertheless, the allocation of priorities involves the exercise of judgment and gives advantages which are bound to be discriminatory. So the question will arise, when transport co-operatives are set up, whether (as was suggested in the case of agricultural machine co-operatives) 1 the public interest does not require that they should receive a preference as representing a form of democratic economy that aims neither at profit nor at power. Electric Power Like transport, the distribution of electric power is normally regarded as a public service, and in densely populated areas, such as large urban and industrial centres, is generally effected by public authorities (State, municipalities, etc.) or by big companies, which are very often operating concessions, with their rights and duties carefully defined by the granters. However, its public service character is sometimes expressed i Cf. p. 13. 5 3 1 * 64 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS by the adoption of the co-operative form of distributive enterprise. The classical example of this is found in Argentina, where in 1944 there were 61 electricity co-operatives of an urban type, with a combined membership of 72,566, and a productive capacity of 22,520,762 kilowatts. A notable feature of these Argentine cooperatives is that municipalities are sometimes members of them as well as individuals. In 1937, there were some 300 urban electricity co-operatives, with a membership of 85,000, in Switzerland. By 1940, the number of societies, most of which were fairly small enterprises, had fallen to 287. Mention may also be made of a plan under consideration shortly before the war for the co-operative supply of electricity to the town of Charleville in France. In rural areas the problem has special features. The construction of a network of power lines to serve relatively few consumers is an undertaking which either does not pay at all or can only be made to pay with difficulty. Such an enterprise, therefore, discourages private capital in search of a return on its investment, while it is likely to place too heavy a burden on the finances of the public authorities who might otherwise undertake it. It is interesting to note that it is mostly since the war of 1914-1918 that the problem of rural electrification has been seriously tackled in Europe. As an indication of the progress made it may be mentioned that in Germany 80 per cent, and in Sweden 65 per cent, of rural undertakings had electric current in 1937; in France, 80 per cent. of the rural population were similarly served. Rural electricity co-operatives have developed in a number of European countries. The following table shows their number and (where possible) their membership in eight countries shortly before the war: Country Czechoslovakia Denmark Finland France Germany Italy Spain Sweden Total No. of societies 2,122 283 183 47 4,808 197 6 1,887 9,533 Membership 91,561' — 11,400 447,267 415,847 107,000 10,688 — 1,083,763 •Of 1,512 societies only. In some countries the electricity co-operatives accounted for an appreciable part of the national distribution of power. In Denmark, for instance, these co-operatives sold 100,000,000 kilowatt hours annually, 20-25 per cent, of the total power sales of the country. Co-operatives constituted about one third of the total number of TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 65 organisations supplying power in Germany in 1935. The data available for Italy show that the electricity co-operatives in that country did an annual business of some 200 million lire before the war. In Sweden, approximately one half of rural electrical distributive facilities were co-operative. Apart from the countries mentioned in the table, reference may be made to Hungary, where some 2 per cent, of the rural population received its electricity supplies from co-operative sources, and also to Austria, Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, Poland and Yugoslavia, in all of which countries there were a few electricity co-operatives. Outside Europe the greatest development of rural electricity co-operatives has taken place in the United States; since 1936, when Congress passed the Rural Electrification Act which established the Rural Electrification Administration (R.E.A.) on a permanent basis, the number of rural electricity co-operatives has grown from 50 to 850 associations, with 1,210,000 persons participating. Between the end of 1934 and the close of June 1941, the national percentage of farms with central station electric service rose from 10.9 to 34.9 (2,126,150 farms). Rural electricity co-operatives are of various types. The rarest are those which produce as well as distribute electric current: one such co-operative, in Czechoslovakia, had one of the biggest electricity works in Central Europe. However, societies of this type tend to disappear as rural electrification proceeds in a systematic way. At the other extreme are societies which merely distribute current bought from the manufacturer of power. In between the two types are those in which the co-operatives participate in some degree in the financing and working of the public utility or other undertaking which produces electric current. The majority of the electricity co-operatives in Czechoslovakia were of this type. Except in the limited number of cases where the co-operatives produce their own current, relations with other bodies, whether private or governmental, are involved. Thus, in the case of the Czechoslovak societies of the last-mentioned type, the co-operatives are connected with undertakings which are a sort of public cooperative service administered jointly by the central Government and the provinces, local authorities and the local co-operative societies directly interested. The financing of the construction of each electrified sector had to be undertaken largely by the users themselves, i.e., as a rule, by their co-operative associations and by public bodies. The individual consumers of current joined together in co-operative societies with the object of raising the necessary money, which was then converted into shares in the public utility undertaking, in the technical and financial administration of which 5 66 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS they participated. As regards the relations with other bodies of societies which only distribute current, a good example is provided by the Swedish societies which conclude individual contracts with the public water-power authorities, construct the overhead lines, purchase transformers and connect their members' farms or other premises with the supply. Maintenance and supervision of the lines and repair of consumers' apparatus are the responsibility of the employees of the societies, though they are assisted by advice given by the water-power authorities. Sometimes the share capital subscribed by the members of the societies is supplemented by loans (which the members guarantee) obtained from special Government funds or contracted with banks. In the United States, the Rural Electrification Administration has authority to make loans to public bodies and agencies, to private utility corporations, and to non-profit co-operative associations of rural consumers, for the purpose of financing the construction and operation of generating plants, electric transmission and distribution lines. By the end of 1941, the R.E.A. had made allotments aggregating more than $4,250,000 to 869 borrowers, 783 of whom were co-operative enterprises. Co-operative associations financed by the R.E.A. reported an operating revenue of $33,400,701 for the year ending 31 December 1941, and by that date 329,544 miles of line had been put into operation, serving 850,458 consumers. The success of the R.E.A. programme has thus been based on effective collaboration between the public authorities and associations created by farmers in order to provide themselves with electric power. The pattern found in rural electrification is thus similar to that in long-term credit, housing, fish refrigeration and other fields where provision for a temporarily or permanently poor population involves the investment of large sums of capital. There is a dearth of ordinary commercial enterprises able or willing to fill the need, while the persons most directly affected are powerless to act by themselves. The public authorities then step in to aid the latter to help themselves, which they do by helping each other through co-operative association. This pattern of events is so well established that it is safe to predict that it will recur in the post-war period. For the problem of rural electrification will be more urgent than ever before. Not only will destroyed networks have to be restored, but projects interrupted by the war will have to be completed in order to satisfy the urgent need for improved agricultural technique and better standards of rural life. Post-war circumstances, such as the necessity of utilising local raw materials and labour, may necessitate measures of industrial decentralisation. Such a de- TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 67 centralisation, which has been made possible by the electric motor, would be a further justification and occasion for a programme of rural electrification. The Housing Problem The housing problem holds a large place in most of the plans for the post-war period, and for evident reasons. First, there is the legacy from the past ; for despite the progress made in certain countries during the last twenty years, the problem of providing homes for families of the low and middle-income groups was nowhere entirely solved. A second factor is the stoppage or slowing down of building activity during the present war. Though the countries principally affected have been the belligerents (building activity in Belgium decreased by 89 per cent, in 1939-40)1, yet other countries have not escaped. Switzerland, for instance, experienced a 47 per cent, drop 2 , while figures for Argentina show an annual decrease of 250 million pesos in the amount spent on building. 3 Finally, in a large number of countries there has been widespread destruction of homes: in Belgium alone, according to figures published in March 1943 (during the German occupation) by the Commissariat for Reconstruction in Brussels, more than 200,000 dwellings were destroyed or damaged during eighteen days of active fighting and two years under war conditions (up to 30 June 1942).4 In its nature, then, the problem is not new, since it is in part a chronic problem, and in part the same as that after the First World War. It is new only in its dimensions: in Great Britain, the Minister of Health has stated that from 3 to 4 million new houses will have to be built after the war, and that it is planned t o build 300,000 houses in the first two years after the end of hostilities. 5 In the United States, it has been unofficially estimated that the nation will require to build one million dwellings annually over a period of ten years or more, in addition to the repair and modernisation of 32 million existing ones. 6 The problem obviously varies a good deal in some of its details from one country to another, owing to differences of climate, re1 2 3 B A N Q U E N A T I O N A L E DE LA B E L G I Q U E : Bulletin d'information, M a r . 1940. SCHWEIZERISCHE NATIONALBANK: Monatsbericht, M a r . 1940. Estimate of the Argentine Industrial Federation, cited in C.G.T. (Buenos Aires), 19 June 1942. 4 Cf. International Labour Review, Vol. X L V I I I , No. 4, Oct. 1943, p . 490. 6 Parliamentary Debates, House of Commons, 15 Mar. 1944, col. 271 (cf. Marian BOWLEY: "Housing Problems in Great Britain", in International Labour Review, Vol. L, No. 5, Nov. 1944, p . 60S). 8 Statement a t a National Conference on Post-War Housing, held in Chicago (New York Times, 11 Mar. 1944). 5 68 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS sources, customs, standards of living, and so forth. It is not proposed here to study the problem in all its diversity or to attempt any exhaustive analysis. Beyond calling attention to the fact that the circumstances of war have made it much more acute and urgent in some countries than in others, it suffices to single out some of the characteristics of the problem that are common to all the various countries, and particularly those features which more closely concern the role of co-operative organisations in the search for a remedy. NECESSITY FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION At least two characteristics require special stress. One of them— the problem's vast extent—has already been noted. The dimension of the problem is indeed such as to constitute no mere external aspect, b u t a fundamental element of which account has to be taken in the quest for any solutions. The other main characteristic which, taken in conjunction with the question of size, helps to indicate the choice of methods consists of those elements of the problem which forbid its solution on a purely individual basis, at least in the case of families of small or moderate means. Because of their possible influence on certain solutions, these elements merit brief discussion. (1) I t is generally recognised that private enterprise is not in a position to provide low or medium-income families with suitable homes embodying proper health standards. Building operations are inevitably costly, involving as they do the use of a great variety of materials and consequently the payment of a host of middlemen supplying them. In addition, the variety of the operations calls for the employment of a large number of different skills, thus limiting appreciably the use of the simplified techniques of concentrated industry. And, for the same reasons, the smaller a project is, the greater the cost, since a small project means an incomplete utilisation of men and materials. Thus the cost of building to some extent explains why the problem of providing cheap housing cannot be satisfactorily solved with any ease, and certainly never on the basis of individual contracts. This high cost is one of the first considerations leading prospective tenants or owners to associate for the purpose of house building. (2) The normal effect of the scarcity of houses after the war will be to raise the price of houses and the cost of building, .unless measures to the contrary are taken, particularly as there is also likely to be a relative shortage of materials (which continued priorities may intensify) and a possible shortage of labour. Unbridled competition for homes by those requiring them would aggravate the situation still further, and the solution would be hardest TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 69 in just those countries where the need will be greatest and most urgent. It scarcely seems possible to avoid or correct such a situation except by introducing order and discipline into the housing market. In other words, there will have to be a certain degree of regulation and the organised collaboration of the interested parties. (3) Houses for lower-income families are rarely built to order, and when they are put up for purely commercial purposes very little trouble is generally taken to discover and satisfy the reai needs of the prospective occupiers. It has to be recognised that the building industry is too often less concerned with providing convenient, pleasant, and health-giving homes to meet the needs of family life than with putting on the market a commodity which will meet with ready sale if the demand for houses is pressing. However, as the general standard of living goes up and food and clothing needs are more fully satisfied, requirements in the matter of housing become more precise. The post-war years may see an intensification of the insistent claim of consumers to. specify the kind of house they wish to live in. Yet the low-income families cannot have their way on this question acting as isolated individuals. (4) A further obstacle to the satisfactory working after the war of the system of individual building contracts—and this applies not only to low-income families—is its incompatibility with modern town planning conceptions. There has been a considerable advance along these lines in public thinking, and post-war housing plans are all in varying degree imbued with the idea. It is probable that the reconstruction of the more heavily bombed towns will be more or less inspired by these conceptions. If this proves to be the case, here will be a further circumstance favouring some form of collective arrangement rather than the individual building contract. The elaboration and execution of a general plan requires contacts with the interested parties, but these can hardly be established with a multitude of individuals. They are easily made, however, with organised groups. CO-OPERATIVE ACTIVITIES The problem of providing houses for lower-income families—in the cities and, more recently, in rural areas—increasingly engaged the attention of the public authorities in the inter-war period, particularly in the countries of Europe. The same problem, but on a far greater scale, in the years following the present war is bound to necessitate, in some form or other, much more general, more vigorous, and more systematic action by the authorities. The vastness of the problem will also call for contributions from numerous sources, and these contributory efforts will require co-ordination both among themselves and with the measures of the public authorities. 5 70 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Certain features of the problem, briefly described above, further require the existence and collaboration of groups of the interested parties. Among such groups are the co-operative organisations, and these must now be examined. Co-operative organisations will certainly concern themselves with the housing problem, to the solution of which they believe they can bring some contribution. In industrial areas their interest and experience are of long standing: urban populations have tried to satisfy their housing needs no less than their food needs through co-operative action. Distributive Co-operative Societies Fairly often, at least in the early period, one and the same organisation was given the task of solving the two problems, whether it was established at the outset as a combined consumers' and housing co-operative or whether, originally founded as a consumers' cooperative, it later extended its activity to housing, in obedience to the common tendency of consumers' co-operatives to interest themselves progressively in all the needs of their members. Thus, in Germany, one of the oldest and biggest consumers' co-operative societies, the Hamburg society, included among its objects (and in its name) the construction of houses in addition to providing for its members' consumer and savings needs. In the same way one of the oldest Argentine consumers' co-operatives—El Hogar Obrero (The Worker's Home), the parent society of the country's consumers', credit, and housing co-operatives—was intended from the beginning to provide housing credit, and has built and continues to build small family dwellings as well as large apartment houses. After the last war, the first achievement of the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society.of Switzerland (U.S.C.) was the establishment of the celebrated village of Freidorf, near Basle. Until about 1914 the British consumers' co-operative societies invested considerable sums (some £9 million up to the end of 1912) in house building, while at the present time a large number of them maintain "house purchase departments" offering credit facilities through which thousands of their members have become house owners. In yet other countries, particularly in those of Scandinavia and in Czechoslovakia, consumers' co-operatives have extended loans at low rates of interest to the housing co-operative societies. Housing Co-operative Societies If consumers' co-operatives have abandoned or, more often, reduced their housing activities, this has generally been due to the TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 71 difficulty of carrying on simultaneously two such dissimilar operations as real estate business and the purchase (or production) and distribution of goods. A further reason for such a reduction of activity by consumers' co-operatives in the housing field has been the fairly rapid growth of special co-operatives, which the consumers' societies very often have helped to form and to which they have given support. The development of these specialised cooperatives in urban and industrial areas is another sign of the importance of the housing problem among people in the lower-income groups. Housing co-operative societies are among the most recent types of co-operative organisation to be developed. It is noteworthy that in most of the European countries such societies were established or developed chiefly after the last war, as an aid to the solution of the housing problem produced or aggravated by the period of hostilities. Being of recent origin, these co-operatives have not yet always managed to federate, and statistical information regarding them is consequently incomplete. However, it is sufficient to point out that co-operatives of this category existed in 22 countries of Europe, and that Continent alone accounted for one half, or 10,747, of the total number of such societies reported in all parts of the world. Co-operative housing societies are of widely different types, depending on the particular nature of the needs to be met and the variety of problems requiring solution. But they are roughly divisible into two groups: (1) co-operatives that are essentially savings and credit societies, providing their members with advances to enable them to build or buy houses; and (2) co-operatives that build houses for sale or rent to their members. 1 Co-operatives of the second type were far the more numerous in Europe, accounting for about nine tenths of the total number of housing societies, though they only represented about one third of the total membership. No hard and fast distinction can be drawn between these two types, since housing co-operatives, like most others, show a tendency to add subsidiary functions to their original and chief function, either to aid the discharge of the latter or to provide their members with additional services. In Great Britain, for example, the building societies, in addition to their credit functions, centralise the purchase of building materials through their federation, which also places a staff of architects and experts at their disposal. Conversely, in Sweden the federation of tenants' co-operative societies, 1 Co-operatives with a membership composed of building workers and with the object of providing the latter with employment are an entirely different type of society. 72 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS extending its original function of helping to form societies and providing them with technical and legal advice, has taken up the purchase and manufacture of building materials and also encourages the members of the societies to save in order to provide funds for building. Both types of housing society demonstrated their effectiveness in the inter-war period. In Great Britain, for instance, the building societies 1 financed more than half of the houses newly built or purchased between 1919 and 1938, while in Sweden the tenants' cooperatives, whose real development dates from 1916, accounted for 10 per cent, of the building in the immediate post-war period and for a far higher proportion later. Housing co-operatives were responsible for 20 per cent, of the more recent structures in the Netherlands, and 33 per cent, of the modern dwellings in Copenhagen. Attentive observers have been impressed with the achievements of this kind of co-operative. Miss Elizabeth Denby, in a book giving the results of her own experiences in London and of first-hand observation in the principal European countries, discusses the relative merits of municipalities, public utility housing societies, and cooperatives as agencies for the construction of houses for the people. Her conclusion is that "co-operative housing organisation . . . probably constitutes the soundest basis yet devised for financing the supply of new buildings". 2 At all events, the part that these organisations were able to play after World War I raises the question of their employment in tasks of the same nature occasioned by World War II. There is every indication that the housing co-operative societies are preparing themselves for these tasks and that wherever circumstances permit they will receive the support and collaboration of the consumers' co-operative societies in the exceptional effort that will have to be put forth. 8 In Great Britain, the Building Societies Association has set up a committee, under the chairmanship of Viscount Sankey, to study the lines on which building societies can participate in post-war housing developments and at the same time assist in improving housing standards for the people. The vastness of the problem has led the English Co-operative Wholesale Society, the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society, and 1 In 1940, their resources amounted to £756,000,000, or more than nine times the 1919 figure of £77,346,603. * Elizabeth DBNBY: Europe Re-housed (London, George Allen & Unwin Ltd., 1938), p. 41. * The trade unions can also make a contribution, either in the form of collaboration with existing housing co-operatives, or independently. In the United States, some of the large workers' organisations have proposed extensive house building programmes, to be carried out on a co-operative basis and under union auspices. TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 73 the Co-operative Permanent BuildingSociety to consider ways of pooling their experience and financial resources. Similarly, the consumers' co-operatives in Switzerland are correlating their efforts with those of the housing co-operative societies. In the United States, the Co-operative League of Consumers' Co-operatives has decided to appoint a committee which will make plans for a vast building programme to be launched at the end of the war. T h e idea has even been advanced that one of the co-operative contributions to the building programme might be the establishment of an international co-operative organisation financed by co-operatives in the various countries and using materials obtained from these national cooperative enterprises. HOUSING CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES AND HOUSING POLICY The success of the co-operative effort now in preparation depends of course on proper provision being made for it within the general housing programme. It will also be necessary for co-operative organisations to mobilise quickly far larger sums of capital than they normally dispose of. The building societies' funds are generally derived from their members (some of whom are merely depositors or lenders), but their scope would be considerably increased if means could be found of utilising a part of the reserves accumulated by some of the consumers' co-operative organisations or by other institutions interested in the housing problem. As to the housing co-operatives proper* these will certainly have to look to other sources of capital than their own members' savings. The smaller the incomes of the members, the greater this necessity becomes. These societies normally complete their resources by •loans obtained from private institutions, municipalities, or the State. For their participation in the housing programme to be of maximum effectiveness, they must draw to an even greater degree on these traditional facilities and, in addition, must in future depend more than hitherto on help from consumers' co-operatives as well as from credit co-operatives, insurance co-operatives, and social insurance institutions. Particularly when their members are drawn from the very low-income groups, the housing co-operatives are accustomed to receive State assistance in the form of mortgage and other loans at low rates of interest and even of direct or indirect subsidies. Sometimes, for instance, capital is provided by social insurance institutions, with the State making itself responsible for a part of the interest on such advances. In most of the countries concerned, then, there is already legal provision, though it may be 5 74 CO-OPERATION AND PKBSSNT-DAY PROBLEMS capable of improvement, for housing credit and loans to housing co-operatives. In the low-cost housing field a link has indeed been rapidly established between co-operative action and the action of the public authorities. In fact, in many European countries the housing co-operatives were the agencies for the execution of a social housing policy whose successful application in large measure depended on the public authorities being able to utilise the disinterested services of responsible and easily controlled organisations possessing the necessary technical and social qualifications. Reconstruction Co-operatives There is one particularly relevant example of this beneficial and indispensable conjunction of the efforts of the public authorities and co-operative organisations in the housing field. The experiment in question, besides being fully characteristic, entirely successful, and unusually conclusive because of the vast scale on which it was carried out, derives its educational and practical value from the fact that it was made under conditions closely similar to those likely to prevail in the immediate post-war period. This was the experiment with the "reconstruction co-operatives" in France, after the War of 1914-1918. After some preliminary attempts made in 1918, co-operatives of this type really began to develop in February 1919. They rapidly spread and by 1 January 1924 there were 2,311 of them, with an aggregate membership of 168,266.' As with all sound co-operatives, these organisations met a real need. People whose property had been destroyed or damaged were faced with a whole set of problems, all of them complex and difficult. If each claimant had remained on his own, he would have had to find his way about in the legislative enactments governing the reconstruction of the devastated regions and providing for the compensation of persons who had suffered damage. He would have had to observe exactly the formalities necessary in establishing his rights of ownership, reaching an estimate of the damage sustained, receiving the advances to which he might be entitled, and so forth. He would have had, besides, in competition with all the other claimants, to look for an architect or contractor, and have plans 1 For additional information on the working and achievements of the reconstruction co-operative societies in France, reference may be made to the following: Pierre C A R A U D : L'œuvre des sociétés coopératives de reconstruction dans les régions dévastées; R. ROUSSEAU: Les coopératives de reconstruction dans les régions libérées. For a good summary, see V. J. TERESHTENKO: " T h e Work of the Reconstruction Cooperatives in France after the First World War", in Monthly Labor Review, Aug. 1943. TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 75 and estimates made of the work to be done. The problem was further complicated by the fact that the labour force employed had to be accommodated in areas where most of the houses had been destroyed, while materials had to be brought to places which lacked railways as a result of military operations, etc. Yet another difficulty was the existence of road, street, and sewage works and other public facilities calling for general plans that sometimes affected individual plans. While the State had established the appropriate legislation, financial resources, and administration, and had laid down principles and a general frame of operations, it was too far removed from individual problems to be able to go into all their ramifications and make all the daily adjustments necessary for their solution. In short, the State could not replace the indispensable action of the parties concerned. The functions assumed by the reconstruction co-operatives correspond fairly closely to that multitude of problems which could not be dealt with either by the State in its aloofness or by the claimants acting individually. Such problems included the establishment of claimants' rights, securing estimates of damage, managing the compensation funds, drawing up building plans, organising and supervising their execution, choosing architects from a panel drawn up by the departmental authorities, passing contracts, dealing with problems of a financial and technical nature, determining the relative urgency of works awaiting execution, etc. These manifold and complex functions are reducible to a simple formula: acting as a disinterested, competent, and easily controlled mediating agency between the claimants on the one hand and the State, architects, and contractors on the other. For the co-ordination of their activities and programmes, the organisation of audit and centralised legal services, the adjustment of their mutual relations, collaboration with the public authorities, the organisation of buying in common, and the raising of loans, the co-operatives of a single or several neighbouring districts began, from June 1919 onwards, to form co-operative unions, and, as a next step, federations. Finally, in the spring of 1921, a General Confederation of Reconstruction Co-operative Societies was established, which soon comprised all the co-operatives and their unions. The object of the Confederation was to co-ordinate the activities of the unions and their federations, to draw up standard forms of contracts to govern the relations of the co-operatives with the architects and contractors, to negotiate with the architects' and contractors' central organisations and with the Government, to float loan issues of the co-operatives, etc. The reconstruction co-operative movement was an entirely 3 2 5 76 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS spontaneous creation and membership in it was voluntary. 1 The spontaneity and accepted value of these organisations and of their achievements are shown b y the fact that in each of its phases development of the movement preceded the corresponding legislation. The first real reconstruction co-operative was established in February 1919, but this new type of co-operative was not legally recognised until 17 April of the same year, and it was only on 15 August 1920 that its legal status was fully defined. Similarly, the General Confederation of Reconstruction Co-operative Societies arose out of a conference held in Paris on 26 January 1921 and began to function effectively on 1 March 1921, while the Act giving it legal recognition was not passed until 31 March 1922. Reconstruction co-operatives undertook building activities in 2,716 out of 4,434 communes destroyed or damaged in the French battlefield area. In the Department of the Marne they operated in all except 10 of the 268 communes. In this same Department these co-operatives, in the space of a few years, almost entirely rebuilt the city of Rheims, where only 15 out of a total of 14,000 houses had been left intact. It is estimated that altogether the reconstruction co-operatives were responsible for 58 per cent, of all building work and 27 per cent, of all repair work in the devastated regions of France. The merit of their services was unanimously recognised and gained them various privileges. Since their organising expenses were proportionately lower than those of individual contractors, their work more efficient, and control of their activities easier, they were entitled to receive advances up to 90 per cent, of the amount of damage estimated to have been suffered by their members, instead of the 75 per cent, limit imposed in the case of individual claimants. Moreover, because of the special projects undertaken by some of the cooperatives, an Act of 12 July 1921 gave them the right to issue public loans, a right made subject later to the authorisation of the Minister of Finance (Act of 31 December 1922). A succession of Ministers of Liberated Areas testified before the French Parliament to the great economies in time and money effected by the reconstruction co-operatives as well as to their indispensable role as intermediaries between the State and individual claimants, and still more precisely, as the State's authorised agents. As early as December 1919, the Minister of Liberated Areas declared : "Whenever I see a co-operative available to replace the State's efforts, I shall be eager to put a t its disposal all possible facilities, 1 However, for obvious reasons of financial stability, the relevant Act (of 15 Aug. 1920) prohibited withdrawal by members from their co-operatives once they had joined. TRANSPORT, POWER AND HOUSING 77 materials, staff, and, if necessary, a grant". During the same period this Minister told the Senate that the organisation of cooperatives was one of the conditions necessary for the accomplishment of the reconstruction programme. The experiment with the reconstruction co-operatives in France 1 is suggestive in more than one respect. Considered only in relation to the problem of housing, it perhaps offers for the immediate future a broad model for a building programme stimulated, guided, and financed by the sole authority capable of providing the necessaryimpetus, direction, and financial means, namely, the central Government, yet decentralised in its execution and entrusted at the point of need to the smallest unit available—the co-operative association of the persons directly concerned. However, the experiment takes on an even wider significance, viewed more broadly as an instance of experiments in integrating State action with co-operative action without impairment of the principles, methods, and peculiar efficacy of the latter. These quite numerous experiments, which developed particularly during the last ten years before World War II, will have to be more closely studied later. 2 1 A similar experiment in Belgium originated in 1916. ' O. Part III. CHAPTER III I N T E R - C O - O P E R A T I V E RELATIONS An outstanding feature of the co-operative movement, and the characteristic which makes it, in the strictest sense of the term, a movement, is the unremitting and many-sided effort which it devotes to carrying out to its final conclusions the idea of association. From this idea it derives not only its origin and principle, but also its direction, vital impulse, and ethic. This idea is the source, moreover, of methods and achievements which can help to define the role of the movement in the work of economic and social rehabilitation and which merit examination from that point of view. There may also be drawn from it a general conception of production and exchange which, beyond the immediate post-war period, entitles the co-operative movement to a place among the economic forms and forces qualified to build a more ordered, better balanced, and more just economy. Within the co-operative movement the association of persons or families in small or large societies is merely a first stage, which almost everywhere is passed as soon as it is reached. Depending on their affinities and the nature of their common needs, the primary societies in turn associate in regional, national, or even international federations, and this federative structure brings to each society the advantages of a concentration of forces without impairing the autonomy of the parts or the flexibility of the whole. But it is not only co-operatives of the same type or having common needs that form ties of association or collaboration. The same tendency is found between co-operatives of different types that have complementary needs which they try to satisfy through a complementary exchange of goods or services. These exchange relations may be established between co-operative organisations with functions as dissimilar as those of consumers' co-operatives, workers' productive co-operatives, handicraftmen's co-operatives, credit co-operatives, housing co-operatives, insurance co-operatives, rural supply co-operatives, agricultural marketing co-operatives, etc. 1 It is to such relations that the term "inter-co-operative relations" 1 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 12 et seq. INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 79 is more particularly applied. They are not established by the simple and almost automatic process that brings together co-operatives desirous of solving their common problems together, but involve more laborious agreements and, in some cases, a greater inventive effort. Therefore, though instances of such relations are already fairly numerous, it cannot yet be said that they are general. Moreover, there is considerable diversity in the methods by which they have been effected. The most notable development of inter-co-operative relations, not only locally or regionally, but also at the national and even international level, has been between marketing co-operative organisations of primary producers (agriculturists, stock-breeders, fishermen) and consumers' co-operative organisations. Since it is these economic exchanges between organised producers and organised consumers that constitute the most readily observable type of inter-co-operative relations, they alone will be taken as a basis of discussion in the following pages. This choice is not only justified by the number and successful outcome of past experiments of this kind and the lessons to be drawn from them, but also has regard to the prospects opened up and problems raised by the development of such relations, as well as to the fact that the question has recently been brought into prominence by discussions proceeding and plans being studied within the co-operative movement itself. Advantages of Direct Inter-Co-operative Relations Reason suggests and practice has demonstrated that any machinery which establishes direct and systematised trading relations between organised producers and organised consumers brings to both parties and to the community at large considerable economic and social advantages. First, such relations represent a simplification of the economic process. A still more radical simplification would no doubt be the distribution of products by the marketing co-operative societies to the ultimate consumer through agencies under the control of the societies, or, conversely, either the production of commodities by the consumers' co-operatives themselves or their purchase of them directly from individual producers. But, in general, such a simplification is either impossible or inadvisable. Dr. G. Fauquet, one of the closest and most continuous students of the theoretical and practical problems of inter-co-operative relations, has written thus upon this question: For reasons of a general kind every endeavour, whether of agricultural cooperative societies or of consumers' co-operative societies, to cover independently 3 2 * 5 80 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS of one another all the chain of operations which separates production from consumption, comes into conflict with limitations which inhere in the very nature of the co-operative system of organisation. On the one hand, the efficiency of marketing co-operative societies is essentially a function of the cohesion that they set up between associated producers and of the internal discipline to which the producers submit. Now the results of this cohesion and of this discipline weaken in proportion as, in the chain of operations which separate the producer from the consumer, we pass from one phase to another more and more distant from the producer. Thus in the phases which are nearest the consumer, the efficiency of the consumers' co-operative society will be more effective than that of the producers' co-operative society. In cases where consumers' co-operative societies buy from individual producers not co-operatively organised, there is the disadvantage of excluding the benefits which for the quantitative and qualitative improvement of production may be secured from the control which agricultural producers exercise over themselves by their membership in an agricultural marketing co-operative society. So far as the direct exploitation of agricultural properties is concerned, the fact that these properties will be managed by consumers' co-operative societies does not appear to be in itself a necessary source of technical progress. The question arises for these properties, as for every other property requiring paid labour, whether peasant exploitation (on condition that it is supplemented by co-operative organisation) does not represent a socially and economically superior method. In fact, experience on this point in Great Britain of local co-operative societies and of wholesale societies is far from encouraging.1 The collective organisation of producers and of consumers, and the division of functions between the two groups, so far from constituting a loosening of the direct contacts between the two parties, is a necessary condition of them. Compared with the usual channels of commerce, which often involve a whole series of relays through agents, factors, and brokers, in addition to the three main stages of collection, wholesaling, and retailing, inter-co-operative relations undoubtedly represent a simpler and more direct route between the point of production and that of ultimate consumption. This simplification has immediately visible and often measurable effects. It results, for instance, in a considerable economy, since inter-co-operative trade relations eliminate numerous incidental expenses, such as commissions, profits, publicity charges, etc. The economies so effected benefit both parties to the transaction. Inter-co-operative relations of this kind also tend to constitute an organisation of the economic process: supply and demand, instead of being merely indirectly and perhaps accidentally linked (by circumstances of time or place), are brought into direct and permanent contact with each other. Knowing better the true needs, 1 Cf. G. FAUQUBT: "Principal Types of Cooperative Relations between Producers and Consumers of Agricultural Products , in Annals of Collective Economy (Geneva), Vol. I l l , No. 1, Jan.-Mar. 1927, pp. 65-66. INTER-CO-OPËRATIVE RELATIONS 81 as regards both quantity and quality, of the buyers, the producersellers can up to a certain point adjust production to these needs. Conversely, the buyers can control their purchases in keeping with the possibilities and conditions of production. Changes in the tastes and habits of purchasers and, on the other side, modifications in productive technique and capacity are quickly noticed, enabling the necessary adaptations to be made smoothly and with a minimum of delay. In this way sharp price reductions or sudden breakdowns of the produce market, which in turn worsen conditions of employment and standards of living, are avoided. From these direct relations there springs the possibility of a series of contractual arrangements tending towards order, equilibrium, continuity, and fair exchange. These arrangements may cover such questions as the time of or delays in delivery, or provide for the warehousing of goods on the basis of mutual recognition of needs. In every case their tendency is to end speculation and introduce elements of orderly marketing, as supply is at each moment exactly adjusted to the requirements of real demand. Inter-co-operative relations do not bring only economic advantages nor do they merely introduce simplification and order into the process of exchange between primary producers and consumers. At a time of general rebuilding, covering moral behaviour and social cohesion as well as the material structure, it is not inappropriate to recall Dr. Fauquet's observation that such relations reintroduce human and moral considerations into the exchange of goods and services, thereby achieving that reintegration of the economic in the social which is the very essence of co-operative effort : When and wherever the urban economy and, later, the commercial and capitalist economy develop, all social bonds between producers and consumers are broken, not merely by the physical distance separating the two groups, but still more by the impersonal and abstract nature of purely economic relations. However, if intcr-co-operative relations are established, elements of a moral order reappear, in varying but always appreciable degree. Throughout the cooperative chain forged by common efforts, the goods which pass along it no longer represent mere economic values.mere dehumanised commodities. Co-operators both of town and of countryside develop an awareness of the bonds uniting them. Between them is established a fellow-feeling which gradually wins acceptance for rules of equity and reciprocity in their dealings with each other and for respect of one another's conditions of life and labour. Inter-co-operative relations thus bring new life to the old moral conceptions of the "fair price" and the "fair wage". Like all co-operative development, they help to re-establish the ascendancy of the social over the economic.1 1 G. FAUQUBT: Le Secteur coopératif. Essai sur ¡a place de l'homme dans les institutions coopératives et de celles-ci dans l'économie (Basle, L'Union suisse des coopératives de consommation; Paris, Les Presses universitaires de France; and Brussels, Les Propagateurs de la coopération, 1942, 4th edition), pp. 35-36. S 82 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Gains of economy, order, stability, and equity in the processes of exchange; the repercussions of these upon the prosperity of the community at large; the rehumanising and remoralising of economic relationships; the rediscovery of the basic identity of interests between the sellers and buyers of goods and services ; the consequential strengthening of human solidarity nationally and internationally— all these are the objectives, at first perceived indistinctly and later with increasing clarity and definition, that co-operative doctrine has set itself in establishing and fostering the development of inter-cooperative relations. This conception has for long met with many obstacles in practice. On the national level a certain resistance has arisen from the supposed clash of interests and mutual prejudices of sellers and buyers. Such difficulties, often artificially stimulated for political purposes outside the co-operative movement, have been inimical to democratic growth. Internationally, legal or de facto monopolies and the shifting stream of regulations governing foreign trade have made relations between co-operatives of different countries difficult. Moreover, both nationally and internationally, a necessary precondition of the establishment of firm relations between primary producers and consumers is a certain degree of development of their respective co-operative organisations. This precondition was not fulfilled a t once or everywhere. Nevertheless, the fundamental tendency of the co-operative movement towards its own unity has already enabled a considerable number of obstacles to be overcome. Inter-co-operative relations, national as well as international, have been established and developed, particularly in the inter-war period. Progress became increasingly rapid in the last few years before World War II. Some Instances of Inter-Co-operative Relations Developments of this kind, usually hidden among the day-today activities of the co-operative associations, are not easily discoverable. They are outside the ambit of official statistics and more often than not escape description or even mention in the annual reports of the co-operatives themselves. They can therefore only be detected by means of special enquiries, such as those undertaken by the International Committee for In ter-Co-operative Relations, or through systematic and patient research, like that made by Miss Margaret Digby first in 1928 and again ten years later. 1 It is mostly from these sources that the following brief factual review is drawn, supplemented, in so far as war conditions have allowed, by occasional more recent information. Not many of the 'Cf. Margaret DIGBY: Producers and Consumers: A Study in Co-operatWt Relations (London, P. S. King & Son, 1938, 2nd edition). INTËR-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 83 examples, therefore, are very up to date and some may appear rather old. A few may even no longer be operative. But a far larger number have probably never been recorded. What is of importance here, however, is not so much to give a full and accurate picture complete in every detail as to show that a clear tendency exists and that its vitality is such that, even if temporarily interrupted by the war, it will certainly reappear as soon as conditions permit and renewed observation becomes possible. It will be convenient to divide the material into two parts, and to consider in the first place instances of inter-co-operative relations within particular countries and, secondly, those less numerous examples of transactions involving inter-co-operative relations between one country and another. INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS WITHIN COUNTRIES During the inter-war period domestic trading relations between consumers' and agricultural co-operative organisations developed in varying degree in a number of European countries. Austria Before the Anschluss (incorporation) of Austria with Germany, considerable purchases of grain and flour were made by consumers' co-operatives direct from the agricultural movement, while for the supply and marketing of cattle a joint undertaking, the Co-operative Cattle Union, was established by agricultural and consumers' cooperative societies. Local distributive societies obtained over 60 per cent, of their butter supplies from agricultural marketing cooperatives, and also a part of their supplies of fruit. Similarly, the consumers' Co-operative Wholesale Society derived a part of its fruit supplies and not less than 20 per cent, of its egg supplies from agricultural co-operative organisations. Bulgaria The federation and wholesale organisation of the Bulgarian distributive co-operatives, Napred, purchased large quantities of cereals and fruit from agricultural co-operative societies, and also obtained all its supplies of milk and dairy produce from agricultural co-operative dairies. It also maintained permanent relations with the beet-sugar factory and salt pit run by agricultural co-operative societies; a large part of the production of these two enterprises was absorbed by the societies affiliated to Napred, which sold the remainder on the ordinary market as agent of the producers. 5 84 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Czechoslovakia Before grain marketing was placed in the hands of the Czechoslovak Grain Company (in which there was organised collaboration between consumers' and agricultural co-operatives), the Co-operative Wholesale Society (V.D.P.) had an agreement to buy grain from Kooperativa, the Supply Association of Agricultural Cooperative Societies in Bohemia, in preference;—prices being equal —to other sources. At one time the V.D.P. obtained 10 per cent, of its grain supplies from Kooperativa, and nearly 60 per cent, either from Kooperativa or from primary agricultural co-operatives or individual growers. In rural districts, the local distributive societies were accustomed to obtain nearly all their butter requirements from local co-operative dairies. In regard to urban consumers' cooperatives, it may be mentioned that for a number of years there was an agreement between these and the agricultural organisations whereby the former undertook to open no more dairy departments of their own and to draw their supplies of butter and other dairy produce from the agricultural co-operative dairies or the central dairy organisations. Denmark The Danish consumers' societies distributing butter obtained their supplies direct from agricultural co-operative dairies and in certain cases direct from co-operative butter export societies. The Danish Co-operative Egg Export Society also sold eggs to some extent to urban consumers' co-operatives within the country, while the Danish Society for the Production and Marketing of Seed supplied the seed requirements of the consumers' co-operative stores dealing in this product. Estonia Local co-operative dairies and consumers' stores in Estonia carried on some intertrading; at one time 10 per cent, of the eggs marketed by agricultural co-operative organisations were estimated to go to consumers' co-operative societies. Finland The Central Union of Finnish Distributive Societies (K.K.), representing the predominantly urban side of the consumers' movement, obtained about 28 per cent, of its butter supplies direct from co-operative dairies, in addition to 19 per cent, derived from the Federation of Finnish Co-operative Dairies (Valio). INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 85 France 1 Some 70 per cent. of the wheat crop in France was marketed through farmers' co-operative silos, but the mills and bakeries of the distributive co-operative societies could only absorb a small proportion of the co-operatively stored wheat. There was also interco-operative trading in milk and dairy produce, either through agreements concluded between local consumers' and local dairy cooperatives or through agreements to which the Co-operative Wholesale Society was a party. Similar arrangements were developed in regard to eggs and fruit. The Co-operative Wholesale Society derived from 20 to 30 per cent, of its fruit requirements from agricultural co-operatives, the proportion in the case of grapes being as high as 80 per cent. The Wholesale dealt only with co-operative societies approved by the Federation of Fruit and Vegetable Growers' Co-operative Societies. Direct purchase by consumers' co-operatives from wine producing co-operatives was also fairly common. A special law was passed in 1936, intended to facilitate the creation of joint organisations and joint undertakings by agricultural and consumers' co-operatives, but circumstances do not appear to have permitted much development in pursuance of the Act. Germany Purchases of livestock, herring, eggs, and potatoes by consumers' co-operatives from producers' co-operatives were reported in Germany. In the case of eggs, the consumers' societies absorbed about 10 per cent, of the total output of the central agricultural co-operative organisations. These and other inter-co-operative relations were developing steadily, until the transfer of the funds and properties of the consumers' movement to the Labour Front brought them to an end. Great Britain Co-operative intertrading developed between the farmers' marketing organisations and the Co-operative Wholesale Society (C.W.S.), and also between the former and the retail consumers' societies. Purchases consisted of fruit in fairly large quantities, grain, dairy produce (mainly milk and cheese), fat stock, and eggs. No complete statistical statement is possible, but according to Miss Margaret Digby*, the Co-operative Wholesale Society purchased some £500,000 of produce from British agricultural co-operative societies in 1935. In regard to eggs, it is reported that in 1930 nearly 50 per cent, of the Co-operative Wholesale Society's domestic sup» 80 per cent, in 1937. For a more detailed treatment of this subject, see Margaret DIGBY, op. cit., Chs. VI and VII. 1 86 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS plies came from agricultural co-operatives. In the same year cooperative purchases of eggs by the wholesale and the retail consumers' societies represented 20 per cent, of the total egg output of the co-operative marketing societies. The most interesting form of inter-co-operative trading was that developed in the case of the Herts, and Beds. Bacon Factory, which became a joint co-operative undertaking of producers and consumers. A little over 50 per cent. of the total share capital was held by the Co-operative Wholesale Society and the rest by farmer members; the Co-operative Wholesale Society purchased 90 per cent, of the factory's output. Hungary The nature of the activities of the bulk of the Hungarian consumers' co-operatives and the structure of their central organisation, Hangya, are such that, though co-operative intertrading between producers and consumers of agricultural produce took place on a large scale, it is difficult to convey a precise picture of what happened. In effect, 90 per cent, of these co-operatives are rural in character and, in addition to supplying their members with foodstuffs, domestic articles, and agricultural requisites, also undertake the marketing of the members' cattle and other agricultural products. A portion of these products is distributed locally within a kind of co-operative closed economy. The larger part, however, is assembled by seven central marketing societies, which are in fact branches of Hangya. The Hangya urban consumers' co-operatives obtain their supplies of fruit, vegetables, eggs and other commodities from the village consumers' co-operatives, either directly or, less often, through the appropriate central organisation. In the case of dairy produce, both the village and the urban consumers' co-operatives obtain their supplies from the Central Association of Co-operative Dairies, either directly or through their own central organisation. Iceland, Latvia, Lithuania The situation in Iceland, and, mutatis mutandis, in Latvia, Lithuania (and also Estonia) was similar to that in Hungary. In all these countries, where the co-operative movement is mostly rural in character, farmer members of consumers' co-operatives sold part of their produce to their societies, and there was also some intertrading, especially between local consumers' co-operatives and cooperative dairies or butter-exporting co-operative organisations. Luxembourg Co-operative intertrading was important in this country, where the agricultural co-operatives marketed as much as 70 per cent, of their output with the consumers' co-operative movement. INTER CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 87 Netherlands Some business relations existed before the war between consumers' and producers' societies in the trade in fruit, eggs, and dairy produce. Nonvay The consumers' co-operatives (which in normal times used to handle about 25 per cent, of the farm butter produced in Norway) bought both from local co-operative creameries and also from the Central Export Agency of Norwegian Co-operative Dairies. There was also some co-operative intertrading in other products, but most of the consumers' societies were strongly rural in character and sometimes themselves bought and exported produce, especially eggsRumania An unusual development was the supply of foodstuffs (6,500 to 9,000 tons annually) by Rumanian marketing societies of the plains to credit, requirements, and forestry co-operative societies in the mountain regions, where food can only be produced during a small portion of the year. Maize, the common food grain of the country, was the commodity principally supplied. Sweden Co-operative intertrading has become quite common in Sweden, and through a system of firm contracts and joint undertakings has developed organised forms which have a suggestive value for the future. The Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society (K.F.) and its affiliates together derived their butter supplies to the extent of nearly 80 per cent, from co-operative dairies or their central organisations. These transactions arose not by mere accident or habit, but were governed by a contract between the distributive societies and the Swedish Dairies' Association by which the societies agreed to take the whole output of certain dairies, the price being based on the quotation for the whole country, with variations for transport, quantity, and similar factors. In the case of fluid milk there was a similar contract in force in Stockholm, while in Malmö a joint cooperative undertaking was established. In Stockholm, a group of farmers' creameries known as the Milk Central, which retailed 30 per cent, of its output (representing two thirds of the city's milk supplies) through its own shops, agreed to refrain from opening new shops in consideration of the Stockholm Consumers' Co-operative Society's purchase of all its milk from the Central. In Malmö, the milk distributing business is owned jointly by farmers' and con5 88 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS sumers' co-operatives, with one third of the earnings going to the farmers' organisation, one third to the consumers' organisation, and one third to reserve. In regard to meat, mention may be made of the arrangement made between the consumers' co-operatives selling prepared meat and the farmers' organisations having almost a monopoly of livestock slaughtering, in which the field of action of both sides in regard to processing was laid down, and an agreement similar to that prevailing in the case of the Stockholm Milk Central concluded. An interesting example of a co-operative joint undertaking is offered by the Swedish Co-operative Fish Marketing Society (Svensk Andelsfi.sk), set up by the Co-operative Union and the Association of West Coast Fishermen, to encourage fish production during World War II. In 1941, the trade of the new society amounted to 6,430,000 Swedish crowns, and it has already salted a very large quantity of fish botli for t h e Co-operative Union itself and for the Government Food Commission. Switzerland The Swiss Wholesale Co-operative Society (U.S.C.) used to obtain all its domestic egg supplies, all its cheese supplies (except for a small amount imported from Italy), and some of its supplies of domestic butter from Swiss agricultural co-operatives. These cooperatives were also the main source of the Wholesale's fruit requirements and a partial source of such supplies to some of the societies affiliated to the Wholesale. Direct purchases of agricultural produce from the farmer by the Wholesale and its affiliates have increased considerably during recent years: in 1943 they bought 15, 749.8 tons of fruit (compared with 6,814.5 in 1938), 6,374.6 tons of fresh vegetables (3,939.9), and 34,180.4 tons of potatoes (16,873.4). In a number of cases (especially milk and dairy produce) cooperative intertrading in Switzerland has assumed permanent and organic shape : in several towns milk delivery contracts are in operation, while in Geneva a joint undertaking developed—the Dairy Union'—which amalgamated the house-to-house services and rival shops of the Swiss Distributive Co-operative Society and the (agricultural) Associated Dairies. INTERNATIONAL INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS WITHIN EUROPE Before the war, international economic relations between distributive and marketing co-operative societies within Europe 2 had ' T h e Dairy Union has been the subject of study by the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations (cf. Docs. C.I. 9/30 and C.I. 18/30). s Instances of intertrading between European consumers' co-operative organisations and overseas producers' co-operative marketing organisations will be found in Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief,'op. cit., pp. 137-141. INTBR-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 89 developed furthest in the dairy produce market, though there was also some intertrading in wheat, bacon, eggs, and other commodities. Wheat Between 1923 and 1936, the English Co-operative Wholesale Society obtained part of its grain requirements from the U.S.S.R., through the Russo-British Grain Export Company, in which the C.W.S. and two British private firms were in partnership with several Russian co-operative and State organisations. The object of the Company was to purchase grain in bond in Russian ports or in cargo and to dispose of it in Great Britain, France, Italy, and South European countries. The C.W.S. had the first offer of grain coming on the market, at the market price, and received a rebate on its purchases. In 1926-27, 20 per cent, of the grain handled by the Company was bought by the C.W.S. After the first few years the Company's trade diminished—it exported as much as 685,800 tons of grain in 1926—but revived in the period 1930-1933. However, by 1936 the Russo-British Grain Export Company had been wound up, and thenceforward the small Russian grain imports of the C.W.S. were obtained directly from Exportkhleb, the State grain export organisation. Bacon and Pork In 1936, the English Co-operative Wholesale Society imported bacon to a value of £3.6 million. Two thirds of its imported supplies came from Denmark, and over 65 per cent, of this amount was bought from co-operative sources, either through the five C.W.S. depots maintained in Denmark or through the Danish Co-operative Bacon Trading Company (incorporated in Great Britain). This Company, which handled about one third of the total Danish bacon exports to Great Britain, had functional and structural characteristics which qualify it partially, but not fully, as a co-operative joint undertaking in the international field: its capital was furnished mainly by Danish co-operative slaughterhouses, with a small part contributed by importers, including the English and Scottish cooperative wholesale societies; its surplus was divided equally between purchasers and suppliers. Ireland was the next most important source of bacon supplies to the C.W.S., with some 35 per cent, of the total directly co-operative. Imports by the C.W.S. of pork from Denmark and Ireland and of mutton from Iceland, though not extensive, were from 40 to 70 per cent, directly co-operative in origin. 5 90 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Eggs The position in regard to the international co-operative trade in eggs cannot be shown statistically, but may be illustrated by examples showing the extent to which certain European co-operative wholesale societies have entered into such trade relations. The English Co-operative Wholesale Society used to import eggs from more than 20 countries, Denmark being the chief supplier, with nearly half the total, 83 per cent, of which came from co-operative sources. Ireland was the next most important European supplier, with almost as high a co-operative percentage as Denmark. Supplies from Estonia and Finland were also mainly co-operative. The C.W.S. likewise made small co-operative imports from Poland. Some English retail consumers' co-operatives appear to have purchased eggs from agricultural co-operative societies in the Netherlands, while the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society made purchases of eggs from co-operative sources in Denmark. The German consumers' co-operative movement, in the days when Germany (with Great Britain) was one of the largest egg importing countries in Europe, bought eggs from the agricultural cooperative movements of Denmark, Finland, Latvia, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the U.S.S.R. , In Switzerland, the Wholesale Co-operative Society U.S.C. received over 2 million eggs in 1931 from Austrian agricultural cooperatives; it also obtained supplies from the Danish Co-operative Egg Export Society. It may be mentioned that sometimes consumers' societies in rural areas, e.g., Poland and Switzerland, purchased eggs and exported them to consumers' co-operative organisations abroad. Butter and Cheese Inter-co-operàtive trade in butter (together with eggs and fruit) has been the subject of an enquiry by the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations (1933). Speaking of relations between co-operative societies of different countries in regard to butter, the Committee reported: These are clearly of importance, but the information given is as a rule insufficient to allow of estimating their volume exactly by means of direct calculations . . . It will be remembered, however, that the Danish co-operative societies have for many years been in touch with the English Co-operative Wholesale Society through the medium of the depots opened by the Wholesale Society in Denmark. The Valio Society in Finland reports that it has similarly been in touch with the English Wholesale Society, as also with the German Wholesale Society, during recent years. The National Union of Co-operative Dairies in Hungary has also got into touch with the distributive societies of Germany and Italy, and at the INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 91 end of 1933 it supplied the English Wholesale Society with 17 wagonloads of butter. Among the foreign purchasers-of the produce of the Netherlands agricultural co-operative dairies mention is made of distributive societies. At the time when Switzerland was still an importing country, the Swiss Union of Distributive Co-operative Societies obtained 78 per cent, of the butter it imported from Danish co-operative societies. In Czechoslovakia, the butter imported was supplied solely by the central organisations of the co-operative dairies of Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Latvia, and Lithuania.1 According to the same report, Danish butter (which is almost wholly produced by co-operative organisations) in 1932 formed 58 per cent, of the total value of butter purchased abroad by the central organisations of the distributive co-operative societies of the main importing countries. The English Co-operative Wholesale Society, for instance, derived nearly 40 per cent, of its butter imports from Denmark in normal times. Other directly co-operative European sources of supply to the English Wholesale Society were Estonia (from co-operative dairies through the Estonian Co-operative Wholesale Society), Ireland, the Netherlands, and Sweden. The Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society also bought butter from co-operative sources in Denmark. Part of the cheese imports of the English C.W.S. came from co-operative organisations of Denmark and the Netherlands. In addition to drawing on these European co-operative sources, the C.W.S. (and likewise the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society) drew supplies of dairy produce from the New Zealand Produce Association, which represents the producers' co-operative movement in New Zealand (through the New Zealand Producers' Co-operative Marketing Association), and the consumers' co-operative movement in Great Britain (through the English C.W.S. and, later, the Scottish C.W.S.). 2 In Belgium, the large consumers' co-operative society in Antwerp at one time made purchases of cheese from Netherlands and Swiss co-operatiyes through the medium of the International Cooperative Wholesale Society. Fruit It is extremely difficult to assess the extent or even to detect the instances of inter-co-operative trading in fruit. However, a few facts may be given by way of illustration. From 1926 onwards the French Consumers' Co-operative Wholesale Society was in touch with Greek co-operative societies market1 General Statement on the Part Played by Agricultural and Distributive Cooperative Organisations and by their Mutual Relations in the Butter Trade (Doc. C.I. 9/11). * For a description of the structure and activities of the New Zealand Produce Association Ltd., see Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., Appendix IV. 3 3 5 92 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS ing currants, which also sold to the consumers' movements of some other countries. In Great Britain, the C.W.S. for a number of years obtained 20 per cent, of its raisin and fig imports from a Turkish federation of agricultural marketing co-operative societies. The same federation at one time also supplied figs to the co-operative wholesale society Hangya in Hungary. Hangya derived its orange imports mostly from Fedexport, a branch of the Italian Federation of Agricultural Co-operative Societies (and from the Pardess Co-operative Society of Orange Growers in Palestine). In Switzerland, the Wholesale Co-operative Society U.S.C. generally tried to cover a part of its imported fruit requirements (mostly citrus fruits) by purchases from producers' co-operative organisations abroad. INTER-CO-OPERATIVE TRADING THROUGH INTERNATIONAL CO-OPERATIVE AGENCIES It is not always possible to observe or state the mechanism of these inter-co-operative relations. Sometimes they are effected through simple direct contacts between large national organisations and at other times through special bodies, such as the Danish Cooperative Bacon Trading Company. The International Co-operative Wholesale Society, while not itself engaging in trading operations, helped to establish certain of these relations. For instance, as already mentioned, it assisted a Belgian consumers' co-operative to obtain cheese from Netherlands and Swiss co-operatives. Of a more general nature was the arrangement reached between the International Co-operative Wholesale Society and the International Commission of Agriculture in regard to the exchange of information which might facilitate trade relations between consumers' and agricultural co-operative organisations. 1 More recently, the International Co-operative Trading Agency Ltd. was instrumental in arranging for the supply of poultry and grapes from Yugoslav agricultural co-operatives to the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society and for the shipment of tea, coffee, and spices in payment for them. It has taken tomatoes, potatoes, and oranges from the French co-operative societies in Morocco, and in return sent them tea and cocoa from the English and Scottish Joint Co-operative Wholesale Society. The Netherlands cooperative movement has used it as a channel for forwarding butter, cheese, and bacon to Scotland, receiving porridge oats in return. 1 For the text of the arrangement, see I.L.O.: Activities of the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations (Geneva, 1935), p. 30. INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 93 Nature of Inter-Co-operative Relations For convenience of treatment the examples of domestic inter-cooperative relations have been listed country by country, while those of transactions of an international character, have been treated on a commodity basis. However, in order to obtain a more precise idea of the true nature of such inter-relations, it is useful to classify them also according to their common characteristics, and, in particular, according to the different forms in which they may occur. The principal forms encountered may be roughly classified into: (a) ordinary commercial transactions; (6) contractual relationships; and (c) the establishment of jointly managed enterprises. Ordinary commercial transactions between co-operative organisations are no different from those that the respective parties might enter into with private business. They introduce no new principle, but repetition of them may set up a stable business relationship and prepare the way for closer ties in the future. On the other hand, firm or long-term contracts and joint enterprises tend to establish on an organic basis an uninterrupted chain from agricultural producer to ultimate consumer. The provisions of long-term contracts or special agreements differ widely in their details, having to meet a wide variety of local conditions: provisions as to quantities to be delivered or purchased; as to grading according to variety or quality; as to procedure for establishing prices or merely for determining what is the prevalent market price. In each case the purpose of such agreements is to provide by means of reciprocal obligations a stable basis for the development of business relations over a given period of time or covering a stated amount of goods. The following examples from the milk trade, collected by Dr. G. Fauquet 1 , illustrate the variety of local conditions to which the contracting organisations have to adapt themselves; they also show how collaboration between organised producers and organised consumers has managed to yield a satisfactory solution to the difficult problem of supplying large cities with milk. In France, for instance, the consumers' co-operative society in the Paris area before the war drew its milk from various sources. Among other arrangements it had a contract with a co-operative dairy which bound it to accept delivery of all the milk delivered by the producers to their co-operative. This contract was signed in 1917 and was renewed each year without the principle underlying it ever being called in question. The results were indeed such that the consumers' co-operative, in agreement with the dairy, requested the French Agricultural Co1 "Principal Types of Co-operative Relations between Producers and Consumers of Agricultural Products", loc. cit., pp. 70-71, 74 et seq. 5 94 CO-OPBRATION AND PRBSBNT-DAY PROBLEMS operative Federation to call a meeting to discuss the possibility of establishing similar contracts with other agricultural co-operatives, either already existing or to be set up later. The dairies expressed themselves in favour of an extension of direct sales to the consumers' co-operative, a t least as regards dairies which had not already established their own sales depots. It will be noted that in this instance the agricultural co-operative could not cover the entire needs of the consumers' co-operative. Sometimes, however, the position is reversed: the consumers' cooperative cannot absorb the whole output of the co-operative dairy, but pledges itself not to take milk from any other producer. This was the case, for example, in Stockholm. The same situation existed in La Chaux-de-Fonds in Switzerland, but a different solution was arrived at. In this town the consumers' co-operative has a contract with the various local associations of milk producers in the neighbouring valley. Under the terms of this contract the consumers' co-operative has to market all the milk delivered by the producers' associations; any surplus of liquid milk must be turned into cheese by the consumers' society, for sale to its members or elsewhere. As to the various co-operative undertakings, found both in the national and in the international field, these differ from each other appreciably in their purposes and structures. Though they seem to be met with more frequently in the course of milk and dairy produce intertrading (Malmö, Geneva, New Zealand Produce Association), yet instances are provided by the meat trade (Danish Co-operative Bacon Trading Company), the wheat trade (Russo-British Grain Export Company), and the fish trade (Swedish Co-operative Fish Marketing Society). Differences in the structure of such undertakings are considerable: there was State intervention in the case of the Russo-British Grain Export Company; the Danish Co-operative Bacon Trading Company, which grew up without any preconceived plan and remains incomplete in character, represents a joint enterprise in process of formation rather than in being; complete types are the Malmö and Geneva milk enterprises, the Swedish Co-operative Fish Marketing Society, and (outside Europe) the New Zealand Produce Association. But they all have certain common characteristics. Whenever they are situated at a suitable point in the economic chain connecting producers and consumers, they can satisfy the complementary marketing and supply requirements of both parties through a single operation. In their purest form they are established, financed, and managed jointly by the producers' and consumers' co-operative organisations, which have equal rights and equal obligations in regard to them. INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 95 COMPARISON OF D I F F E R E N T FORMS OF INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS It is not possible to lay down any absolute rule as to when cooperative joint undertakings are to be preferred to firm contracts, or one form of contract to another. The choice will rather depend on the economic, geographic, and perhaps even psychological circumstances of each case. But there is no doubt that inter-co-operative relationships, whether in the one form or the other, bring into plav new principles and motives deserving of some attention. Firm or long-term contractual agreements between co-operatives of different type have much in common with the now well recognised procedure of "collective bargaining" in the industrial world. In so far as these two practices reintroduce the principle of equity and reciprocal obligation, the one into the relations between sellers and buyers and the other into those between employers and employed, they may be said to contribute to the rehumanisation of economic relationships. Both practices prevent one party from imposing upon the other and avoid the necessity of recourse to the public authorities or other arbitrator of their mutual relations. It is true that both joint undertakings and collective bargaining exist and operate within the general legislative framework and under the final control of the public authorities, yet within this framework and subject to this control, the two practices have shown themselves to be more efficient and elastic methods than direct legislative provision. Reciprocal obligations between co-operative organisations of different type have also the same stabilising effects as the practice of collective bargaining, and these effects extend to the economic as well as to the social field. The fact that producers undertake to produce and supply commodities under certain conditions, and that the purchasers, on their part, assume a fair share of the risks run by the sellers, makes for security and stability, both in the sphere of marketing and in that of supply. It may even lead to order and relative stability—subject to natural contingencies—in production. The better adjustment between supply and demand expresses itself in a relative stability in prices. Stability does not, of course, mean that prices are frozen, but merely the possibility of avoiding sudden and sometimes catastrophic changes; the contacts established enable jolts and jars to be foreseen and avoided or a t least diminished. Any adjustments found necessary will be the result of mutual agreement and can' be made with due caution and by degrees. In a report submitted in November 1943 to the International Co-operative Conference held in London, Mr. George Walworth. 96 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Agricultural Adviser to the British Co-operative Union, drew attention to a further advantage of such contractual relations. He showed how they could become factors of technical progress, since the need for careful sorting and grading is increased in the measure that agreements contain precise stipulations as to price or methods of fixing prices. To quote his words, "there is no question of adopting fixed contracting prices for commodities regardless of grade, quality or pack". 1 The general rationalising influence that firm contracts involving mutual obligations exercise on agricultural production was clearly recognised by the International Co-operative Conference. The advantages of such contracts were summarised thus by Mr. Walworth : With such an arrangement between co-operatives, the producer knows the type and extent of his market, can concentrate on ideal production and handling, and can utilise waste produce or inferior grades for processing or farm use, thus minimising transport and wastage in distribution.' It is worth remarking that what is here given as the result of a particular form of inter-co-operative trading corresponds very closely to one of the objectives proposed to Governments by the United Nations Conference on Food and Agriculture in connection with measures "to secure the provision of adequate processing, transportation, and distribution facilities required for improving the nutritional levels of their populations". In a note appended to a recommendation on this subject, it was stated : Among the objectives of this action are better utilisation of foods not consumed in fresh form, the avoidance of loss of value of perishable foods, the prevention of waste, and the stabilisation of marketing conditions to induce as far as possible an adequate and even flow of goods to consumers.' Co-operative joint undertakings obtain the same and additional results through other more elaborate and intimate arrangements. While they may perhaps be regarded as the most perfect form of inter-co-operative trading, this does not mean that they are necessarily the most appropriate form in all cases or that they can be set up without careful preparation and planning. First of all they presuppose a high degree of development in each of the parties involved, as well as a fully matured co-operative consciousness. They also require a careful selection of the most convenient point of contact between the parties. Such a point will vary according to the commodity concerned and also according to the relative degree of development of the parties. 1 "Relations between Co-operative Consumers' and Agricultural Producers' Organisations", in Review of International Co-operation (London), Nov.-Dec. 1943, p. 184. ' Ibid. ' United Nations Conference on Food and Agriculture. Final Act and Section Reports (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office, 1943). Cf. International Labour Review, Vol. XLVIII, No. 2, Aug. 1943, pp. 139-1S6: "The United Nations Conference on Food and Agriculture". INTER-CO-OPBRATIVE RELATIONS 97 From the examples given it would appear that joint co-operative undertakings are particularly suitable: (a) for trading over long distances (in which case they perform the functions of import and export agencies) ; and (b) where the commodity has to undergo some transformation or a series of transformations which directly interest both the agricultural marketing and the consumers' co-operative organisations. In the latter case, the processing plant is the convenient point of contact between the two parties, as it is there that a common interest arises. When the product has to pass through a whole series of transformations, the joint manufacturing undertaking will be found higher or lower in the series according to the degree in which the parties have respectively forced their way towards the source of supply (consumers) and the final sales outlet (producers). For instance, both consumers' and agricultural marketing co-operatives are interested in the transformation of wheat into flour or bread, and this common interest can lead to the establishment either of a joint fiourmill (when the consumers' organisation is relatively strong) or of a joint bakery (where the agricultural co-operative has pushed nearer to the point of contact with the ultimate consumer). But whichever the enterprise, it will, when once established, serve equally the marketing needs of the agriculturist and the supply needs of the consumer. Joint undertakings are without doubt a novel and specifically co-operative solution to the problem of producer-consumer relations. "It is, indeed, not sufficiently observed", said Charles Gide, in a lecture he gave on the future of co-operation, "that every co-operative form is nothing else than the solution of a conflict. For what is a consumers' co-operative, if not the suppression of the conflict between vendor and purchaser ? What is a credit society ? The suppression of the conflict between lender and borrower. And the productive society ? The suppression of the conflict between employer and employed." Co-operatively organised consumers buy together and sell to themselves; the members of a credit co-operative lend among themselves the funds they collectively have saved or have obtained on the basis of their joint liability ; the members of a workers' productive society collectively act as their own employer. In other words, in each case the interests of the two parties are merged in the same person. It is the same with joint undertakings. It is no longer a question of reconciling or attempting to reconcile divergent interests. The supposed conflict is resolved, and with it the problem. Within the common enterprise the partners have the same interest, of the same kind and to the same degree, namely, the good management and successful operation of the common enterprise from which they both draw equal benefit. 5 98 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS It is primarily for the co-operative societies themselves and for their central organisations to establish, develop, and multiply these inter-co-operative relations, to adjust the means to the varied circumstances that present themselves, to improve steadily on methods already in use, and to invent new ones for meeting new cases. A Considered Policy This review of inter-co-operative trading activities, incomplete and cursory as it must be in the circumstances, is nevertheless sufficient to show the existence of a definite trend. The experiments made in the inter-war period generally had a successful outcome; they grew steadily in number and at all points demonstrated their conformity with co-operative teaching as regards both principles and social and economic objectives. Indeed it may be said that what was in the beginning a natural trend has developed into a considered policy. This policy has gradually been worked out both within countries and on the international level, by means of theoretical discussions and practical experiments which have progressively brought to light the nature of the problem, the difficulties which beset it, and the best way of overcoming these difficulties as they arise. The International Co-operative Alliance, at its second Congress held in 1896, declared that it was "desirable to establish in all countries committees for the organisation . . . of international commercial relations between co-operative societies". The question of interco-operative relations arose in some form or other at most of the following Congresses, but it is particularly in the last thirty years, beginning with the 1913 Congress, that a definite movement towards more practical measures can be noted. During this period the subject has received some attention at all the triennial Congresses of the Alliance. The World Economic Conference held by the League of Nations in Geneva in May 1927 paid tribute to the economic value of close organic relations between agricultural and consumers' co-operative societies. A special resolution of the Conference was passed in the following terms: Agricultural co-operative societies will contribute to a still greater rationalisation of economic life in proportion as they develop their relations with the consumers' co-operative societies. Direct commercial relations between producers and consumers, and between associations of producers and of consumers, eliminate superfluous intermediaries, and, when they are sufficiently widespread, result in the establishment of prices which are advantageous to both parties. In addition to material profit, there is a moral advantage; by direct commercial relations producers and consumers learn to know each other and to take account of the special characteristics and requirements of the other party. The producers' and con- INTER-CO-OPERATIVE RELATIONS 99 sumers' co-operative societies learn to appreciate the value of direct relations in accordance with their common principles. The clear realisation of the possibility of mutual collaboration and mutual confidence in business transactions are essential to a practical solution of the question of direct commercial relations between producers' agricultural co-operative societies and consumers' co-operative societies—a question which for a long time past has been settled in theory. In particular, the World Economic Conference recommended that: These efforts of agricultural and consumers' co-operative organisations should be encouraged and furthered by the creation of a committee representing national and international co-operative organisations of agriculturists and of consumers— a committee which should be entrusted with the establishment of a programme of research and documentation, as well as with the task of elucidating the lessons taught by past experience, with a view to bringing about new achievements.1 In December 1929 an informal conference of representatives of the International Co-operative Alliance and of the International Commission of Agriculture was convened at Paris by Albert Thomas, the first Director of the International Labour Office, to explore the means of further promoting organised inter-co-operative relations. As a result of this and two subsequent meetings, the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations 2 was established in February 1931, having as its object the development of moral and economic relations between agricultural producers' and consumers' societies. At the national level, thirteen special committees for the guidance and encouragement of inter-co-operative action have been formed in eleven European countries. Again, the development of inter-co-operative relations received particular attention at the International Co-operative Conference held in London on 25 November 1943 under the auspices of the International Co-operative Alliance. As already mentioned, one of the papers presented to the Conference dealt with this subject, and after discussion resolutions were adopted emphasising that "collaboration between consumers' and agricultural co-operative organisations is of particular importance in view of the great problems of rehabilitation with which the movement will be confronted after the war", and recommending that "the basis for collaboration must be the conception of the co-operative movement in all its ramifications as an economic and spiritual whole, and the recognition that mutual understanding and unity of purpose are indispensable to successful co-operative action". And, while recognising that "the concrete shape of the relationship between co-operative organisations could vary from country to country according to conditions in each—economic, social, legal, political, etc.", the Conference re» LB AGUE OF NATIONS: The World Economic Conference. Final Report (Series L.O.N. Publications, 1927, II. 46(a), Geneva, 1927). s For the achievements of the Committee, see Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., p. 18. 5 100 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS commended that "a definite division of functions of consumers' and agricultural producers' societies must be agreed upon, and, wherever possible, a jointly administered central organisation established as a firm foundation for collaboration". 1 A Conference on International Co-operative Reconstruction held at Washington, D.C., on 19-20 January 1944 adopted recommendations in much the same sense, including one which called on the co-operative movement to "expand international co-operative business between the various national co-operative movements, consumer and producer". As an expression of the desire for such action, mention may be made of the presentation at the Conference of a proposal for an Internationa» Co-operative Trading and Manufacturing Association, which would supplement or share in the efforts of existing international co-operative trading agencies' to develop and rationalise international co-operative trade. * • * It obviously lies with the co-operative organisations themselves to take the necessary steps to implement such recommendations and proposals. There is every indication that the co-operative movement, in the course of and as a means to its complete and methodical reconstruction, will steadily push forward the development of inter-co-operative relations. Nevertheless, legislative and other measures taken by public authorities can aid or retard such efforts, both nationally and in the international field. The better these inter-co-operative developments are known and their implications understood, the more likely they are to receive legislative and administrative encouragement. In particular, national laws hindering such developments can be repealed or facilitating legislation introduced. Similar encouragement to inter-cö-operative trading might well be exercised at the international level, in view of the fact that international co-operative trade is to a large extent a self-liquidating arrangement, making Government credits or advances unnecessary. These cooperative measures of simplification require at least the nod of State authorisation, especially in a period of strict governmental control of foreign trade, and the avoidance, in the planning of quotas and similar measures designed to create an ordered economy, of unnecessary obstacles to the full development of such a mode of international trade. 1 For the complete text of the recommendations, see Review of International Co-operation, loc. cit., p. 189. * Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 7-8 and 141-144. PART II Social Problems of Rehabilitation 5 CHAPTER IV EMPLOYMENT The terms employment and unemployment will be used here in a broad sense, to cover the situation, not only of wage earners, but of independent and semi-independent workers; of those engaged in agriculture as well as in all forms of industry, including handicrafts, cottage industry, and both small- and large-scale industry. The problems of reabsorption and redistribution of manpower as such, together with plans for demobilisation and the transition from war to peace production, are outside the scope of this study. It is proposed merely to place selected tasks falling within this framework in apposition with the functions and characteristics of certain co-operative forms, to determine what contribution the latter can make to their solution. The nature and importance of this contribution will vary from country to country, depending on the problems, plans and general situation prevailing in each. Among differentiating factors are a country's wartime position (belligerency, devastation, occupation, or their absence), its degree of industrialisation, the state of its agricultural technique, the amount of cultivable land it has available, and over- or under-population of agricultural regions. Before co-operative forms of employment in industry and on the land are considered, some of the social results of co-operative activities in the restoration of primary economic functions may be passed rapidly in review. If it be admitted that for agriculturists, fishermen and handicraftsmen it is the equivalent of unemployment to be dispossessed of their means of production (land, vessels, tools, etc.) through bankruptcy, or to fail to earn a livelihood (because of too high costs of production or too low prices for their produce, or a combination of both), then it follows that co-operative organisations, by supplying the necessary credit, by furnishing trade requisites or domestic goods at lower prices, and by marketing products a t more remunerative prices, help to ensure the stability of their members' occupations and to increase the purchasing power that they derive from their work. Since the same person may be and fairly often is a 5 104 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS member of more than one co-operative society1, it is not easy to estimate with accuracy the number of families so protected, but it is certainly considerable. It is sufficient to recall that before the war agricultural co-operatives and non-agricultural occupational co-operatives throughout the world comprised almost 75J^ million members, with more than 30 million in Europe alone (without the U.S.S.R.). When to these figures there is added the number of employees of co-operative societies of all types*, it may fairly be said that the re-establishment and, more still, the development of co-operative activities in the various fields would react favourably on the level of employment and on working conditions, both directly in the co-operative sphere and, to a less extent, outside it, where the cooperative influence is felt. Co-operative Forms of Employment of Industrial Workers As regards industrial workers, the co-operative contribution will be discussed under three heads: (1) co-operatives among the unemployed, as an organised way of utilising demobilisation bonuses, discharge grants, doles, etc. ; (2) workers' productive and labour (or labour contracting) co-operatives as they affect organisation and working conditions in the building and public works industries; and (3) the possible contribution of co-operative organisations of the occupational type to the restoration of production of consumer goods in countries whose economies have been dislocated. The first two headings fall within the classical methods of palliating the consequences of unemployment or of preventing its incidence, while the second is also related to the problem of national equipment; they therefore concern all countries, though in varying degree and from different points of view. The third heading concerns only certain countries, but these are quite numerous. CO-OPERATIVES AMONG THE UNEMPLOYED However perfect the plans for creating full employment and however efficient their execution, some residual unemployment is not altogether unlikely, e.g., in temporarily or permanently depressed areas or among disadvantaged groups, such as disabled ex-soldiers or workers, marginal or over-age workers, etc. 1 On the other hand, general statistics do not show the membership of all the societies reported. * Their number is not inconsiderable, especially in consumers' co-operatives, though nowhere nearly as high as in the United Kingdom (with 306,000 employees of wholesale and retail societies in 1941). EMPLOYMENT 105 In the past, the spontaneous or directed reaction of groups afflicted or threatened with loss of suitable employment or gainful occupation has sometimes been a collective endeavour to find a means of livelihood by a pooling of the members' human and material resources. Such co-operative action among unemployed has been experimented with in widely scattered parts of the world, e.g., the operation of disused commercial plants—a bakery, for example— by young unemployed men in Poland; subsistence production on the land for groups of unemployed in England; in New Zealand, the taking over by co-operative groups of a contract for railway construction abandoned by a private contractor; in the U.S.S.R., the organisation, in 1929, of "collectives" similar in some respects to the "self-help co-operatives" in the United States which will be considered later. In the first two instances goods were not produced for sale to the public, but only for the use of members of the group or other unemployed persons. The War of 1914-1918 led to the encouragement and organisation of workers' productive societies among disabled men: about 400 such societies were founded in Czechoslovakia (including some societies for the making of orthopaedic appliances) ; in the U.S.S.R., there were in 1939, 2,300 federated workers' productive societies, whose 240,000 members consisted of persons of limited working capacity as well as disabled persons. In China, displacement of thousands of people by invasion, coupled with the need of providing civilians and the army with manufactured goods, stimulated the creation of the workers' productive societies known as "industrial co-operatives". In June 1942, there were more than 1,500 such co-operatives, with a membership of 22,700, in affiliation with the central headquarters of Chinese Industrial Co-operatives ; their monthly production totalled 24 million Chinese dollars. According to one closely connected with the movement from its inception, "the conditions existing in the 1,300 little industries that have been set up by co-operative methods are not perfect, but they contain the seeds that can make for happier and creative living 1 ". More consciously connected with unemployment were the "self-help co-operatives" formed among unemployed people in the United States, particularly in the West, following on the economic depression of 1929. These organisations, which were of several kinds, represented "the co-operation of unemployed men and women who come together in groups to get for themselves the things they 1 Rewi ALLEY: The Chinese Industrial Co-operatives (The China Information Publishing Co., Chungking, 1940). 5 106 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS cannot get as well in any other way". 1 In the early stages of the depression (1931-1933), they were essentially barter groups through which the unemployed traded things among themselves and with other people, or where they exchanged, not goods, but services, or, again, where the group as a whole traded its labour for goods or services, e.g., harvesting a crop in exchange for food. From 1934, the emphasis shifted to production; the Division of Self-Help Cooperatives of the Federal Emergency Relief Administration set up by the Relief Act of 1933, with power "to aid in assisting cooperative and self-help associations for the barter of goods and services", assisted this new development. These production groups did many things: "landscape gardening, farm labour on shares, dairying, butchering, raising of poultry and rabbits, canning of fruits and vegetables, plumbing, fishing, grinding of grains, logging, carpentry, house-repair work, house wrecking, art work, dentistry, printing, making of bakery goods, brooms, bedding, box shook, crates, cider, cloth, clothing, furniture (also upholstery), maple syrup, pickles, soap, hand-made rugs, and rubber mats (from automobile tires); repair and manufacture of clothing, furniture, shoes, radios and stoves; operation of store, commissary, cafeteria, beauty shop, barber shop, blacksmith shop, coal mine, foundry, garage, laundry, sawmill, and wood yard". 2 For every dollar of Government money, the co-operatives gave their members an average of $2.25 worth of goods and services.* Between 1931 and 1938 more than half a million families were affiliated with "self-help" organisations in 37 States; from 1933 to 1938, public funds totalling about $4,730,000 (not including Government administrative costs) were expended on production enterprises of the self-help co-operatives. Productive enterprises were generally under the supervision of the State relief administrations. By the end of 1938, the number of self-help organisations (barter and production) in the United States was already considerably less than in the peak years of the depression. Since self-help co-operatives rarely had money enough to pay the workers, they sometimes issued certificates for work done, redeemable in goods or services, known as "scrip". Care was ex1 Self-Help Co-operatives, An Introductory Study (Division of Self-Help Cooperatives, Federal Emergency Relief Administration, Washington, D.C., undated), p. 3. 2 Idem, p. 8 a During the 1933-34 depression, the Department of Welfare of the State of California made a study of the costs of relief given through some 300 selfhelp co-operatives in Los Angeles county and found that it cost only one seventh as much to take care of a family through the self-help co-operative as it did through a direct dole. EMPLOYMENT 107 ercised in the issue of scrip that it should be backed by goods or services of a kind that people needed. Particularly in the case of rural self-help co-operatives, it not infrequently happened that permanent co-operative enterprises developed out of the emergency organisation. For instance, a selfhelp co-operative organised in 1935 by a group of farm families in Idaho constructed a small lumber sawmill in order to supplement its members' income during the winter and to build necessary farm buildings. Later production was entirely for war use. This and similar co-operatives were organised with the assistance of the U.S. Farm Security Administration which was confined chiefly to small farmers unable to obtain financial credit from any other source. Rural self-help co-operatives relieve unemployment (due to lack of land, machinery, sire service, marketing or transport facilities, etc.) or underemployment (through undersized farms or unfavourable climate for year-round operations) by enabling groups of farmers to open up land (e.g., collective acquisition of a bulldozer), operate a tractor, set up a cannery or cheese plant, form a forest "harvesting" association, and so on. In certain cases, these activities are performed by small and quite informal cooperative "groups", analogous to the "co-operative buying clubs" which sometimes precede the formation of a consumers' co-operative society in the United States. 1 An unemployed group of 15 families in a village in the State of Idaho, using as a revolving fund a grant of $1,750 from the Federal Emergency Relief Administration, managed by group action to provide themselves with homes and other buildings valued at ten times that amount. 2 Of the "self-help co-operatives" in the United States it has been said3 that while they obviously cannot be expected to take the place of either direct or work relief, they appear to offer an acceptable form of public aid to a limited group, particularly older and under-employed workers who can meet at least part of their needs through their own efforts. Despite their many limitations, the co-operatives have furnished a certain amount of work and training to persons in need of total or partial public support, and they have often also provided recreational and social facilities. It is also significant, in evaluating this form of public aid, that surveys of public opinion and of the attitude of the members themselves have 1 Cf. Joe J. KING: "Rural Co-operative Self-Help Activities in the Pacific Northwest", in American Sociological Review, Dec. 1943, pp. 706-710. 5 Among other examples of "self-help housing co-operatives", in which members contributed their own labour as well as cash, mention may be made of the Penn-Craft Community in Pennsylvania and the Tompkinsville Housing Society in Nova Scotia, Canada, in both of which the members were mostly coal3 miners without full employment. U.S. NATIONAL RESOURCES PLANNING BOARD: Security, Work and Relief Policies (Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1942). 3 4 5 108 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS been generally favourable, although with reservations concerning their effect upon retailers. If economic situations similar to those prevailing in 1931rl935 arise in the post-war period it is likely that there will be a similar need for "self-help co-operatives". Co-operative leaders in the United States have expressed the view that consumers' co-operative organisations "should step in and take the leadership in the development of such co-operatives in order to tie them as closely as possible in with the consumers' co-operative movement and establish them on a more permanent and socially useful basis". 1 Such a connection between the "self-help co-operatives" and the existing cooperative movement would help to secure continuity between the relief and rehabilitation periods and to make the most of the capacities for self-help and mutual aid developed by participation in these emergency organisations. BUILDING AND PUBLIC W O R K S The building and public works industry, combining skilled and unskilled labour in happy proportion, has always been thought capable of absorbing a considerable amount of idle manpower. Because of the number of professions and crafts that it directly or indirectly concerns, there is even a general—and perhaps excessive— inclination in times of economic depression to believe that a revival in the activity of this industry can largely suffice to set the economic machine working again. There can be little doubt, at all events, that the industry can look forward to a good many years of expansive activity in view of the urgent and necessary tasks awaiting execution in the devastated countries: the rebuilding or restoration of ports, roads, railways, bridges, tunnels, canals, stations, and other public buildings, factories and dwellings, while possible and certainly useful works in all countries will be the building of homes and the carrying out of a vast programme of national equipment. But such a vast programme will present problems of finance and also of efficient organisation in its execution, especially if it is "to assure the prompt and orderly use of human and material resources, avoiding on the one hand rush demands for materials which leave contractors temporarily in short supply, and on the other hand inadequate development of demand". 2 It will also raise the ques1 W. J. CAMPBELL: "A Report on Cooperative Post-War Planning", in Consumers' Cooperation, Dec. 1943. ' See the Public Works (National Planning) Recommendation 1944 (No. 73), adopted bv the 26th Session of the International Labour Conference (I.L.O.: Official Bulletin, Vol. XXVI, No. 1, 1 June 1944, p. 75). EMPLOYMENT 109 tion of what special measures will be necessary to assure the protection of the considerable body of workers engaged on these works. In reality all these problems are more or less linked together. For the dimensions of the task will necessarily call for the assistance of the public authorities as providers of capital and credit. Under these circumstances they will possess the responsibility as well as the right and the means of exercising a certain control over the organisation and execution of the works, over the application of the capital and credit they supply, and over the working conditions of those employed on the various schemes. Like long-term credit, housing and rural electrification, this is another case where the authorities, called on to provide stimulus, guidance or control in a field of social or economic life, will have to seek means of execution that are at the same time elements of order and discipline. Workers' Productive and Labour-Contracting Co-operatives Possibilities are offered in this connection by two related forms of co-operative: workers' productive co-operatives and labour-contracting co-operatives or co-operative labour groups or gangs. A workers' productive co-operative exercises the full responsibility of an entrepreneur as regards capital, technical direction, commercial policy, etc. A labour-contracting co-operative, on the other hand, generally has little or no capital and does not bear the multifarious responsibilities of a complete undertaking; it replaces, in its relation to its member-workers and to those who employ it, the subcontractor or foreman. Both types aim a t securing the workers' independence and his dignity in the performance of his work. Between the two types there are, of course, transitional forms: labour co-operatives with some capital equipment, or workers' productive co-operatives with very little. In continental Europe, and more particularly in Czechoslovakia, Denmark, France, Italy, and Switzerland, a large proportion of the workers' productive co-operatives were building and public works societies. In France, for example, out of 474 workers' productive co-operatives in 1939, 274 were of this type, and by 1943 their number had grown to 309 (out of 526). They were among the most important contractors for the building of pavilions at the Paris Exhibition of 1937. In all the countries named except France, and, a t one time, in Germany, the building and public works societies had even organised separate federations. It is, however, in Italy and, outside Europe, in Palestine, that they have probably attained the highest degree of organisation. In 5 110 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Italy, workers' productive and labour co-operatives were an outstanding feature of the co-operative movement before the war. Some of these societies were engaged on building and public works," and even on shipbuilding. The members of these groups generally worked in squads of about 15 in carrying out any particular contract, since it was found that esprit de corps was more easily maintained in small groups. The various societies were generally grouped in provincial federations, whose principal functions were the distribution of contracts involving a number of different services among the societies or groups, the production, in some cases, of building materials and the maintenance of heavy machines, such as trucks and roadcrushers, used by the societies in their work, and thirdly, the examination of tenders, general direction over the execution of the work (often through committees of architects and other technicians). It seems that sometimes large societies exercised all or some of these functions themselves. The labour co-operatives were particularly strong in the provinces of Bologna and Ravenna. In the city of Ravenna they built the town hall and also a large school; the society in Faenza held a contract for the maintenance of all the roads in the province and built a palace for government offices. The provincial federations in turn belonged to a national federation of workers' co-operative societies. Outside Europe, co-operative building and contracting has developed furthest in Palestine, where co-operatives in which new immigrants were trained as buildingvworkers developed into labourcontracting co-operatives. These were later federated in an organisation called Solel Boneh, the contracting department of the Federation of Jewish Labour (Histadrut), which in turn employed its member societies as well as unregistered co-operative groups of workers on the execution of its building and public works contracts. Solel Boneh and a similar organisation, the Tel Aviv Contracting Co-operative Office (Misrad Hakablani), have both been utilised by the public authorities for the execution of numerous projects, ranging from the construction of temporary camps to the erection of buildings, fortifications and port works. Since 1939, Solel Boneh has carried out works to the value of £P7.5 million, while the Tel Aviv Office in the 13 years of its existence carried out works valued at £P 3.5 million, including £P 700,000 in 1942 alone. These two central organisations have recently been amalgamated. In New Zealand, co-operative contracting has been used in the construction of public works for fifty years, and has also been regarded as a method of administering relief works for the unem- EMPLOYMENT 111 ployed. 1 In 1939, three eighths of all the workers employed by the Government on public works were under the co-operative contract system. The method now in use is laid down in an agreement made in 1939 between the New Zealand Workers' Union and the Public Works Department, under which a written contract containing elaborate provisions is made between a representative of the Department and the members of the workers' group engaged on each project. On all public works jobs the Workers' Union has a local committee and inspector who exercise control over prices and represent the men in all disputes arising out of co-operative contracts. While these workers' societies concerned with building and public works are not numerous, they have a tendency to spread, and, as the examples show, are capable of forming a solid system of enterprises and subenterprises of proved efficacy.8 The persistency with which these co-operatives are established claims attention and suggests that they meet a part of the demands of labour. Security is the chief preoccupation at the moment, but as this basic need gets satisfied, the demand will grow that work shall be performed under conditions which guarantee the independence and dignity of the person. Those most attached to this principle include in their conception of security opportunity for the free exercise of individual capacities for work, foresight and group action. It is difficult to estimate the prospects of such organisations in the postwar period, but it is perhaps indicative that the Swiss Co-operative Union has recently included labour co-operatives on its studycircle syllabus and has a special booklet prepared on the subject. 3 As early as 1921, on the occasion of a report submitted by Albert Thomas, the first Director of the International Labour Office, the Eleventh International Co-operative Congress (Ghent) discussed the part that labour co-operative societies could play in the organisation of industrial work. Owing to the opportunities which they give to certain categories of workers who feel the need for Independence and creative expression of their faculties, these organisations should certainly not be overlooked and would even seem to merit encouragement. The bodies responsible for financing, organising and controlling large 1 And in the mining, saw-milling and various other industries. See, Dr. Anthony E. C. HARE: "Co-operative Contracting in New Zealand", in International Labour Review, Vol. LI, No. 2, Feb. 1945, pp. 167-190. » This type of organisation of work has developed not only in the public works and building industries but in other industries and in a number of countries. For a particularly typical example, see Charles MARAUX: "The Commandite: Co-operative Work in the French Printing Industry", in International Labour Review, Vol. XII, No. 5, Nov. 1925, pp. 693-711. ' Dr. G. FAUQUET: L'Organisation du travail par équipes coopératives (Bibliothèque coopérative populaire: No. 24: L'Union suisse des coopératives de consommation (U.S.C.), Basle, 1943). 3 4 * 5 112 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS reconstruction schemes or other public works undertakings will appreciate the advantage to the work of being able to deal with organised, disciplined and easily controlled groups of workers with a sense of responsibility. Since one of the objects of the works is to create and widely distribute purchasing power, there is the further advantage in dealing with such groups that the whole of the amounts paid for labour will be received by the persons actually performing it, without deductions of a parasitic nature. Moreover, encouragement given to these organisations helps them to rid the building industry of the economically and morally reprehensible practice of "job-work", which involves sweating and other abuses. Besides being a satisfactory substitute for this undesirable method of hiring labour, labour co-operatives help to develop democratic forms of organising work and so to further the démocratisation of the whole economy. It is reasonable to assume that in the course of any public works scheme a large number of contracts will be drawn up by the public authorities or under their control. For some time it has been generally accepted, in democratic countries a t least, that the latter, in contracting for the execution of constructional work, should concern themselves with the working conditions under which the operations in question are carried out. In this connection specifications might explicitly prohibit job work, with adequate penalties for non-observance. Workers' productive co-operatives can be encouraged by the extension of credits and also by favourable treatment by the public authorities in tendering for contracts, as was the case in France. It is difficult to improvise workers' productive co-operatives, but labour-contracting co-operatives and co-operative labour groups are much more easily organised, and their formation, in collaboration with or under the control of the trade unions, could be encouraged in contracts made by the public authorities. In return, the workers' productive co-operatives and the labour co-operatives or groups could be made to assume certain obligations, such as the employment of disabled persons, the employment of apprentices, and vocational training. FORMS O F SCATTERED INDUSTRY The occasions and forms of employment so far discussed concern problems that under one aspect or another and in varying degree can arise in almost every country. But there are also problems peculiar to certain countries only. The one now to be examined is principally related to countries whose apparatus of industrial EMPLOYMENT 113 production has been wrecked by the devastation of war or enemy occupation, or, often, by a combination of the two. 1 This dislocation of industry will inevitably have consequences in the social as well as in the economic field, and particularly in the sphere of employment. Destruction of factories and loss or complete breakdown of machinery in such countries, coupled with difficulties in obtaining necessary credits promptly, scarcity of certain raw materials, dislocation of communications, and lack of transport make it unlikely that every branch of industry can start again immediately in its most modern form and so absorb rapidly a great quantity of manpower. It is therefore not unreasonable to foresee a period—of varying length, according to the industries and countries concerned—in which the problem of employment will largely be covered by the formula: "find work for as many people as possible with a minimum of capital expenditure and a minimum of imported raw materials". In other words, because of the interruption or inadequacy of communications, local or regional needs will have to be met primarily through use of local or regional resources in manpower and raw materials. New sources of wealth and employment will perhaps have to be sought in material and intellectual fields hitherto neglected. During this period recourse will almost certainly have to be had to the manifold forms of scattered industry—some of which are today regarded as out of date—included in the complex amalgam of cottage industries, home workers, handicraftsmen proper, and a whole series of intermediate forms of such production. Not only in Asia, but also in European countries (including the most industrialised), these forms of industrial production till recently gave and can still give employment to a large number of workers. Rarely absorbed by industrial concentration, they have in some cases been little affected by it and in others have derived a new vitality from preparatory or complementary operations performed to satisfy its needs. Cottage Industry and Home Work Cottage industries are found mainly in agricultural countries, more particularly in regions where overpopulation or climatic conditions force agriculturists to seek a supplementary source of income. They play an important part in China, India, Japan, Nor1 Certain of the observations which follow also to some extent concern the underindustrialised countries. But the problem facing these countries of course includes other elements not considered here. 5 114 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS way, Rumania, Sweden, the U.S.S.R., and Yugoslavia, as well as elsewhere. Home work often occurs as a degenerate form of a cottage industry, especially where the latter produces for a distant market. The formerly independent workers, having lost contact with the market, become home workers attached to an entrepreneur who supplies them with the necessary raw materials and markets the product of their labour. This combination, which Le Play terms "collective factory", is at the present time chiefly found in cities. In particular, it is predominant in the clothing industry throughout the world, including the most highly industrialised countries. Widespread though they are, these extremely varied forms of industrial production are not easily brought within the realm of statistics. In industrial censuses they are sometimes included among handicraft enterprises, sometimes they are counted separately and often they are not counted a t all. It even happens—in the case, for instance, of the "collective factory"—that they are classified with large-scale industry. The following data given for some countries chiefly refer to handicrafts proper. Handicrafts In Germany, for example, before the advent of national socialism, 87 per cent, of all industrial establishments employed less than five persons. Not long ago the same was true of France, while in Switzerland more than one third of the industrial workers were classed as handicraftsmen. In the less industrialised countries the percentages of handicraftsmen are even greater. In the Balkan countries, 40 per cent, (and sometimes even more) of the industrial population were engaged in handicrafts and small industry. In Bulgaria, statistics give the number of handicraftsmen as 71,800, but it has been estimated that there are 100,000 or even 130,000-140,000 of them altogether, including home workers 1 ; in other words they comprise almost half the total number of persons given as employed in industry, mining and quarrying in the 1934 census. In Greece, more than 100,000 enterprises employ less than three persons. 2 In the U.S.S.R., despite the immense strides made in industrialisation, the production of the small industries still plays an important role and with Government backing this has increased as a result of the war. In general, the small industries and handicrafts produce mainly consumer goods, especially articles of prime necessity such as 1 Das Deutsche Handwerk, 7 Mar. 1941. « Idem, 11 Apr. 1941. EMPLOYMENT 115 cloth, garments, footwear, headgear, gloves, brushes, baskets, cutlery and pottery. Some idea of the nature of this handicraft production is given by the following figures relating to Bulgaria and Poland. In Poland there were in 1937 altogether 373,529 artisans, including tailors (25.4 per cent.), bootmakers (15.3 per cent.), blacksmiths (8.6 per cent.), joiners (5.1 per c e n t ) , bricklayers and masons (3.6 per cent.), locksmiths (2.9 per cent.), carpenters (2.5 per cent.), wheelwrights (2.1 per cent.), housepainters (1.9 per cent.), tinsmiths (1.7 per cent.). Butchers, bakers and hairdressers also formed important groups. In 1936, Bulgaria had more than 69,200 handicraft undertakings, comprising 71,385 skilled craftsmen and 53,545 other employees. 42,513 were one-man firms; 4,176 employed more than five men. The gross value of handicrafts production was 4.5 million leva in 1935, rising to 7.5 million leva in 1939. The skilled craftsmen were distributed among the various trades as follows: weaving (20 per cent.), woodworking (17.5 per cent.), food and beverages (16.5 per cent.), metal-working (15.1 per cent.), building and allied trades (12.3 per cent.), tanning (10.4 per cent.), miscellaneous (8.2 per cent.). The foregoing figures suffice to show t h a t there is a place for these simple enterprises using mostly local raw materials and needing a comparatively small capital. It can safely be said that in the rehabilitation period, a t least, they will and should be given encouragement. Though these small units of production are widely dispersed, they are accessible through the bodies linking them together: craft associations and similar institutions for the protection of their occupational interests, and, more especially, co-operative organisations for the satisfaction of their economic needs. These co-operative societies have as their chief objects the procurement of credit for handicraftsmen (by joint organisation of their savings and by loans obtained on the joint responsibility of the group) and the supply of the raw materials and tools necessary to their trade. Before the war, there were in Europe more than 13,250 such urban credit and handicraftsmen's co-operative societies 1 , spread over 18 countries. The following table, showing the number of such co-operatives in 1937 in the 11 leading countries (in order of membership), will give some idea of the number of handicraft enterprises accessible through co-operative organisations. It is to be noted t h a t the figures are only approximate, as a single handicraftsman may be affiliated to more than one co-operative. 1 This figure includes some co-operative societies of small traders. 5 116 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS The total membership of the urban credit and handicraftsmen's co-operatives is not far short of five million and may well be greater, as membership figures are not known for a considerable percentage of the co-operatives reported. Country Germany Czechoslovakia Poland Rumania Austria Bulgaria Switzerland Yugoslavia France Latvia Lithuania Total: No. of societies Membership 4,579 2,495 2,064 655 498 429 295 409 156 207 103 11,890 1,675,660 1,547,433 727,618 208,478 185,832 184,292 90,314 89,600 80,270 72,421 25,775 4,887,693 There were also a considerable number of such societies in Belgium (649), Italy (440), and the Netherlands (296), but data relating to their membership are not available. The handicraftsmen's co-operatives in Hungary, though less numerous (S3), nevertheless comprised more than 7,000 members and had developed a considerable activity, particularly in the making of furniture. In the majority of countries, these handicraftsmen's co-operatives are grouped into federations and other central organisations, especially in the credit field. Moreover, in a number of countries, e.g., Czechoslovakia, Sweden, Switzerland, Yugoslavia, associations have been formed to help market handicraft products, particularly those of an artistic character. In Sweden, the consumers' co-operative wholesale society {Kooperativa Förbundet) proposed in 1935 to the owners of small enterprises and to the craftsmen that a special organisation, with agents in different parts of the world, should be set up for the export of the products of handicraft and small industry. Kooperativa Förbundet expressed its willingness to contribute a capital sum of 500,000 Swedish crowns for this purpose. Workers1 Productive Societies A large number of workers' productive co-operatives have former handicraftsmen as their members and some of them have evolved out of handicraftsmen's co-operatives. Besides those connected with the building and public works industries 1 , there were also in Europe workers' productive societies turning out clothing, household articles and other consumer goods. »Cf. pp. 109-112. EMPLOYMENT 117 In France, for instance, out of 526 co-operatives affiliated to the Federation of Workers' Productive Co-operative Societies in 1943, 22 produced textiles and clothing, 29 were woodworkers' societies, 38 made metal and electrical goods and 12 made glassware or works of art. In 1942, there were 90 productive co-operative societies in the United Kingdom with a total membership of 18,296 and an aggregate trade of £8.7 million; sales of cotton, linen, silk and woollen goods totalled more than £500,000 and those of boots, shoes and leather nearly £2 million—almost all such sales being made to consumers' co-operative organisations. In 1935, the productive co-operative societies accounted for more than one third of the total output of co-operative clothing and for one quarter of the output of co-operative footwear. Woodworkers' co-operatives were important not only in France, but also in Hungary, Italy and Yugoslavia. Some of the Italian workers' productive co-operatives made glassware. In the U.S.S.R., almost all the handicraft and small-scale industries, especially those using local raw materials, are organised into workers' productive co-operatives. In 1937, there were some 15,000 industrial or workers' productive co-operatives, with a total membership of 2 million. As already noted, some of them were organised for the benefit of disabled persons. Their production figures regularly in the general annual plan and in the five-year plans for the development of the Soviet economy. During the war they played a considerable role, as is shown by the production quota assigned to them in the plan for 1942: 5,500,000 spoons, 2.500,000 knives, about 4,000,000 forks, 45 million yards of cotton cloth, 24 million pairs of stockings, 14 million combs, the repair of 57 million pairs of boots and shoes, the manufacture of furniture to a value of 72 million roubles. 1 In most of the countries named the workers' productive societies, like those of the handicraftsmen, are accessible through federations or other central organisations. Application of the Forms of Scattered Industry to Rehabilitation Their Regional Character. As regards the utilisation of these forms of scattered industry as sources of employment, it is to be observed t h a t they 1 For 1945 the production quota isas follows: 10,500,000 pairs of footwear, 4,500,000 pairs of felt boots, 17,500,000 pairs of stockings and socks, 75,000,000 spoons, 8,000 tons of household soap, 175,000,000 roubles' worth of furniture, etc. Altogether this production will have a value of 8,650 million roubles (cf. Izvestia, Moscow, 23 May 1945; Soviet News, London, 26 May 1945). 5 118 CO-OPERATION AND PRBSBNT-DAY PROBLEMS generally occur in the shape of trades more or less narrowly specialised by regions and therefore lend themselves to use in post-war conditions requiring the maximum use of local resources and productive facilities. These various trades have grouped themselves, either from the beginning or in course of timei around certain raw materials or around craftsmen whose professional skill and equipment have been handed down and improved from generation to generation. Sometimes they have developed around a concentrated industry which they brought into existence and with which they live in a kind of symbiosis or else, as in the case of the clothing industries, around large metropolitan centres of consumption like London, Paris, New York and Vienna. The Russian "nests of kustari" probably represent the classical type of such regional craft specialisation, but similar instances may be found in most of the countries of Europe. The best known are perhaps those in France: the horn industry, later the tortoise-shell industry, and later again, the plastics industry (bakélite) at Oyonnax; pipe making and diamond cutting a t Saint-Claude; precious stone cutting at Septmoncel ; silk and velvet ribbons in the SaintEtienne district; Cévennes silk woven goods (hosiery); woollen fabrics from Ste. Marie-aux-Mines; Cambrai lawn and cambric; glove making in the Grésivaudan Valley; cutlery in Thiers, and so on. Without any attempt to be exhaustive, mention may be made of the Solingen cutlers in Germany, of Belgian damask, of the glovemaking in the Bologna district in Italy; also of watch and clock making in the French and Swiss Jura, of musical boxes, and later gramophones at Sainte-Croix in Switzerland, and, in Yugoslavia, the furniture-making centre of St. Vid, Terzic for leatherwork, and the village of Kropa, which has specialised in iron work (especially nails and screws) for four hundred years. The disappearance of these forms of production and work in the face of concentrated industry has long been prophesied but has not yet occurred. 1 I t is doubtful if these predictions will come true in the immediate period of post-war rehabilitation. On the contrary, it is probable that under the conditions of disorganisation likely to prevail, the contribution of such forms of industry will be an indispensable element in the improvisation of rapid measures to overcome unemployment and the scarcity of consumer goods. In the emergency situation they will continue to render and a t the same time to develop the services which they have been giving in many countries during the war. They will also have a considerable 1 Cf. G. RABINOWITCH: "The Handicraftsman and Modern Industry", in International Labour Review, Vol. XVII, No. 6, June 1928, pp. 818-839, and also La notion de l'artisanat et son êvoluticn, Essai d'analyse et de définition (Confédération générale de l'Artisanat français, Paris (undated)). EMPLOYMENT 119 role to play in the immense task of vocational training or retraining; the handicraft workshop, in particular, has always been in Europe and still is the training ground of a large number of skilled workers employed in large-scale industry. It is not possible here to go fully into the question, but a moment may be spent to consider whether the effort of reconstruction proper, particularly if it involves a real attempt to start afresh, is or is not likely to deal the death blow to all the forms of scattered industry. Only the future will tell, and the answer doubtless depends in large measure on the capacity these forms of industrial production show for the solution of their problems, which are not always or principally of a technical or economic nature. The surviving rural cottage industries and handicrafts owe their continued existence partly to the fact that they have, generally speaking, been able to solve their economic and technical problems through co-operative organisation, particularly when working for a distant market, and partly to the fact that they satisfy certain needs better than any other form of production. But their major problem concerns working conditions, especially in the case of home workers employed by the "collective factory". It is among them that the most wretched conditions are found, though to say that this form of production is rooted in the poverty and exploitation of those engaged in it would be to generalise unduly. Thanks to employers with a social sense, to organisation, in some cases, of the workers concerned, and, most frequently, to legislative progress, conditions have materially improved in certain industries and certain countries. But the legislative effort made in the last twenty years has not touched every country. Even in those which it has touched, it has not always been fully effective, either .owing to failure to define properly the responsibility of the entrepreneur of the "collective factory", or because the means of checking the application of the law have proved inadequate. Co-operative Organisation. Besides trade union action putting forward claims and bargaining on behalf of home workers and besides legislative measures for their protection, there is co-operative action which works for their liberation. By renewing or maintaining the workers' direct relations with the market and thus eliminating the entrepreneur, it restores or guarantees to the workers full responsibility in, and full benefit from, their labour. Conforming to the particular circumstances of each case, cooperative organisation assumes a variety of forms, ranging from 5 120 CO-OPERATION AND PRESBNT-DAY PROBLEMS the simplest to the most elaborate. For instance, the co-operatives found in the Julian Alps in Slovenia may be mentally grouped to form a series leading from the simple purchase and sale agency to the workers' productive co-operative society. The co-operative at StradiZce went beyond the first stage from the start, because, in addition to supplying requisites and marketing products, it operates a common workshop for the cleaning and preparation of the horsehair which its members weave into sieve material in their homes. At St. Vid, the cabinet-makers, who are handicraftsmen rather than home workers, work in their individual workshops, but also have a joint workshop with machines purchased jointly. The nailmakers of Kropa have established a real workers' productive cooperative possessing the most primitive and therefore inexpensive equipment as well as the most modern and efficient machinery, so that it can switch from hand to machine manufacture and vice versa according to customers' requirements and the number of orders received. The co-operative a t Ter2ic is a t once a workers' productive society providing tanners with work and a supply co-operative providing independent shoemakers with leather. This same diversity is found in other countries as well. In France, for example, the gem cutters' co-operative a t Septmoncel is of much the same type as the co-operative a t Stradi2ce. The neighbouring pipe and diamond cutting co-operatives at SaintClaude resemble the Kropa co-operative and the group of French workers' productive societies. In the U.S.S.R., the different types of co-operative known as industrial co-operatives cover the same range. Observation of these transitions from one co-operative type to another at the same time leads to awareness of the continuous chain of intermediate types linking together handicraftsmen proper, home workers, jobbers and workers in cottage industries, and their problems are seen to be fundamentally the same in each case. As the examples given show, in some countries the co-operatives grouping these categories of workers occupy a more important place than is generally imagined. Industrial Decentralisation. The powers of adaptation, organisation and survival shown by these forms of scattered industry may be thought to take on a new significance when set side by side with certain tendencies easily discernible in the evolution of industrial production. The steam engine gathered round itself increasingly large masses of labour and gave birth to the great enterprises of concentrated industry. Yet the mass production which was the direct result of this concentration marks the beginning of a new direction: the breaking up of EMPLOYMENT 121 the productive process into an increasing number of distinct operations a t the same time makes possible the division of the large enterprise into workshops which for all technical purposes can be separate from each other and from the financial and commercial headquarters. In some industries the workshops producing certain standardised parts can even be geographically a t some distance from each other and from the place of assembly, as is the case with the préfabrication of houses, which may be considered as an extention of the technique of mass production. Finally, the small electric motor and the spread of rural electrification enable motive power to be dispersed, when necessary, to the smallest village and the humblest workshop. This development represents one of those not infrequent cases where progress takes the form of an apparent return to the past. The use of motive power and mass production which seemed inevitably to call for increasingly large industrial plants have reached a point in their evolution where the almost unlimited capacity of expansion of the former and technical developments in the latter appear to lead to a partial breaking up of large-scale industry. These observations do not of course apply to industries in which the productive process cannot be interrupted, like those, for instance, that depend on a necessarily continuous chemical transformation. It is similarly possible that the manufacture of certain finished articles or the préfabrication of standardised parts in small scattered workshops will not always be economically justified. Whether it is or not can be decided in each case only by an analysis of the processes involved, a study of the market, and calculation of all the costs. There is no doubt, however, that this division can be advantageous for certain industries. Over twenty years ago Henry Ford had already arrived at this conclusion: "The belief that an industrial country has to concentrate its industries is not, in my opinion, wellfounded. That is only a stage in industrial development. . . The combination of little plants, each making a single part, will make the whole cheaper than a vast factory would." 1 Moreover, is not the break-up of the large concentrated industries, which Ford predicted as inevitable, already occurring ? The electric motor, for instance, has permitted the breaking up, at least partially, of the textile industry in the Laval district (France), and in Silesia (Germany). The same thing has occurred in the silk spinning and glove making industries in Italy and in the silk weaving industry in the Isère valley in France, as well as elsewhere. 1 My Life and Work (in collaboration with Samuel Crowther) (New York, 1922), p. 191. 5 122 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS The processes of préfabrication seem applicable, and have sometimes already been applied, to the clothing and footwear industries, to the manufacture of typewriters, radio sets, clocks and watches (the parts for the last two items can even be prefabricated in individual workshops), and also to the building of houses. 1 More generally, in a large number of European countries the production of certain war materials has led, as is well known, to a decentralisation of industry. The social advantages of such a dispersal are so considerable that despite the force of inertia, the spectacular successes of concentrated industry and the common cult of bigness, they have been the principal inspiration of the growing movement for the decentralisation of industry. In the field under discussion, that of employment, the new techniques make a fresh and essentially human contribution. Before their appearance, the worker, when obeying the law of supply and demand in employment, had to go and serve the machines wherever they happened to be located and also the capital locked up in them. But from the moment and in the degree that machines are ready to move to the worker and place themselves at his service, and that work, under certain conditions of organisation, can be brought nearer to the worker's home, a new industrial revolution has begun. The data of the problem of labour supply and demand have been profoundly altered, and old habits of thought may be abandoned. From this moment of technical change, man's striving for progress may be directed to substituting mobility of the workshop for mobility of the worker. In this way and in this respect labour ceases to be a commodity and the worker recovers some of his attributes as a man, including the right to a full personal and full social life. A further, though subsidiary consideration is that the worker thus brought close to his natural social environment and to the land acquires a greater measure of security and stability in his employment. I t is suggested by some that these new techniques will enable underindustrialised countries, with their traditions of cottage industry, to carry out a good part of their programme of industrialisation without uprooting vast masses of manpower and without having to build up huge urban concentrations for the storage of future "reserve armies of labour". Naturally the various elements composing the scattered industry now in process of development should be properly correlated for purposes of control and co-ordination. What has been said in the foregoing pages will perhaps be enough to suggest that the natural form of organisation for scattered industry, more parti1 Since 1926 Swedish co-operatives have been prefabricating houses for erection by the purchaser himself. EMPLOYMENT 123 cularly at its lower stages, is the co-operative one, in which the small workshops—whether individual, family or co-operative—are linked together either by a purchase and sale co-operative or by an assembly workshop, as circumstances may demand. The examples given show that this constructive process has begun; they point the way, perhaps, to new co-operative ventures in a field the extent of which cannot easily be gauged a t the present time. Co-operatives and Employment on the Land Nearly all countries, belligerent or not, and whether their economy is mainly agricultural or mainly industrial, have plans directed to securing employment on the land (as a chief or subsidiary occupation), or a better utilisation of the manpower engaged in agricultural production, or, again, better working and farming conditions. In some cases the problems to be solved are war-made, such as the resettlement on the land of men who left it for military service, war industry or some other national service, or who were driven from it by invasion or deportation. In other cases it is a question of putting into cultivation new or incompletely utilised land under some land settlement or migration for settlement scheme. Elsewhere the plans and projects express a traditional or recent policy of protecting and developing the small family holding on broad social grounds. Finally, all these plans, and particularly the plans for land settlement and encouragement of family holdings, may be linked to land reform programmes of varying thoroughness. The number of workers concerned in such plans differs from one country to another, but is, in the aggregate, considerable. The execution of the plans, and, still more, their successful outcome demand careful preparation and constant attention at every point. All these projects (subject to reservations as regards the problem in countries with rural overpopulation) have this feature in common, that they seek to create the conditions of stable and remunerative employment in the interests of the agriculturist and the community alike. For, on the land, farming conditions can only be satisfactory, technically and economically, when agricultural employment is stable and remunerative. Stable employment implies the existence of a well-defined legal relationship between the land and those farming it: there must be ownership, long-term tenancy or other similar arrangements, either on an individual or on a collective basis. The right of permanent or long-term occupancy is not of itself sufficient to make employment stable and remunerative. The 3 5 5 124 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS holding has to be made ready for operation: the land has to be improved (or even cleared), drainage ditches have to be dug, the farm house and other buildings must be constructed, and sometimes local roads have to be built. The cost of this generally exceeds and may even be double that of the land itself. In order to start operations, it is also necessary to assemble the technical means of production (fertilisers, seeds, feeding-stuffs, tools, machinery, etc.), and for the agriculturist to possess the technical knowledge and ability required. Finally, in all those cases where any considerable part of the production is destined for the market, a solution must be found for the problem of organising its disposal; in its absence all the other problems will have been solved in vain. It is obvious that a land reform programme, a land settlement scheme, or, more generally, any programme which aims at establishing people on the land cannot be limited to procuring the land for those who are to farm it. All the other problems must be solved as well. Actually, a large number of the schemes in preparation or already made known provide the means of solving them more than did the programmes of the past. Some of these problems must normally be solved, and others can be partially or wholly solved, by the authority organising or encouraging land settlement. But in the plans themselves or in the absence of complete plans, there is room for the effort—generally the organised collective effort— of the parties concerned. For each of the problems awaiting solution there exist proved co-operative methods of approach. ACCESS TO THE ENTERPRISE The problem of securing access to the land may contain elements which demand solution in a particular form. This is so, for instance, when the owner of. a large estate declines to enter into a multitude of sale, tenancy or share-cropping agreements with small prospective cultivators; or when he refuses to break up the estate except on unconscionable terms which competition between the families needing land enables him to exact; or again, when there is a parasitic head lessee standing between the applicants and the absentee owner. To overcome these difficulties or obstacles the agriculturists can organise on a co-operative basis and choose between solutions reducible to the three following types: (1) Their association can be a co-operative allotment society, which purchases the estate and divides it into parcels to be transferred to the members outright ; EMPLOYMENT (2) It can be a land-leasing co-operative, which members parcels of an estate which it has bought or (3) It can be a co-operative for joint cultivation, or leases the estate, keeps it undivided and sees to its 125 rents to its leased; which buys operation. This division into three types naturally simplifies and schematises a more complex reality. There are variants of each type and each exhibits mixed and intermediate forms shading off into the others. One or other of the co-operative forms of access to the land, in one or other of its variations, will be found adaptable to the widest range of circumstances. Allotment or land-leasing co-operatives are found in places as remote from each other in space and circumstances as the island of Cyprus and the United States, where the Farm Security Administration encouraged their development. They have played a particularly important role in Czechoslovakia, Finland, Greece, Hungary, Poland, Yugoslavia, and several other countries in the application of land reform measures or of legislation tending to encourage small agricultural holdings, and, in at least one instance, in the execution of a plan for the settlement of refugees. In Hungary, such co-operatives (which began to be established in 1907) do not have a separate corporate status, but each of them forms a special section of a credit co-operative which acts as head tenant and guarantor as between its members and the estate owner. In Greece, they were used as far back as 1912, when the large estates of Thessaly and Thrace were expropriated; they are compulsory in the sense that no land transfer can take place without an allotment co-operative being formed and that the latter cannot be dissolved until the whole purchase price has been paid. It is interesting to note that co-operative allotment societies served in the settlement of some 150,000 families brought from Turkey to Greece in 1923 and 1924. In Rumania, when the land reform was in progress, there were as many as 2,400 allotment and land-leasing co-operatives, which distributed about 2 million hectares of land; they were compulsory, as in Greece. The forms of joint cultivation will be examined later. It is enough here to recall the role played by the Kolkhozy in the U.S.S.R. as an indication of the use to which such forms might be put in a fundamental reorganisation of agriculture, and the experience of the agricultural communities in Palestine, suggesting their possibilities in schemes of migration for settlement on the land. To sum up, then, the choice between the different co-operative forms of access to the land will not be determined by the particular occasion of establishment on the land (spontaneous decisions or legislative 5 126 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS action, land reforms or land settlement schemes, etc.)- The choice will depend on the form of the establishment, that is to say, on the mode of land allocation or distribution adopted: small family holdings and medium holdings, or, at the other end of the scale, large holdings. Whether the land is to consist of small, medium or large holdings will not be decided on theoretical grounds, but according to the systems of cultivation that have to be applied to the land itself. Large holdings suit extensive systems of cultivation, characterised by a relatively small contribution of capital and labour, or systems involving a fairly advanced division of labour and the maximum utilisation of groups of workers variously specialised. Intensive systems, characterised by a considerable contribution of capital and labour, call for small family and medium holdings.» The small family holding is particularly suitable where the labour factor outweighs the capital factor and where work is so distributed through the year that an agriculturist's family can carry out all the tasks required without normally having to bring in outside manpower. The medium holding presupposes a more important capital contribution than labour contribution and such a distribution of work through the year t h a t the agriculturist has to bring in outside manpower in considerable amount and for long periods. Finally, systems of cultivation do not depend on the farmer's caprice; they are strictly related to the natural and human conditions of the particular milieu. Natural conditions include climate and the nature and condition of the soil, while among human factors are density of population, the demands of the market, means of communication, and also the economic and financial situation and the general needs of the country. These general considerations 1 serve to show that there are no grounds for considering a priori any one system of cultivation or mode of land distribution superior in absolute terms to another. Nor, in consequence, can there be any question of giving an unconditional preference to any particular co-operative form of access to the agricultural undertaking. But depending on whether the individually run enterprise or the jointly managed enterprise is decided on, and, consequently, on whether allotment or landleasing co-operatives or some form of co-operative for joint cultivation is selected, different forms of co-operative action will be adopted for the preparation, organisation and operation of the holding. These forms will now be examined. 1 They are derived in part from an article by Olindo GORNI: "Les réformes foncières en Europe orientale et centrale; leurs causes économiques et sociales", in Annales d'histoire économique et sociale, Paris, 3rd year, pp. 207-226; and in part from an unpublished memorandum on land reforms prepared by the same author for the I.L.O. Cf. also Olindo GORNI: "Land Reform in Rumania", in International Labour Review, Vol. XXII, No. 4, Oct. 1930, pp. 445-482. EMPLOYMENT 127 Co-operative Forms for the Organisation and Operation of Agricultural Holdings under Individual Control The allotment and land-leasing co-operatives do no more than solve the problem of gaining access to the undertaking. They effect this by a division of the property into lots and once this is done they can be dissolved. Sometimes, however, they remain in being, and, turning into temporary co-operatives for joint cultivation, organise or put into shape the holdings that they first helped to constitute. In Greece, the members of the allotment co-operatives were even obliged to proceed jointly to the necessary works of drainage and irrigation. When the allotment or land-leasing cooperatives disappear, they give place to new co-operatives which carry out these preparatory tasks. Co-operatives for land improvement, co-operatives for the supply of drinking water, co-operatives for the building and maintenance of local roads, telephone cooperatives, etc., often spring up in this way. Similarly, in the land settlement area of Abitibi, in the Canadian Province of Quebec, the instinctive and traditional mutual aid which sustains the arduous life of the settlers led to the formation of work groups (syndicats de travail) for ensuring or carrying out the clearance of the land and sometimes for carrying out the initial ploughing, for digging wells and building barns. As the phase of preparation and organisation yields to that of operation, new co-operative organisations are established which meet the new needs of the holdings and consolidate the economic position of the agriculturists. When the lots to be worked are the result of a recent breaking up of a large estate, co-operatives may be formed to keep as joint property the inventory items which cannot be divided: tractors, mills, dairies, barns, etc. It would appear that the present land reform1 in Poland, for example, is being carried out under these conditions. Similarly, credit co-operatives, which generally date from the preparatory period, can assist in the formation, financing and operation of other co-operative societies designed to help the agriculturists' families to obtain technical means of production of good quality a t fair prices, to assemble their products, grade them, prepare them for sale and place them on the market. Some of the co-operatives set up during the preparatory period can continue, with the same functions when these correspond to lasting needs or with new ones. For instance, co-operative groups for mechanised land clearance may change into threshing or machinery co-operatives. In addition, alongside these co-operatives that are directly auxiliary to agricultural holdings 1 Beginning of 1945. 128 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS proper, other co-operatives may be formed for the organisation of the supplementary occupations of the peasant family (weaving, embroidery, woodwork, etc.). 1 Finally, co-operative organisation in all its forms is not merely the projection and economic support of the farm enterprise, but can help in the formation and development of the agriculturist's vocational skill, the possession of which is another essential condition of stable and remunerative employment on the land. The experimental farms and schools of agriculture, which are usually Government establishments, are the natural centres of rural vocational education and technical progress, and they are indispensable and, as a general rule, effective instruments. But their radius of action may be limited and their influence cannot always spread rapidly among the whole body of cultivators. The latter do not always have the necessary time, are hesitant to embark on journeys that are perhaps difficult or costly to make, and, moreover, have not always an unlimited confidence in the opinions of the official experts. To a large extent technical capacity has first to be gained on the land and in the social milieu of the agriculturist. The rural co-operatives, as organised forms of this social milieu, may be said to constitute the most convenient distributing system for conveying quickly to the agricultural population expert counsel and advice. For that advice is thus conveyed, not to isolated individuals, but to a permanent coherent group, whose activity continues and confirms that of the transient individual expert. They cease to be the bloodless precepts of academic theory and become th¿ living practical standards of education by experience. They cease, for the farmer, to be instructions, mistrusted because official, and perhaps also obscure; they become methods of action, used and recommended by his fellows, his friends, those to whom he has given his personal confidence and entrusted the direction of his community. Their acceptance may be attached as a condition to the granting of credit, so that the borrower is obliged by his loan agreement to start on the road of technical progress; or again, their faithful observance may be encouraged and rewarded by the higher price which the best disciplined farmers receive from the marketing co-operative societies for the better quality of their products. It is no exaggeration to say that both by the discipline they impose and by the means they offer of easy submission to it (supply of selected seed, fertilisers, pest killers, equipment, technical advice, etc.), the co-operative societies are practical vocational schools; they teach the smallholder to save time and trouble, to improve the quality of his products and to market them in a way which reduces to a minimum the costs of grading, preservation, transport and sale.2 Co-operative and Collective Forms of Farming The effect of the forms of co-operation just described is to bring within the reach of small family holdings the financial means and 1 Cf. pp. 113-116. Cf. also, Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op rit., pp. 75-76. ' European Conference on Rural Life, 1939: Co-operative Achan %n Rural Life (League of Nations, Geneva, 1939), pp. 30-31. EMPLOYMENT 129 technical equipment enjoyed by the large landowner. In a sense they can be said to re-establish, in a federative form, the technical unity of the large estate which was divided. The co-operatives for joint cultivation, on the other hand, maintain this unity from the start and have to exercise, in a centralised form, all the functions that small family holdings entrust to several more or less specialised co-operatives. It should be added here—as examples given later will illustrate—that collective cultivation can suit medium-size holdings as well as large ones. Their unity of administration and direction, their direct contacts with the market and the relationship of their members among themselves and to the joint enterprise give these co-operatives broadly the same organisation as the industrial workers' productive co-operatives and most of them could legitimately be called agricultural workers' productive co-operative societies. As in an industrial workers' productive co-operative, the general administration and the technical, financial and commercial direction arc in the hands of a management committee elected by the members. This committee is responsible for the division of the work among groups of workers which sometimes resemble labour co-operatives in certain features. The work can be remunerated in accordance with a variety of methods, depending on the particular country and particular co-operative concerned. Usually payment is made partly in cash and partly in kind (for instance, housing, fuel, and, nearly always, farm produce); sometimes, besides certain supplies, the members receive an advance for subsistence; finally, the association decides, at the end of the financial year, how any surplus shall be allocated. In exceptional cases, these co-operatives for joint labour can be temporary concerns, limited, as already mentioned, to the period of preparation and organisation of a number of small holdings. They can be of an incomplete character where there is a system of small holdings. They can be of an incomplete character where there is a system of cultivation comprising certain jobs done individually on individual lots as well as other jobs performed jointly, either on the individual lots but using jointly owned machinery, or on another piece of land jointly owned or leased. Comparable to these temporary or incomplete forms are certain borderline cases when the joint enterprise is in reality serving family undertakings for a strictly limited purpose: for instance, the joint cultivation of fodder for animals that will be cared for b y their individual owners. Agricultural workers' productive co-operatives or co-operatives for joint cultivation are therefore not all uniform in structure; on 5 130 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS the contrary, they lend themselves to a large variety of combinations capable of fitting a variety of circumstances. The role that they can play in the application of land reforms, in the execution of plans of land settlement and migration for settlement on the land, depends on this very elasticity, and comes out perhaps more clearly from a consideration of some of the main types of agricutural workers' productive co-operatives from the standpoint of the causes or purposes for which they originated: those, for instance, of Italy, the U.S.S.R., and Palestine. Affitanze Collettive. In Italy, the agricultural workers' productive co-operatives have existed for a quarter of a century. Their experience is instructive, not only by its length and independence of general political circumstances, but also because of its entirely spontaneous character. In an examination of the co-operative forms of employment on the land, it should first be stressed that these co-operatives are the outcome of an effort by a section of Italian labour to combat unemployment. It is also interesting to observe how, without previous plan, b u t by continuous growth in meeting a succession of problems, they developed out of labour co-operatives. 1 For they were formed out of and in development of the co-operatives of braccianti, which were themselves established to deal with unemployment by organisation of work and the elimination of subcontractors in all operations connected with the land (navvying for public works as well as agricultural labour). Among the tasks undertaken by these labour co-operatives was the "redemption" of uncultivated lands. Little by little, the co-operatives of braccianti, after accomplishing the task of creating new land, decided to work it themselves as a means of prolonging and stabilising their employment. 2 Such, then, was the origin of the Italian co-operatives for joint cultivation (affiitanze collettive a conduzione unita). The property farmed is generally of medium size and suited to systems of intensive cultivation. When summer work demands a larger labour force than that provided b y the membership, the co-operative has to take on some day labourers. When, on the contrary, the members cannot all be employed throughout the year, they are given work in rotation and those who are temporarily unemployed undertake earth works (roads, canals, etc.) during the winter months and »Cf. pp. 109-110. 1 Cf. Manlio SANCISI: De l'action syndicale à l'action coopérative. L'expérience du prolétariat rural en Italie (1870-1922). Preface by Dr. G. Fauquet (Geneva, Imprimerie populaire, 1940). EMPLOYMENT 131 are usually organised in co-operative labour groups for this purpose. The co-operatives for the joint cultivation of the land are grouped in regional federations which help them with their accounts, give them technical advice, and, fairly often, supply them with agricultural and other requisites. Kolkhozy. Joint farm operation in the U.S.S.R. comprises special features which distinguish it in certain respects from the comparable Italian experience. Its chief instrument is the kolkhoz, an agricultural form of the artel or labour co-operative, which began to spread after the 1917 revolution, but did not become really general till 1930, the second year of the first five-year plan. (There were 57,000 of them in 1929 and 242,000 in 1938.) From this time on, the kolkhozy ceased entirely to be spontaneous organisations. They afford a solution to the problems raised by the peasants' land seizures and, in this sense, bring final form and order into the efforts at land reform ; they become elements of a centralised and planned economy, and as the plan aims at the industrialisation of the country, they have the distinctive characteristic of being the instruments of the mechanisation of agriculture. They are also the chief agents for the execution of the plans of agricultural production. The kolkhoz is to be distinguished from the sovkhoz, which is an agricultural enterprise managed directly by the State and employing wage earners. The kolkhoz is an association managed by a management committee elected by its members. Any agriculturist of good repute has a right to membership provided he is ready to pool his land and resources and to accept the rules and regulations of the association. The land is State property, but the kolkhozy have the right to occupy their farms in perpetuity. In addition to •the land collectively held and operated, each family on a collective farm possesses a lot for its own use. The size of these lots varies from five eighths of an acre to two and a half acres according to the district. Each family on the collective farm is also entitled to own a limited number of animals: poultry, rabbits, cows (1-10), sheep (10-50), etc. Work is organised by groups (as in the Italian cooperatives), each group being responsible for carrying out a definite task. Remuneration for the work, or, in other words, the division of the joint income, is made on the basis of the work-days contributed by each member. A positive or negative coefficient may be applied to the work-day according as the output is higher or lower than that regarded as normal, or as the work to be done requires more or less skill. The definition of the work-day unit and the different coefficients are fixed by the management committee, 5 132 CO-OPERATION AND PRESËNT-DAY PROBLEMS subject to approval by the general meeting of members. Payment for work is made in cash and in kind. Credit needs are satisfied through the State Agricultural Bank. As one of the objects of collective farming has been the mechanisation of agriculture, it is natural that the State machine-tractor stations should be a central feature of the system. There were 6,647 of these stations in 1941, with 496,000 tractors and 140,000 harvester combines. Their relations with the kolkhozy are governed by contracts whose principal object is to provide for the rental of the station's machinery and services to the kolkhoz in return for a fixed amount of agricultural produce. The station also performs certain of the functions t h a t under the Italian system belong to the regional federations: it helps the kolkhoz to solve its administrative and technical problems; it is a sort of pool of agricultural, veterinary, mechanical and other experts on which the kolkhoz can draw according to need. In addition, the machine tractor station is the chief link between the State and the kolkhoz for the making and execution of plans and the collection of agricultural produce. Finally, it should be added that, once the prescribed deliveries have been made to the State and to reserve funds, the kolkhoz is at liberty to sell the surplus in the "collective farm markets". Quite often its income is increased by earnings from secondary occupations, such as handicrafts, cottage industries, and fisheries. The families on collective farms are also allowed to market their own produce at "collective farm markets". In 1940, these markets absorbed almost 20 per cent, of all agricultural produce. 1 Kvutzoth. By general consent Palestine provides an example of successful migration for settlement and co-operative farm operation occurs there as a mode of colonisation. Two forms of co-operative farming are found: the incomplete moshav-ovdim and the extremely comprehensive kvutza. In 1943, there were 70 settlements of the former type and 134 of the latter. In both cases the land is owned by the Jewish National Fund and not by its occupants, who must farm the land themselves without the help of paid workers. 1 For further details of collective farming; in the U.S.S.R., see, for instance, G. RABINOWITCH: "The Kolkhozes in the Economy of the Union of Socialist Soviet Republics", in Rural Sociology, Vol. VIII, No. 3, Sept. 1943; N. BAROU"Collective Farming in the U.S.S.R.", in Review of International Co-operation, July 1942; and N. BAROU: "Soviet Agricultural Co-operation", in Year Book of Agricultural Co-operation, 1943-1944 (Manchester, Co-operative Wholesale Society Ltd., 1944), pp. 154-160. EMPLOYMENT 133 The moshav-ovdim is a kind of a co-operative village, that is to say, a village in which all economic functions are, as far as possible, carried out by co-operative organs. But in general the land is cultivated by the individual smallholder. In certain of these settlements, however, wheat is cultivated on a joint basis and each settler receives a share of the crop proportional to the area he has sown. The kvutza (plural kvutzoth) goes much further. Contrary to what might be expected from the strictness with which the principle of collectivisation has been applied, it is not the product of a preconceived idea. Its features have emerged, stage by stage, out of experience. In the first place the very idea of group colonisation arose out of the early failures of inexperienced settlers meeting intolerable living and working conditions. But the first kvutza, founded in 1908, though it adopted the practice of joint labour, did not immediately give up the division of the annual surplus among the participants. It was the problematical nature of these surpluses that led it to get rid of any individual appropriation within the community. It may be said, then, that though the kvutzoth developed systematically 1 like the kolkhozy, they were at the same time a spontaneous creation, as was the case with the Italian co-operatives for joint farm operation. In the kvutza not only the farming but all the economic functions of the community and its social life as well are organised on a collective basis. Meals are prepared in a common kitchen and are eaten in a common dining-room. Even the education of the children is carried out jointly. Naturally the income of the enterprise is shared, but exclusively in the form of food, clothing, shelter, recreation, medical care, education, etc., and, contrary to the Soviet system, the division does not take into account the quantity or quality of the work done by the member. There is no use for money within the kvutza. The size of the settlement is generally restricted, but varies with the system of cultivation and the number of members in the kvutza, with an average of S acres per member. The settlement is organised on the basis of a plan which in its broad outlines has been drawn up by the general meeting of members. The plan takes into account not only economic considerations, but also social ones, among others being the need of finding employment for each of the members. In its relations with the outside world, the kvutza utilises co-operative channels almost exclusively: the Workers' Bank 1 To the extent that young people preparing to settle in Palestine underwent preliminary training in manual labour, agricultural labour, and community living in their country of residence. S 134 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS (Bank Hapoalim) for its financial transactions, and the Central Marketing Institution of Agricultural Co-operative Societies (Tnuva) and the Palestine Co-operative Wholesale Society (Hamazhbir Hamerkazi) for the marketing of its produce and the purchase of its supplies. The surplus on the year's business is not divided ; after making provision for reserves it is used to raise the standard of living (nutrition, clothing, housing, etc.) or, by far the most common, to bring in new members and thereby enlarge the settlement. 1 Other Instances. The example of Italy shows that joint farm operation cannot be regarded as just a recent development. Nor is it to be regarded as really an exceptional practice. Besides the examples already given as representative types, others are to be found in several countries, not only of Europe, but also of Asia and America. In Bulgaria, the collective farm movement sprang up spontaneously among the peasants and was later encouraged by the public authorities as a remedy for the excessive division of holdings; since 1939 it has been placed under the control and management of the Agricultural and Co-operative Bank of Bulgaria. 2 In Yugoslavia, the traditional and still existing institution known as the zadruga is comparable to a co-operative for joint cultivation. In the zadruga the members of a family group (whatever the degree of relationship and including kinsmen by adoption) live and work together on jointly owned property. It is hard to tell what has become of the Spanish "collectivities", but there were 123 of them reported in 1938. As for Asia, there were several hundred, co-operatives for joint cultivation in Japan in 1938; a few are also reported in India, where the President of the 14th (July 1944) Conference of Registrars of Co-operative Societies recommended that this method of farming should be studied. Similar interest has been shown in Australia, where the Rural Reconstruction Commission, in its third report to the Commonwealth Government, recommended the establishment of co-operatives for communal farming, but on a purely voluntary basis. At present the federal Government is operating communal farm machinery centres, which lease machinery to farmers. 1 For a detailed study of the kvutza, see H. F. INFIELD: Cooperative Living in Palestine (New York, The Dryden Press, 1944), and also Report by the Registrar of Co-operative Societies on Developments during the Years 1921-1937 (Jerusalem, 1938). * On the basis of the experience acquired, a new Act concerning agricultural co-operatives, promulgated in April 1945, provided co-operatives for joint cultivation of land with a legal framework. EMPLOYMENT 135 On the American continent, the difficulties experienced by small and medium farmers in western Canada have led to interest in the possibilities of collective farming of large tracts of land. The question is being keenly discussed in the co-operative press of the prairie Provinces. In August 1944, a conference held under the chairmanship of the Minister of Reconstruction of the Province of Saskatchewan and attended by representatives of farm organisations, the provincial and federal Governments, the armed forces and veterans' organisations, discussed the use of co-operative farming in establishing returned soldiers on the land. Plans are being prepared. Some actual beginnings have already been reported in the three prairie Provinces as well as in Nova Scotia. In most of the experiments there is co-operation for limited purposes; certain services are jointly provided or certain well-defined tasks are performed collectively. In Saskatchewan, however, application was made in August 1944 for the registration of a co-operative which seeks to operate a farm of 150,000 acres of arable and pasture land. In the United States, the Farm Security Administration encouraged twenty or so experiments in co-operative farming of varying size.1 I n the countries where interest has been aroused in forms of collective farming these are often regarded as a modern revival of the village communities which in every country for centuries gave agricultural organisation its pattern and agricultural employment its stability, while expressing man's deep social instinct. In countries where communal traditions have not yet been entirely obliterated, it has been possible to graft new co-operative institutions on to them. This is so, for instance, in Mexico, where the land reform has restored communal ownership of the land (ejido) by all the inhabitants of a village. The ejido or collective holding is cultivated sometimes by individual methods and sometimes by collective methods. The best-known example of collective farming is that of the cotton-growing region of La Laguna, where nearly 285,000 acres of land are farmed by 221 agricultural workers' productive co-operatives comprising 28,500 families.2 Similarly, in Peru "agricultural settlements of collective labour" are beginning to be established on the basis of the old Indian communities. This rapid review of the methods of joint farm operation may suffice to bring out their common features as well as the characteris1 For a general study on co-operative farming, with special reference to the F.S.A. experiments in thi» field, see J. W. EATON: Exploring Tomorrow's Agriculture. Co-operative Group Farming: A Practical Program of Rural Rehabilitation (New York, Harper and Bros., 1943). * Cf. Clarence SENIOR : Democracy Comes to a Cotton Kingdom. The Story of Mexico's La Laguna (Mexico, D.F., Centro de Estudios Pedagógicos e Hispanoamericanos, 1940). 5 136 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS tics that distinguish them. Their capacity for adapting themselves to the widest variety of geographical, economic and historical conditions and the fact that they recreate in modern structures an age-old tradition will perhaps give them new scope in post-war plans of land reform, land settlement and migration for settlement. At all events, it may be said that they complete the vast existing network of co-operative organisations that, suiting their form to systems of cultivation, size of holding and mode of tenure, ensure and protect stable and remunerative employment on the land. 1 The Co-operative Economy and the General Level of Employment The forms of co-operative just examined were considered from a particular standpoint, as agencies providing access to employment or stabilisation of employment o r a s commendable means of organising work in industrial and agricultural occupations. The contribution that co-operative organisations can make in this way to the execution of plans for reabsorbing manpower is by no means inconsiderable. It remains, however, to see if this exhausts the possibilities offered by co-operative organisations in helping to avert the threat of widespread unemployment. While organisation and stabilisation of employment often enough mean the creation of jobs, this is not always the case, and in any event co-operative institutions in so far as they do so only benefit their own members and employees. The question is whether they are able, by their action or through the new forms they give to the economy, to create occasions of employment in their vicinity and so help to raise the level of employment in the community at large. Persons well qualified to speak declare that they do. Sir William Beveridge, for instance, speaking about consumers' cooperatives to a group of American journalists in the summer of 1943, declared that "the consumers' co-operative movement has an important role in organising productive industry to canalise demands of consumers and to maintain steady employment". 2 The First Lord of the Admiralty in Great Britain, Mr. A. V. Alexander, in a speech a t Rochdale on 19 December 1943, expressed the view that if the nation's whole retail trade were placed on a co-operative basis, the purchasing power of consumers would be 1 Cf. also Henrik F. INFIELD: Cooperative Communities at Work (New York, The'Dryden Press, 1945), for an analysis and comparison of the co-operative communities of the United States, Mexico, U.S.S.R., and Palestine. 8 As reported in Canadian Co-operator, Aug. 1943. EMPLOYMENT 137 increased by at least £300 million annually through the mechanism of the savings refund or so-called "dividend", and he affirmed that in such case "at least half our normal peacetime problem of unemployment would be solved by the consequent demand for goods and services". 1 These statements, inspired chiefly by the spectacle of the British co-operative movement, merit attention, and there should be investigation of the facts in support of them and, if possible, an explanation of these facts. STABILITY OF EMPLOYMENT IN CO-OPERATIVE ENTERPKISES First it may be asked how stable is employment in the co-operatives themselves and how this measure of stability has been affected by the economic depressions of recent times. The directors and managers of co-operative enterprises are not, of course, immune against business errors, and co-operative institutions may find themselves in difficulties and, as a result, have to reduce their staff when there has been bad management or a defection by the members. However, it is a fact of common observation that as a whole they resist economic fluctuations better than enterprises run for profit. This was noticed, for instance, by Mr. Houston Thompson, 1 ^ former chairman of the Federal Trade Commission in the United States. Reporting on his visit to European countries after the last war, he declared: "I found the co-operatives to be a stabilising factor in the inflation-ridden economic system. In Denmark, the leading banker who opposed co-ops committed suicide when his banks failed and practically took the whole economic system with him. The co-ops, being decentralised, stood up . . . " A consequence of the co-operatives' greater resistance to disturbances of economic life is more stable employment of the workers engaged in them. Among others available, the example of the British co-operatives may be given to show the trend of employment in them during the last depression. The total number of workers of all categories employed in the distributive and productive services of British consumers' cooperatives and their two wholesale societies rose from 226,610 in 1929 to 272,449 in 1935—an increase of 45,839. During this period in which the British co-operative movement experienced a 20.2 per cent, rise in the number of its employees, the number of totally unemployed persons registered with the labour exchanges of Great Britain and Northern Ireland increased by 89.5 per cent. The number of persons registered as totally unemployed was highest in 1932, when it stood at 2,136,052, or 137.19 per cent, more than 1 As reported in The Cooperative Consumer (Kansas City), IS Jan. 1945. 5 138 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS in 1929. Even during this period of intense unemployment, the co-operative movement slightly increased the number of its employees to 241,583 in 1932 (i.e., by 6.6 per cent, or 14,973 persons). Instead of comparing in absolute figures unemployment in the United Kingdom with the rise in employment in the co-operative movement, comparison may be made between employment in the country as a whole and that in the co-operative movement. Using index numbers calculated on the basis of 1929 = 100\ it is found that the index of employment in co-operative enterprises went up to 120 in 1935, whereas the general index was only 101.5, and during the period 1929-1932 the co-operative index advanced 6.6 points, while the general index fell 8.6 points. 2 This example is particularly significant, since the size of the figures involved nullifies the influence of minor and accidental variations. But it is not exceptional. Between 1928 and 1934 the volume of employment in European consumers' co-operatives— the only ones for which a complete series of exact figures is available—rose in all countries, with the possible exception of Austria. In countries such as Czechoslovakia, France, the Netherlands, Sweden and Switzerland, it increased even more than in Great Britain, varying, according to country, from 25.5 per cent, to 187.10 per cent. Even if the example of Great Britain alone is considered, it would be instructive if the causes could be established which account for the difference between the development of unemployment and employment in the country a t large and the development of employment in co-operative enterprises. The first consideration is that, food needs being those least capable of reduction, it is natural in a time of crisis for the food trade and industry to be less affected than many other trades and industries. The British co-operative movement is mainly a consumers' co-operative movement and its trade activity is principally concerned with foodstuffs. In 1932, during the period under examination, foodstuffs accounted for 80 per cent, of co-operative trade (75 per cent, at the beginning of 1940). This percentage is still greater in the case of the consumers' co-operatives of most of the other countries. Another explanatory factor is that the cooperative movement is constantly growing and that the consumers' co-operative movement, particularly, tends to quicken its rhythm 'Cf. I.L.O.: Year Book of Labour Statistics, 1942 (Montreal, 1943). The indices used here refer to persons employed in mines, industry, transport and commerce in the United Kingdom. They were prepared on the basis of statistics of compulsory unemployment insurance. 2 At the same time the fixed assets of co-operative enterprises (land, buildings, plant) rose from £48,406,257 in 1929 to £50,534,021 in 1932 and £54,822,932 in 1935. EMPLOYMENT 139 of growth during economic crises; when its membership is increasing, it is natural that there should be a corresponding rise in the number of its employees. DISTURBANCES OF ECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM It is to be doubted, however, whether these two considerations can account entirely for a phenomenon that is so distinctive and widespread. Co-operators advance some additional and, in their view, more fundamental explanations. They do not, of course, claim that there is a co-operative remedy for unemployment, the more so as this most dreaded among social evils is the symptom and result of disease rather than the disease itself. Attack must be made on the cause, not on the symptom. The cause must be sought in the uncompensated disturbances of equilibrium from which the prevalent economic system suffers and on which some of its elements even thrive. The machinery of price establishment is out of gear ; there is no necessary and constant relation between cost prices and sale prices, between productivity and production, between production and needs, between needs and the purchasing power of those with the needs. Price Oscillations Lord Keynes has stressed the instability of prices and its consequences. He has pointed out, for instance 1 , that during each of the ten years preceding 1938 the price of rubber was at some date double the price at some other date in the year, that with cotton the average excess of a year's high price over the year's low price was 42 per cent., with wheat 70 per cent., and with lead 61 per cent. He showed that these differences were not primarily due to monetary or exchange fluctuations. It is evident that such an instability of prices of foodstuffs and raw materials (which naturally reacts on the prices of manufactured goods) must lead, particularly when it occurs over a relatively short period, to serious disturbance of the economic process and, in consequence, to disturbance in the employment field. Co-operative enterprises rarely have either the ambition or the means to impose a particular price on the market directly. But they are not without influence on the general trend of prices as regards a fairly large number of important products or services. This influence is towards stabilisation. It is true that individual buyers and sellers of goods or services may try to obtain respectively falling and rising prices. But collectively and even individually 1 Economic Journal, Sept. 1938. 140 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS they have the same overriding interest in stable prices. Moreover, co-operative organisations comprising buyers or sellers have a business interest, whatever their functions, in avoiding violent price fluctuations. While they may be powerless to prevent them, they do nothing to provoke them and try to reduce them. In their own particular sphere, at all events, either by direct action or indirectly through the mechanism of the savings refund which tends to reduce prices to real costs, co-operatives maintain an equilibrium between prices and costs and thereby act as a stabilising factor in the determination of prices. Distribution of the National Income Being mainly negative, the action of co-operative organisations in checking price instabilities is not always easy to trace. It is easier to see how co-operative business methods tend to eliminate from the co-operative sector of the economy and, partially, from the surrounding territory another—and perhaps the most direct—cause of unemployment, namely, the incomplete absorption of production by the market owing to faulty distribution of the national income. The productivity of labour, which is increased by technical progress and improved organisation, grows more rapidly than the effective purchasing power available to absorb the production. This is particularly marked in the case of industrial production. In this connection reference may be made to the report published in 1929 in the United States by the Committee on Recent Economic Changes, of the President's (1921) Conference on Unemployment, of which Mr. Herbert Hoover was chairman. This report 1 shows that between 1922 and 1927, the general productivity of labour went up by an average of 3.5 per cent, per annum, nominal wages by 2.8 per cent., and real wages by 2.1 per cent., while profits of industrial companies went up 9 per cent, and distributed dividends 6.8 per cent. Though there has been an advance in wages, then, this has been less than the advances in the productivity of labour and in profits. This smaller increase in wages results in a lessened demand for goods and, consequently, in an increased amount of unabsorbed products. The clogging of the market tends to slow up production and to diminish employment. At the same time, however, the larger rate of increase in profits, which has little effect on demand for consumer goods but allows the investment of capital in new productive facilities, has a tendency to augment the potential of pro1 Recent Economic Changes in the United States (New York, McGraw Hill, 1929), Vol. I I . EMPLOYMENT 141 duction, and, eventually, production itself. While the creation of new productive facilities gives employment, it also tends to aggravate the disproportion between production and absorption of consumer goods. This leads to a slowing down or stoppage of production, either as a result of a collapse of prices if the law of supply and demand is operating or, if it is not, by a slump in trade. On the other hand, if the additional profits are not reinvested in industry, they stand idle and are without benefit to the economy. They accumulate in the hands of those whose income is larger than their expenditure and reduce the purchasing power of the community. The problem always comes down to the necessity of increasing over-all purchasing power by augmenting that of the social groups which are numerically greatest and the least well-todo. The economic effect of social security systems is to bring about such an increase. It is also brought about by the co-operative economy, which from this standpoint may be regarded as a means of distributing the national income. This is clear when it is remembered that the co-operative enterprise is a service and not a profit enterprise, is owned and managed by its users, and that the latter belong to the social groups with deficient purchasing power. Its whole business mechanism is geared towards provision of the most economical service: first, the cost of the service is reduced to a minimum, and, secondly, the user pays as nearly as possible its real cost. The cost of the service is reduced in various ways. In the first place, the federal structure of the co-operative movement, with its central machinery (financial, commercial, legal, statistical, etc.) put a t the disposal of co-operative enterprises, enables the smallest of these to effect the same economies as the large concern run for profit. Secondly, the co-operative enterprise normally effects additional economies1: only a fixed and limited interest or no interest at all is paid on share capital; directors do not receive any percentage of the profits; superfluous middlemen and commissions are eliminated; the nature of the relationship between the enterprise and its users makes extravagant commercial publicity unnecessary; still further economies are effected when co-operative 1 Cf. A. M. CARR-SAUNDERS, P. SARGANT FLORENCE, Robert PEERS and others: Consumers' Co-operation in Great Britain. An Examination of the British Co-operative Movement (Harper Brothers, New York and London, 1938). See, in particular, pp. 375, 396 and 397, for figures showing that the general operating costs of consumers' co-operative societies amount to 13.9 per cent, of total sales, compared with 18 per cent, in the case of independent grocery shops, and 18.2 per cent, for chain-grocery stores. Operating costs of co-operative wholesale organisations are given as 1.3 per cent, of sales, as against 9 or 10 per cent, for ordinary wholesale grocery firms. 5 142 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS enterprises with complementary needs (marketing and purchase, borrowing and lending, etc.) can satisfy them by mutual exchange cf goods or services. 1 The economies effected by the well-managed co-operative enterprise benefit its users. Such benefit may reach them in more than one way. Most frequently it will be through the mechanism of the surplus refund, which is the most obvious feature distinguishing co-operative from profit business. It introduces into the economy an entirely new principle, whose full significance as a means of transforming the system of exchange has not always been grasped. It is also through the surplus refund that the co-operative enterprise constitutes an organ for the redistribution of the national income. Assuming that the business is not running at a loss, there will be a surplus shown at the end of the year. In a profit enterprise this surplus would be called "profit" and be distributed among the shareholders in proportion to the amount of capital each has invested and risked in the business. In a co-operative enterprise, on the other hand, each member receives a share of the surplus in proportion to his patronage of the business.2 In other words, each of the transactions of the member with the enterprise only resulted in a provisional settlement at the time it was made and final settlement, with completion and adjustment of the transaction, occurs when the surplus is divided. The result of this adjustment is to return to the member any sums he has paid in excess of the real cost of the service rendered or, in the case of a marketing or labour co-operative, to pay to him monies withheld out of proceeds of sale of goods or out of payments for work done. Such return will not be complete, because a portion of the surplus will have been placed to reserves; but subject to this reservation the price of the service will have been reduced to the real cost of supplying it.3 It follows that in a workers' productive co-operative the final remuneration of the worker-members and their purchasing power practically keep pace with the productivity of labour. Similarly, with all the other forms of co-operative, such as rural supply, credit and consumers' co-operatives, the mechanism of the surplus refund operates to put at the disposal of low-income families sums which under the prevailing economic system would accumulate outside 1 2 Cf. Part I, Chapter III: "Inter-Co-operative Relations". The surplus may also be devoted, in whole or in part, to social purposes, such as various kinds of insurance, children's nurseries, holiday homes, which create or release purchasing power or give rise to employment. As pointed out on p. 134 it is used in the Palestinian kvutza to create employment directly. 3 It may also be noted that the reserves are generally applied to the expansion of the business and consequently give rise to employment. In particular, one of the chief objects of deferred refunds forming individualised reserves is the acquisition of capital equipment. EMPLOYMENT 143 the consumer goods market. These sums are not negligible, as the following instances will show. Thus in Great Britain, the consumers' co-operatives, selling at State-fixed prices which are the same for all traders, are returning more than £30 million annually to their members. In Switzerland, the consumers' co-operatives distributed more than 450 million Swiss francs in surplus refunds between 1869 and 1939; in France in 1939, they returned a t least 125 million French francs to their members either as refunds or in various social advantages. Dr. Joseph C. Knapp, principal agricultural economist in the Farm Credit Administration in the United States, has estimated that the country's seventeen largest rural supply co-operatives alone saved their members $17,702,605 in 1943. Orientation of the Economic Process Among the causes of unemployment there is one on which cooperators lay particular stress. This is the defective orientation of the economic process, the lack of correspondence both quantitatively and qualitatively between production and real needs—more especially the needs of the masses. It is held that there is a fundamental difference between the co-operative economy and the profit economy. The enterprise run for profit and the capital invested in it to yield a return naturally organise production with a view to securing the highest or surest profit possible. The co-operative enterprise, as a service enterprise, organises it to meet needs. The quest for profits may satisfy needs, but not necessarily. In the first place, the profit enterprise has no direct and intimate relations with real needs and cannot always gauge them with certainty. As the president of Consumers' Co-operative Association of Kansas City has pointed out: "One of the great unknown quantities facing every business a t the moment is the nature of the backlog of consumer demand for durable and consumer goods immediately after hostilities cease". 1 On the other hand consumers' or housing co-operatives are in permanent touch with those whose requirements they supply. They are acquainted with their way of life, their purchasing power and the way in which they spend their income. Consequently, they are in a better position than any other organisation to make purchases which fulfil the necessary conditions as regards quality and price, and, in a word, to carry on all their activities on the basis of requirements which have been ascertained or sufficiently closely estimated.2 1 The Cooperative Consumer (Kansas City), 31 Aug. 1944. » International Labour Conference, Sixteenth Session, Geneva, 1932: Report of the Director, pp. 56-57. 3 6 * 144 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS A committee of directors or managers of co-operatives can thus easily and rapidly collect the particulars which make it possible to guide orders for materials and production. Secondly, the search for profit very often turns or tends to turn production away from a market already partly occupied towards a market waiting to be built. I t endeavours to stimulate new needs and thereby introduces a dynamic factor into the economy, though without necessarily bringing progress. It is also apt to introduce uncertainties and disturbances of economic equilibrium. T h e search for profit aggravates (and at the same time partly explains) the difficulty of estimating future demand, because it leads to the supply of real and basic needs being abandoned before they are fully satisfied.1 It also explains the paradox of the importance attached to the art of salesmanship—with schools being founded for teaching it—at a time when consumers are competing with each other to obtain necessary goods in short supply. The seller has to use his ingenuity to market a product for which a demand does not exist, but must be created. A service undertaking is concerned to satisfy expressed needs. It is true that the line separating real needs and artificially created needs is a shifting one. I t is truer still that indisputably basic needs which are left unsatisfied or insufficiently satisfied are extremely numerous. Co-operative enterprises not only have the means of knowing what these needs are, but have been set up in order to satisfy them. T h a t the British co-operatives were able to maintain and even increase their means of production and the number of their employees during a period of economic depression was due to the fact that they fulfilled their role, which is to adjust their types of manufacture to the real demand of their members. The same observation applies, of course, mutatis mutandis, to cooperatives of other categories. Furthermore, it should be noted t h a t the mechanism by which co-operatives create their working capital also operates in such a way as to relate size of capital equipment automatically and as closely as possible to the total needs to be satisfied. As is known, the rule of proportion mentioned in connection with the division of the annual surplus also applies to the contribution made by each member to the expenses of operating the joint enterprise. He makes a contribution in proportion to the services he expects to receive from the enterprise—a contribution roughly proportionate and in advance, when it is measured by the 1 In the United States a questionnaire addressed to industrialists revealed that almost 25 per cent, of them wished to manufacture electric household appliances and air-conditioning equipment after the war (Bulletin de la Chambre de Commerce du district de Montréal et de la Chambre des jeunes, Sept 1944). EMPLOYMENT 145 number of shares he must subscribe, strictly proportionate and automatic, when it is effected through the mechanism of deferred refunds and individualised reserves. 1 While this rule is primarily based on considerations of equity, it also operates to establish an exact relation or fairly close correspondence between the real needs of the enterprise and the capital invested in it. In this way the danger of overequipment, leading to a disturbed equilibrium and unemployment, is removed. Finally, when production is indifferent to real needs—as regards both their quality and their quantity—it is less concerned to satisfy them fully than to satisfy them exactly to the extent that will bring the greatest or most sure profit. Concern for security becomes more powerful than ambition and love of risk. Prices are kept artificially high on a market which could otherwise be much wider. Thus originate the restrictive tendencies which are so characteristic of certain sectors of the present-day economy. It is not always easy to measure how far such restrictive tendencies and artificially high prices are causes of unemployment. Nor is it always possible to discover in the unrecorded history of the co-operative movement experiments sufficiently detached to be used as proof of effective action against these tendencies. However, fairly sure conclusions may be drawn from the history of the co-operative movement in Sweden during the last 25 years and from the close s^udy made of certain of its aspects 2 , and this instance provides figures which illustrate some of the considerations advanced above. The Swedish Co-operative Union, by fighting or negotiating with the cartels, achieved considerable price reductions of a number of widely consumed products. Exact figures are available for certain articles: a reduction of 59.2 per c^nt. for margarine (in 1921-22); of 11 per cent, for flour (1923-24), despite a rise in the cost of wheat; a 46.7 per cent, decrease in the price margin between flour and wheat; a reduction of 58.8 per cent, in the price of rubber footwear (galoshes); of 15 per cent, for linoleum (1929); of 37 per cent, for electric light bulbs (1931); of 55.4 per cent, for petroleum (19281932); of 26.3 per cent, for packaged rolled oats (1929-1933); of 1 This rule is not observed in consumers' co-operatives, where it would be useless and a source of complication. But it is found in the majority of agricultural processing and marketing co-operatives, in most housing co-operatives, and in a large number of credit co-operatives. ' Cf. Georges LASSERRE: Coopératives contre cartels et trusts—L'expérience suédoise (Fédération nationale des coopératives de consommation, Paris; Union suisse des coopératives de consommation, Basle; Les propagateurs de la coopération, Brussels, 1939). Information on the methods used by the Swedish co-operatives in their struggle against cartels may also be found in Herman STOLPE: "Co-operation and Monopolies in Sweden", in International Labour Review, Vol. XVIII, No. 1, July 192S, pp. 46-57. 5 146 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS more than 50 per cent, for artificial silk fibre (1935); and of about 15 per cent, for superphosphates (1938). These price reductions benefited the whole Swedish population. In the case of certain products it is possible to show what these reductions mean in terms of annual savings on the normal national consumption: more than 600,000 Swedish crowns in the case of margarine; rubber footwear, 6-7 million crowns; superphosphates, 2-3 million crowns; electric light bulbs, 6 million crowns 1 ; and linoleum, 3 million crowns. On these articles and by this means of action alone a total annual saving of some 17-20 million crowns was effected, resulting in a corresponding increase in the purchasing power of the Swedish people. But the chain of effects caused by this action must be pursued further. Any reduction in prices sets going a series of mechanisms in the economy. In varying degree, according to the commodity concerned 2 , consumption increases, and, with it, production. Increased production affects the industry directly concerned and has other consequences as well. In the industry concerned it naturally creates a tendency towards increased employment and, since there is more compíete utilisation of the means of production (with no increase in the fixed charges), lowers the average cost of production. In the final analysis this means an increase in the real income of the community. The increase in production also has its effects outside the industries concerned, as the sums saved by purchasers through the reduction of prices in the particular industry are available for the purchase of other goods and so stimulate production and employment in other industries. Mr. Georges Lasserre's study of the Swedish experiment measures the effects of price reduction in terms of increased production and employment as regards at least two of the products mentioned: margarine and galoshes. Before the intervention of the Swedish Co-operative Union (1921), the factory price of margarine was very high 3 : 3.41 crowns per kg in 1919, 3.04 crowns in 1920, and a slightly lower figure, 2.45 crowns, in 1921. Production was more or less stagnant over the same period: 12,203 tons in 1919, 14,844 tons in 1920, and 12,631 tons in 1921. Immediately after the Union intervened, prices fell to 1.51 crowns per kg in 1922 and then almost uninterruptedly to 1.15 crowns in 1929. At the same time the total Swedish production of margarine went up to 17,622 tons in 1922 1 The cost of building the co-operative electric light-bulb factory was only 3 million crowns. 1 While the possible increase in consumption is limited and variable, it often proves to be larger in practice than was thought likely beforehand. » Georges LASSSRRB, op. cit., p. 29. EMPLOYMENT 147 and then without interruption to 55,243 tons in 1929, representing an increase of 39.51 per cent, between 1921 and 1922 and of 337.36 per cent, between 1921 and 1929. Finally, between 1921 and 1929 the number of persons employed in the margarine industry also rose by 22.04 per cent, despite a 68.55 per cent, increase in mechanisation (number of horsepower). The experiment with galoshes 1 is somewhat less conclusive, as the figures used to show the growth of employment refer to the Swedish rubber industry as a whole and not to production of rubber footwear only. It is pointed out, however, that over the period considered (1926-1929) the increase of employment which occurred is almost wholly attributable to this branch of production. This increase amounted to 38.67 per c e n t , despite the progress in mechanisation (an increase of 32.44 per cent, in the number of horsepower employed). Strictly speaking, these examples do no more than establish and measure the relationship between co-operative action and rise in employment in the articles, country and periods of time considered. However, they serve at the same time to illustrate the mechanism whereby co-operative action has led to the same results in other countries and under other circumstances, e.g., Denmark, France, Switzerland, Great Britain (particularly in struggles against the Proprietary Articles Association), as well as in Canada and the United States (reduction of the excessive price of fertilisers, feeding-stuffs, electric appliances, agricultural machinery, etc.). These instances help to explain not only the stability and security of employment in co-operative enterprises, which were dealt with at the beginning of this chapter, but also the role of the co-operative movement as an economic regulator tending to prevent unemployment in the community at large. This preventive and curative action is directly connected, as has been shown, with the special business methods of co-operative organisations. Co-operators regard it as the product of a more general cause, since the business methods of a co-operative enterprise are dictated by its nature as a service undertaking, just as the business methods and policy of a profit enterprise are derived from the primary concern that capital shall yield a return. It may not be profitable to make loans to the economically weak or for this or that purpose; it may not be profitable, under certain circumstances, to build houses, or to supply drinking water, telephones or electricity in certain areas. More generally, it may not pay to produce necessary artLies or to produce them in sufficient amount. i Idem, p. 45. 5 148 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS It may be unprofitable, particularly in a period of economic depression, to develop an enterprise and increase production. On the other hand, those who have need of some service always find it to their interest to procure it for themselves, provided they can bear its real cost. And it is always an advantage to those who are related to an enterprise, not on a profit-on-capital basis, but on a service-to-user basis, that the service provided should be developed and improved, even in time of depression and sometimes particularly at such a time. There is no necessary and constant identity between the conditions most favourable to the increase or security of capital, on the one hand, and, on the other, technical progress, volume of production, and social well-being. But there is a necessary and constant relationship between a service and the most efficient ways of rendering it. The reason why the co-operative economy is a balanced one is that it is a service economy existing for the advantage of lowincome families and under their control. CHAPTER V IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OF LIVING All the post-war rehabilitation and reconstruction plans include among their objectives the raising of the standard of living of the mass of the people, together with full employment. These two aims are regarded as complementary and even as forming an indivisible whole, as was stressed in the resolution concerning social provisions in the peace settlement (No. 1) adopted by the International Labour Conference at its 26th Session (Philadelphia, 1944). In the preceding chapter a review was made of the forms of cooperatives able to organise and stabilise employment and of the mechanisms of the co-operative economy which tend to eliminate unemployment. It remains, therefore, to examine briefly the influence of co-operative methods and action as regards the improvement of standards of living, including in the term, in particular, income derived from work, mode of life and social security. Influence on Real Income from Work There is no need to say much about the influence of co-operatives on earnings. As regards independent or semi-independent workers in agriculture, handicrafts and fisheries, earlier chapters have indicated the role played by co-operatives of all types in reducing costs of production, in improving and standardising produce and in obtaining remunerative and stable prices: all of them factors which increase earnings. Workers' productive co-operatives, too, when frtily established, and labour-contracting co-operatives, lead to similar results. Information on the wages and working conditions of employees of co-operative organisations is complete and reliable only in the case of the consumers' co-operative movement, but it points to increased earnings. In Great Britain, it was the co-operative store which first introduced the weekly half holiday. Minimum wages for male labour and a scale for women workers were fixed by 5 150 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS the C.VV.S. before the W a r (1914-1918). Trade Union membership was made compulsory on all C.VV.S. employees in 1919, a n d many retail societies either anticipated or followed this lead. 1 An enquiry made by the International Labour Office shortly before the war and covering most of the principal European consumers' co-operative organisations showed that they endeavoured, in close contact with the trade unions, to provide their employees with exemplary wages and working conditions and that they were often ahead of social legislation. In Finland, France, Great Britain, Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland, working conditions in these co-operatives were governed by collective agreements. In most cases, wages automatically followed changes in the cost of living in accordance with a sliding scale ; the rate of wages usually varied with length of service. In some instances, particularly in France, Sweden and Switzerland, a "collective bonus" system was in force, under which a wage supplement was paid varying with the increase or decrease in the trade of each shop or department. In France, Norway, and Switzerland, employees received half or the whole of their wages while performing their military service. In France, payment of wages during periods of illness was generally backed by sickness insurance and some of the large co-operatives paid the insurance premiums themselves ; women employed for more than a year were entitled to three months' leave with full pay at childbirth (half before and half after). In Finland, Great Britain, Norway, and Switzerland, sick employees received wages for periods varying according to country and with length of service and which might be as much as three months with full pay and three months with half pay. In the six countries considered, the co-operative organisations also gave their employees holidays with pay, the length of which generally varied with length of service, ranging from six working days to one month. In most cases, wages were also supplemented in one way or another by old-age insurance schemes and other social services (sanatoria, holiday homes, etc.). Finally, the foregoing chapter pointed out the stability of employment and, consequently, of income enjoyed in co-operative enterprises: "the bulk of the male employees remain in co-operative service all their lives or until they qualify for a pension. All but a small fraction of these workers are pensionable as a right—a rare 1 A. M . C A R R - S A U N D E R S , P . SARGANT F L O R E N C E , Robert P E E R S and o t h e r s : Consumers' Co-operation in Great Britain, op. cit., p . 44. While trade-union membership is universal among co-operative employees, only 5-10 per cent. of the workers in general distributive industry a r e members of trade unions. Cf. E. TOPHAM and J . A. H O U G H : The Co-operative Movement in Britain (London, Longmans Green and Co., 1944), p p . 41-42. IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OF LIVING 151 condition in the general retail trade and in most other callings." 1 It is evident, however, that the level of nominal incomes and wages is not sufficient to gauge the level of workers' possible consumption. The purchasing power of wages, i.e., real wages, and what has been termed "social wages" (social insurances-, maternity benefits, pensions, etc.) also depend on the prices of the goods and services of interest to all workers. Increasingly, then, social policy is found to include price control measures among its features. The various facts and considerations adduced in the foregoing chapter may suffice to indicate what effective support consumers' co-operative organisations (and purchasing co-operatives generally) can give to such a policy of control. Their action is not confined to reducing costs of distribution for the direct benefit of their members. Their influence is wider. In the first place, as service undertakings they form standards of reference which can and often do assist the public authorities to fix prices and margins at a reasonable level. Secondly, wherever such co-operatives are firmly established and well managed, they tend to regulate prices around them, as many observations and experiments attest. Some of these, made in Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Great Britain, Hungary, Sweden, and Switzerland and involving a great variety of methods, were cited in a brief memorandum prepared for the International Economic Conference held in Geneva in 1927.2 But co-operative history is full of examples of the prevention or checking of unjustified, excessive or too rapid rises in prices by the action of consumers' or purchase co-operatives; it also provides well-documented examples of the influence exerted by the mere "presence" of purchase co-operatives: prices rising from one locality to another in proportion to its distance from a co-operative, prices going down in a locality as soon as a co-operative is established in it, etc. Mode of Life Being associations of persons, co-operative societies are in fact usually associations of households; their enterprises extend, complement or replace the activities of the households, and, as the history of their development shows, they tend, as time goes on, to organise as many of its activities as possible. It is in this way that co-operative institutions affect some of the factors making up the mode of life of the social groups that are economically weak: improve1 s Cf. E TOPHAM and J. A. HOUGH, loc. cit. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC CONFERENCE: Results of Certain of the Enquiries for Instituting a Comparison between the Retail Prices in Private Trade and Those of Distributive Co-operative Societies (C.E.I. 11, Geneva, 1926). 5 152 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS ment of their housing and dietary conditions ; organisation of their leisure, cultural activities and amenities; protection of their health. ENVIRONMENT The contribution that the various types of housing co-operative can make to a social housing policy has already been indicated by instances drawn from the history of the last twenty-five years. 1 The consumers' co-operatives have already entered the field of furniture making, particularly in Great Britain, Switzerland, and, more recently, Sweden. They not only endeavour to reduce the cost, but also to turn out furniture which will bring real comfort and simple beauty to the home. They are even interested in forming their members' tastes. A monthly review, prepared by the Swedish Co-operative Union (Kooperativa Förbundet) for co-operative study circles, deals with all problems relating to the home; in addition to questions of child care and nutrition, space is devoted to modern trends in furnishing and to interior decoration. Similarly, the rural electricity co-operatives not only assist farm operations but also represent a means of transforming and improving the conditions of rural life2; the telephone co-operatives end the isolation of rural families.* LEISURE There are also the various social services established by co-operative organisations either as additional functions gradually grafted on to their original functions or as separate enterprises. The organisation of leisure particularly concerns urban and industrial areas, where the spheres of life and work are more distinct from each other than in the country. In all countries, besides publishing numerous magazines for home reading, co-operative institutions therefore organise evening parties, lectures and moving picture shows; they encourage and help to support allotments (workers' food gardens) ; they have initiated or encouraged many other activities as well. Their nature varies from country to country: in Belgium, 400 or more "people's houses" which are centres of community life (restaurants, halls for meetings and shows), and similar institutions in Finland and Czechoslovakia; in France, the National Committee on Leisure, with its libraries, music schools, sports societies, popular fêtes, excursions, and visits to museums, factories, garden cities, vocational schools, etc.; in Great Britain, photographic competi1 Cf. pp. 67-77 above, and also Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cil., pp. 49-54. * Cf. pp. 64-66 above, and Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 77-78. ' Idem, p. 77. IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OF LIVING 153 tions, arts and crafts exhibitions, as well as orchestras, choral societies, and drama groups, often of a very high standard, and where the artists' or performers' use of their leisure adds to the audience's enjoyment of theirs. In Great Britain again and in the United States, there are co-operative cinema enterprises organised by consumers' co-operatives or with their assistance. In France, a large consumers' co-operative (Amiens) had its own theatre with a seating capacity of 1,500. Besides occasions for relaxation and recreation, mention should be made of the facilities offered to co-operators for completing their general education or improving their vocational training. 1 For spending holidays there is organised travel at home or abroad; there are hotels, inns and holiday homes or camps (Czechoslovakia, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United States). Sometimes, as in Great Britain and Sweden, co-operative institutions collaborate with the trade unions in travel and holiday organisations. HEALTH In the field of health and medical care, reference may be made to the co-operative pharmacies in Belgium, Bulgaria, Great Britain, Italy, Switzerland, etc., and to the health co-operative movement in Yugoslavia, Bulgaria, India, Japan, Poland, and Spain, with the corresponding medical co-operatives and co-operative hospitalisation schemes in Canada and the United States. There are also the complementary functions in the 'îealth field of consumers' co-operatives, workers' productive co-operatives, rural credit co-operatives, various agricultural co-operatives and insurance co-operatives: convalescent homes, creches and sanatoria for children in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, France, and Great Britain; medical, surgical and dental clinics in France and elsewhere, and hospitals, as in Denmark and Hungary; the numerous mutual insurance associations in the Netherlands, mostly in connection with the consumers' co-operatives, owning their own central pharmacy; the sending of children, as part of the campaign against tuberculosis, to special rest camps or preventoria at the seaside or in the mountains, as has been done notably in Belgium, France, Germany and Italy. NUTRITION Co-operative organisations seem particularly well qualified to contribute to the solution of yet another problem—that of nutri1 Idem, pp. 19-34. 5 154 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS tional improvement. The food deficiencies of large sections of the population in every country were the object of numerous studies and consultations during the years immediately preceding the war; the situation has since grown worse in most of the countries and the problem occupies a larger place than ever in plans for the future. The problem is how to make accessible to the largest possible number of people the necessary range and quantity of foods of wholesome, constant and controlled quality, together with the requisite knowledge and facilities to enable these foodstuffs to be used under conditions favourable to health and economically practicable. It is not only a problem for nutrition experts ; it is also a problem of production, prices, improvement and control of quality, and education. It is therefore largely a matter for the agricultural producers' and the consumers' organisations. The former, cooperatively organised, are in very many countries responsible for a large part (often the greater part) of the production and marketing of various important commodities, while the latter are the commonest organised form of popular food distribution. Something has already been said about the useful contribution that can be made by co-operative organisations of these two main types to efforts to increase production by extending the area of cultivable land (irrigation, drainage, soil improvement, etc.) and improving techniques (selection of plant and animal species, better fertilisers, better methods of cultivation and breeding), and also to improve the costs of production and distribution. Their intervention can perhaps be especially useful in present or future efforts to improve and gurantee the quality of foodstuffs, and in the necessary but difficult task of consumer education. This is the conclusion which may be drawn from the enquiry undertaken by the Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations in 1936-37, at the request of the International Labour Office, and with the collaboration of 22 agricultural co-operative organisations in 15 countries of Africa, America, Asia and Europe, and of 14 consumers' co-operative organisations in 12 European countries and the United States of America. 1 The Committee concluded its enquiry with the following general observations: Hygienists do not confine themselves, in the present state of scientific knowledge, to determining the composition of the food ration of a man, according to a^je, occupation, climate, etc. 1 I.L.O.: The Co-operative Movement and Better Nutrition; Standard Definition of Foodstuffs; Education of Producers and Consumers (Studies and Reports, Series B (Social and Economic Conditions), No. 24, Geneva, 1937). IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OP LIVING 155 They are also aware, and have insistently called attention to it, of the importance of another problem of a practical character: that of assuring to consumers the quality and genuineness of the food products placed at their disposal; that is to say, of obtaining and giving a guarantee that such products comply exactly, uniformly and constantly with definitions established with precision and scrupulously observed. The foregoing information shows the means employed by the co-operative organisations for solving this problem. It has also another scope. It furnishes an occasion for elucidating the problem itself, reflecting on it, and recognising its extraordinary complexity. How is it possible to secure that, from numerous orchards and pastures, widely dispersed and varied, cultivated by producers not possessed of considerable financial and technical resources, apples or oranges of the same variety, the same quality, the same colour, etc., or butter of an identical chemical composition, taste, and smell shall, week by week, and year by year, be put not only on the local and regional, but even on the international markets ? If the pieces proceeding in a practically unlimited series from an embossing machine are all identical with each other and perfect, this is due to the perfection of the machine and the perfect homogeneity of the metal plates with which it is fed. If the products issuing from a multitude of rural undertakings appear on the market in a practically unlimited series, homogeneous and of irreproachable quality, it is no exaggeration to say that such uniformity and quality is due to the co-operative organisation. It is true that, especially in food-exporting countries, the State frequently ensures the control of the finished product and gives its guarantee, or superimposes its control and guarantee on those of the co-operative organisation. Apart, however, from the fact that this is not always the case, it is a fact worthy of remark that in almost all cases the initiative for a control and for a guarantee mark has come from the co-operative organisations, which have preceded and even guided the action of the State, and that State control has not been imposed on the co-operative organisations but demanded by them, and that they collaborate actively in such control. Finally, the control of the finished product is merely the end and consecration of a long preparatory process from which it derives its virtue. It eliminates defective products. It does more: it marks the end to be attained, it fixes the rules and definitions or at least invests them with a certain constraining force. It creates the necessity for observing such rules and definitions, but it does not furnish the means for doing so. The isolated producer does not possess these means and may not even know of them. As regards some of these means at least, it is not sufficient to procure them for him, or to teach them to him. He must procure them for himself or accept them voluntarily and without reserve, since their effectiveness depends in large measure on his adhesion to them. If agricultural producers have been able to carry their technical resources to the degree of perfection which has been seen, they owe this first of all to the financial means which their associated forces have been able to provide and thanks to which laboratories have been instituted and continual research carried on. But this alone would not have been enough; if they have been able *o develop their own sense of responsibility, identify themselves individually—during their daily round of work—with the common task of progress, and to compete together therein; if they have been able to submit to the most exact prescriptions, the most meticulous checks, and even accept punishment—all of which would have 3 7 5 156 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS been intolerable if imposed by an outside authority: they have been able to do so because the discipline to which they submit is the expression of the aims and the will of their societies, is based on rules they have themselves framed or voluntarily accepted, and thus draws its compulsory strength from within themselves. As regards the distributive co-operative societies, emphasis should be placed on their sustained and varied efforts for the enlightenment and guidance of consumers—efforts towards what may be called the latters' "food education", on the basis of the knowledge acquired by specialists in food hygiene, and even in some cases by taking a direct part in such researches. It is further desirable to mention the assistance which they are able to render to the public authorities in the repression of fraud and in all action directed to progress in the matter of food. Lastly, the enquiry has been of undoubted help in drawing attention to the care exercised by the distributive co-operative societies, on their side, in the choice and verification of the goods which it is their duty to distribute, and the inspection, check and test which they apply to the manufacture and preparation of the goods they produce themselves. In this connection, their most characteristic efforts take the form, first of all, of precautionary measures relating to the preservation, handling and packing of foodstuffs, and secondly, the establishment of laboratories for analysis, which apply severe tests to raw materials for manufacture, the process of manufacture itself, the finished products and the goods offered for sale to the central organisations and their affiliated bodies. The work of the consumers' and of the agricultural co-operative societies in this field is thus mutually complementary. The products which the agricultural marketing co-operative societies put on the market are not all delivered direct to the actual consumer. Wherever, however, they are directly received for transformation or preparation by the distributive co-operative organisations an uninterrupted and complete chain of provisions extends from the place of production to the household of the consumer, which fully ensures and guarantees their character as well-defined and wholesome food products. In cases where such direct contacts are established between agricultural co-operative organisations and distributive co-operative organisations, they may even, as certain replies have shown, lead to confident collaboration between the parties concerned, which makes it possible to simplify the controls and to bring the nature and quality of the products more completely into harmony with the requirements of consumers. Inter-co-operative relations appear, therefore, to secure not only an economic advantage by the elimination of superfluous expenditure, but also an advantage as regards genuineness and hygiene in the trade in foodstuffs. In the countries for which information is available, it seems that wartime circumstances have led Co-operative organisations to extend and make more detailed application of the action already reported by the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations. Some instances, drawn from various countries, may be given of cases where co-operative organisations, either through recent achievements or through plans for the future, have manifested their concern to advance nutritional progress by control of products, information and consumer education. IMPROVEMENT OP THE STANDARD OF LIVING 157 In the United States, the Office of Price Administration, when seeking in 1943 to prevent hidden price increases by means of cheapened quality, wished to make grade labelling of canned fruits and vegetables compulsory, in accordance with standards laid down by the Agricultural Marketing Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture. The majority of the manufacturers and wholesalers opposed the measure, while the consumers' co-operative organisations gave it vigorous support. A compromise solution was arrived at, which enabled merchants to know the precise quality of goods they buy and sell, without making it obligatory to give this information to the ultimate consumer. The consumers' co-operative organisations decided to continue grade labelling, despite difficulties in obtaining supplies. This case illustrates the traditional effort of consumers' co-operatives to eliminate false description and adulteration of goods. It also shows how in this field as in others there is a natural conjunction of co-operative action and that of the public authorities. The testing laboratories of the consumers' co-operative organisations, already found, for instance, in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Great Britain, Hungary, the Netherlands, Poland, Sweden, and Switzerland, are beginning to spread in such countries as the United States, where the consumers' co-operative movement is younger. They protect consumers by testing goods and also by giving" information and warnings. This latter aspect of their work seems likely to develop further, judging by the recent establishment, in both Sweden and Switzerland, of housewives' committees whose job it is, with the help of the testing laboratories of the co-operative organisation, to examine goods, specially articles newly put on the market and substitutes, and report on their merits. Both these committees were set up and operate with the help of women's •co-operative guilds. The Swedish committee also includes representatives of the chief women's organisations, the press, the Association of Rural Industries, and the Institute of Hygiene. It will not only advise the public, but will also guide the Swedish Co-operative Union in its programme of production. The sphere of information clearly borders on t h a t of education. Co-operative organisations do not merely warn their members against adulterated products or sharp practices in advertising; it is also within their province to give shopping guidance to the housewife, in the light of the knowledge acquired by nutritional science. As early as 1927, before resolutions and recommendations were adopted on the subject by the official international organisations, the International Co-operative Women's Guild had prepared a report on the nutritive value of foods and had proposed that the 5 158 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS associations affiliated to it should open a campaign in favour of wholesome nutrition. Similarly, long before the present war, the International Co-operative Ailiance studied means of raising the standard of nutrition. The work of education goes on, and sometimes new means (films, radio, etc.) or improved methods have been introduced. In 1941, immediately before the fruit-canning season, a film on fruit and vegetable preserving wa9 shown to more than 100,000 Swedish housewives. In Great Britain, Sweden and Switzerland, problems of nutrition have been dealt with by experts in lectures, in the co-operative press and in pamphlets and have been discussed in study circles. The Swiss Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society has published an excellent booklet, clearly written and well documented, and at the same time directed towards practical problems, as its title "Food Health and the Family Budget" indicates. 1 In the United States, a certain number of consumers' co-operatives have established Consumer Centers which give useful information and advice. From their educational and informational activity, co-operative organisations seem disposed to move into the field of scientific research. Some of the testing laboratories are moving in this direction, or, in some instances, lead to the establishment of a special research laboratory. The idea of setting up funds for scientific research work is spreading among the large central consumers' co-operatrve associations in the United States. Such a fund has already been created in Sweden; the research fund established by the Swedish Co-operative Union has led to the creation of Nor disk Biokemisk Industri, which manufactures vitamin products, and it has also led to the vitaminisation of margarine. Along the same lines, the Swedish Co-operative Union has been able during the war to develop the drying of rose-hips rich in vitamin C. It seems that co-operative organisations, especially consumers' and agricultural co-operatives, have a vast new field of activities open to them as a result of the steadily increasing interest shown by consumers' societies in nutritional questions, of scientific progress in this field during recent years, of improvement in the technical processes of food manufacture and preservation, and of the co-operatives' own research in nutrition. Particularly in the United States, the co-operatives of these two important categories have already entered the field of fruit and vegetable dehydration and are preparing to play an increasingly large part in spreading this process, which makes it possible to have a varied diet all the year 1 Dr. H. MûLLBR:/fygtène alimentaire et budget familial (Bibliothèque coopérative populaire, No. 1; Union suisse des coopératives de consommation, Basle, 1941). IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OP LIVING 159 round, without much loss of vitamin content. In the countries where food refrigeration is not yet common, some of the central consumers' co-operative organisations have been considering the possibility of manufacturing and distributing inexpensive refrigerators. It has been suggested that in rural areas communal refrigerating plants with individual lockers might be built, of the type which has developed extensively in Canada and the United States during the last ten years. Such plants could be associated with existing co-operatives that already produce or use, or could use refrigeration (dairies, slaughterhouses, agricultural co-operatives marketing extra-perishable produce) ; the rural credit co-operatives could help to finance them. The co-operative movement has its testing and research laboratories; it possesses its own means of production; in some countries it has started special health-food stores; it has trained dieticians, and effective channels pf education ; it enjoys the confidence of its members; it has enlisted the services of women members on a voluntary basis to advise housewives shopping at co-operative stores; it has established information centres for consumers. These activities, which seem likely to be developed and co-ordinated as time goes on, give an idea of the contribution t h a t co-operative organisations in general and consumers' co-operatives in particular can make to efforts at food reform. Making a synthesis of these elements, the President Emeritus of the Cooperative League of the U.S.A., Dr. J. P. Warbasse, who is himself a physician, has outlined a plan of action which would give a fresh impetus to the efforts already made in this direction. The consumers' co-operative organisations, Dr. Warbasse points out 1 , are not run for profit, but to serve the needs of consumers; their methods should be in harmony with this purpose; concerned with their members' interests, they cannot be indifferent to the good or bad effect of diet upon their health; the manager of each co-operative store, therefore, or one of his assistants, should be carefully trained in the problems of nutrition and be able to give competent and disinterested advice to housewives and other customers 2 ; and the co1 Dr. James P. WARBASSB: "The Food Store, A Health Center", in Rochdale Cooperator, Jan. 1944. * The big rural supply co-operatives in the United States similarly give their members guidance on the way to feed cattle; instead of recommending the artificial feeds with the most expensive formulae, they advise those that are most suitable. The largest of them, the Cooperative Grange League Federation Exchange (G.L.F.) of Ithaca, New York, with a membership of over 125,000, instructs its managers and staff that it is not their duty to make the largest sales, but to consider the fanner's real needs; it tells them, for instance, to take into account the quantities of hay, grain and alfalfa available to a farmer seeking advice on the best and most economical means of providing his cattle and poultry with the correct ration of protein, vitamins and fats. 3 7 * 5 160 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS operative store should become a real people's health centre. Eventually, says Dr. Warbasse, it should become a social and cultural centre, with educational and health activities, a library, a motion picture theatre, children's day nursery and playground, etc. 1 Such a project, already partially realised here and there, if carried out in its totality, could give a new vigour to, and open up a new chapter in, the consumers' co-operative movement. In any case, it shows the serious thought being given among co-operators to the role that their organisations could play in any programme aiming at better nutrition. Social Security Another factor in the improvement of the standard of living is the removal or reduction of the particular hazards which attend the economic situation of low-income families and individuals. Loss of productive equipment or other personal possessions through theft, fire or other cause, illness or accident, unemployment, permanent or temporary incapacity, death of the breadwinner, or indebtedness: these all place on small incomes a burden which may upset their delicate balance for quite a long while and, in some cases, irreparably. The systems of social assistance and social insurance which together constitute social security are designed to cover risks of this kind. The importance of social security systems in the history of social progress is shown by the way they have developed in recent years, geographically, structurally, and in the risks covered, and by the place that they occupy in plans for the immediate future. Historically, the social security institutions based on compulsory mutual aid have developed out of the spontaneous mutual aid practised among neighbours and fellow workers for individual protection against the hazards of life. Social security represents a systématisation and generalisation of these earlier voluntary efforts. But it does not put an end to them, as it does not remove their cause. Institutions for voluntary mutual aid still have a useful role to play. In the first place, since they involve activities inspired by conscious foresight and intentional solidarity, they are preferred by some people for their educational value and are perhaps the best adapted to certain circumstances. Secondly, they take the place ' On a more modest scale, the "health houses" (zdravstevni dorn) of the Yugoslav health co-operatives were centres of cultural life in the villages. IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OP LIVING 161 of and sometimes prepare the way for the establishment of compulsory social security systems where the latter do not exist; where these do exist, the voluntary institutions fill in the gaps and in any case are a useful addition to them. 1 Finally, as is not infrequently the case in some systems of social insurance, the voluntary institutions can be entrusted with local administrative functions in certain branches of compulsory insurance. INSURANCE An important place among these voluntary insurance institutions is held by co-operative institutions. As with the co-operative organisation of leisure and health, these sometimes take the form of "social services" of local or central co-operatives and sometimes of separate institutions which very often develop out of the social service activities. In the social service category are the welfare and mutual-benefit funds of many consumers' co-operatives in urban and industrial areas. These funds are sustained either by direct appropriations from the trading surplus or by voluntary contributions of members or by a combination of the two methods. They are used to distribute to members allowances in cash (and sometimes in kind) in case of unemployment, sickness or accident, and also special grants on the occasion of marriages, births, deaths and so on. The insurance co-operatives proper protect their members, in both town and country, against a variety of risks, the chief being those of life, accident and fire. In the country, they also give protection against loss of cattle, hail and other weather risks. Before the war, the insurance institutions set up in a dozen European countries by consumers' co-operatives insured their members for more than $2,250 million (life, accident and fire alone) 3 ; the British Co-operative Insurance Society, which is a joint department of the English and Scottish co-operative wholesale societies and provides nearly 3,500,000 members of consumers' co-operatives with insurance, is one of the most important insurance institutions in the United Kingdom and has "next to the Prudential [Assurance Co. Ltd.] the lowest expense ratio of any industrial office".3 Throughout the world there were 60,000 agricultural and rural 1 "The State in organising security should not stifle incentive, opportunity, responsibility; in establishing a national minimum, it should leave room and encouragement for voluntary action by each individual to provide more than that minimum for himself and his family." Social Insurance and Allied Services, Report by Sir William Beveridge (London, H.M. Stationery Office, and New York, The Macmillan Company, 1942), pp. 6-7. * Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 47-49. • Social Insurance and Allied Services, op. cit., p. 257. 5 162 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS mutual insurance co-operatives with a combined membership of 6 million—according to co-operative statistics. 1 From the most recent reports it seems that urban insurance co-operatives, at least, have continued to develop in neutral countries such as Sweden and Switzerland (where the amount insured by the Co-operative Life Insurance Society increased tenfold in the 25 years 1918-1943), and also in Finland. In the rural districts, mention may be made of the remarkable progress made by certain types of insurance co-operative or mutual insurance company in the United States, the most striking example perhaps being that of the insurance institutions of the Ohio Farm Bureau Federation. In less than 20 years the automobile insurance company of the Federation has risen to fourth place among insurance institutions doing this type of business in the United States 2 ; in 1944, it was operating in 14 States and had assets amounting to $13,764,626. Meanwhile, in 1934, the Federation set up a fire insurance company which in 1944 had policies in force totalling $492,742,100. In 1935, it established a life insurance company and in 1942, acquired a private business operating in this field ; the total amount insured by the two lifec-ompanies was $210,507,080 in 1944. On 31 December 1944, the combined assets of the Farm Bureau insurance group exceeded $38 million; since 1935, the group has extended its activities to urban and industrial areas. CREDIT To the risks just mentioned must be added another which always finds a place in plans of social security, the risk of indebtedness, so disastrous to the small-income family. The role of the rural credit co-operatives in this connection is well known. 3 But the role played in the past and now by the cooperative institutions of urban and industrial areas is far from negligible. Too little attention has been paid to the consumers' co-operatives' business rule of cash trading. It has been established by numerous enquiries how much the free disposal of earnings and even the independence and dignity of the wage earner are menaced by the practice of sales on credit. By reacting against the custom, 1 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., p p . 80-82. A still larger number appear in the statistics of friendly societies. In the United States, for example, there are more than 1,800 mutual insurance companies, with policies in 1941 totalling \Zy2 million dollars and covering half the total farm property t h a t is subject to insurance. * I t is not itself strictly a co-operative organisation, but is managed by the Federation. 1 Cf. pp. 18-26 above and Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 61-63. IMPROVEMENT OF THE STANDARD OP LIVING 163 the consumers' co-operatives have performed a real work of social and economic liberation, just as they have done a job of education in organising in various ways their members' savings. The result of the provident funds mentioned above and of other savings funds on which members draw in case of need, is that thrift replaces borrowing. Low-income families may nevertheless have legitimate credit needs which cannot be met by the savings funds of the consumers' co-operatives. Loans may be required for such things as the purchase of furniture on marriage, acquisition of a productive thing like a sewing-machine, perhaps even a refrigerator. The big banks are not equipped to handle these small loans. The municipal pawnoffices found in some countries or various charitable or semi-charitable institutions render services in this field, but on too small a scale or under hampering conditions. Outside these institutions, the urban wage earner is obliged to turn to instalment buying or else to small loan agencies and "salary-buying loan sharks" 1 for satisfaction of his legitimate credit needs. The savings and credit co-operatives of urban areas were established to get rid of these dangerous and exploitive practices. These co-operatives retain the essential features of the rural credit co-operatives: personal credit, homogeneous membership, etc., with the necessary modifications to meet the needs of wage earners. There were or are a few societies of this type in Europe, especially in Austria and Switzerland. But their chief development has been in Canada and the United States. The first society was founded in Canada at Levis, Province of Quebec, in 1900; in 1942, there were 1,500 of these credit unions throughout the Dominion, with an aggregate membership of 300,000. Many of them are urban, but the majority are either rural or semi-urban, semi-rural. In the United States, they are almost exclusively urban, but have begun to spread in rural areas; the movement, after hardly 20 years of existence, counted 10,601 societies with a membership of 3,159,457 in 1942; at this date these credit unions' total assets amounted to $340,188,694, and loans granted during the same year totalled $249,660,061 ($362,291,005 in 1941). 1 An enquiry made under the auspices of the Russell Sage Foundation, New York, in the spring of 1926 revealed that wage earners often had to pay interest at the rate of from 260 to 3,600 per cent, under this widespread practice. 5 CHAPTER VI DEMOCRATIC MANAGEMENT OF THE ECONOMY This long and cruel war, total and almost universal in character, will have had manifold and deep repercussions on men's minds no less than on events. Such repercussions will probably nowhere be short-lived, but their duration and degree of seriousness in the different countries will depend on the nature and extent of the sacrifices endured. In the majority of countries, and particularly in those which have suffered most, physical rehabilitation will have to be accompanied by a psychological rehabilitation, the one aiding the other. Restoration of economic functions, the endeavour to secure the fullest possible employment and to raise the standard of material living represent only one aspect of reconstruction. The period of convalescence will require the intervention of moral forces, a new vigour in the sentiments of justice and solidarity; it will entail, for individuals and groups alike, the renewal of self-confidence, mutual confidence, confidence in the future and the awakening of new hopes—hope in the new and as yet imperfectly defined promise of a new social order. It is unlikely that health will be regained by a simple return to the past. The war period has revived and the post-war period, by unavoidable trial and error, will seek to satisfy, a number of aspirations already felt, including the aspiration towards a more democratic management of the economy. Already formulae are being devised and tested to ensure that the economy will be carried on, more than in the past, for the common good and under the control of those it is to serve. A Sector of Democratic Economy Co-operators propose their own formulae, already tested by experience, in addition to and in conjunction with those just mentioned. The co-operative movement, they declare, is not only, in the words of Albert Thomas, "an important fragment of planned economy", but is also a democratic sector of the economy. DEMOCRATIC MANAGEMENT OF THE ECONOMY 165 One outward sign of its democratic character is its steady growth. A necessary, though not of itself sufficient, condition of any democratic institution is that it must first correspond to the people's will. Is not the very fact of the growth of co-operation proof of this condition's fulfilment ? And those who want to have co-operation are not content merely to demand it; by their own efforts, at their own risk and without recourse to compulsion, they bring it about and practise it. Co-operators do not rely only on outward signs to justify their claim. They recall the popular origins of the co-operative movement, the social groups it embraces, its philosophy, aims, methods and structure. 1 As in any human ¡ndertaking, there may here or there be lags between the doctrine and its application, the purpose aimed at and the purpose attained, the ideal and its achievement. Any democratic system has its problems, the most important of which is to bring about a steady increase in real democracy. The co-operative system, then, has its own problems and strives to find a solution for them. But with this reservation—to the extent, that is to say, that the members do in fact exercise their rights and assume their responsibilities—each co-operative enterprise is a successful democracy in microcosm. Co-operators even venture to think that certain forms of democratic government in co-operative organisations merit careful study. In particular, they point to the precise and balanced division of responsibilities between the executive bodies and the controlling bodies—a division which leaves the executive a wide freedom of action subject to a vigilant control which gives aid or registers disapproval, but without undue interference. Without going into details of the organs of co-operative democracy, which with minor variations and under different names are very much alike in all countries, it is enough to recall the sovereign function performed by that organ common to all co-operative institutions, the general meeting of members. It is true that the proportion of members regularly attending the general meeting is not always large (generally much smaller in urban and industrial centres than in the rural areas). But those who participate in the general meeting are the most active and best informed members, who have voluntarily made it one of their civic duties to watch over the common interest in their co-operative. By regular attendance and through their keen interest, they are able to familiarise themselves rapidly with the various aspects of the life of their society and thus to fulfil intelligently and efficiently 1 Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., Part I: "Characteristics of the Co-operative Movement", pp. 4-36. 5 166 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS their self-appointed task. A large number of them are members of the guilds and other groups operating within the co-operative. Because of their developed social consciousness, those who take part in the general meeting are normally in contact with the larger number of members who show a less active but nevertheless real interest in the affairs of their society; they can thus reflect faithfully what may be called the public opinion of the membership and rally it, on important issues, in support of common action. The general meeting, then, does effectively play its part in the cooperative organisation and has a real influence on the latter's life. Moreover, this role and influence are incomparably greater in a co-operative organisation than in a joint stock company. The shareholders of such a company come to the general meeting with a single preoccupation, quantitative and relatively simple: the productiveness of their invested capital. It is known beforehand that such a preoccupation exists, and it is also shared by the directors, who therefore have little to learn from the general meeting. Co-operators, on the other hand, are not only jointly owners of the enterprise, but are personally and directly the users of it. Each member therefore comes to the general meeting with a much more complex and varied purpose, which takes into consideration all the manifold elements making up the quality of service expected of the enterprise. The general meeting of a co-operative organisation is thus a necessary source of guidance and information for the managers who are fully informed there of the members' wishes. It is also a source of information for the members themselves, who learn at it all they need to know about the progress of the business and are thereby enabled to contribute any needed assistance to the common enterprise. Finally, the general meeting, besides being an organ of mutual information, is also, of course, the body through which the membership exercises its control, protects itself if occasion arises, and chooses those who are to manage its interests. Furthermore, unlike stock companies, the co-operative society is equalitarian both in conception and in operation. It is open without distinction to anyone who can use it and so cannot legally become the tool of any particular group at the expense of others. And within it all the members have the same rights and duties:. each has one and only one vote in the general meeting1 and may be elected to the various offices. Finally, appointment of a man to the board of management because he has his fellows' confidence means that he is invested with a function, not that he enjoys special privileges or a power of domination over others. The directors of * There are still a few exceptions to this rule, but they are never full exceptions and their number is diminishing quite rapidly. DEMOCRATIC MANAGEMENT OF THE ECONOMY 167 a co-operative society do not form and have not the feeling that they form an aristocracy; they are chosen leaders who remain at the service of those who commissioned them. The powers exercised by the general meeting, coupled with the various measures assuring to the members the daily exercise of rights and duties divided among them equally, thus give those associated in a co-operative society the opportunity and feeling of effective participation in the management of their own affairs. They can also help and feel that they are helping by their vigilance and other forms of collaboration to manage these affairs for the common good. As a result, for instance, labour is sovereign in a workers' productive co-operative society, since it assumes the entire management of the enterprise, or in a labour-contracting co-operative, since it is subject to no rules but its own. 1 Similarly, and for the same reasons, in a consumers' or rural supply co-operative the purchaser is master, while the primary producer has control over the product of his labour, and the saver and borrower over their savings and loan transactions within their respective cooperatives. In short, to quote a formula which might serve to define economic democracy, "co-operation locates the origin and exercise of power at the very origin of needs. Man, then, remains his own master and the organisation is his servant".' The foregoing observations refer to primary co-operative societies. It need hardly be said that they are equally valid throughout the mounting stages of the federal structure of the co-operative movement. The democratic rules governing the mutual relations of the members of a primary co-operative apply mutatis mutandis to those between co-operatives of the same type within their federating body. They likewise apply to the relations between co-operatives of different types, in so far as such relations exist and are developed. This last point merits a moment's attention. The experiments in "inter-co-operative relations" 8 are sufficiently numerous and conclusive to demonstrate that co-operation is an economic system allowing within itself the organised collaboration of a large number of different economic forces. In particular, co-operation has shown itself able to establish a sphere of understanding between urban and rural populations, a necessary condition for a firm national cohesion as well as for the political and economic progress of democracy. » The labour-contracting co-operative "is, in a particular sense, the participation of the workers in the management. In this instance, however, it is not a partial influence on the management of the whole enterprise, but complete management of a part." Charles MARAUX: "The Commandite: Co-operative Work in the French Printing Industry", in International Labour Review, Vol. XN, No. 5, Nov. 1925, pp. 650-667. ' Dr. G. FAUQUBT: cp. cit., p. 50. • See pp. 78-100 and Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 13-19. 5 168 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS If it be granted that economic democracy cannot rest solely on a system of consultations and representations, but also needs a foundation of economic institutions with a democratic constitution and mode of working, and if it be also granted that co-operative enterprise is a democratic form of enterprise and consequently that the co-operative movement as a whole represents a sector of democratic economy, then, say the co-operators, the effort to build economic democracy should, among other things, aim at encouraging the growth of co-operative management and the enlargement of the co-operative sector. Co-operators also point out that co-operation does not influence only its own sector of the economy; it has several other ways of helping the building and working of the democratic economy generally. In both the economic and political fields, the. success of democracy will not be solely judged by the degree of material satisfaction that it brings to individuals, but also by the degree to which individuals participate actively and of their own free will in the achievement of the common good. To secure this participation, democracy will have to fashion its own economic system ; it will need in its service administrators who are accustomed or willing to attune their thought and action to the demands of the common good. For, as past experiments in economic democracy have shown, good intentions cannot reach the goal unless they are backed by the requisite knowledge and talent, nor does business experience alone suffice unless it is subordinated to new purposes and a new ethic. The co-operative movement, with experience in almost every branch of business, is a breeding ground of administrators of the type which the democratic economy needs. Usually drawn from the ranks of the people and still in contact with them, such administrators represent the people and strive to realise its aspirations. Moreover, they have learnt to handle affairs and have grown in capacity with the development of the sometimes considerable enterprises which they created or direct. Finally, democracy will have to bring into play and perhaps to devise the techniques which can ensure, in the economic field, the collaboration of millions of people; in other words, the creation of a public opinion capable of exercising control, if participation is not to degenerate into, submission. Will not cooperators, or at any rate the more active ones, who have a knowledge of economic realities and the problems of management, and are already often influential in their respective communities, form within this wider public opinion a core of well-informed citizens, trained and ready to give all possible assistance ? DEMOCRATIC MANAGEMENT OP THE ECONOMY 169 Co-operative Democracy and Political Democracy An examination of the methods of political democracy is outside the scope of this study. But if, with the effort of reconstruction, there is to be a spiritual and social rehabilitation, and if this effort aims at an improvement (and where it has been destroyed, a restoration) of democracy, it may not be without utility to repeat the commonplace that if political democracy is to be solid and vital, it must be rooted in economic and social democracy. It may therefore be worth trying to see how the economic and social democracy being achieved within the co-operative movement can help to strengthen and perhaps to revitalise democratic structures generally. In all the countries directly affected by the war the social fabric will be more or less strained. In the countries t h a t have suffered most, and particularly in those which have been under military occupation, it will largely have been destroyed. Community life, the life of most associations (especially those most strongly organised) and family life itself will have been sadly impaired or else destroyed through the absence from home of conscripts or prisoners, through deportations, or through service in guerrilla units. The sole exceptions will be the underground organisations and, to some extent, the co-operative institutions (as businesses if not as associations). But with this exception, groups will have been broken up into numbers of isolated persons individually subject to the authoritarian police State. This splitting-up process, joined to and reinforcing the modern world tendency towards the formation of a mass mentality, will have worked against the democratic current. For any process that tends to turn a nation into a mere agglomeration of people exposes it to the risk of falling a too easy prey to mass propaganda and, finally, to loss of its sense of responsibility, of its means of control, and even of its freedom of thought. The answer to this danger, which contemporary history has shown to be a grave one, and the soundest basis of true democracy is the existence of a host of small groups endowed with independent life and activity, freely responsible and freely joined together, such as local government bodies, trade unions and other essentially popular organisations. Among the cells of a reorganised and revitalised social fabric, co-operative organisations of all types will have a role as centres of democratic life and sources of initiative directed to the common good. Besides this role, which co-operatives will share with other people's institutions, mention may be made of another which is more particularly their own and is due to their character as econo5 170 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS mic institutions and to the way in which they are linked to form a co-ordinated whole. The efforts made to put political democracy on the firm basis of a democratic management of the economy stimulate search for a complement to the purely political representation and participation of citizens in the changing State organs. Liaison bodies must be found or established, in the economic field, between individuals and the community. It is doubtful whether there can be found for the liaison a formula capable of answering all needs whatever the time and place. But to judge by the experience of the past fifteen or twenty years, it can hardly be doubted that co-operative organisations will have a place in consultations. In all the countries where the co-operative movement is strongly developed, it has been recognised as an indispensable source of concrete information, as one of the places where the people's economic will is formed, and as the natural organ for the expression of this will, whereby the individual is put in contact with the State without loss of his individuality. 1 Co-operative organisations, as instruments for transmitting upwards, and there interpreting, the needs and aspirations with which they are in daily contact, are equally well equipped to transmit downwards the needs expressed by and the impulses coming from the central organs of the economy. Thus without any loss of autonomy, by the mere fact of their solidarity with the wider community in which they operate, co-operative institutions find their place in the economic structure of the political State. Co-operators do not confine the role that their institutions can play in the rebuilding of democracy to that of supplying essential constituent elements to the democratic social body and of acting as liaison organs between individuals and the community. They consider that co-operatives have another and, in their view, perhaps a still more fundamental role. They think that there cannot be real reconstruction in general and democratic reconstruction in particular, without a broad and persistent effort of re education, for the paramount need of democracies is for well-informed and active citizens. They hold that it is within genuine people's institutions, especially within trade union and co-operative organisations, that habits of passive obedience can be most quickly dissolved and that a sense of democratic discipline and re°ponsibility can be restored. The patient and many-sided effort traditionally brought to the task of education by co-operative institutions is well known. 2 Of all the people's movements, the co-operative movement has perhaps been the one to understand best that, in a continually 1 1 Cf. Part III, Chapter II: "Forms of the Co-operative Contribution". Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 1^-34. DEMOCRATIC MANAGEMENT OF THE ECONOMY 171 and rapidly changing world, education must not confine itself to preparing the young for life, but must be a continuing process so that adults may remain receptive all their life to new ideas. In this connection, reference may be made, in particular, to the activity of the study circles where minds are formed and informed, and concrete and responsible action is prepared in an atmosphere free from oratory, away from ready-made and uncritically received ideas, and out of the reach of catchwords made meaningless by excessive repetition. This activity of adult education and democratic training goes on quite naturally in the life of co-operative organisations, as the co-operative institution, "through the means which it employs and the qualities which it demands of its members and which it develops in them" 1 , is a real school of human development, citizenship and democracy. As the First Lord of the Admiralty in Great Britain, Mr. A. V. Alexander, declared in a Rochdale Day broadcast address to the American continent: "I came to public service through the co-operative movement, in which I learned the tasks of administration and democratic discipline . . . There is no finer training for responsibilities of citizenship than service in a democratic organisation like the co-operative movement, which stresses the responsibilities of freedom as well as its privileges."* Understanding of the meaning and use of freedom, recognition and exercise of its responsibilities, these are indeed the hallmarks which should grace the citizen of a democracy. If national cohesion is to be rebuilt and fostered, if human relations are to be well ordered internationally, if great civilisations are to flower, there must also be a vigorous sense of common interest, the perception of common aims, the spirit of interdependence and the will for solidarity. By steady widening of the definition which they give to their ever-growing sphere of common action, and in the daily exercise of their rights and duties, co-operators can gradually attain to this universal outlook. Thus, while the development of the democratic economy is aided by the ethic, methods and the human element of co-operative management, co-operative education, both that preceding and preparing for co-operative action and that resulting from' it, helps to form within the democracies the ideals and leadership of which they stand in need. 1 Dr. G. F A U Q U E T : Le Secteur coopératif, op. cit., p . 44. Reported in The Cooperative Builder (Superior, Wisconsin, U.S.A.), 20 Jan. 1944. s PART III Conditions and Forms of the Co-operative Contribution to the Rehabilitation and Reconstruction Effort 5 PROBLEMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION Earlier chapters and a previous study have called attention to the number of co-operative societies and of the families whom they serve; to the practically unlimited variety of .their economic and social functions and the place, nearly always important, and sometimes preponderant, that the latter give them in the national life of almost all countries; to their wide dissemination, coupled with a high degree of mutual cohesion assured by their federal ties; and, finally, to the fact that by giving their members experience in the responsible management of enterprises, co-operatives contribute to the building of a democratic economy and are effective instruments of economic, technical and social education for workers of all categories. In this way some idea has been conveyed of the features that fit co-operative organisations to make an important contribution to the solution of certain post-war problems. Moreover, the leaders of the co-operative movement, conscious of their responsibilities and also convinced that the development of cooperative institutions is at times an indispensable condition of rehabilitation, in both its immediate and more permanent aspects, are everywhere preparing for the role that circumstances indicate to them. They point out, however, that the willingness and readiness of the co-operative organisations are not the only factors determining the extent and^fficacy of their contribution. Such a contribution is assured by the very nature of co-operative activity. But its importance will depend in part on the degree to which the movement is asked to participate and, most of all, on the way in which it can be fitted into the general framework of the intervention that the public authorities of most countries will be led to make in the economic field. For though co-operative organisations and public authorities may often have the same objectives, thus making their collaboration possible and desirable, their methods of action are clearly very different. In view of the peculiar character of co-operative organisations, which are at once voluntary associations and undertakings subject to very special rules of working and management, the question arises under what conditions and by what methods this collaboration can be best developed. In certain of its aspects, at 3 8 * 5 176 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS least, this question inevitably introduces the more general problem of relations between co-operative organisations and public authorities. And, for a proper appreciation of the problem, it will probably be necessary to look at it, not only from the standpoint of the immediate tasks of rehabilitation, but also, at certain moments, from the broader one of the general organisation of the economy. CHAPTER VII CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION When co-operators try to define the external conditions which would give the maximum scope and effectiveness to co-operative action in post-war tasks, they limit themselves to very simple yet fundamental wishes. In general they ask for no privileges. They are even afraid that any privileges granted might weaken the sense of responsibility and the spirit of initiative. If they are pressed by a particularly friendly Government to say what it can do to make the task of co-operative institutions easier, they simply ask for assistance in their work of teaching and training, since they regard that work as directed to a purpose of general interest and therefore a legitimate recipient of State aid. Some even ask only that the State should help in a wide programme of adult education, for they are convinced, it seems, that properly informed adults would quite naturally seek co-operative solutions to some of their problems.1 The other claim of co-operators, emphatically and unanimously advanced, is that any obstacles to the free development of cooperative organisations and free expansion of their activities should be removed and that the State should not interfere with their principles and methods of working. Teaching and Training The interest taken by the public authorities in the teaching of co-operation and the training of co-operative officials varies considerably from one country to another. It is least strong and sometimes practically non-existent in countries where the co-operative movement is older and more developed. in the State universities of Europe special chairs of co-operation are rare. In France, there were such chairs at Lille and Lyons 1 Cf. for example, the evidence of Dr. M. M. Coady before the Special Committee on Reconstruction and Re-establishment of the Canadian House of Commons, Minutes of Proceedings and Evidence, No. 12, 13 May 1943 (Ottawa, 1943), pp. 297, 314, 318 and passim. 5 178 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS und the one occupied by Charles Gide at the Collège de France in Paris. Other chairs for the teaching of co-operation were the chair (established in 1920) of the Faculty of Rural Economics and Veterinary Science of the Royal Hungarian University of Technical and Economic Science in Budapest, that of the Faculty of Law and Economics of Riga University, replacing, from the beginning of the university year 1926-27, the few courses on co-operation given ever since 1919, and also that at the University of Kaunas in Lithuania. With these and perhaps a few other exceptions (e.g., certain Polish universities), co-operation had hardly more than an accessory place in courses on sociology or political economy in institutions of general higher education. 1 It figured more prominently in specialised higher education : in the commercial colleges, for instance, in Poland and Turkey, and more particularly in the agricultural colleges in France, Hungary, Latvia and elsewhere. Some of these courses were established with the collaboration of co-operative organisations. The position is much the same as regards institutions for general secondary education in which students are sometimes taught about co-operation in courses on citizenship. Real teaching of cooperation* is only found in the vocational secondary schools, as in Bulgaria (complementary and practical schools of agriculture, commercial schools, schools of cabinet-making, mechanics, electricity, and domestic economy), in Latvia (commercial and agricultural schools), in Luxembourg (industrial and commercial schools and agricultural schools), and in Poland, where commercial education included three types of institution entirely devoted to the teaching of co-operation (introductory co-operative schools, intermediate co-operative schools, higher co-operative schools). From the little information available it does not seem that the teaching of co-operation often occupied an important place in elementary and higher elementary education. In France, some idea of the co-operative movement was given to students in teachers' training schools and in higher elementary schools; more important, perhaps, was its well-developed school co-operative movement. 2 In Luxembourg, the winter agricultural courses (elementary) included classes on co-operation. In Poland, where school co-operatives were very numerous, an interesting feature was the inclusion of teaching of co-operation in courses on geography and arithmetic. 1 It may be noted, however, that the University of Geneva (Switzerland) has recently introduced a Certificate of Co-operative Studies, which is obtainable by bachelors and doctors of economic and social science, and at the same time has considerably enlarged the place allotted to the teaching of co-operation in four1 of its faculties. For further information on the school co-operative movement in various countries, see Co-operative Organisations and Post- War Relief, op. cit.. pp. 27-28. CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVB ACTION 179 During recent years there has been a considerable increase in the number of school co-operatives in Turkey. While these examples do not perhaps cover the whole place occupied by co-operation in the various stages of public instruction in Europe, they probably account for most of it. As regards the teaching and training activities of the co-operative organisations themselves, it does not seem that the public authorities gave any considerable assistance towards them. A few instances, however, may be noted: the French, Polish and Turkish school authorities encouraged the school co-operative movement; some chairs of cooperation have been created in secondary or higher agricultural schools at the request of agricultural co-operative organisations; the Czechoslovak, Finnish and Polish Governments subsidised the education of managers, employees and members of co-operative organisations 1 ; and the Greek law on co-operation (of 1938) provided for the establishment of a co-operative school offering a diploma which would have to be obtained by all officials responsible for the supervision of co-operatives. A fairly large number of Governments periodically issued statistics, either on the co-operative movement as a whole, or, more frequently, on certain forms of co-operation. But, with this exception, it is difficult to think of any regular official publication which gave the public information on co-operative activities. Outside Europe the picture is somewhat different, mainly owing to the interest shown by a large number of Governments in the development of co-operative organisations, and to the direct or indirect contribution that they make to such development, more especially by encouraging the teaching of co-operation. In India, eight or even ten universities give extensive courses on the history and theory of co-operation, on the different types of co-operatives and on the organisation and working of the cooperation movement in that country. In the Universities of Agra, Calcutta, Lucknow, Mysore and the Punjab this instruction has to be taken to obtain certain university degrees. In addition, there is the extremely important role played now and in the past by the officials, British and Indian, on the staffs of the registrars of co-operative societies, as regards both co-operative education and the organisation, guidance and stimulation of the movement. In nearly all the British colonies and possessions Government officials have been appointed with much the same functions; these registrars, most of whom have received special training, have in 1 The Swedish Government has likewise given financial assistance to certain œntral organisations of agricultural co-operatives for the development of their educational and supervisory activities. 5 180 CO-OPBRATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS general obtained excellent, and, in some cases, remarkable, results from their efforts. Most of the republics of Latin America, though using partially different methods, have made similar endeavours. Some of them (Brazil, Cuba, Peru) have written the development of the cooperative movement into their constitutions. Argentina, Brazil (and its component States), Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico and Peru have set up special departments to guide and supervise co-operative organisations and, first of all, to spread or help to spread knowledge of co-operative principles and methods by every available means. In Venezuela, a course on co-operation was instituted in October 1942 by the Department of Labour and Communications. In Argentina, the Universities of Buenos Aires and La Plata and, in Colombia, the University of Cauca have special chcirs for the teaching of co-operation. The Institute for Economic Research of the National University of Mexico makes investigations and publishes studies for the information and guidance of the co-operative movement. In the majority of these countries, and particularly in Argentina, Brazil and Venezuela, encouragement has been given to school cooperatives and they are often specifically provided for in co-operative legislation or else made the subject of special regulations. In the United States, consumers' co-operation is taught in a number of scattered public schools, both urban and rural, in many parts of the country, and in some of them such instruction is supplemented by the establishment of school co-operatives. In some of the States, e.g., Colorado and Oregon, the further stage is reached of having the co-operative movement or some aspect of it included in courses of study in secondary schools. In higher education, cooperative subjects (often including both agricultural and consumers' co-operation) are taught in the land-grant (State) colleges and universities in 42 States. Three States have passed special legislation on the teaching of co-operation in their educational institutions. In 1935, Wisconsin passed a law which provided that co-operative marketing and consumers' co-operation should be taught in the high and vocational schools of the State. It also required that adequate instruction in the principles of co-operation should be given in universities, State teachers' colleges and county normal schools. In North Dakota, the 28th Legislative Assembly in 1943 passed a law providing for the establishment of a course on co-operation (methods of administration, history, principles, organisation, etc.) in State teachers' colleges and the teachers' college of the University. In Minnesota, there is no State law requiring teaching about co-operation, but in 1937 the Legislature passed a CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 181 law' giving the Department of Education a special appropriation to be used in the preparation of courses on co-operation. In Canada, the elementary and junior high school syllabus approved for use in Catholic schools in the Province of Quebec authorises the teaching of co-operation in the senior grades. Some idea of the co-operative movement is given to pupils of elementary schools in Manitoba (in the geography course) and in Saskatchewan (in the course on citizenship and character education). Secondary school curricula in most of the provinces include the teaching of co-operation in courses on other subjects: agriculture (Alberta, Quebec, Saskatchewan), history (Manitoba, Saskatchewan), commerce (Quebec), and political economy (Quebec). In Nova Scotia, the course of studies of the senior grades of the secondary schools includes "adequate information on the philosophy, progress, methods of co-operation, and its place in the programme of social reconstruction". In addition, at least three provincial Departments of Agriculture have introduced courses on co-operation into their intermediate schools which give occupational training courses in agriculture and household science. As regards higher education, it is to be noted that the provincial Governments have recognised the importance of co-operation in rural and national economics and have encouraged its progress, in collaboration with co-operative organisations, by making a place, which is often considerable, for the teaching of co-operation in the nine agricultural colleges in Canada (three in Quebec Province, none in New Brunswick or Prince Edward Island, and one in each of the six other provinces) and also in their extension courses (winter or evening courses open to the public) . Co-operative subjects are taught to a varying extent in the provincial Universities of Alberta, British Columbia and Saskatchewan, and also in the Universities of St-Francis Xavier (Nova Scotia), Ottawa (Ontario), and Laval (Quebec). The Dominon Department of Fisheries gives a grant to the extension departments of the Superior School of Fisheries in Quebec, St-Francis Xavier University, and the University of British Columbia for co-operative education among fishermen. Finally, the help given by the public authorities of the United States and Canada to the formation and development of the cooperative movement is perhaps best indicated by the number and variety of publications issued and distributed by their federal and State or provincial Governments, and the support given by some Canadian provincial Governments to the publishing activities of the co-operative organisations themselves. The official publications range from textbooks and monographs down to handbooks and pamphlets giving useful information on the way to form, direct 5 182 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS and manage a co-operative organisation. The objectivity of some of these publications and the practical nature of others have certainly done much, in the last ten or fifteen years, to forward the growth of a vigorous co-operative movement. To sum up, it may be said that the desire of co-operatives to obtain State assistance in their teaching and training activities has already been to some extent satisfied, though apparently less in Europe than elsewhere. Legislation Actual or possible obstacles to the free operation and development of co-operative organisations are of various kinds. There may be inadequacy or, sometimes, entire lack of specific legislation setting out their precise legal status and giving them a correct and 6trict definition. Not infrequently, too, their functioning is impaired or their activities are limited by fiscal or general economic measures expressly aimed at them or unintentionally affecting them. CO-OPERATIVE LEGISLATION The gaps which are still sometimes found in co-operative legislation are largely explained by the way such legislation came into being and developed. Co-operative organisations, being a spontaneous and independent outgrowth from the poorest social strata, were a t the beginning too weak and too dispersed to catch the attention of the legislator. They had to develop a t first more or less extra-legally or else, though essentially associations of persons carrying on an economic enterprise, accommodate their activities as best they could to rules designed for stock companies. Even today there are still several countries in which co-operative associations are not governed by special laws. However, these cases are exceptional. In the course of years the majority of countries have made legal provision for the co-operative movement, in their civil law, in their commercial or industrial law, or in one or more special enactments. The provision made is sometimes satisfactory in the aggregate, b u t even so is capable of improvement. It is often defective in some important point, owing to living needs having outstripped the law. Co-operative legislation is modelled on co-operative custom and has done little more than record this as :t appears in the memorandum, articles of association and by-laws of societies, and as it has been modified by contact with experience, and strengthened by the action of the co-operative federations and given currency by the spread of the movement. CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 183 However, the legislator has not always freed himself from the timidities and hesitations of the early period, and certain legal enactments governing co-operatives, including some of the best and oldest provisions, still impose on their field of activity and mode of operation restrictions which were justified by considerations of prudence at the time but have since lost their raison d'être. Nor has the legislator always been entirely successful in freeing himself from ideas which served to define and regulate societies based on capital when laying down the legal status of co-operative organisations. Certain definitions of the co-operative society, by their lack of precision, can be and are in fact applied to stock companies. Others are too narrow or only explicitly provide for certain forms of co-operative society, thereby excluding from co-operative law other forms regarded as authentically co-operative by cooperative doctrine and custom. This inability to recognise and express the principles common to all co-operative societies is at the same time an inability to recognise and express those which are special to them. The consequences of this double failure are found in the provisions of the laws in which it occurs. Questions relating to acquisition or loss of membership, rights and duties of members, the mode of forming share capital and the nature of the shares, the liability of members for the society's debts, the establishment of reserves and the nature and role of such reserves, the division of the annual surplus, etc., all of which are questions of special significance and fundamental importance in co-operative societies, are sometimes dealt with by reference to legislation on stock companies, whether by making the rules for stock companies partially or wholly applicable to co-operatives or by having the rules of co-operative societies appear merely as exceptions to general company law. Where this confusion of ideas exists in legislation, it is naturally reflected and aggravated by the law's interpretation and application. It obviously impairs the functioning of co-operative organisations. It also hinders the co-operative movement in its work of teaching and spreading co-operative principles. Hence the desire of co-operative organisations, in quite a number of countries still, to enjoy a legal status appropriate to themselves, that is to say, in clear and strict conformity with their needs and conceptions, and their desire, in a growing number of countries, to be governed by a single comprehensive statute applying to all co-operative organisations and to such organisations alone. FISCAL AND ECONOMIC LEGISLATION Traces of the same confusion appear in fiscal legislation and in that concerning the functioning of the economic system in general. 5 184 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS This is not the place to enumerate them in detail ; for the needs of this study it will be sufficient to call attention to some of the most common or most recent types of hesitations or mistaken interpretations. As regards taxation, it is true that many legislations have taken the popular character of co-operative organisations into account. They have therefore simplified the formalities connected with the establishment of a society and thereby also reduced their cost. But in certain countries, the fiscal law placing a tax on the reserves or profits of businesses has shown itself puzzled by the indivisible character of co-operative reserves and also by the surplus distributed among the members. This distribution of surplus is regarded as a profit, whereas it really eliminates profit and is simply the refund of an overcharge. I t has even happened that where national commercial and industrial companies pay a lower rate of tax on income from capital than that paid by foreign companies and by natural persons, cooperative organisations have been taxed at a high rate because they are not companies within the meaning of the law. Finally, it not infrequently occurs that the revenue authorities treat some types of co-operatives differently from others, through failure to appreciate the community of their principles and rules of operation. This uncertainty about the nature of co-operative organisations leads to an equal uncertainty as to the place they should be given in the economic system and as to the role that they play in it or could play in it if they were free to do so. For instance, the interpretation placed on the anti-trust legislation (Sherman Act) in the United States for a time threatened the development of the cooperative movement in that country. It was eventually necessary to pass a special law, the Capper-Volstead Act of 19221, to remove this menace ; incidentally, this was for a long time the only federal act to contain provisions defining co-operative associations. The numerous measures of regulation and rationalisation taken by the Governments of most countries in the economic field since die world depression have naturally affected the working of cooperative societies and the development of the co-operative movement. The restrictions put on industrial and agricultural production, and on imports and exports, succeeded, though not in every case, 1 The earlier Clayton Act (1914) had already laid down that labour, agricultural, and horticultural organisations which are instituted for purposes of mutual help, which do not have capital stock, and which are not conducted for profit, should not be held or construed to be illegal combinations or conspiracies in restraint of trade under the anti-trust laws (§6). CONDITIONS OP CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 185 in checking an excessive fall in prices, in restoring certain equilibriums and in protecting certain enterprises. But such restrictions often led, in the case of the co-operative organisations, to a slowing down or stoppage of some of their activities or of their development. For by these measures the co-operatives were given quotas (production, import, export) which necessarily referred to a past state of affairs and made no allowance for their growth (even at a time of crisis) and for the real needs of their members. Among other things there were instances of consumers' co-operatives being forbidden to sell at prices lower than those fixed by the regulations; in the fixing of price margins, a consumers' co-operative wholesale, through a false interpretation of its nature and role, was sometimes classed among "owners of retail shops"; others had lower price margins imposed on them than their competitors, because their costs were less; agricultural co-operatives were proceeded against for having paid their members a return based on the regulation price and representing simply a saving effected on the cost of management. There are countries in which restrictions have been placed on the number or size of the branches permissible to consumers' co-operatives. On the grounds of "rationalisation" cooperative organisations have been obliged to deal with capitalist import and export enterprises which have thus enjoyed at least a temporary monopoly. There are even cases where co-operative organisations have been in danger of having to enter cartels or of being legally compelled to do so. These typical examples are of course far from being universal. But they have provoked a reaction where they have occurred and also in the co-operative movement generally. Co-operators, though theoretically and in practice opposed to the system of "all against all" competition, consider that to suspend or hamper competition at the expense of institutions which represent a type of organised economy "is a very poor occasion on which to sacrifice freedom and is, in fact, a departure from the object in view". 1 They hold, moreover, that certain measures affecting them also affect the right of association and the natural right of each individual in a democratic order to dispose of the products or remuneration of his labour as he may see fit. To put the matter briefly, since most Governments, particularly in the last fifteen years, have intervened more and more widely and directly in the economic field, with the result that their action impinges on that of co-operative organisations with growing frequency, co-operators have been led to define their 1 Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of Public Authorities in the Economic Field. Conclusions of an enquiry undertaken by the Internationa Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations (I.L.O., Geneva, 1939), p. 12. 5 186 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS attitude generally in regard to efforts in the direction of an organised economy and, in particular, in regard to the interventions of public authorities in the economic field. Their views on these two points may be found in a large number of articles and discussions. It may be useful, however, to recall that the question was the subject of a special enquiry undertaken by the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations just before the war. The highly representative character of this Committee, a joint organ of the International Co-operative Alliance and the International Confederation of Agriculture, gives a special authority to the conclusions which it drew from this enquiry and it is legitimate to look t o them for the most complete and exact expression of co-operative thought at the time. As these conclusions were reached on the basis of written opinions obtained from 35 national organisations in 26 countries, they give, not so much an exact reproduction of the attitude of each of these organisations, as a sort of composite picture in which the different shades of opinion expressed are combined. But it may be assumed that on such a wide basis of enquiry the principal features of the co-operative attitude have been brought out. Their general correspondence with co-operative philosophy also allows the assumption that these are fairly permanent features, even though recent years may have introduced new shades of opinion here and there. Co-operative Institutions and the Planning of the Economy The conclusions of the International Committee for Inter-Cooperative Relations were not inspired by any preconceived idea and they follow easily a general line which keeps clear alike of extreme laissez faire doctrine and an exaggerated devotion to planning. After pointing out that the co-operative movement is developing in the existing structure of the contemporary world a form of planned economy1, the Committee declares: Co-operators have thus no hesitation in recognising the existence of a common motive behind their own efforts and all other sincere moves towards an organised or planned economy—namely, the need for order and the firm desire to introduce the considered will of man as a determining factor in economic life. But their attitude, although not unfavourable, is not uncritical, and they are not prepared to adhere without reservation to the most ambitious theories of economic planning or organisation, still less to subscribe indiscriminately to all the attempts, systematic or piecemeal, to put these theories into practice. 1 See, on this question, Co-operative Organisations and Posl-War Relief, op. cit., Part I: "Characteristics of the Co-operative Movement". CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 187 It goes on to explain its "middle way" position: They [co-operators] condemn the unrestricted war of selfish interests, in all its forms, because it leads to disorder and cruelty; but they would not deprive progress of the contribution which the free play of initiative and invention can make to it. They would like to be able, by the organisation and practice of solidarity, to limit and so to render supportable the risk entailed by economic activity and by the fact of existence; but they refuse to carry such a policy to the point at which the sense of responsibility disappears with the disappearance of the risk. They deny that, under guise of a doctrine of liberty, the supreme control of economic affairs, national or international, should be left in the hands of the great financial companies; and they feel surprise and resentment, as at a gross misconception and a grave injustice, whenever Government action fails to make the essential distinction between big business groups, whose object is profit, and co-operative organisations, whose object—whatever their size—is one of service.1 On the role of experts in the organisation of the economy it says: They were not the last to realise the importance of research, thought, organisation and foresight in any effort deliberately to establish and maintain in economic life that equilibrium which the liberal school expected from the free play of individual action; and so they greet with satisfaction and gratitude the necessary appearance of "experts" on the public scene. But though they welcome them as eminent servants of economic life, they are not prepared to accept them as its infallible, omniscient, all-powerful lords. Their experience is that if anything has harmed the idea of economic planning as much as absolute authoritarianism, it has been the irresponsible, but none the less imperious whims of amateurs, giving orders to "grow more" one day, to "uproot" the next. The economic system should not, in their view, be placed at the mercy of the experiments, fancies, or manias of irresponsible "experts" who may well be nothing but doctrinaires. Themselves at daily grips with the thorny problems of real life, they have been able both to build up their confidence in the powers of the human spirit and to realise its limitations. Practical men, who have learned modestly from experience, they prefer the expert who faces his task with due humility, the expert who does not imagine that a single man or a single body of men have the knowledge and genius required to grasp the whole complexity of the economic world and direct its destinies without restraint. While recognising, of course, the value of acts and regulations, the Committee considers that legislative action has its limitations: They know and teach the benefit of discipline, but do not confuse it with compulsion, which they consider inapt to establish and maintain order or to secure the prevalence of truth. They subscribe to Lacordaire's celebrated dictum that—"Between strong and weak, rich and poor, or master and servant, liberty is oppression and the law sets free". But they know also that there are more wrongs in heaven and earth than acts and regulations can put right. Neither have they waited until their attention was drawn to the disorders, unjust profits and underserved misery which flow from the fluctuations—too sudden, too frequent or too wide—in rates of exchange; from excessive discrepancies between the price at which the producer sells and that at which the con1 Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., pp. 8-9. 188 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS sumer buys, or between the prices of manufactured goods and of farm produce; and from analogous phenomena. They know that one of the essentials of economic order is to discover more stable conditions, a better equilibrium; and it is to the search for these that their own efforts are directed. But, in their view, stabilisation and balance do not mean stagnation, and Government action should have neither the object nor the effect of crystallising all forms of activity and all types of economic relationship.1 After these last observations the next step is to examine a little more closely, with the help of the same and some other documents, the co-operative attitude towards interventions of public authorities in the economic field. Co-operative Institutions and the Public Authorities The intervention of public authorities in the economic field is not new and co-operators have not failed to observe that it has often been instigated by business circles themselves, as when they demand protective tariffs or expect the Government to finance and sometimes to rescue from difficulty large railway and shipping enterprises and similar undertakings. But though there is nothing new in such interventions, they have greatly increased in number during the last fifteen or twenty years, particularly since the economic crisis of 1929 and, of course, during the present war. This increase, then, has taken place during a period of decided advance for the co-operative movement. . It is this fact which explains the growth from this time on of thought within the co-operative movement on the respective roles of cooperative organisations and of the State in economic planning. But the discussion has been carried on with a dispersion of effort and does not seem to have led to a complete unity of doctrine. A really thorough examination of the question is therefore not possible and would in any case be out of place here. Without entering into the details of the discussion, it is sufficient, but essential, to indicate the different tendencies that have emerged and to try to single out the tendency that seems to be dominant at the present time. Though there are co-operators who show a disposition to allow the State a considerable place in the planning and control of the economy, others are afraid of seeing it entrusted with excessively large powers which would quickly become uncontrollable. Dr. James P. Warbasse, founder and President Emeritus of the Cooperative League of the U.S.A., is perhaps the most uncompromising representative of this last attitude. " I assert", he writes, that the mere expanding of the functions of the political State is not in itself a virtue; nor can it be regarded even as radical. My own critical scrutiny shows 1 Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., pp. 9-10. CONDITIONS OF CO-OPBRATIVB ACTION 189 it to be a reactionary tendency; for as State control and ownership become wholly dominant, the multiplication of officials and the mechanised increase of officialdom set the stage for autocracy and the abnegation of democracy.1 Further on he adds: "The philosophy of stateism rests on cumpulsion which moves on towards totalitarian domination over the individual and his freedoms. It begins as socialist reform and ends in autocracy." 2 In so far as these declarations express apprehension of the possibility that the State may become all-powerful, they may be said to reflect the general trend of co-operative thought. Even cooperators who would hesitate to go so far cannot accept the idea of a "unitary, monolithic and absolute" State wielding excessive powers in the economic field ; they are almost as resolutely opposed to it as they are to the power of private monopolies and cartels, and for much the same reasons. This does not mean that they deny the State all economic function. Dr. Warbasse, whose opposition, despite its vigour, is not unqualified, regards it as a necessary evil. As he writes in the article already quoted: "I am not here objecting to the expansion of the State. As a reform measure, in a capitalist society, it often becomes necessary. . . I am questioning the expediency of co-operators giving themselves to this end."' Elsewhere he writes again: "I have no quarrel with the compulsory political State. I believe in it for the multitude of non-cooperative and unsocial souls. It is necessary to supply needs and services when the people cannot supply themselves individually or in their voluntary associations." 4 On this point too it can be said that the thought of Dr. Warbasse is in accord with the doctrine and general tendency of the cooperative movement, in preferring voluntary solutions to compulsory solutions whenever possible. In practice, however, most co-operators are prepared to make concessions. The extent of such concessions varies according to the degree to which their makers are influenced by doctrines other than the co-operative one and also according to the degree to which they take account of the limitations inherent in or imposed on cooperative action at the present time or in the immediate future. It may be useful to give a concrete illustration of this complex attitude in which are combined devotion to liberty, considerations 1 Dr. James Peter WARBASSE: "Co-operatives to be Absorbed by the State", in Review of International Co-operation (London), May 19&3, p. 66. 1 Idem, p. 68. s Idem, p. 66. 1 James Peter WARBASSE: "Leading Cooperation to Ruin", in Consumers' Cooperation, New York, Mar. 1943, p. 38. 5 190 CO-OPßRATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS of order, search for justice, pursuit of an ideal and a sense of what is possible. It may be found in the replies made to one of the questions asked by the International Labour Office in a questionnaire sent in 1942 to accessible co-operative organisations. The question was: "Define your attitude towards continuance for some time of: (a) rationing, (fe) State control of raw materials, (c) State control of stocks, (d) State control of prices, (e) State control of home trade, and (/) State regulation of international trade". 1 In some cases separate answers were given for each heading and in others a single answer covering the question as a whole. They are not very numerous, but come from countries as diverse as Canada, Mexico, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States, and from organisations operating mainly in rural areas, as well as from those of an urban and industrial character. Despite this diversity of origins, they show a large measure of agreement in their general trend, and the observations, qualifications and reservations accompanying them, so far from being contradictory, are complementary and together reveal an attitude which is broadly common to all the organisations that replied. With very few exceptions, the organisations replying showed themselves in favour of the maintenance of the different controls, or of some of them, for a certain period; at the same time they stressed more or less strongly that the measures should be regarded as temporary and be dispensed with as quickly as possible; in other words, as soon as thev cease to be "necessary and desirable". The only two real exceptions were in regard to State control of home trade. The Ohio Farm Bureau Cooperative Association (U.S.A.) considers that maintenance of its control will definitely not be necessary, and the Swedish Federation of Co-operative Meat Marketing Societies is of the opinion that it will probably not be necessary. Some other organisations accept the maintenance of such control explicitly (Co-operative Union and Wholesale Cooperative Society of Switzerland (U.S.C.)) or appear to accept it by implication (Co-operative Union of Great Britain, Consumers' Cooperative Association of Kansas City (U.S.A.)). The replies received are summarised or reproduced below. First come the answers, item by item, of the organisations which gave replies on each of the controls specified, and then the answers defining a general attitude. Midland Cooperative Wholesale of Minneapolis (U.S.A.), and 1 The questionnaire referred to the period which would begin when hostilities ended. CONDITIONS OP CO-OPBRATIVE ACTION 191 the Swiss Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society unreservedly accept the maintenance of rationing for some time after the war. The other replies, including those that are negative in form, really say the same thing, though with some variations. The Ohio Farm Bureau Cooperative Association is for its maintenance for "as long as supplies of essentials are scarce". In Canada, the Associated Growers of British Columbia would maintain rationing, but "not beyond the necessities brought about by the war", while the Swedish Federation of Co-operative Meat Marketing Societies would like it dropped "as soon as possible after the end of hostilities". To understand correctly the attitude of the Cooperative Union and Wholesale Society of Sweden, it is necessary to recall that this organisation petitioned the Swedish Government as early as the summer of 1939, asking that a satisfactory system of rationing cards should be prepared for the chief articles of food; and that as early as March 1939 the organisation, while approving in principle the State control of prices during wartime, stressed that such control could not be effective and could even be harmful unless combined with the rationing of goods in short supply. Though it approved and even advocated certain measures of control the Swedish Co-operative Union expressed the view that "when there is no longer a shortage of goods the market should once more become free in the sense that rationing or other forms of State restriction of consumption which are now both necessary and desirable should cease". The temporary maintenance of control of raw materials is considered necessary by the Midland Cooperative Wholesale of Minneapolis and the Swiss Co-operative Union, while the Ohio Farm Bureau gives no categorical answer, but observes that "conservation of national resources and prevention of private monopoly would decide". The same organisations, together with the Swedish Federation of Co-operative Meat Marketing Societies, consider some continuation of State control of stocks as necessary or as probably and temporarily necessary. They have much the same attitude regarding control of prices. It should be maintained "in certain cases", according to the Swedish Meat Marketing Federation; "probably, especially with rationing", in the view of Midland Cooperative Wholesale of Minneapolis. The Ohio Farm Bureau recalls that after the last war "prices hit peak one year after hostilities ceased". State regulation of international trade will have to be maintained for a time, according to the Swiss Co-operative Union; the Swedish Meat Marketing Federation regards it as "very probably 3 9 * 5 192 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS necessary". The Ohio Farm Bureau says: "the State will have to be a medium for expression of national policy with respect to trade between nations, unless supra-national agencies come into being". Next come the replies of co-operative organisations which defined their attitude towards all State controls generally. The answer of the Co-operative Union of Great Britain is categorically affirmative; nevertheless, it looks for the removal of controls when the time comes. Its Executive Committee, it is stated, therefore "considers it desirable, and in the interests of the community, that Government control should continue for such a period after the war in which supplies are inadequate on account of national and international conditions, or as is necessary to allow of the smooth liquidation of wartime controls". The Swedish Co-operative Union has opposed in the emergency "every system of restrictions which confines freedom of movement . . . if there has been any feasible alternative". This is an attitude held as a matter of principle and must be interpreted in the light of the observations made in the preceding paragraphs. The reply of the Consumers' Cooperative Wholesale of Kansas City is particularly explicit: State controls "clear across the board" probably must be maintained for a longer period after this war than was the case at the close of World War I, if runaway inflation is to be avoided. After conversion to peacetime production is made, and long denied consumer wants are in a fair way of being met adequately, then co-operatives generally will want to see relaxation of governmental economic controls. Starting negatively, the reply of the Manitoba Co-operative Wholesale Ltd. (Canada) is very significant: The general attitude of this organisation towards State control is that it should be abolished as soon as possible, as said State control will protect interests which are already heavily established. If, on the other hand. State control should protect the natural resources of the country and see that they are properly developed for the people of Canada, the co-operative attitude would be very definitely in favour of these sorts of regulations. This declaration, expressing the general social outlook of cooperative organisations, may be compared with that made on the same occasion, not by a co-operative organisation, but by the Bureau of Consumers' Co-operatives of the Mexican Department of Labour and Social Insurance: The Bureau considers—and believes this to be the view of the co-operatives under its control—that it is desirable to maintain all the State controls mentioned in the question for a period the length of which will depend on the work of national and international economic reconstruction and, most of all, on the welfare CONDITIONS OP CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 193 of the common people of each country, in order to protect the lower income groups, i.e., the workers, against the consequences of unrestricted trade. Looked at from the standpoint of what they have most deeply in common, these various replies seem to reveal not only a willingness to seek a reasonable compromise between a principle and practical necessities, but also, explicitly or by implication, recognition of a certain possible convergence of co-operative action and State action. As Dr. Fauquet says: "On condition that the State is independent of special interest groupings, there is a community of purposes between State action and co-operative action: both tend to win acceptance for the idea of organised service as against struggle for profit". 1 Whenever State action and co-operative action converge on the same objective, they are or can be complementary, despite the fact that they use different methods. This is the idea expressed, for instance, in an editorial article which appeared in the Canadian Co-operator: "We have no blue-print of a Co-operative Commonwealth. When it comes. . . it seems probable the technique adopted will be partly voluntary by co-operative societies, and partly compulsory by the State as the circumstances suggest to be the most useful, efficient, economical and desirable." 2 This was also the conclusion reached by the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations. It presented the conception in an extended form which made room for three instead of two sectors in the economy: Refusing to engage in academic disputes, indeed to some extent laying their own theoretical preferences aside—in other words, striving to remain within the bounds of present facts and possibilities—they consider that, in the economic system now being constructed, freedom without check (but not without risk or supervision), planned compulsion by the State, and that "organised liberty" which the co-operative movement represents, all have their contribution to make.' This idea of mixed economies had already been clearly presented by Dr. Fauquet in the first edition (1935) of his Co-operative Sector* and led him to the following reflections on the "complex and variable" relations which exist or can be established, among others, between what he calls the "co-operative sector" and the "public sector": 1 Dr. G. FAUQUET: Revue des études coopératives (Toulouse), Jan.-Feb.-Mar. 1943, p. 19. 1 "Co-operation and Stateism", in Canadian Co-operator (Brantford, Ontario), June8 1943, p. 6. Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., pp. 12-13. 4 Le Secteur coopératif, op. cit. See particularly the Introduction. 5 194 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS As soon as co-operators, taking a positive view of the realities of the past and present, accept the idea of mixed economies and reject the abstract idea of a pure economy, and are persuaded that economic development occurs as a succession of mixed economies of variable composition, then they have no fundamental objection to make to measures that may be decided on by the public authorities either to ensure the working of public services or to take in hand the over-all regulation of the economy. . . Co-operators can accede to forms that are intermediate between public action and co-operative action (public co-operatives (.régies coopératives), delegation of public utility functions to co-operatives). They may equally find in public action an effective means of control over those parts of the economic process which are strongly held by capitalist economy and can be captured only with difficulty, or not at all, by co-operative economy.1 A large number of leaders or supporters of the co-operative movement in various countries 2 have stressed the mixed character of contemporary economies that have reached a certain degree of development, and it is interesting to note the coincidence, of their views with those expressed by leading administrators and public men holding widely different political outlooks. Mr. Leon Henderson, for example, formerly head of the Office of Price Administration in the United States, speaking at the Congress of the Cooperative League at Chicago in November 1944, declared: " I t is not a choice between reliance on business enterprise or being completely dominated by a State economy. It is, rather, one of a mixed economy." 3 Mr. John Bracken, leader of the Progressive-Conservative Party in Canada, gave this comprehensive definition of "free enterprise" in a broadcast speech: "Free enterprise means private enterprise where it can serve better than any other, and co-operative enterprise in the fields where it can best serve, and Government development in the fields where public ownership and operation will give the best social dividends." 4 Mr. Henry Wallace, when Vice-President of the United States, put the matter thus: "I have always believed that the Swedish people have the ideal democratic approach: corporate form of business where corporations do the best job, Government super1 2 Le Secteur coopératif op. cit., pp. 47-48. Cf., for instance, C. R. FAY: Co-operation at Heme and Abroad (P. S. King and Son Ltd., London, 1939), Vol. IÍ, p. 25; R. A. PALMER (General Secretary of the British Co-operative Union): "British Co-operation and the State", in Review of International Co-operation, Mar. 1944 (in reply to Dr. Warbasse's article quoted in the text); Murray D. LINCOLN, in a speech made at the annual meeting (1943) of the Ohio Farm Bureau Federation, cited in Ohio Cooperator, IS Nov. 1943; Joe GILBERT in Midland Cooperator, 9 June 1943; W. C. GOOD. President of the Co-operative Union of Canada, in his evidence before the Special Committee on Reconstruction and Re-establishment of the Canadian House of Commons, Minutes of Proceedings and Evidence, No. 11, 12 May 1943, p. 266. * As reported in "Pennsylvania Cooperative Review, Nov. 1944, p.9. 4 As reported in Canadian Co-operator, July 1943, p. 17. CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 195 vision where it is needed, Government ownership where the Government does the best job, and co-operatives where they do the best job. . . It is a four-way approach. . . "l The tendency, then, which seems to be dominant in the complex pattern of co-operative thought and also runs parallel to a strong current of modern economic thinking, is t o recognise and define within a mixed economy the place which belongs to State action in certain fields where such action is considered indispensable and as regards the over-all management of the economy. However, co-operative organisations, aware of the limits and conditions of State action 2 , at the same time try to define their own role in a mixed economy and the means of correlating it with that of the State. In this connection they point out that the State has to find means for the carrying out of the plans it has prepared, that its action inevitably becomes diluted as it moves away from the centre and that if it is to remain effective it must make use of intermediary agencies. The question is which means and what agencies are to be employed. In the human endeavour to acquire knowledge and devise methods of action there is no dearth of investigators able to reconstruct the past from history or of poets able to build the future by imaginative effort. But there is equally need for minds capable of observing, interpreting and utilising the present. For while it is useful to seek in the past means of influencing the future, and both useful and necessary to foreshadow the future in well-laid plans, it is also necessary, for solid results, to prepare for the future by fashioning our present. In other words, it is first necessary to take a careful inventory of the present and to recognise the seeds of the future in it as well as the lessons of the past. 3 Finally, in looking for means of action, preference should not be given to those of untried value, but rather it should be asked if there are not among existing ones some whose development would fit in with the general intention of the plans in question. This suggestion has already been advanced by the International Committee for InterCo-operative Relations in the following terms: In the search for executive organs, the desire to save time, thought and money induces Governments to abstain from creating new institutions out of the void 1 Cf. The Cooperative Builder (Superior, Wisconsin), 23 Sept. 1943. 2 Opinions as to what constitute these limits and conditions abound in cooperative literature. See, for instance, the message of R. A. PALMER, Acting President cf the International Co-operative Alliance, on the occasion of International Co-operation Day {Review of International Co-operation, June 1942) ; Sir Thomas ALLEN, former Vice-President of the International Co-operative Alliance {idem, June 1943)' ; and Dr. G. FAUQUET, op. cit., in chapter on "Etatisme et Coopération", pp. 45-52. ' * Just as both surviving and newly developed non-capitalist forms are found alongside the prevalent capitalist forms in the mixed economy of to day. 5 196 CO-OPERATION AND PRËSENT-DAY PROBLEMS until they have reviewed and examined such as already exist, and sometimes to choose among the latter those which by character and experience are fitted for the object in view.1 Recalling the federal structure of the co-operative movement, the Committee also pointed out the advantages of such a structure for the preparation as well as the execution of plans: This structure, based on elementary economic units, has obvious advantages for the preparation iof a plan or for its execution; for in so far as it is deliberately organised or planned, an economic system must first of all be well informed. The collection of the necessary information is partly the duty of the statistician; but not more than partly, for statistics can grasp only generalities and averages and not the current realities of life. In order to remain in touch with problems and needs; to realise at any moment their real character, their real proportions; to have a sure vision of the goal; to choose, adapt or devise the means best fitted to reach it; to foresee or to observe in good time all the direct or indirect, shortor long-term repercussions which the use of such means will produce; to grasp the new problems which arise out of all these factors when they arise and to propose a solution for them: to achieve all this, a more sensitive mechanism, a mechanism which can penetrate, not intermittently but permanently, into the depths of economic and social life, must be available and must be used with knowledge and skill. This mechanism, this instrument of research and achievement, can be provided by the co-operative societies, because they stand close to man, to his labour and his needs—and because they are at his service.' The Committee added: In offering this instrument the co-operative organisations realise that they are also suggesting a method—at least whenever such an instrument and method can be used. In the name of their own experience, they say that every effort to put the economic world in order must proceed from contact—permanent contact —between reality and thought. They mean by this, not that it is enough to create theories and to put them to the test of experience, for this type of experience would be the most expensive of amusements. They mean that ideas themselves should be conceived in the womb of present reality and ripened by day-to-day action before they take shape as methods; and that methods, once shaped, must undergo continual adaptation through contact with experience.' And it concluded : The co-operative organisations believe, then, that if excessively bureaucratic forms of economic planning are to be avoided, if some of the advantages of the experimental method are to be introduced between the lines of purely mathematical conceptions, there can be little choice but to call for their aid and advice —as has indeed already been done in a number of countries.4 Dr. Fauquet, too, discusses in somewhat more detail the link between State action and co-operative action: Since their federal structures bring together their component units in a rising scale of integration, co-operative organisations offer the State—if it is ready to 1 Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., p. 13. » Idem, pp. 13-14. » Idem, p. 14. 'Ibid. CONDITIONS OF CO-OPERATIVE ACTION 197 take advantage of it—a chain of intermediaries between the directive centres of the economy and the depths of social life. The link so established is not a rigid one, but elastic and capable not only of transmitting directives from above, but also of correcting and mitigating errors in them. The equilibrium of the laissez faire economy was assured, at least in theory, by the automatic reactions of the market: the managed economy may hope to find a similar regulative action in the free play of the elements grouped federally in co-operative organisations.1 To the problems, then, already mentioned as the chief preoccupations of the co-operative movement at the present time and for the immediate future—the continuous enlargement and renewal of educational activity 2 , and the constant effort to achieve unity of the co-operative movement (particularly through the development of inter-co-operative relations) 3 —must be added a third. Since co-operative organisations and the public authorities, though using different means and methods, have to operate, in part, in the same field, and since their interventions, under certain conditions, can be convergent or complementary, it is necessary to seek the forms and methods most appropriate for linking them together and ensuring their mutual support. In particular, during the period of post-war reconstruction search must be made "within any general plan" for the place and role which suit co-operative organisations—which correspond, in other words, to their abilities while safeguarding "respect for their peculiar principles and their administrative autonomy". 4 This problem may be examined under the following two heads: (a) consultation and representation of co-operative organisations in the bodies through which the economic and social policies of Governments are planned,, executed and controlled; and (£>) direct assignment of public utility functions to co-operative organisations. The war and immediate pre-war periods yield numerous examples of tasks entrusted to co-operative organisations or to representatives of them. It is not necessary, nor would it be possible under present circumstances, to catalogue them all. The selection given merely seeks to illustrate in a concrete manner the nature, form, variety and, sometimes, the extent of the assistance that cooperative organisations have been called on to render to the public authorities. 1 Dr. G. FAUQUET: Le Secteur coopératif, op. cit., p. SI., • Cf. Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief', op. cit.. Part I, Ch. IV: "The Co-operative Movement and Education", pp. 19-34. *4 Idem, Part I: "Characteristics of the Co-operative Movement", pp. 4-36. Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of the Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., p. 15. 5 CHAPTER VIII FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION Consultation and Representation Agricultural and consumers' co-operative institutions have reached a fairly high stage of development in a large number of countries and it is natural that they should generally have been consulted upon the fixing, regulation and control of prices, upon rationing, and upon the organisation of production and marketing of foodstuffs and other agricultural produce. However, some of these co-operatives play such a role in the general economy of their country, have acquired such a competence, and represent interests of so great importance t h a t a tendency is found, as some of the following instances show, to associate them with consultations of a broader character. P R I C E REGULATION, RATIONING Before the present war the public authorities, over-riding market conditions, had already begun to regulate the prices of agricultural products, and already co-operative organisations had been invited to share this responsibility. Some instances of this trend will be given. In Australia, co-operative organisations held two out of the six seats on the Australian Wine Board which fixed export prices. Under a Colombian law (No. 134 of 1931), consumers' co-operatives and purchase and sale co-operatives were (by §13) considered to be agencies for price regulation in the areas in which they operated and it was laid down that they "shall be consulted and represented in all existing or future official bodies established to bring down the cost of living". In France, agricultural co-operatives held 18 seats and consumers' co-operatives three seats on the board of administration of the National Inter-Occupational Wheat Office, which, among other things, fixed the prices paid to the producers of wheat and the prices at which it was supplied to the millers. The consumers' co-operatives were represented in the national FORMS OP THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 199 committee and departmental committees for price control, and also in the flour and bread price-fixing committees. Price fixing was also one of the functions of the Czechoslovak Grain Company, in which co-operative organisations had a three-fifths majority (two fifths for agricultural co-operatives and one fifth for consumers' co-operatives). The Czechoslovak co-operative dairies played an important role in the provincial committees responsible for fixing the prices of dairy produce. During the war there was a great increase in the number of bodies entrusted with the regulation, fixing and control of prices and often with the rationing of essential commodities as well. In Western Australia, and perhaps in other States of Australia, price-fixing boards benefit by the presence and advice of co-operators. In Canada, a number of co-operators serve in various capacities on the Wartime Prices and Trade Board. In Iceland, the Federation of Co-operative Societies holds one of the five seats on the Price Regulation Committee. The Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society of Sweden is also represented on the State Price Control Board, and the Federation of Co-operative Meat Marketing Societies has participated in various committees concerned with the introduction and application of the meat-rationing system. In Switzerland, the President of the Federal Price Control Committee was a former president of the committee of management of the Swiss Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society. In the United Kingdom, the General Secretary of the Co-operative Union sits on the Central Price Regulation Committee and the co-operatives have a representative on each of the local price regulation committees. In the United States, a number of co-operators have been members of various committees (Consumer Goods Distribution and Use Panel, Farm Equipment Suppliers' Advisory Committee, etc.) set up to advise the Office of Price Administration. ORGANISATION OF PRODUCTION AND MARKETING In a large number of countries co-operative organisations have been invited to express their opinion on proposed measures for the organisation of production and marketing, particularly as regards consumer goods of agricultural origin. Sometimes the views of the large national co-operative organisations are sought directly, and sometimes there is consultation in permanent or temporary committees and councils on which co-operative 'organisations are represented. First, some facts from the pre-war period may be given, which perhaps still apply in a more or less modified form. In Australia, 5 200 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS co-operative organisations were represented on the following boards established by the Commonwealth Government: on the Australian Dairy Produce Board, 9 out of 17 seats were held by co-operative butter factories; one of the 5 members of the Canned Fruits Export Control Board represented co-operative canneries, and one member of the Australian Meat Board was nominated by co-operative mutton and lamb exporting organisations. The co-operatives of Western Australia were represented on the Royal Commission on Wheat and Baking Industries of 1934; in New South Wales, 2 out of 7 members of the Dairy Products Board were nominated by dairy co-operatives. In Czechoslovakia, representatives of agricultural co-operation were often invited by the Minister of Agriculture to formulate draft laws and ordinances. In Denmark, the Central Committee of Co-operative Organisations held a number of seats on the Agricultural Council, which exercises an influence on the country's economic policy. In Finland, most of the measures adopted for organising the agricultural market were taken at the instigation of the central co-operative unions. In France, cooperative organisations had secured seats on most of the interoccupational committees responsible for fixing quotas on imports of agricultural products or agricultural requisites. In Luxembourg, 4 of the 12 members sitting on the Milk Commission represented co-operative federations and central organisations. In Norway, the Marketing Council established in 1930 with a membership of 8 persons, included representatives of the following co-operative organisations: Central Federation of Norwegian Dairy Societies, Norwegian Central Union for the Marketing of Meat, Norwegian Farmers' Co-operative Egg Export Association, and the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society of Norway. The Egg Export Association also nominated members to the special committee set up for price regulation and exports. In Poland, co-operative organisations were represented on the Foreign Trade Council and also on the official committees for grading butter and cheese ; they were also consulted about all proposed measures which could directly or indirectly affect them. In the United States, the co-operative organisations generally have special committees which collaborate with County and State Colleges of Agriculture in making recommendations to the legislative assemblies of the States or to the Congress of the United States; in addition, when a bill concerning agriculture is being drawn up, the Secretary of Agriculture is accustomed to summon the leaders of the co-operative movement to hear their opinion; co-operative organisations are also generally represented on the committees responsible for making recommendations on or collaborating in the drafting of such bills. In FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVB CONTRIBUTION 201 Yugoslavia, 3 out of 15 seats on the council responsible for allotting livestock export quotas were held by co-operative organisations. Quite numerous instances have been reported during the war period. In Argentina, the agricultural co-operative organisations are represented on the National Commission for Grains and Elevators and the National Commission for the Dairy Industry. Similarly, the consumers' co-operative organisations are represented on some of the bodies established by the public authorities for the planning and control of production and distribution; the co-operatives consider, however, that their present representation is inadequate. In Ireland, the agricultural co-operative organisations have nominated representatives to the Agricultural Production Consultative Council and to similar councils concerned with eggs and livestock. The Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society of Sweden is represented on the State Food Commission. In Switzerland, two members of the Supervisory Council of the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society and the director of the Swiss Peasants' Union sit on the Committee for the supervision of import and export trade; the Swiss Peasants' Union is generally consulted on all wartime economic measures affecting agriculture. In the United States, co-operators sit on a large number of (federal) industry and commodity advisory committees and in organs of some of the State Governments. REPRESENTATION OF A M O R E GENERAL, N A T U R E The general or particular competencies acquired by co-operative organisations or their representatives are sometimes utilised in the widest and most various fields, and it would not be without interest to list all the responsibilities in which the co-operative move.ment has been invited to share, either before the outbreak of war or during it. However, only some instances can be given here. In Argentina, the Union of Argentine Co-operative Societies is represented in the National Mortgage Bank; it occupies one out of five seats on the National Agricultural Council responsible for applying the Act of 21 August 1940 on land settlement. In Australia, besides the instances of representation already given, it may be mentioned that t h t Australian Wheat Board includes some cooperators amnng its members and that in 1939 its General Manager was the General Manager of the Westralian Farmers Ltd.—a cooperative organisation. Similarly, the General Manager of two fruit handling co-operatives was appointed Vice-Chairman of the Apple and Pear Board; the General Manager of the Westralian Farmers Ltd. participated in the World Wheat Conference of 5 202 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS 1939 and the Federal Conference on Shipping in 1929, and he is at present Consultant to the Commonwealth Government on Shipping. The War Contracts Board, the Transport Board, and the Liquid Fuel Control Board also avail themselves of the advice of representatives of co-operative organisations. In Canada, the President of the Associated Growers of British Columbia is a member of the Agricultural Advisory Committee set up by the Dominion Department of Agriculture; the President of the Manitoba Pool Elevators sits on the advisory committee of the National War Finance Committee; and the Manitoba Co-operative Wholesale Ltd. is consulted by the Wartime Prices and Trade Board. In France, delegates of the consumers' co-operatives had seats not only on the central committee of the Inter-Occupational Wheat Office and on the Superior Council of Co-operation, but also on the National Economic Council, the Superior Council of Labour, the Railways Advisory Committee, the Superior Council of Social Insurance, and the General Council of the Bank of France. In Great Britain, the English Co-operative Wholesale Society is represented on some thirty wartime committees established by the Government or under Government auspices, and the Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society is similarly placed; generally speaking, English co-operators report that they are today much more closely associated with the solution of national economic problems than they were during the First World War. In Sweden, the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Society (Kooperativa Förbundet) is represented, not only on the State Price Control Board and the State Food Commission, but also on the State Industrial, Trade, Transport and Fuel Commissions. 1 In Switzerland, the consumers' co-operative organisations are represented on 14 wartime trade associations (which have the legal form of a co-operative society) responsible for carrying out wartime economic measures. The President of the Co-operative Union and Wholesale Co-operative Society is Vice-President of the Swiss Central Office of Importers of Foodstuffs. In the United States, the President of the Consumers' Cooperative Association (North Kansas City) is a member of the National Petroleum Advisory Committee; the co-operative movement is represented on the Economic Stabilization Board ; and the National Council of Farmer Cooperatives has been recognised by the Office of Defense Transportation as spokesman for all agriculture on transportation matters. 1 In the post-war programme of the Swedish trade unions it is suggested that credit should be distributed in accordance with plans drawn up by mixed bodies on which the Government and co-operative organisations would be represented, as well as capitalist enterprises. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 203 PLACE OF CO-OPERATION I N THE PERMANENT MACHINERY OF GOVERNMENT The foregoing examples relate to the help (mostly in the form of advice) that' co-operative organisations have been called upon to give in the fields in which they are active and therefore admittedly have a certain competence and responsibility. They do not concern the facilities available to the public authorities for receiving advice on the co-operative movement itself. For making known their preoccupations, needs and problems, trade, industry and labour have at their disposal liaison bodies (usually in the form of ministerial departments) connecting them with the political and executive apparatus of the State. What is the position in this respect of the co-operative movement, which can also have its special problems occasioned by its structure, mode of business and particular objectives? In almost every country there are one or more administrative services performing some functions in connection with the co-operative movement. At the very least there are services responsible for compiling statistics of all co-operative societies or co-operative societies of certain types. Fairly often there is a registration service which provides the basis for the statistics and also ensures that the rules and activities of co-operative societies conform with the law. There are sometimes services which audit or supervise the auditing of the accounts of co-operative organisations. Some co-operators, concerned to preserve their independence vis-à-vis the State, feel that these useful or necessary services are sufficient. Others regret that the co-operative movement as such has no suitable means of making its voice heard when its own interests are at stake. This seems to have been the opinion of the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations: Owing to their powers of growth rather than to their principles, co-operative organisations have opponents. Yet their most dangerous enemy is not ill-will but ignorance. Every time co-operative organisations have suffered from Government action or omission, it must be frankly recognised, however strange it may seem, that they owe their misfortune very largely to the failure of public opinion in general, of Government departments and of most Members of Parliament, to understand clearly the real character, the legal position, the peculiar structure, and the special administrative details of the co-operative movement.1 Among the bodies suited to securing permanent collaboration between the co-operative movement and the public authorities should be mentioned the councils or committees which have been set up in a number of countries to advise Governments on co1 Co-operative Organisations and the Intervention of the Public Authorities in the Economic Field, op. cit., p. IS. 204 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS operation. France, for example, has had, since 22 February 1918, a Superior Council of Co-operation for the consumers' and workers' productive co-operatives, and these two classes of organisation together occupy more that half the seats on the Council; in addition, by a Decree of 28 March 1935, a Superior Council of Agricultural Co-operation, on which agricultural co-operative organisations were well represented, was established in the Ministry of Agriculture, with the task of advising the Minister on the measures which should be taken to assure the development of agricultural co-operation. By a law passed on 30 May 1944, Egypt has just created a Superior Advisory Council of co-operative societies, with the novel addition of regional co-operative advisorv councils to complete the structure. The liaison between the co-operative movement and the central administrative machinery is all the more strongly established when co-operation is consciously and firmly regarded ,as a factor in the general policy of the country. In India, in most of the British colonies, and in almost all the nations of the American continent, special administrative departments ensure this liaison and are in a position to inform the legislative and executive authorities about the co-operative movement. Usually, however, these departments have only a limited scope and means of action. They are generally more or less heterogeneous elements in larger administrations whose central interest is not the co-operative movement. Through the chances of parliamentary and political circumstance they have been tacked on to the Ministry of Labour or Social Affairs, Ministry of Agriculture, Ministry of National Economy, or other ministry. Often they are dispersed, without any connecting links, among several administrations each of which is interested separately in one or other of the many forms of co-operative organisation. Because these departments are dispersed and are in the position of appendages, the legislative and executive authorities cannot get a comprehensive and therefore true picture of the co-operative movement. Since co-operative organisations are in contact with a large number of economic and social problems, it is felt that the co-operation services in public administrations should be in a position to collaborate suitably with other departments (labour, agriculture, economy, health, education, public works, fisheries, finance, trade). They should not therefore be subordinated or attached to any one of them. This seems to be the most widely held opinion among the cooperators who have considered this question, and some steps have already been taken towards implementing this doctrine. It appears that in the British colonies and possessions a tendency is develop- FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 205 ing to grant independence to the services responsible for the cooperative movement: the Co-operative Societies' Department of the Federated Malay States has been independent since its inception in 1922; the Co-operative Department of Ceylon became independent in 1930, and that of Nigeria in 1936. In France, a commission has been attached (7 April 1938) to the Premier's Office "to study the present situation of co-operation and to propose to the Government what measures should be taken to improve it and establish a permanent liaison between the different forms of co-operative action". But the most notable example is doubtless that provided by the Canadian Province of Saskatchewan, whose Government has recently created, alongside other departments, a Department of Co-operation and Co-operative Development. This department has the express function of assisting the development of the cooperative movement, by helping to organise co-operatives and to make a proper interpretation of legislation, and by giving any necessary aid in research work, auditing and management. The Government considers of vital importance "the co-ordination in close, harmonious working relationships of the various branches of the co-operative movement in the province and in other provinces of the Dominion, as well as similar movements having similar aims in Great Britain and other countries adopting the principles of cooperation as a way of life and as a way of doing business". 1 REPRESENTATION IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL ORGANISATIONS In the inter-war period the question of the representation and collaboration of the co-operative movement on international bodies arose chiefly in connection with the International Labour Organisation. Representation of the co-operative movement is not provided for under the Constitution of the International Labour Organisation, but the collaboration of co-operative organisations is called for by the latter's purposes and activities. As early as its 4tb (1922) Session, the International Labour Conference recognised that co-operative organisations "form a factor in the economic life of the world which cannot be neglected and that in consequence it should be possible for them to be able to give their opinion directly on all questions of labour legislation affecting them to the same degree as private enterprises" 2 , and on 14 November 1920, the Di1 In a report of an interview given by the Hon. Lachlan F." Mcintosh, Minister oí Co-operation and Co-operative Development for the Province of Saskatchewan, to Co-operative News (Manchester), 2 Dec. 1944. 2 I.L.O.: Record of Proceedings, 4th (1922) Session of the International L a b o u r Conference, Vol. I, p. 600. 206 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS rector of the International Labour Office communicated to the Governments of the States Members of the International Labour Organisation a decision of the Governing Body suggesting that Governments "might nominate as one of the advisers whom they are entitled to attach to their delegates a representative of the cooperative societies". Certain delegations to the International Labour Conference have in fact included co-operators, either as delegates or as technical advisers, and co-operative organisations have been consulted on various questions on the Conference agenda, including that of night work in bakeries and the use of leisure. Co-operators have also sat on certain committees of the International Labour Organisation: the Advisory Committee on Management, the Recreation Committee, the Correspondence Committee on Women's Work, the Committee of Experts on Workers' Nutrition, and the Permanent Agricultural Committee. Co-operators also participated in the Preparatory Committee for the World Economic Conference in 1927, in the Conference itself, and in the Economic Advisory Committee set up afterwards with the responsibility of seeing that the Conference resolutions were implemented. Mention should also be made here of the International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations 1 , of which it has been said that "its creation is certainly the most important result of the 1927 Conference, and possibly even its sole positive result". 2 Co-operators also were represented on the Mixed Committee on the Problem of Nutrition, set up by the League of Nations. Finally, some co-operators participated in the comparatively recent United Nations Conference on Food and Agriculture (Hot Springs, Virginia, May 1943); among them were the President of the Cooperative League of the U.S.A. and Secretary of the Ohio F"arm Bureau Federation (one of the five members of the American delegation), and one of the members of the Superior Council of Co-operation of the Province of Quebec (in the Canadian delegation). All these occasions have incontestably served to bring out the particular value of the co-operative contribution to international action. 3 Co-operative organisations, sometimes with the support of the trade unions, also claim representation in the bodies which will be responsible for planning the economic life of the different countries and of the world. 1 See pp. 99-100, and Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief, op. cit., pp. 18-19. 2 Edgard M I L H A U D : Le rôle et les tâches de la coopération dans l'économie de demain (Union suisse des coopératives de consommation, Basle, 1943). * Idem, p. 47. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 207 Certain particular recommendations made by two recent international conferences should be noted in this connection. Though co-operative organisations are not expressly mentioned in them, it is reasonable to think that the following texts apply to them, at least in part, or can apply to them. In its XXVth resolution, dealing with international commodity arrangements, the United Nations Conference on Food and Agriculture recommends that "such arrangements will include effective representation of consumers as well as producers". 1 Similarly, the 26th Session of the International Labour Conference (Philadelphia, 1944), in a resolution concerning economic policies for the attainment of social objectives, considered that international arrangements for the international exchange of goods and services "should provide for adequate representation of consumers as well as producers, representing both importing and exporting countries, in all authorities responsible for the determination and application of policy". 2 Finally, although the Constitutions of the United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration, and of the proposed Food and Agriculture Organisation exclude non-Government representation, it is to be noted that both these bodies have given prompt and clear recognition to the co-operative movement as a valuable aid in the achievement of the tasks entrusted to them. Assignment of Public Utility Functions In the national sphere, collaboration between co-operative organisations and public authorities has often been of a far more active nature than the, mere consultation exemplified above.11 It remains to review these more active forms of collaboration where co-operative organisations have found themselves entrusted, either within or in extension of their normal activities, with functions involving a public responsibility. These forms of collaboration between the "co-operative sector" and the "public sector" have been studied over a period of years in the Annales delà régie directe, and, later, in the Annales de l'économie collective.* The editor of these reviews, Professor Edgard Milhaud, has enumerated some of them in a brochure recently published 1 U N I T E D N A T I O N S C O N F E R E N C E ON F O O D AND A G R I C U L T U R E : Final Act and Section Reports (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office, 1943). » I.L.O.: Oficial Bulletin, Vol. X X V I , No. 1, 1 June 194'4, p. 94. 3 Some of the examples given, it should be added, involve responsibilities more extensive and direct than mere consultation. * Published in Geneva (8 rue Saint-Victor) in four languages (French, English, German, Spanish). ,. 4 0 * 208 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS for the use of Swiss co-operative study circles.1 Its use by these circles stresses the interest felt in this question by co-operators today. The International Committee for Inter-Co-operative Relations surveyed these forms of collaboration in a considerable number of countries in one of the last enquiries it made before the war. The following instances are taken from these sources, supplemented by information communicated directly to the International Labour Office. These examples are fairly varied. In some cases it is a matter of improvised, unsystematic measures, taken without previous study to meet an urgent necessity, though such measures may establish habits. Other examples show actions of a more permanent kind, but which remain isolated and limited in their scope and bearing. Finally, co-operative organisations are sometimes associated with carefully planned interventions so related to one another in time and space that they lead to concerted action destined to replace the automatic adaptations of the laissez-faire economy. However, for the purposes of this study, it seems better to classify the examples according to their form, along the lines of the classification proposed by Professor Edgard Milhaud. He distinguishes four cases: (1) the simple mandate conferred by public authorities on a co-operative or a group of co-operatives; (2) delegation, which establishes a real mutual collaboration when the public authority (State, provincial, municipal, etc.), "desirous of attaining certain ends of general interest, has recourse to existing cooperatives or fosters the creation of new co-operatives and entrusts them with certain functions which it enables or assists them to perform by giving help of various kinds—financial, technical, administrative, propagandist, educational, etc." 2 ; (3) association of public bodies (Government departments and public corporations) and co-operatives in semi-public, semi-co-operative joint service undertakings, in which case the public bodies have a role "of the same order as that of the co-operatives, collaborate on a footing of equality, are simply associated; they co-operate" 3 ; (4) integration of co-operatives in public administrations or joint service undertakings, which may be regarded as a particular instance of the preceding case, with the difference that the co-operative activity, while remaining independent, is included in a wider system of economic activities. Like any classification, this necessarily leaves out intermediate and border-line cases which can almost equally well be placed in 1 Edgard MILHAUD, op. cit. »3 Idem, p. 41. Idem, p. 43. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 209 one category as in another. In particular, certain instances are such by nature, or the information available upon them is such that it is not always possible to measure the degree of collaboration on the part of the public authority and therefore to distinguish between simple mandate and delegation. Similarly, as regards the participation of co-operatives in joint service undertakings, there may be transitional forms between association and integration. Accordingly, the facts collected will be given under two headings only: mandates and delegations under the first, and associations and integrations under the second, with occasional further details on certain forms when possible. MANDATES AND DELEGATION OF FUNCTIONS These are the least complicated forms and also the forms providing the most numerous examples. To get an idea of their variety, it may be of interest briefly to glance at some of them. First, a very simple case of mandate may be cited. Recently, when the Government of the United States wished to liquidate its stock of wool purchased abroad during the early years of the war, it selected the Co-operative National Wool Marketing Corporation to handle the sale by auction of the wool. .When the public authorities have no means of their own for carrying out a group of actions or a particular act, they sometimes delegate the execution of such actions or act to co-operative organisations. Mention has already been made of this intermediary role played by the credit co-operatives in the distribution of Government credits made to agriculture 1 , by housing co-operatives in a considerable number of countries, and by the reconstruction cooperatives in France. 2 It is also the role of certain rural co-operative insurance societies in France, which have been entrusted with the administration of the legislation on accident compensation as regards their members. Similarly, under the Beveridge plan, the local administrative functions of social insurance may be vested in co-operative organisations carrying on voluntary insurance in one or other of the fields of social insurance covered by the plan. As already noted, a similar formula of delegation governs, with the necessary modifications, the relations of the Rural Electrification Administration in the United States, and of theSwedish Government with rural electricity co-operatives', and the relations of some of the provincial Governments in Canada with telephone co-opera' It will be recalled that the loan negotiated by the Bulgarian Government with the League of Nations was partly distributed through the medium of the Agricultural and Co-operative Bank of Bulgaria. « Cf. pp. 74-77. » Cf. pp. 64-65. 5 210 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS tives. In Ireland, there is a comparable situation as regards the cutting of peat, which is organised by a public department and carried out by local co-operative societies in liaison with this department. In the field of hygiene and health, the grants and privileges given by the State to the Yugoslav health co-operatives were simply a return for the delegated functions exercised by the cooperatives in vaccination, preventive medicine and sanitation matters. To these instances may be added that of the Government of Ecuador, which turned to co-operative organisation for the reconstruction of the provinces devastated by the war with Peru and to this end provided newly organised co-operative societies with two years' working capital, by way of compensation for losses sustained by the population. 1 At a time of scarcity, the public authorities may decide to entrust the distribution of certain commodities to co-operative organisations. In France, during the First World War, the State, wishing to popularise the use of frozen meat as a means of reducing prices on the meat market, made arrangements with the National Union of Distributive Co-operative Societies and the Co-operative Wholesale Society, whereby meat from Argentina was delivered directly to the latter and distributed by it to its affiliated societies.2 In 1916, the Austrian Government authorised the consumers' co-operatives and their wholesale society to supply the workers employed in munition plants, whether or not they were members of co-operatives, and to do this at their place of work. The present wartime period provides some instances of the same nature. First, mention may be made of the various commissions given the Hungarian co-operatives in the course of a single year, between the end of 1941 and the autumn of 1942: distribution of sugar and soap for the Green Cross organisation; the feeding of villages cut off by floods from ordinary commercial relations: distribution of Government clothing to certain categories of the population (more than 300 wagon loads and nearly 10,000 parcels) ; commission given to the co-operative organisation Hangya by the Ministry of Trade and Communications to feed 12,000 workers engaged on railway construction; a similar commission given by the Ministry of Agriculture for the feeding of 23,000 workers in-* the Carpathian forests and, later, for the feeding, at the border, of 8,500 agricultural workers returning from Germany; and commission by the Ministry of Finance involving the feeding of 12,000 workers in salt mines. 1 Decree of 18 March 1942; Registro Oficial (Quito), 11 Apr. 1942. ' Quoted by Edgard M I L H A U D , op. cit., from Ernest POISSON: "La collaboration coopérative et municipale pour la vente de viande frigorifiée à Paris et dans le Département de la Seine", in Annales de la régie directe, 1915-16, pp. 1-32. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 211 In Turkey, the Government has established "people's distributive unions" whose duty it is to acquaint people with the food regulations and rationing provisions and to assist in making a fair distribution of available supplies, particularly of State-provided articles. Membership in these unions is voluntary. A regulation published on 22 June 1942 laid down that existing co-operatives should be recognised as "people's distributive unions" and that any union could decide, by a majority vote, to turn itself into a co-operative society. In Cyprus, the Co-operative Central Bank has become the principal agency in wartime for the supply of such various articles as fertilisers, sulphur, soap and sugar, which it has distributed through the medium of the co-operative societies. At the request of the Government it has also undertaken the distribution of certain commodities imported or bought locally by the Government, such as tires, cloth, margarine and condensed milk. The co-operatives have also been given thé task of storing wheat reserves. In India, there is the successful experiment made first in the City and, later, in the Province of Madras. In April 1942, when the City of Madras was threatened with air raids and most of its retail shops and all its wholesale depots were closed, the consumers' cooperative was asked by the Government to open 30 new shops and to supply all citizens with goods. The Government gave it assistance in the form of payment of rent for the new shops, wages for new employees, and interest-free advances for the purchase of stocks, and provision of transportation. A year later, the extension of this experiment to the whole province and the institution of a Government plan for distributing foodstuffs to a part of the population led to the opening of 14 co-operative wholesale and 65 cooperative retail stores in 34 towns. The Government, on its part, provided stocks and guaranteed loans contracted by the co-operatives for carrying out the plan. In 1942, in Ceylon, there was a similar solution to a similar problem: scarcity of food and clothing, a rapid rise in prices, exorbitant profits made by traders and failure of price control, which made goods leave the legitimate market for the black market. The Government therefore decided to open a vigorous campaign for the establishment of consumers' co-operatives, and the co-operatives set up as a result reported a trade of more than 45 million rupees in their first year. 1 In India, again, in the United Provinces, the Government turned to the co-operatives for the distribution of certain essential commodities about which there were difficulties, despite rationing 1 1 rupee = approximately U.S. $0.30. 5 212 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS and price-control measures. But, although the consumers' cooperatives naturally take part in this action (their number increasing from 31 to 132 in the course of the year), the Government has also used co-operatives with a marketing function and most of the work has been done by them. It is perhaps in the marketing of agricultural products that the co-operative organisations have most commonly received direct responsibilities, which often involve the job of co-ordinating production, sale on the national market, imports and exports, and sometimes even go as far as the award of a monopoly or quasimonopoly to co-operatives. First, some examples may be given of simple regulatory action, relating to the pre-war period. In Belgium, in order to overcome certain abuses in the import of foreign butter, the Government gave the co-operatives for the marketing of domestic butter, for nearly a year in 1934-35, a third of the import licences, which had the effect of regulating domestic prices. In Czechoslovakia, the co-operative dairies played an important role in the managing committee of the Dairies Equalisation Fund; in addition, the operation of the Fund for the purchase of eggs was left to the cooperative marketing organisations. In Japan, the Act to control rice production authorises and even encourages co-operative societies to act in place of the rice-control companies which are responsible for storing rice in times of surplus production; in addition, the National Federation of Agricultural Co-operative Marketing Societies and the regional federations receive compensation for expenses incurred in consequence of measures for the orderly marketing of wheat. In Luxembourg, the Central Association of Raiffeisen Funds made advances on stored wirie. In New Zealand, the co-operative federations supplement the national boards established in 1922 to regulate the marketing of meat, dairy produce, fruit, honey, wheat, and poultry and take care of actual commercial transactions; the boards do not accept commercial risks or fix prices. In Sweden, the Union of Co-operative Dairies was entrusted by the State with the execution of the milk regulations. Asimilar part was played, in Switzerland, by the Central Union of Milk Producers, through which the State directed the regulation and organisation of the milk and dairy produce market. During the war, the authorities naturally turned to the cooperative organisations in taking general measures for the collection and marketing of agricultural products. The Australian Wheat Board, set up by the Government to organise the marketing of wheat, appointed the Wheat Pool of Western Australia and the Co-operative Bulk Handling Ltd. its agents for certain purposes FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 213 in Western Australia; the Australian Government also sought the collaboration of the Overseas Farmers' Co-operative Federations Ltd. 1 in marketing Australian wheat in Europe. In Cyprus, the Controller of Cereals has made considerable use of the co-operatives, which collected, on behalf of the Government, three quarters of the wheat and barley crops and also helped with the collection of silk cocoons and olive oil. Sometimes it is a case of encouraging new production, of setting up a complete marketing system, or of meeting a scarcity. In the Philippine Islands, towards the end of the First World War, the rural credit co-operatives were invoked; at this period, scarcity of cereals and the rise in prices threatened the economy and social peace of certain countries of the Far East. The Government of the Philippine Islands decided to encourage rice and corn cultivation and for this purpose put a million pesos at the disposal of agriculturists. The credit co-operatives were designated as the exclusive agents for the application of the grant ; they received and examined requests for loans and made the advances. The "rice and corn" funds and the privileges of the credit co-operatives remained in being beyond the war period. To introduce order into the production, assembling and marketing of maté, and to fix prices and production and export quotas, the State of Parana in Brazil set up a special administration 2 , within which place is made for a body (Commission for the Co-operative Organisation of the Production of Maté) responsible for helping to establish co-operatives among the producers. Co-operative organisation is meant to form the basis of the whole system as soon as possible and gradually to replace the lower stories of the structure set up by the State. Difficulty may arise with products other than agricultural products: mention has already been made of the combined effort of co-operative and Government action to avert a serious crisis in the fishing industry in the Gaspé region of Canada.* Finally, organisation of the marketing of agricultural produce has, as already stated, often led to the establishment of monopolies. This was the case, particularly, during the long crisis in the agricultural market preceding the war. In a large number of instances the monopolies so established were exercised either directly by cooperative organisations or by ad hoc institutions in which co-operatives participated. 1 Its membership comprises an agricultural co-operative organisation from each of the following countries: Australia, Kenya, New Zealand, Rhodesia, and Union of South Africa. * Decree of 4 November 1942, issued by the Co-ordinator of Economic Mobilisation. ' Cf. pp. 54-55. 214 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS The following examples first of all concern cases where the delegation entrusted to co-operative organisations has taken the form of the direct exercise of a monopoly. This may be no more than the confirmation of a situation existing in fact or may sometimes involve the introduction of some measure of "compulsory cooperation" of one kind or another. In Austria, the Federation of Agricultural Co-operative Societies of Lower Austria, as the marketer of the major part of the rye produced in the country, had the sole right to import rye from abroad, under the supervision of a sworn commissioner appointed by the Federal Ministry of Trade. In Estonia, the exportation of butter, eggs, pigs, pork and sausages has been monopolised by the State and the monopoly rights were vested in the three central co-operative organisations respectively concerned with the export of butter, eggs and meat. In Greece, it was through the agricultural co-operative unions of the wheatproducing districts that the Central Committee for the Protection of Home-Grown Wheat bought from associated or individual producers; it was likewise agricultural co-operative unions which, under a system of "compulsory co-operation", were entrusted with the collection and exportation of fruit and wines. In Hungary, the co-operative organisations, and notably Futura (which directly and indirectly derives a large part of its capital from the State), were entrusted with the purchase and exportation of cereals as agents of the Department of Foreign Trade, while in the dairy produce export trade a prominent part was played by the Hungarian Central Association of Co-operative Dairies; the co-operative organisations were also entrusted with the exportation of horses, potatoes, onions, etc., and were used by the public authorities as an intermediary for the distribution of loans granted to tobacco growers. In Latvia, the co-operative movement was really a part of the economic machinery of the State, which used it most extensively for the collection and exportation of dairy produce, eggs and meat products. In Lithuania, the Central Union of Co-operative Dairies embraced almost the whole dairy production of the country and served as an agency for regulating the dairy market under State control. In Norway, the Central Export Agency of the Co-operative Dairies had a monopoly of butter and cheese exports and the sole right to supply butter to the margarine factories; the Norwegian Central Union for the Marketing of Meat had the monopoly of the export of bacon and mutton, and was entrusted with the execution of all the measures taken by the State as regards this industry. In Switzerland, the Central Union of Milk Producers, which included practically all the producers, held what amounted to a monopoly and was the body through FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 215 which the State directed the regulation of the milk and dairy produce market; the Union received subsidies and had at its disposal special resources derived from the proceeds of certain taxes and deductions. In the egg and poultry trade, the Union of Swiss Egg Marketing Societies organised the production, marketing, importation and general trade. In the Union of South Africa, the co-operative organisations were granted the sole right to market tobacco and to distil wine. Some instances may next be given of co-operative participation in institutions set up by the public authorities for the exercise of monopolies. Two refer to the pre-war period and the third to the period of the war. In Czechoslovakia, the monopoly of import licences issued by the Government for dairy produce, eggs, cattle, meat, lard, animal fat, bacon and ham was given to the Syndicate for the Marketing of Cattle and Animal Products in the Czechoslovak Republic, of which the Federation of Unions of Agricultural Cooperative Societies ("Centro-co-operative") and the Joint Committee of Consumers' Co-operative Federations were members (together with and on the same footing as the Central Confederation of Czechoslovak Manufacturers). The Czechoslovak Grain Company, founded in 1934, was given the triple monopoly of buying home-grown wheat (at a price fixed by the company) and of importing and exporting wheat, rye, barley, oats, maize and practically all kinds of fodder. The company's capital was provided and its business was managed by groups interested in its operations: co-operative organisations, 60 per cent. (Centro-co-operative, 40 per cent., and the Joint Committee, 20 per cent.) ; flour-mill unions, 20 per cent.; and private trade, 20 per cent. Its President, however, was appointed by the Government, and State supervision was exercised by a commissioner appointed by the Minister of Finance; under certain circumstances the company could receive a State subsidy. It should be added that the federations of agricultural co-operative societies, with all their constituent units, were at the disposal of the cattle marketing syndicate and of the grain company for their operations. Moreover, the inspectors of the federations saw that the orders of the State were observed, and the cooperative warehousing societies and the federations acted as the principal agents of the grain company. During the war, the authorities in Croatia established an organisation, known as the "Milk Co-operative", which functioned under their control; under its monopoly this organisation was responsible for the production and marketing of milk and dairy products; the co-operative dairies as well as the private dairies were obliged to belong to it. The foregoing examples chiefly concern functions delegated to 5 216 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS co-operative organisations with a view to introducing order into the agricultural produce market and to regulating prices in it. In some of them co-operative organisations are seen as the agents of the public authorities for the carrying out of partial programmes of agricultural policy, and it has already been noted that this is a role that they are often called on to fulfil. Governments may even rely wholly on co-operative organisations for the execution of their entire agricultural policy. This is so, for instance, in Bulgaria, where the Government has endeavoured in recent years to shift the agriculture of the country away from purely food-crop production in. almost closed peasant economies towards the production of crops useful to industry, with an eye to the international market. It has made use of co-operative organisations for distributing credits, seeds, selected animals, implements and machinery, as well as the technical knowledge required for carrying out this policy. It has also exerted influence on them through the medium of the Agricultural and Co-operative Bank, a mixed body in which the State predominates and to which it has given not only certain monopolies but also extensive powers over the co-operatives themselves. Although these powers have been wielded with moderation, they give the Bank and therefore the State a sway over the co-operative movement which has met with some resentment. Subject to any changes that may have been brought about by the war period, however, the Bulgarian co-operatives are reported to have kept a large measure of vitality and local initiative. CO-OPERATIVE ORGANISATIONS AND P U B L I C BODIES L I N K E D IN J O I N T SERVICE UNDERTAKINGS The cases reported in which co-operative organisations are associated or integrated with public bodies in joint service undertakings are less numerous than those in which co-operatives have had functions directly delegated to them. Among simple cases of integration is that of labour co-operatives operating in municipal or national printing works 1 or performing other works or services (transport, public works, mining works, etc.) within State enterprises. 2 A considerable number and variety of instances exist of forms of association between co-operatives and municipalities. The "Bavarian Dairy Society", established in 1928 to organise a regional 1 Cf., for example, Charles MARAUX: "The Commandite: Co-operative Work in the French Printing Industry", in International Labour Review, Vol. XII, No. 5, 1925, pp. 650-667 (reprinted in Annals of Collective Economy, MayJuly 1940). * 1 Cf. Anthony E. C. HARE: "Co-operative Contracting in New Zealand",. in International Labour Review, Vol. LI, No. 2, Feb. 1945, pp. 167-190. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 217 milk market, consisted of the three municipalities of Nuremberg, Fürth and Regensburg and of four producers' and two other cooperatives. 1 The electricity works of Provdiv in Bulgaria are the joint property of the municipalities concerned, of the local cooperative societies and of some individual shareholders. Slightly different in form are the electricity co-operatives in Argentina, and the consumers' co-operatives in Germany, which had among their members municipalities purchasing supplies for hospitals, schools and similar institutions. Sometimes it is the State which appears as a partner of the co-operative organisation. 2 For instance, certain "collective economy undertakings" (gemeinwirtschqftliche Anstalten) set up in Austria after the First World War took the form of societies composed of public bodies and co-operatives. Among such enterprises were the United Leather and Footwear Factories, formed jointly by the State and the Co-operative Wholesale Society. 3 Among the more complex cases of integration, mention has already been made of the Czechoslovak electricity co-operative societies which participate, together with the State, the provinces and the municipalities, in the public service electricity undertakings set up by the Act of 27 July 1919.4 The numerous national credit institutions where State intervention is more or less closely bound up with the activity of co-operatives of various kinds, mostly credit co-operatives, may equally be regarded as semi-public, semi-cooperative joint service undertakings. 5 As already stated, the Futura company in Hungary, which acts as the State's organ of intervention on the market, was established (1919) and financed by the joint action of the State, of the Central Institute of Credit Co-operative Societies (itself semi-public and semi-co-operative), and of the large Co-operative Wholesale and Productive Society Hangya. In France, the National Inter-Occupational Wheat Office, which held a monopoly of the import and export of wheat, though it carried on no buying and selling operations itself, provides a typical 1 Cf. Josef E H R L E R : " T h e Bavarian Milk Supply Company", in Annals of Collective Economy, Vol. VII, No. 3, 1931, p p . 367-374, and Maximilian M E Y E R : " T h e Economic Undertakings of the Municipality of Nuremberg", in idem, Vol. VIII, No. 2, 1932, pp. 184-192. 2 The Finance Bill passed on 13 December 1944, by the New Zealand House of Representatives, authorised (Sec. 8) the Minister of Finance to acquire shares in co-operative dairies. 3 Cf. Käthe P I C K : "Les entreprises communautaires autrichiennes", in Annales de la régie directe, 1922 ; and Emmy F R E U N D L I C H : "Collaboration between Co-operative Societies and Municipalities in the Development of Collective Undertakings in Austria", in Annals of Collective Economy, Vol. I l l , 1927, pp. 167, et seq. * Cf. pp. 65-66. s Cf. pp. 20-27. 5 218 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS example of the participation of co-operativës in joint service undertakings. An important place is given to co-operatives on its Council, in which are represented all the bodies interested in and connected with the production of wheat, its industrial processing, and the distribution and consumption of wheat products. Out of 51 members, 4 represent the State (the Ministries of Agriculture, Finance, National Economy and the Interior), 18 represent the agricultural co-operatives and 3 the consumers' co-operatives. In addition, as in the case of the Czechoslovak Grain Company, and the Syndicate for the Marketing of Cattle and Animal Products, the whole cooperative network (credit co-operatives, wheat-marketing co-operatives, etc.) forms the basis of the system for carrying out the operations of finance and crop collection. In French Morocco, the Moroccan Inter-Occupational Wheat Office has similar functions, though they are restricted to an import monopoly; its Council of 33 members includes 4 representatives of agricultural co-operatives engaged in the storage of wheat. Futura and the French and Moroccan Wheat Offices are not the only instances that can be given of joint service undertakings in which the State and co-operative organisations participate in the field of the marketing and import or export of agricultural produce. In Yugoslavia, Prizad, which was established in 1930 to organise the marketing of wheat, maize, fruit and opium, to fix prices and allocate export quotas, was a company in which the State held the majority of shares; the remainder were divided among cooperative organisations and private businesses. The export of cattle and meat was organised along similar lines. The case of Rumania merits special attention. The National Co-operative Institute covers the whole co-operative movement, with the exception of the organisations of minority groups. It became one of the chief instruments of the Government's agricultural policy and for this purpose possessed a vast apparatus for distributing the requisites of agricultural production (including machinery) as well as for collecting and marketing farm products. Despite its name, it was mainly a State organisation. From the time of its creation under a special Act (23 June 1938), it was under strict State control and this has probably not been relaxed since. The State holds shares in it to a value of 249,810,000 lei; the co-operatives subscribed a slightly larger amount (256,130,000 lei) and paid up a smaller amount (216,404,544 lei). The State is naturally represented on the governing body and it also exercises control through a commissioner. It seems that in this instance the State has completely absorbed and "officialised" the co-operative societies, which do not seem to have enjoyed their full managerial freedom in recent years or, in cotise- FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 219 quence, to have been as effective as they otherwise might. This example illustrates the danger which may be encountered in collaboration between public authorities and co-operative organisations when this collaboration places on a co-operative movement that is still too weak excessively heavy public responsibilities far removed from its own functions and a t the same time imposes on it a too rapid rhythm of growth. Finally, something should be said of the original and complex structure of two joint service undertakings in the international field: the Russo-British Grain Company and Ratao. The former was established in 1923 to purchase wheat in bond in Russian ports or in cargo and to market it in Great Britain, France and South European countries. On the Russian side it consisted of State organisations (Commissariat for Foreign Trade, its London agency Arcos, and the State Bank) together with Centrosoyus, the central organisation of the consumers' co-operatives, Selskosoyus, the central organisation of the agricultural co-operatives, and Vsekobank, the Russian co-operative bank. Great Britain was represented by the English Co-operative Wholesale Society (one half share), and two shipping and brokerage firms (one half share). Ratao (Russisch-Osterreichische Handels A.G.), which was also set up shortly after the First World War, comprised the consumers' coope'rative wholesale society and a private firm on the Austrian side and Centrosoyus and the State on the side of the U.S.S.R. This long and varied enumeration yields some useful findings. Its size is itself enlightening. It shows, first, t h a t the instances of collaboration between the "public sector" and the "co-operative sector" are far from exceptional, but, on the contrary, may be found wherever the co-operative movement has developed far enough in some fields. This list, incomplete as it is, contains examples drawn from some 40 countries. Secondly, it stresses the important place the co-operative movement has gained for itself during the last 25 years in a large number of national economies, and, consequently, suggests the potential role of the movement in the task of post-war reconstruction. The examples given are not all of equal significance or of equal informative value. Some deal with structures and working methods, which for practical purposes should be analysed in detail but have only been touched upon. Others raise the question of "compulsory co-operation" on which co-operators are not yet entirely agreed and which can perhaps only be solved by a consideration of specific cases. Finally, co-operative collaboration in an action of a public nature is seen to involve limitations and to presuppose certain conditions. But, subject to these reservations, the general finding * 1 5 220 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS must be that the combination of co-operative action with that of the public authorities has been achieved in pursuance of convergent aims and without prejudice to the free development and, working of the co-operative institutions. That is naturally so as regards modes of consultation and representation. In the committees and offices in which they are represented, as with the departments of State consulting them, cooperative organisations are invited to exert their influence in regard to an action of a public nature which directly or indirectly concerns them by virtue of their functions, but is generally an extension of their own sphere of activity. On the one hand, they have the opportunity of putting forward their own rights and interests, but within the framework of the interest of the community as a whole; and, on the other, they also freely give the advice which their experience and special knowledge suggest to them, and the usefulness of this advice lies precisely in the fact that it is independent. When co-operative organisations are called upon to exercise functions of public interest, whether by mandate or delegation, or in association with other private or administrative bodies, these functions are, and should be, within the field of their competence and experience or, at most, an extension of their normal activities. Though they thereby cease, to some extent, to be at the exclusive service of their members, they nevertheless remain under the members' control; in addition, they continue to exercise, in accordance with co-operative methods, the functions delegated to them by their members. As Edgard Milhaud puts it: "They keep their whole character and all their prerogatives as co-operative societies. They work and act in full co-operative freedom—and therefore with full co-operative responsibility—but have their place in a system of economic activity within which they exercise their cooperative function—implying precisely their total co-operative independence." 1 What finally emerges from this enumeration is the great diversity of the examples presented. Diversity of the geographical, economic, social and political circumstances in which the formulae of collaboration originate and develop; diversity of the fields in which collaboration has been achieved: production and domestic and foreign marketing, distribution, credit, supply of electric power, insurance, housing, health, etc.; diversity in the formulae adopted in the course of this collaboration—a diversity apparent despite the effort made to group them under a few headings. Some of the formulae are simple, others complex, embodying, as the case may be, limited 1 Edgard MILHAUD, op. cit., p. 44. FORMS OF THE CO-OPERATIVE CONTRIBUTION 221 or extensive powers and very different forms of articulating public intervention with co-operative action. This manifold and almost universal development can hardly have failed to impress itself on thosewho have had occasion to observe it. It is perhaps not without interest to consider it in connection with plans being made for the immediate and more distant future, where there is a general tendency towards increased intervention by the public authorities in economic organisation. If it takes place in a democratic framework, such intervention will meet with its own particular problems and will have to seek its appropriate forms and means. It is probable that, either from the beginning or as the result of experience, it will be seen that its effectiveness gradually decreases as the impetus given or the restraint imposed at the centre makes its way down to the sphere of individual needs and wills. In this event the vast wealth of formulae provided by recent or current experiments can be drawn upon to help the inventive and constructive effort made to find in the co-operative organisations and other people's institutions "a series of relays between the directive centres of the economy and the depths of social life". 5 CONCLUSION In examining some of the problems of rehabilitation and reconstruction, this Itudy has reviewed a large number of the various forms of co-operative. This survey, reinforced by a knowledge of the principles and methods of co-operation, provides an answer to the question how far and by what means co-operative organisations can contribute to the post-war rehabilitation and reconstruction effort. Several features stand out clearly from the survey. First, there are the great diversity and elasticity of co-operative institutions as regards form, functions and problems dealt with, while observing the same principles,ethics and methods. Second, there is the fact that they have penetrated,in some cases far,in others little,and,recently, into numerous branches of economic and social life. Equally outstanding are the large and ever growing number of people whom they embrace and the service that they render to workers of all categories in every country and climate. Lastly, there are their almost unlimited possibilities of growth, in function no less than in membership. Their service to the low-income social groups in the rehabilitation period is the same that they render them in normal times, for the people in these groups are habitually engaged in a permanent effort of liberation and rehabilitation, an effort simply made greater and more necessary by the post-war situation. Using the concrete information available, the foregoing pages have sought to give an idea of the nature and worth of the cooperative contribution. They have also tried to reflect the idea which the thinkers and leaders of the co-operative movement themselves have of the action in which they share, since ideas, if based on facts, illuminate them. But in these final remarks it may be pointed out that it is not only the fully authorised representatives of the co-operative movement who have appraised the value of the co-operative contribution t o the rehabilitation effort. It would be difficult to improve on the following concise definition of this contribution by one not directly connected with the co-operative movement, though a close observer of it 1 : "Reduction of prices to the consumer, increase of prices to the producer, democratic management of industry, education in self-help, in the capacity for com1 Rev. John A. RYAN, quoted in Annals of Collective Economy (Geneva), May-Aug. 1939, p. 337. CONCLUSION 223 munity action, and in the ability to manage business, are all within the reach oi the masses, both in the country and in the city, if they are willing to use the methods that have been tested and approved in the co-operative movement." Co-operative institutions, besides providing the community with new methods of distributing goods and incomes and a system of channelling credit and means of production down to the humblest producer, also provide means of spreading technical progress, formulae for organising work and production, elements of order and equilibrium, and foundations for economic and social democracy. That their principles and activities are in accord with and even in advance of present-day demands is attested by another figure active in public life, but outside the co-operative movement 1 : "Cooperatives are definitely anti-authoritarian. They help in the redistribution of income. They are not afraid of better wages, not afraid of social security, not afraid of democracy. They are a people's movement. They have a great opportunity in the exciting and exhilarating days to come." 2 That the co-operative movement is fairly generally regarded as an instrument standing ready-made and well adapted for immediate use in the work of rehabilitation is confirmed by the declarations and programmes coming from quarters which have been in a position to acquire an acute sense of the necessities and conditions of rehabilitation and post-war restoration: resistance groups, and former and new Governments of countries which have been overrun, as, for instance, in Czechoslovakia, France, Poland, and Yugoslavia. In Italy, too, there have been spontaneous efforts, encouraged by the authorities, in Sicily and at Rome, Leghorn and other places, to establish consumers' co-operativcs, as well as plans for the restoration of thé agricultural co-operative movement. But though there is now fairly full agreement on the nature and potential value of the co-operative contribution, only the future can show its possible extent. This future depends on men: it depends on those who build and can build the co-operative movement; outside co-operative institutions, it depends on the structures, and on the legislative and institutional environment of such institutions, which can help or impede their development and action. The building of the co-operative movement is primarily the responsibility of co-operators, and depends on the zeal with which they exercise their rights and fulfil their obligations. But as it is a voluntary movement, whose action is not the subjept of decree, its 1 Mr. Leon HENDERSON, formerly head of the Office of Price Administration in the United States, speaking a t the 1944 Congress of t h e Cooperative League of the U.S.A. in Chicago. 8 As reported in The Cooperative Builder, 26 Oct. 1944. 5 4 1 * 224 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS development and influence also concern those who will decide to give or not to give it new strength. Because it is continuously growing, it can be a permanent and vigorous constructive force. But such growth is not predetermined and automatic. To quote Father John A. Ryan once again, its advantages "cannot be achieved in a day nor in a year, nor by governmental subsidies, nor through any easy formula or recipe. They must necessarily come about gradually and through the action of men and women who are willing to exercise patience and make the sacrifices which are indispensable to any important or lasting reform of industrial conditions." 1 Though co-operative action is not a matter of enactment, its spread is none the less partly dependent on external circumstances and, in particular, on the attitude of the legislator and those in charge of public affairs. In an economy still hedged around by restrictions, rationing and priorities, regulations and controls, and one from which the power of large concentrations of capital will not have disappeared, the contribution of co-operative institutions to the task of relief, rehabilitation and reconstruction will depend not only on their immediate possibilities or on the potentialities contained in them. It will also depend on the extent to which these possibilities and potentialities and the original character of such institutions in the economic and social world are grasped by public opinion, by the representatives of t h a t opinion, and by those with the direct responsibility for establishing, adjusting and executing reconstruction plans. In the countries where the co-operative movement has lost part of its means of action, a priority will be given to the appropriate measures for restoring it, if the conviction is strong that its restoration will forward rehabilitation at large. Similarly, in all countries the development and activity of the co-operative movement will be regarded with public favour, disfavour or indifference according as it is or is not clearly recognised that such development and activity harmonise with the general direction, possibilities and necessities of the reconstruction effort. Only where it is recognised that they do, will the legislative and other legal obstacles that still sometimes stand in the way of co-operative activities be removed and the teaching of co-operation be enlarged and encouraged. It is only in such cases that co-operative institutions, the industrial organisations of labour and management, the technicians and other qualified bodies will be directly and variously associated with the work of restoration in such a way as not to be distorted or emasculated by such association, but able fully to deploy their action for the common good. 1 Loc. cit., p. 337. ÍNDEX 5 INDEX The index which follows is almost exclusively one of countries and of types of co-operative organisation. It includes no names of persons, books or individual organisations (with the exception of international co-operative organisations and institutions and some other organisations of a special type). Its purpose is to help the reader to find the main references in the text to the many types of co-operative organisation and to the numerous countries concerned. It has been decided to include in this index references to the earlier study in the series, Co-operative Organisations and Post-War Relief. References to the first study are preceded by a Roman numeral I; those to the present work by a Roman numeral II. Agricultural co-operative societies with distributive activities, I . 98-99, 111, 112 Agricultural or rural co-operative organisations, I. 38, 39, 58-82, 90, 95, 98-99, 103, 106-107, 108, 111, 112, 116-135, 138-142; I I . 7-47, 59, 60, 61, 64-67, 78-100, 104, 124-136, 142, 145, !52, 153, 154, 156, 158, 159, 161, 162, 163, 167, 191, 198, 199, 200, 209, 212, 213, 214, 217, 218, 219, 223 Alaska I. 121 Algeria, l". 63, 66, 124, 126, 127, 132; I I . 24, 49 Allotment societies, I . 72; I I . 124, 125, 127 Antigua, I. 129 Argentina, I. 17, 25, 26, 28, 50, 66, 79, 113, 117, 118, 119, 122, 123, 126, 131, 132, 134, 138, 139, 141, 149, 150; I I . 64, 67, 70, 180, 201, 217 Australia, I. 7, 23, 30, 31, 57, 64, 1 loi n , 118, 119, 122, 124, 125, 126, 127, 129, 132, 133, 134, 136, 138, 139, 140, 141; I I . 58, 134, 198, 199, 200, 201, 212-213 Austria, I. 16, 17, 24, 25, 41, 51, 57, 95, 97, 99, 105, 106, 108, 111, 143, 149, 151, 164; I I . 19, 39, 47, 65. 83, 90, 116, 138, 163, 210, 214, 217, 219 Barbados, I. 129 Belgium, I. 7, 24, 28. 30, 31, 41, 48, 73, 81, 82, 95, 97, 99, 100, 101, 103, 104, 105, 106, 107, 115, 136, 137, 138, 142, 143, 149, 164; I I . 7, 18, 19, 34, 35, 37, 47, 49, 53, 58, 62. 67, 91, 92, 116, 118, 151, 153, 157, 212 Better living societies, I. 80 Brazil, I. 17, 28, 66, 77, 113, 118, 120, 121, 123, 124, 126, 127, 129, 130, 131, 132, 134, 142; I I . 50, 51, 180, 213 British co-operative electric bulb factory (Luma), I . 7 British Honduras, I . 129 British West Africa, I . 130, 136 Building (or building and loan) societies, I. 53-54; I I . 71, 72, 73 Bulgaria, 1. 7, 17, 23, 24, 25, 28, 30, 42, 48, 53, 55, 62, 63, 69, 74, 76, 77, 82, 97, 98, 99, 100, 101, 104, 107, 112, 142, 143, 149; I I . 18, 19, 20, 21, 24, 28, 29, 33, 35, 40, 41, 43, 44, 45, 47, 57, 58, 60, 65, 83, 114, 115, 116, 134, 153, 178, 217 Bulgarian co-operative rubber factory, I. 7 Cameroons (British), I. 130 Cameroons (French), I . 28 Canada, I . 11, 13, 24, 28, 30, 31, 55, 58, 63, 67, 68, 75, 77, 79, 81. 82, 112, 117, 119-120, 120-121, 122, 123, 125, 128, 129, 132, 133, 134, 136, 137, 138, 139, 140, 141, 142, 149; I I . 15, 17, 50, 54-55, 59, 60, 61, 127, 135, 147, 151, 153, 159, 163, 181, 190. 191, 192, 199, 202, 205, 209, 213 5 228 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS Ceylon, I. 15, 114, 130. 131, 132, 136. 137; II. 205, 211 Chile, I. 113; II. 180 China, 1. 12, 63, 80, 92, 93, 113, 132, 136, 143, 150; II. 105, 113 Colombia, I. 26, 113, 126; II. 62, 180, 198 Consumers' co-operative organisations, I. 13, 38, 39, 40-49, 89, 95, 97-98, 99, 102, 103, 104-106, 109, 110, H I , 112, 113, 128, 135, 136, 137, 138144; II. 1, 10, 12, 17, 23, 31, 46. 47, 48, 53, 54, 57-58, 61, 70, 72, 73. 78, 79, 80, 83, 85, 86, 87, 88, 90, 91, 93, 97-98, 99, 108, 116, 136, 137-139 142, 143, 144, 145-147, 149-151, 152, 153, 154, 156, 157, 158, 159, 160, 161, 165-167. 185, 198, 200, 210, 211, 217 economic activities of, I. 42-46; II. 12, 47, 158 personnel of, I. 103-104; I I . 137, 139, 149-151 social strata served by, I. 41-42 stores, number of, I. 102-103 Consumers' co-operative organisations (rural), I. 69, 94, 97-99, 108; II. 10, 12, 28, 32, 34, 46, 86 Co-operative banks of the consumers' movement, I. 46-47 Co-operative dairies, I. 64-65, 115, 122-123, 134, 139-140, 141-142, 167171; II. 32, 36-39, 83, 84, 85, 86, 87, 88, 90-91, 93, 159, 200, 212, 214 Co-operative distilleries, II. 41, 43-44, 215 Co-operative hospitals, I. 101; II. 153 Co-operatives for joint cultivation, I. 73; II. 125, 127, 129-136 Co-operative lockers, II. 159 Co-operative marketing, I. 59, 60, 62, 63-71, 90, 99, 112, 114, 116-135, 138142; II. 9, 17, 27-47, 78, 79, 80, 83, S4, 85, 86, 87, 88-92, 93, 97, 128, 145, 156, 159, 212, 213, 214 specialised marketing co-operative organisations, I. 59, 60, 63-68, 116-134, 137-142, 167-171; IF. 9, 28, 30-47, 83. 84, 85, 86, 87, 88. 89-92,93,97, 159, 200, 201, 212, 213,214 cacao, I. 130 cereals, I. 67, 116-118, 138-139; II. 30-32, 89, 212, 214, 218 coffee, I. 130-131 copra and palm-oil, I. 128 dairv produce, I. 64-65, 115, 122123, 134, 139, 140, 142, 167-171; II. 32, 36-39, 83, 84, 85, 86, 87, 88, 90-91, 93, 159, 200, 212,214 eggs and poultry, I. 67-68, 121. 122, 139;II. 30,34-35, 87, 90,200 fibres, I. 132-134; II. 44-45, 209 fish and shellfish, I. 120-121 fruit and vegetables, I. 66, 123128, 140; II. 40-44, 87, 91-92, 201, 214; (apples, I. 124-125; bananas, I. 126-127; citrus fruit, I. 123-124, 140; II. 92; dried fruit, I. 125, 126, 127, 140; II. 41, 42, 92; grapes, I. 125-126; II. 43; nuts and almonds, I. 127; II. 41, 43; pears, I. 124-125; vegetables, I. 128) honey, I. 129; II. 44, 45 livestock, bacon and meat, I. 65, 119-120, 139; II. 30, 32-34, 159, 200, 214 maté, I. 131; II. 213 olive oil, II. 44 sugar, I. 129; II. 44 tea, I. 131 tobacco, I. 131-132, 141; II. 44, 45 wheat, I. 67, 138-139; II. 30-32, 89, 200, 212, 218 wine and grapes, I. 65-66, 125126; II. 43 purchase and sale co-operative societies (non-specialised), I. 68-71, 112, 134; II. 12, 29, 30, 31, 32,34 rural credit co-operative societies, marketing activities of, I. 62, 130; II. 28 Co-operative petroleum associations, I. 79, 137; II. 58-59 Co-operative research, I. 26 Co-operative restaurants, I. 100 Co-operative society: definition of, I. 4-5 functioning of, II. 165-167 Co-operative societies: consolidation of credit, for, I. 73 general statistics of, I. 37-40; II. 179 geographical distribution of (tables), I. 39, 41, 49, 54, 56, 59, 64, 65, 66, 70, 78, 82 land improvement, for, I. 73; II. 127 Co-operative study circles, I. 30-32; II. 110, 152, 208 Costa Rica, I. 113, 126 Credit co-operative societies (rural), I. 13, 59, 60, 61-63, 99, 107, 112, 130; II. 9, 18-27, 28, 60, 61, 87, 125, 127, 142, 153, 162, 209, 213, 217, 218 Credit co-operative societies (urban), I. 13, 54-55; II. 73, 78, 115, 116, 159, 163, 217 Cuba, I. 28, 129; II. 180 Cyprus, I. 66; II. 125. 211, 213 Czechoslovakia, I. 7, 17, 23, 24, 25, 28, 30, 41, 42, 44, 46, 51, 55, 57, 62, 64, 65, 67, 68, 69, 70, 72, 76, 78. 95, 97, 99, 103, 104, 106, 107, 108, 109, 111, 115, 138, 143, 149, 151, 164; II. 12, 14, 18, 19, 21, 31, 32, 33, 36, 39, 40, 41, 43, 44, 45, 47, 57, 64, 65, 70, 84, 91, 105, 109, 116, 125. 138, 152, 153, 179, 199, 212, 215, 217, 218, 223 INDEX Danish Co-operative Bacon Trading Company, I. 16; II. 89, 92, 94. Danzig, II. 19, 33, 40 Definition of co-operative society, I. 4-5 Denmark, I. 7, 11, 12, 16, 22, 24, 28, 31, 42, 45, 47, 48, 63, 64, 65, 68, 71, 81, 92, 95, 97, 98, 99, 100, 101, 103, 104, 106, 107, 108, 109, 111, 115, 137, 138, 139, 142, 143, 149, 172; II. 7, 8, 9, 11, 12, 15, 17, 19, 33, 34, 35, 36, 37, 38, 39, 47, 49, 56, 58, 64, 72, 84, 89, 90, 91, 109, 147, 153, 157, 200 Dentists' co-operative societies, I. 100 Ecuador, I. 118, 130; II. 180, 210 Egypt, I. 113, 132, 134; II. 204 Eire, see Ireland Ejidos, I. 74; II. 135 Electricity co-operative societies, I. 77-79; II. 64-67, 152, 209, 217 El Salvador, I. 130 Estonia, I. 7, 12, 42, 64, 68, 69, 71, 99, 107, 137, 142, 143, 149, 164; II. 9, 11, 15, 18, 19, 33, 35, 37, 39, 40, 43, 45, 47, 49, 53, 57, 58, 65, 84, 90, 91, 214 Finland, I. 7, 12, 22, 23, 24, 25, 26, 30, 42, 45, 46, 47, 49, 63, 64, 65, 68, 69, 71, 72, 76, 77, 81, 88, 97, 99, 100, 101, 103, 104, 106, 107, 137, 142, 143, 149, 164; II. 9, 10, 11, 12, 15, 16, 19, 24-25, 31, 33, 35, 36, 39, 47, 57, 60, 61, 64, 84, 90, 91, 125, 150, 152, 153, 157, 162, 179, 200 Fishermen's co-operative societies, I. 58, 120-121; II. 48-55, 213 Forestry co-operative societies, I. 7677; II. 44, 57-58, 87 France, I. 17, 24, 25, 26, 28, '30, 31, 41, 44, 49, 57, 58, 63, 64, 65, 66, 67, 70, 72, 73, 77, 78, 82, 84, 92, 95, 97, 99, 100, 101, 103, 104, 105, 106, 107, 109, 112, 115, 136, 137, 138, 142, 143, 149, 164; II. 7, 9, 14. 15, 19, 22, 24, 25-27, 31, 32, 37, 38, 40, 41, 43, 44, 45, 47, 49, 51, 53, 58, 62, 64, 747 7 , 8 5 , 9 1 , 9 2 , 9 3 , 109, 112, 116, 117, 118, 120, 121, 143, 147, 150, 151, 152, 153, 177, 178, 179, 198, 200, 202, 204, 205, 209, 210, 217-218, 219, 223 French West Africa, I. 28, 137 Geographical distribution of co-operative societies (tables), I. 39, 41, 49, 54, 56, 59, 64, 65, 66, 70, 76, 78, 82 Germany, I. 17, 23, 24, 25, 41, 44, 51, 53, 54, 55, 56, 61, 62, 63, 64, 65, 66, 68, 69, 70, 71, 77, 78, 81, 84, 92, 95, 97, 98, 99, 101, 105. 106, 107, 108, 229 109, 111, 115, 137, 138, 148, 149; II. 9, 11, 15, 16, 19, 20, 24, 28, 29, 31, 33, 34, 35, 36, 38, 39, 40, 41, 43, 47, 49, 57, 60, 64, 65, 70, 85, 90, 114, 118, 121, 151, 153, 217 Gold Coast, I. 124, 127, 130, 131 Great Britain, I. 6, 7, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 23, 24; 25, 26, 27, 28, 29, 30, 31, 33, 40, 41, 43, 46, 48, 51, 53, 57, 88, 90, 91, 95, 96, 97, 98, 100, 101, 102, 104, 105, 107, 108, 110, 111, 114, 115, 119, 135, 136, 137-138, 139, 140, 141, 143, 149, 164, 167, 171; II. 10, 11, 12, 13, ¡4, 15, 17, 29, 33, 34, 35, 36, 40, 41, 44, 47, 49, 53, 56, 57, 58, 67, 70, 71, 72, 80, 85, 89, 90, 91, 92, 105, 117, 137-139, 143, 144, 147, 149, 150, 151, 152, 153, 157, 158, 161, 190, 192, 199, 202, 205, 219 Greece. I. 25, 63, 65, 67, 85, 99, 107; II. 7, 14, 19, 24, 28, 32, 37, 40, 41, 43, 44, 49, 91, 114, 125, 127, 179, 214 Guadeloupe, I. 12 Handicraftsmen's and small shopkeepers' co-operative societies, I. 56; II. 23, 78, 115, 116 Health co-operative societies, I. 79-80, 100-101, 107; I I . 153, 210 Horace Plunkett Foundation, I. 18, 23, 26, 27 Housing co-operative societies, I. 13, 38, 49-54; II. 70-74, 78, 143, 145, 152, 209 Hungarv, I. 13, 17, 28, 42, 47, 49, 57, 63, 68, 69, 72, 76, 77, 81, 92, 97, 102, 104, 106, 137, 143, 149, 150; II. 10, 15, 19, 24, 31, 32, 33, 36, 37, 38, 39, 40, 42, 43, 45, 47, 62, 65, 86, 90, 92, 116, 117, 125, 151, 153, 157, 210, 214, 217 Iceland, I. 13, 25, 69, 98, 107, 109, 120, 133. 134, 137, 149; II. 29, 33, 38, 44, 45, 49, 86, 199 India, I. 13, 15, 21, 25, 28, 31, 49, 50, 55, 56, 62, 64, 69, 73, 76, 80, 113, 121, 129, 131, 132, 133, 136, 137, 149, 150; II. 51. 60, 113, 134, 153, 179, 204, 211 Insurance co-operative societies (agricultural and rural), I 80-82; II. 161, 162, 209 Insurance co-operative societies (urban), I. 47-49; II. 73, 78, 153, 161, 162 Insurance Committee of the International Co-operative Alliance, I. 8, 49, 148 Inter-co-operative relations, I. 12-19, 137-144; II. 12, 16, 47, 53, 78-100, 156, 167, 197 5 230 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS inter-co-operative action, national committees for, I . 16-18; I I . 99, 203-204 International Committee (or Interco-operative Relations, I . 18-19, 22, 166; I I . 82, 90, 99, 154, 156, 186, 193, 195, 203, 208 joint undertakings, I. 14, 16, 141142, 167-171; I I . 53, 83, 87, 88, 89, 91, 92, 94, 96-98, 219 Danish Co-operative Bacon Trading Company, I. 16; I I . 89, 92, 94 Dairy Union, Geneva, I I . 88, 94 Dairy Union, Malmö, I I . 87, 94 New Zealand Produce Association, I. 16, 141-142, 167-171; I I . 91, 94 Ratao, I. 16; I I . 219 Russo-British Grain Export Company, I . 16; I I . 89, 94, 219 Swedish Co-operative Fish Marketing Society, I. 14; I I . 53, 88, 94 International Confederation of Agriculture, I. 18, 23, 26, 166; I I . 92, 99, 186 International Co-operative Agr icultural Purchasing Society {Intercoop), I. 7; I I . 18, 59 International Co-operative Alliance, I . 7-8, 17, 18, 23, 26, 46-47, 89, 96, 147-163, 166; I I . 98, 99, 158, 186 International Co-operative Banking Committee, I . 8, 46-47, 148 International Co-operative Trading Agency, I . 8, 143, 148, 164-J65; I I . 59, 92 Internationa! co-operative trading and manufacturing association, I . 143144; I I . 60, 100 International Co-operative Wholesale Society, I . 8, 137, 142; I I . 59, 91, 92 International Co-operative Women's Guild, I . 30, 102; I I . 157 International Institute of Co-operative Studies, I . 26 Iran, l l . 24 Ireland, I . 29, 76, 97, 98, 99, 104, 107, 142; I I . 17, 19, 20, 36, 39, 57, 58, 89, 9 0 , 9 1 , 201, 210 Italy, I. 13, 51, 57, 58, 64, 65, 66, 67, 70, 73, 77, 82, 97, 99, 101, 105, 107, 115, 137, 138, 148, 149, 151; I I . 19, 37, 40, 42, 43, 44, 45, 49, 62, 64, 90, 92, 109, 110, 116, 117, 118, 121, 130, 153, 223 Jamaica, I. 25, 126, 128 Japan, I. 13, 23, 25, 59, 63, 70, 80, 134, 149; I I . 24, 113, 134, 153, 212 J a v a , I . 129, 142 Joint cultivation, co-operatives for, I. 73; I I . 125, 127, 129-136 Kenya, I. 7, 131 Kolkhozy, I . 59, 74-75; I I . 125, 131132 Kooperativa Lumaförbundet, I . 7; I I . 59 Kvutzoth, I. 73; I I . 132-134 Labour contracting co-operative societies, I . 57-58; I I . 61, 62, 109-112, 149, 167, 216 Land improvement co-operative societies, I. 73; I I . 127 Land leasing societies, I . 72; I I . 125, 127 Latvia, I. 13, 24, 28, 42, 64, 65, 69, 71, 97, 98, 103, 105, 107, 137, 143, 149; I I . 9, 11, IS, 16, 19, 33, 35, 36, 38, 39, 40, 43, 45, 47, 49, 53, 57, 65, 86, 9 0 , 9 1 , 116, 178,214 Lithuania, I . 13, 24, 28, 42, 57, 64, 65, 69, 71, 95, 99, 103, 107, 137, 143, 149; I I . 9, 11, 15, 16, 17, 19, 2 4 , 3 1 , 33, 37, 39, 40, 42 .45, 47, 57, 86, 91, 116,178,214 Luxembourg, I. 71, 73, 99, 107; I I . 9, 16, 19, 33, 37, 38, 39, 40, 42, 43, 86, 178, 200, 212 Madagascar, I. 63; I I . 24 Malay States, Federated, I I . 205 Marketing co-operative organisations, see Co-operative marketing Mexico, I . 26, 28, 57, 58, 63, 74, 113, 121; I I . 50, 51, 62, 135, 180, 190, 192 Morocco, I . 63, 75, 77; I I . 49, 92, 218 Netherlands, I. 7, 17, 23, 25, 31, 41, 49, 51, 62, 64, 65, 66, 68, 70, 81, 95, 97, 99, 101, 103, 104, 105, 106, 107. I l l , 112, 129, 136, 137, 143, 149, 164, 173; I I . 7, 9, 11, 12, 15, 17, 18, 19, 20, 33, 34, 35, 36, 38, 39, 40, 42, 43, 44, 47, 56, 58, 72. 87, 90, 91, 92, 116. 138, 153, 157 Netherlands Indies, I. 13, 58 Newfoundland, I . 31, 58, 112, 121; I I . 50, 51 New Zealand, I. 7, 15, 16, 30, 57, 64, 119, 122, 125, 129, 134, 136, 138, 139, 140, 141-142, 150, 167-171; II. 91, 105, 110, 212 New Zealand Produce Association, I. 16, 141-142; 167-171; I I . 91 Nigeria, I. 21, 128, 130 Nordisk Andelsforbund, I . 7, 142; II. 59 Norway, I. 7, 22, 25, 30, 42, 45, 49, 70, 76, 88, 95, 97, 98, 103, 104, 106, 107, I I I , 112, 142, 143, 149; I I . 7, 11,33, 34, 36, 38, 39, 40, 42, 43, 47, 49, 58, 60, 87, 113, 150, 200, 214 Nyasaland, I. 131 INDEX Occupational (other than agricultural) co-operative societies, I . 38, 54-58,. 120-121; I I . 23, 48-55, 56-57, 61, 62, 73, 78, 104, 105-108, 109-112, 115, 116-117, 120, 129, 142, 149, 153, 159, 163,213,217 Overseas Farmers' Co-operative Federations Limited, I. 7, 125, 140, 141, 142; I I . 213 Palestine, I. 17, 49, 50, 57, 66, 73, 77, 92, 124, 126, 127, 134, 138, 140, 141, 143, 149, 164; I I . 62, 92, 109, 110, 125, 130, 132-135 Pasture co-operative societies, I I . 12 Peat co-operative societies, I I . 57, 210 Peru, 1.26, 113; I I . 135, 180 Petroleum co-operative associations, I . 79, 137; I I . 58-59 Pharmaceutical co-operative societies, I. 100, 101; I I . 153 Philippines, I I . 213 Poland, I. 14, 25, 26, 28, 30, 31, 42, 51, 55, 62, 63, 64, 65, 68, 69, ,70, 72, 80, 92, 95, 97, 99, 100, 103, 105, 107, 115,143, 149, 164; I I . 14,19,21,24, 29, 31, 33, 35, 37, 39, 46, 47, 65, 90, 105, 115,125, 127, 153, 157, 178, 179, 200, 223 Portugal, I. 85, 97, 105, 106, Public co-operatives, I I . 61-62 Publishing and bookselling co-operative societies, I. 24 Puerto Rico, I. 28 Ralao, I. 16; I I . 219 Research, co-operative, I. 26 Restaurants, co-operative, I. 100 Rhodesia (North and South), I. 7, 118, 131, 132 Rumania, I. 13, 25, 30, 55, 63, 72, 76, 95, 97, 99, 105, 107, 115, 149; I I . 19, 21, 24, 31, 32, 37, 40, 42, 43, 44, 57, 87, 114, 125,218 Russo- British Grain Export Company, I . 16; I I . 89, 94, 219 St. Kitts, I . 129 St. Lucia, I . 124 Sakhalin, I. 58 Salvador, El, I . 130 Scandinavian Co-operative Wholesale Society (Nordisk Andelsforbund), I . 7, 142; I I . 59 School co-operative societies, I. 27-28; I I . 178, 179 Self-help co-operative societies, I I . 105108 Sierra Leone, I. 118 Social services of co-operative societies, I . 101-102, 109; I I . 150, 152, 161 Spain, I. 17, 25, 28, 57, 58, 85, 95, 97, 105, 143, 149, 151; I I . 44, 50, 54, 64, 153 231 Statistics, general, of co-operative societies, I . 37-40; I I . 179 Study circles, co-operative, I. 30-32; I I . 110, 152, 208 Supply co-operative societies (rural), I . 68-72, 103, 111, 112; I I . 7, 8, 9-18, 27, 59, 78, 87, 142, 151, 159, 167 purchase and sale co-operative societies (non specialised), I. 68-71, 112, 134; I I . 9, 11, 12, 28, 29, 30, 31, 40, 198 rural supply co-operative societies (specialised), I . 71-72; I I . 7, 8, 9, 10-18, 30 farm implement and machinery, I I . 9, 13-16, 127 feeding stuff, I I . 7, 8, 9, 10-12 fertiliser, I I . 7, 8, 9, 10-12 livestock, I I . 16 seed, I I . 12-13 Sweden, I . 7, 13, 14, 17, 22, 23, 24, 25, 26, 27, 28, 30, 3 1 , 32, 41, 42, 43, 46, 47, 48, 51, 52, 65, 67, 68, 69, 71, 76* 78, 81, 88, 90, 96, 97, 98, 100, 101, 103, 104, 106, 107, 110, 111, 112, 115, 142, 143, 149, 164; I I . 9, 12, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20, 29, 31, 33, 34, 35, 36, 38, 39, 40, 42, 44, 45, 47, 48, 49, 50, 53, 57, 58, 64, 65, 66, 71, 72, 87, 91, 94, 114, 116, 122, 138, 145-147,150, 151, 152, 153, 157, 158, 162, 190, 191, 192, 199,201,202, 209, 212 Switzerland, I . 14, 17, 21, 23, 24, 25, 26, 30, 31, 4 1 , 43, 46, 49, 51, 53, 62, 64, 66, 68, 69, 71, 73, 76, 77, 78, 82, 96, 97, 98, 100, 101, 103, 104, 106, 107, 109, 111, 112, 115, 138, 143, 149, 164; I I . 9, 10, 12, 15, 16, 17, 19, 20, 29, 30, 33, 36, 38, 39, 40, 42, 43, 44, 47, 56, 57, 60, 64, 67, 70, 88, 90, 92, 94, 109, 116, 118, 138, 143, 147, 150, 151, 152, 153, 157, 158, 162, 163, 190, 191, 199, 201, 202, 208, 212, 214 Vanganyika, I . 131, 132 Telephone co-operatives, I . 77; I I . 60, 127, 152, 209 Tenants' co-operative societies, I . 5052- I I . 72 Tobago, I . 124, 128, 130 Transport co-operative societies, I . 77; I I . 61-63 Trinidad, I . 124, 128, 130 Tunisia, I . 127 Turkey, I . 63, 76, 97, 105, 140; I I . 19, 20, 24, 40, 42, 43, 44, 45, 92, 179,211 Union of South Africa, I . 7, 28, 66, 113, 118, 123, 124, 125, 127, 129, 132, 133, 134, 138, 140, 149, 150; I I . 24, 215. United States, 1.15, 24, 25, 26, 27, 28, 31, 32, 42, 45, 49, 50, 54, 55, 58, 63, 64, 65, 66, 68, 69, 70, 72, 77, 78, 79, 82, 86, 87, 88, 96, 112-113, 117-118, 5 232 CO-OPERATION AND PRESENT-DAY PROBLEMS 120, 121, 122, 123, 124, 124-125, 126, 127, 128, 129, 131-132, 133, 134, 136, 137, 138, 139, 140, 141, 142, 143, 149, 150; I I . 15, 16, 17, 50, 51, 57, 58, 59, 60, 65, 66, 67, 105-108, 125, 135, 140, 143, 147, 153, 157, 158, 159, 162, 163, 180, 181, 184, 190, 191, 192, 199, 200, 201, 202, 209, 215 U.S.S.R., I. 16, 25, 28, 30, 41, 57, 58, 74, 75, 76, 77, 84, 92, 95, 108, 114, 143, 148, 149, 151; II. 10, 50, 57, 58, 89,90, 105, 114, 117, 118, 120, 125, 130,131-132 Uruguay, 1.26, 113 Venezuela, I. 26, 28, 113; I I . 180 Vine growers' co-operatives, I. 66, 125126; I I . 40, 43, 85 Water-supply co-operatives, I. 77; I I . 60, 127 West Indies, French (Guadeloupe), I . 149 Women's co-operative guilds, I. 28-30, 102 Workers' productive societies, I. 56-57; II. 57, 61, 62, 78, 105-108, 109-112, 116-117, 120, 129, 142, 149, 153 Chinese industrial co-operatives, I. 1 4 3 ; I I . 105 self-help co-operative societies, II. 105-108 Yugoslavia, I. 13, 17, 23, 27, 28, 42, 55, 58, 62, 63, 65, 67, 70, 71, 72, 79, 80, 84, 92, 95, 97, 99, 100, 101, 105, 107, 115, 149, 151; II. 9, 14, 15, 19,21,30, 31, 33, 37, 38, 40, 42, 43, 45, 47, 50, 51, 65, 92, 114, 116, 117, 118, 120, 125, 134, 153, 210, 218, 223 Youth education, I. 27-28; II. 171