INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE STUDIES AND REPORTS Series C (Unemployment) No. 8 UNEMPLOYMENT 1920=1923 GENEVA 1924 PRINTED BY ALBERT KUNDIG, GENEVA. CONTENTS Pages INTRODUCTION. 5 PART I. — THE OUTBREAK AND DEVELOPMENT OF THE CRISIS. 7 Chapter I. — The United States and Japan. Chapter II. — The British Empire. Chapter III. — Scandinavia, Finland, the Netherlands and Switzerland. Chapter IV. — Italy, France and Belgium. Chapter V. — Central Europe. Chapter VI. — General Survey. 9 18 PART II. — THE PERIOD OF RECOVERY. Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter Chapter PART III. I. — The United States, France, Belgium and Italy. II. — Central Europe. III. — Switzerland, Scandinavia, Finland and the Netherlands. IV. — The British Empire. V. — General Survey. 31 42 50 68 73 74 89 93 103 131 — CONCLUSIONS. Fluctuations of Prices and Unemployment, 1920 to 1923. The Movement of Prices and the Trade Cycle. The Relationship between the Unemployment Crisis of 1920-1923 and the General Trade Cycle. The Stabilisation of Prices. 135 135 142 144 INTRODUCTION The present study has been undertaken in pursuance of the resolutions on unemployment adopted by the International Labour Conference at its Sessions of 1921 and 1922. A report on the general enquiry into unemployment is published as an Appendix to the Report of the Director to the 1924 Session of the Conference; it describes how the Office has carried out the various instructions of the Conference in respect of the enquiry, either in the course of its normal activities or in co-operatfon with the Economic and Financial Section of the League of Nations. The present report deals more particularly with the origin, development and abatement of the crisis of unemployment from which the majority of industrial countries suffered during the years 1920 to 1923. Following the method prescribed by the Conference, the principle has been adopted of examining, first, the situation country by country; then, when this preliminary analysis has been completed, an attempt has been made to draw certain general international deductions. It will be seen that in each country the growth and diminution of unemployment appear to have been influencedr if not exclusively, at least very largely, by the same factors. In order to bring out more clearly this important consideration, from which it has been thought justifiable to draw certain general conclusions, it was felt advisable to examine separately (1) the conditions under which the unemployment crisis originated and developed its maximum severity in the various countries; (2) the conditions under which the crisis subsequently abated, rapidly in some countries, gradually in others. Each of these two series of separate accounts is concluded by an international survey of the general movement of growth or decline. There are certain difficulties confronting the presentation of a comprehensive and detailed report on any social phenomenon which cannot be examined on the spot and for which full information is not available of all the national economic factors which have affected it at different times — a consideration the importance of which is continually emphasised by experience gained in the pursuit of international scientific investigations. The difficulty may, however, be avoided if no pretence is made of examining in detail the phenomenon under consideration, but merely of throwing light on the principal aspects. Such a course has been followed in the present survey, which deliberately refrains from a minute analysis of the situation in each country or from any attempt to deal with minor — 6 — factors influencing a given section of the national market. Such a comprehensive task was impossible with the means available, a circumstance which may, however, yield a certain advantage, in that an abundance of detail would have masked certain general observations which have been deduced. Thus, no consideration has been given to the situation by industries, for instance, attention having been devoted exclusively to showing relationships between general changes in unemployment, as illustrated by the most reliable national statistics, and other important economic factors for which regular statistics were also available \ The chief of these factors have been changes in prices and in foreign trade. In a number of cases fluctuations in the exchanges and the movements of currency and credit have also been considered, for they have an important bearing on the first two factors, and sometimes assist in explaining their variations. In the pursuit of such a course of study the conclusion has been reached that in most countries there is a surprising absence of any general relationship between the national unemployment situation as a whole and changes in the volume of exports, while on the other hand there is a constant and very close relation between unemployment and price fluctuations (certain observations of fact already made in the Enquiry into Production support this conclusion). Finally, it has been observed that there is a close relationship between price fluctuations and the financial and credit policy of the different countries from which the existence of a general relation between such policy and unemployment may be deduced. The scientific character of the study has perhaps suffered to some extent through circumstances which have dictated hasty methods, and in consequence no dogmatic importance is attached to the conclusions, essentially o fa provisional character, developed in the third part of the study. Since, however, they contribute evidence in support of a very marked current of opinion recently developing among economists as the result of the study of the same group of phenomena as examined here, there seems reason to believe that subsequent research will but confirm them. In view of this development of economic science, the conclusions reached are such as to justify a certain spirit of confidence that there is here revealed a true basis upon which measures for preventing periodical crises of unemployment may be developed, and it is in the hope of such action that the suggestions contained in the present study are put forward for further expert examination. 1 As a rule, the figures used have been those published by the League of Nations in the Memorandum on Currency of 1923 or the Monthly Bulletin of Statistics. PAKT 1. The Outbreak and Development of the Crisis. If the phenomenon of unemployment since 1920 be analysed country by country, and the situation in the different countries compared, the first striking fact that emerges is the irregularity in the date of development of the crisis in the different countries. The United States and Japan were affected as from the spring of 1920. Towards the end of the same year Great Britain and her Dominions began to suffer; also the Scandinavian countries, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and, less acutely —- or at least, for a shorter period — Italy, Belgium and, still less severely, France. The Centra] European countries, on the other hand, were not affected until 1922, or even 1923. This more or less chronological order will be followed in the report, for it makes it possible to bring out more clearly the similarity of the general conditions under which the crises originated in each different country, namely, either through the cessation of inflation. followed by a sudden fall in prices, or, in certain instances, through the prolongation of excessive inflation, which itself led to a certain dislocation of trade before the ultimate collapse of the labour market which followed the complete restraint of the inflationary boom. Such conditions were not realised simultaneously in the different countries and, in consequence, the crises appeared at different dates. CHAPTER I UNITED STATES AND JAPAN. UNITED STATES "The number of unemployed in September 1921 was reported by the President's Conference on Unemployment, which held its Session 26 September 1921 in Washington, D.C., as between three and one-half and five and one-half millions, with a much greater number of persons dependent upon them. No attempt was made to estimate the number of their dependents, but on the basis of 30,000,000 employees in a total population of 105,000,000 the number should be between 10,000,000 and 15,000,000" \ This evidence of the Bureau of Labour Statistics is corroborated by that of the enquiry of the Committee of the President's Conference on Unemployment. "The depression of 1921 caused a diminution of approximately one-sixth in the total volume of employment in the United States" 2 . Expressed in terms of wages paid, this meant at one period a decline of 23 per cent., in dollar amounts, as compared with the highest point recorded in the boom3. The incidence of unemployment was very uneven. According to statistics quoted in the Industrial Employment Survey Bulletin, No. 1, Jan. 1921, the industries which suffered worst were the automobile and the building trades, i. e. luxury and capital goods manufacture; whereas the least affected were packing and food products, lumber, house furniture, boxes, etc., i.e., articles for direct use by the consumer. Small employers in general gave more steady employment than did larger employers in the same industry. Certain towns were 1 UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOUR, BUREAU OF LABOUR STA- TISTICS: Industrial Unemployment, p. 1, Bulletin No. 310. 2 Business Cycles and Unemployment, p. 98. McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1923. 3 Ibid., p. 96. — 10 — worse affected than others, probably on account of the specialised character of their industry. For instance, the volume of unemployment as revealed in the statistics of the Manufacturers' Association of Racine is astounding *. r,.ta uale March April June Aug. Oct. Dec. 1920 1921 1921 1921 1921 1921 Number of persons employed (the employment peak) 19,351 (52 per cent, less than the peak] 9,215 (60 » » » 7,785 (67 » » » 6,415 (66 » » » 6,600 (68 » » » 6,192 The more heavily populated districts suffered much worse than the agricultural areas. For instance, the index of employment for New-York shows a decline from 125 in July 1920 to 88 in July 1921 2. The same intensity of unemployment is reflected in the percentages reported by trade unions in the State of Massachusetts from 1919 to 1921: 1919 March June . Sept. Dec. . . . . . . . . 11.4 . . . 2.8 . . . 2.7 . 4.1 1920 March . . . 4.1 June . . . 14.6 Sept. . . . 16.4 Dec 29.2 1921 March June . Sept. . Dec. . . . . . . . . 22.2 . . . 20.6 . . . 20.0 . 25.0 The United States Bureau of Labour Statistics index number shows a growth of employment almost continuous to 108 3 in May and June 1920. The collapse from that point was phenomenal, the lowest point, 74, being reached within eight months, i.e., in January 1921. In this respect the American crisis was like all previous cycles, winding up to the highest pitch of activity, then, almost without warning, plunging into the depth of depression, nearly every industry being taken unawares. In the early months of 1920 demand was still intense and prosperity seemed unending. A period of doubt and tension followed about May and June. By the month of August practically the whole of industry was plunged into depression ; enterprises were drawing in ; orders were cancelled ; 1 UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOUR, CHILDREN'S BUREAU: employment and Child Welfare, p. 8. » Base: July 1914= 100. ' B a s e : Average for 1919 = 100. Un- — 11 — stocks piled up unsaleable. In fact, so extreme was the difficulty of marketing goods that the period became to be known as the "buyers' strike". A crisis of such unprecedented severity has naturally given rise to the most widespread speculation as to its causes. The explanations suggested in different quarters are altogether too numerous, varied, and controversial to receive adequate treatment here. Certain very definite facts become evident, however, from a mere study of statistics. The first point of importance is the close relation which exists between the movement of prices and the volume of unemployment. Mr. William A. Berridge, of Brown University, has published, through the Pollak Foundation for Economic Research, a very comprehensive account of statistical observations of unemployment in the United States 1. From the graphs which he has constructed to show the unemployment situation from 1913 to 1921, the following coincidences between the movement of prices and the growth of unemployment are revealed. • A considerable decline of employment was evident during 1913 and 1914, corresponding with a similar fall in wholesale prices from the high level of 1912. Owing to the war demand, revival was rapid, the price level rising from 101 2 in 1915 to 194 in 1918. Unemployment hardly existed during this period, except during the summer of 1917 when there was a slight fall accompanying a decline in the rate of rise of prices. Immediately after the Armistice there was a period of "hesitation", when, owing to certain inevitable changes from war to peace conditions of production, and perhaps some political uncertainty, a considerable fall in industrial activity was noticed. Unemployment reported in Massachusetts in March 1919 was as heavy as 11.4 per cent. This was accompanied by a break in wholesale prices during the early months of the year. A very rapid rate of recovery is then noticed, both in prices and employment, marking the period of intense boom 1919-1920. From this period onwards, the close relationship which existed between the movement of wholesale prices, of employment, and of production is clearly shown in the following table. 1 2 W. A. BERRIDGE: Cycles of Unemployment. Houghton, Mifflin Co., 1923. Yearly average. Bureau of Labour Statistics, 1913 = 100. — 12 — INDEX NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE PRICES, Oí' EMPLOYMENT, AND OF PRODUCTION FOR 1920 AND 1921. Employment Date Wholesale prices ! 2 U.S. Bureau of New York State Labour StaDept. of Production tistics Labour (12 industr.) (55 industr.) 3 1920 Jan Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 233 232 234 245 247 243 241 231 22fi 211 196 179 107 105 107 108 107 108 105 105 103 101 93 85 108 106 108 108 107 107 107 106 103 102 94 87 115 111 113 104 105 107 104 102 100 96 92 86 1921 Jan Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 170 160 155 148 145 142 141 142 141 142 141 140 79 80 80 77 77 75 76 78 79 81 80 80 82 81 81 81 81 80 78 80 80 82 81 81 81 81 76 74 72 74 73 78 79 80 81 83 1 Bureau of Labour Statistics; monthly average. Base: average for 1913 = 100. In all cases, unless otherwise stated, the statistics of wholesale prices given in this report are reproduced from the League of Nations' Monthly BuUelin of Statistics or Memorandum on Currency, 1913-1922. 2 Monthly average. Base: average for 1919 = 100. Seasonal variation eliminated. Reproduced from Review of Economic Statistics, Harvard, Oct. 1923. 3 Harvard Economic Service, Statistical Record, 1922: Normal = 100. The break in the upward swing of prices and the swift decline from May 1920 was followed immediately by an increase in the volume of unemployment, the collapse of wholesale prices, from 247 in May 1920 to 145 in May 1921, being accompanied by a fall of 27 points in the employment index. Little fluctuation from this low level of employment was observable until the end of 1922, when wholesale prices were again recovering. The above table also yields some evidence that production responds closely to the movement of prices, a rising level being marked by a high rate of output and a falling level accompanying depression. — 13 — With a view to showing the relationship between the unemployment crisis and the international market it would be well to examine the statistics of export and import for the United States during the period under discussion. The value of imports rose from the figure of 147,624,000 dollars in 1914 to 318,974,000 dollars in 1919 and to 425,152,000 dollars in 1920. In the year 1921, when depression was most intense, the value of imports fell to 213,072,000 dollars. It must be remembered in comparing these figures that they do not represent the real value or the physical volume of the merchandise, since the price of the goods fluctuated enormously during the period concerned *. However, even allowing for this factor, there is evidence of considerable swelling during the prosperous years and diminution during the slump. The change in the volume of exports is even more pronounced. From 172,588,000 dollars in 1914 the value of goods exported rose to 673,373,000 dollars in 1920. In 1921 it was again as low as 364,911,000 dollars, a still further decline being noticeable in 1922 «. The monthly movement of exports for the period of the crisis was as follows : Date Exports (in thousands of dollars) 1918 .(month, aver.) 1919 ' » » 1920 » » 503,990 645,818 673,373 1920 J u n e July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 616,155 640,132 570,796 594,538 741,522 666,540 708,531 . . . . Date 1921 J a n Febr.. March April May . June . July . Aug. . Sept. Oct. . Nov. . Dec. . Exports (in thousands of dollars) 642,186 469,567 369,470 330,304 322,449 329,749 318,710 360,626 319,273 337,121 294,437 291,297 This table shows that there was no serious diminution in exports for seven months after the beginning of the depression, a fact 1 The index number of wholesale prices (Bureau of Labour Statistics) rose from 98 in 1914 to 247 in May 1920, whence it fell to 138 in January 1922. 2 Figures quoted from the League of Nations' Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, Dec. 1923, p. 12. In all cases, unless otherwise stated, the figures for foreign trade given in this report have been drawn from the above source. They refer invariably to the special trade of the country concerned, i.e., imports for domestic consumption and exports of domestic produce only, unless indication is given to the contrary. — 14 — which contributes materially to the evidence showing that the American crisis did not owe its origin to the failure of foreign markets. A further important point for consideration is the state of the money market at different stages of the crisis. In the past history of the United States every recorded crisis has been accompanied by severe monetary stringency; in numerous cases the state of affairs in the money-lending organisation has been such as to cause a serious breakdown and financial panic \ The recent crisis, although escaping anything in the nature of a financial collapse, such, for instance, as was experienced in 1907, was marked by the severest monetary stringency. The cause of this stringency was, on the one hand, the decision of the Federal Reserve Board that it was necessary to check the inflationary process which had been taking place since the beginning of the war and was reaching extreme and dangerous limits. In order to put an end to this rapid expansion, the Federal Reserve Board raised its rate of rediscount (i. e. raised the rate at which it would lend to Member Banks and consequently obliged the latter to increase their own rates to customers), in November 1919, to 6 per cent. On the other hand, the rapid rise in prices and costs caused very heavy demands to be made on the banks for loans, and the continous expansion of credit began to threaten the adequacy of bank reserves. This danger was increased by a rapid ebb of gold to Japan and to other countries, where the demand for it became intense owing to the critical situation of the banks 2. In the year 1919, although 40.7 million dollars of gold represented the balance of gold imported from Great Britain, large quantities were exported to British India (34.3 million dollars), Japan (94.1), China (39.1), Hong Kong (30.1) and South American countries (74.1). The drain of gold continued into 1920 so that the reserve situation was rapidly weakened, as seen in the following table 3 : Reserve percentages of the Federal Reserve System, 1920. 23 Jan 44.8 13 Febr 43.2 30 Jan 44.5 20 Febr 42.7 6 Febr 44.1 27 Febr 42.5 1 Cf. Wesley C. MITCHELL: Business Cycles, p. 576. University of California Press, 1913. 2 See later p 17 3 Federal Reserve Bulletin, March 1920, p. 220. — 15 — This double strain on bank reserves obliged the Federal Reserve Banks to raise their Rediscount Rate still further to 7 per cent, in May 1920. The consequent stringency in the money market is considered by many American economists to have been a direct cause of the cessation of feverish activity in 1920 \ In point of fact the diminution in employment began in June 1920, one month after the raising of the Rediscount Rate. In conclusion, it would seem that the unemployment crisis in the United States may not be considered to have originated from some swift change in the foreign market 2 , but rather from other factors, such as the policy of credit restriction, which was responsible for bringing to an end a long period of inflation. It is evident, however, that tbe continuation of the policy of credit expansion would not have prevented, but would merely have delayed, the crisis. Moreover, it appears that an earlier application of the monetary brake, if such had been possible, would have had the salutary effect of preventing or attenuating the boom, of which the depression was the inevitable reaction. JAPAN The situation presented by Japan is remarkable not only because that country was one of the earliest to be affected by the world crisis but also on account of the intensity of the earlier months of depression. In most other countries the maximum unemployment figure was not reached until 1921, but in Japan the situation was apparently worst in August 1920, some slight improvement being noted during the following month. Evidence of this is to be found in the following figures of discharges and engagements published in the Osaka Mainichi of 24 November 1920. Date 1920 April May June July Aug. Sept. Workers discharged Workers engaged Comparison 76,148 105,930 105,724 75,158 70,063 69,132 79,040 62,022 62,107 60,281 65,922 83,570 + — — — — + 1 2,892 43,908 43,617 14,877 4,141 14,438 i The sign + signifies: engaged in excess; the sign — signifies: discharged in excess. 1 Reference in this connection might suitably be made to the Annual Report, 1920, of the Federal Reserve Board itself. 2 It might be noted that the volume of exports from the United States(see Report of the President's Conference on Unemployment, p. 147) does not amount to more than about 10 per cent, of the total national production. — 16 — The situation was still serious in 1921, but less critical than in 1920. The number of factories obliged to close temporarily or permanently was 145 as compared with 691 in the year 1920 *. On the other hand, it was estimated that the number of workers employed in factories in the Osaka prefecture was, even at the end of 1921, 10 per cent, less than in 1919, the year of maximum prosperity 2. The number of factories working was 25 per cent. less, a figure which would seem to give evidence of much speculative enterprise and dangerous expansion during the boom. The suffering caused by the intense depression of 1920 would have been much more serious had it not been possible for the workers discharged from factories to return to the country districts and secure some measure of employment in agricultural pursuits. This relieved the situation considerably in the prefectures of Osaka, Hyogo, and Hiachi. In the case of the prefecture of Kyoto, however, it is stated that of the 11,755 workers discharged in the town of Nishijin up to 15 June, 7,000 were entirely without employment 3 . Statistics of unemployment are not sufficiently complete in Japan to permit a comparison between price movements and the demand for labour. However, it will be seen from the table below that both wholesale prices and the volume of foreign trade rose until March 1920, the decline being rapid in both cases as from April 1920. The unemployment figures quoted above also show the most violent increase immediately after this date. Date 1913 (monthly aver.) 1919 » » 1920 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov Dec. 1921 J a n . Febr. March April May June 1 2 Index number of wholesale prices (Bank of Japan) 100 240 301 314 322 301 272 248 240 235 231 226 221 206 201 195 191 190 191 192 Imports (in thousands of yen) 60,474 177,113 202,853 268,977 324,436 292,298 292,451 220,115 151,297 119,729 108,369 105,294 106,319 102,011 103,005 118,079 134,533 137,254 148,200 145,019 Osaka Mainichi, May 1922. Ibid. •» The Japan Weekly Chronicle, 15 July 1920. Exports (in thousands of yen) 52,393 170,897 174,433 172,622 188,979 212,924 189,864 183,812 148,481 171,591 144,055 131,438 102,902 85,000 73,500 75,500 91,684 113,350 103,687 103,990 — 17 — From accounts given in the Japanese Chronicle, one of the earliest signs of the crisis was the feeling of uneasiness on the part of the banks and the consequent restriction of credit. "Things, however, have of late taken a turn for the worse, through the general uncertainty caused by the cautious attitude of the banks in the matter of advancing loans" \ Further details of conditions in Japan during the critical period 1919-1920 are given in The Street of 24 May 1920. After discussing the period of intense activity of 1918, it states: This unprecedented boom was followed by a period of wild speculation. The country seemed possessed by a mania for expansion of trade and industry and all kinds of new and sometimes hazardous enterprises were undertaken. As early as the autumn of last year it became evident that there would be a reaction from this wild speculative mania. The Bank of Japan, therefore, twice raised its discount rate until it reached 8 per cent., at the same time advising city banks to follow a conservative policy in respect to loans and discounts. It was hoped by this means to control speculation and avert a crisis. At about the middle of last January the fears of financiers began to be realised. The market was flooded with securities, and prices began gradually to decline. This condition was hastened by the îapid increase of the excess of imports over exports from the beginning of this year and the stringency of the money market due to heavy tax instalment. On 15 March there was a sharp decline in prices of securities,, and the stock exchange was obliged to close for two days in order to make adjustments. 2 Two important points would appear to stand out clearly from the above summary : (1) the close relationship between movement of wholesale prices and of industrial activity; (2) the stringency of the money market and the difficulties of the banks — factors which were evident towards the end of the boom and seem to have contributed to its restraint. 1 Reprinted in the Economic Review, 2 June 1920, from the Japanese Chronicle of 15 April 1920. 2 Reprinted in the Economic Review of 23 June 1920. CHAPTER II BRITISH EMPIRE GREAT BRITAIN. The years immediately following the war, 1918, 1919, and early 1920, had all the appearance of phenomenal prosperity. Demand was intense owing to the new requirements of peace; credits were being granted on every hand for purposes of reconstruction; industrial development went on apace in every sphere. At one stage (April 1920) unemployment in trade unions making returns fell below 1 per cent. This intense activity was, however, accompanied by a violent rise in prices, the level of wholesale prices rising from 217.2 in April 1919 to 313.1 in April 1920 \ As in the case of America, it was felt (see below) that this rapid price inflation was disorganising production, and should be restrained at the earliest possible date. Not only was it giving rise to much speculative enterprise and industrial friction, but was tending to draw Great Britain further away from the gold standard. The Cunlilïe Committee, appointed in 1918 to examine the question of "Currency and Foreign Exchanges after the War", recommended various measures for checking this rapid inflation and substituting for it a certain measure of deflation. Amongst its recommendations were: the cessation of government borrowing as soon as possible after the war; the maintenance in working order of the recognised machinery for controlling credit, namely, the raising and making effective of the Bank of England discount rate; and the legal limitation of the fiduciary issue of currency notes. As regards the first of these recommendations the British Government was successful, as early as April 1920, in budgeting not only for sufficient revenue to meet expenditure but also for a surplus of £251,800,000 for the reduction of debt. Large amounts of both funded and floating debt were paid off during the financial years 1920-1921 and 1921-1922, 1 Statist. 1913 = 100. — 19 — The deflationary effect of this policy was reinforced by the adoption of a Treasury Minute in December 1919 limiting the total fiduciary issue of currency notes in any year (the issue in excess of gold and Bank of England notes held in the currency notes redemption account) to the maximum actual fiduciary issue of the previous year. The limitation of the issue of legal tender notes in this way entailed a simultaneous restraint of credit advanced by banks. In order to make such restraint effective, the Bank of England raised its rate to 6 per cent, in November 1919 and subsequently to 7 per cent, in April 1920. These measures were effective in checking inflation in May 1920 — roughly the same time as the American crisis had its genesis. Prices began to fall in May and continued in precipitous decline until the end of 1921. Identically simultaneous with this decline of prices was the outbreak of the unemployment crisis. Having been reduced to the low figure of 0.9 per cent.1 in April 1920, unemployment showed a slight increase in May, a development which continued throughout the year, 6.1 per cent, of unemployment being reported by trade unions in December. The increase from that date onwards was exceedingly rapid, the figure of 23.1 per cent, being reached in June 1921.» It will be seen that in the initial stages of depression, although prices fell precipitately there was only a gradual diminution in employment. This may have been due partly to the continued activity of the foreign market (see figures of export below) and partly to the fact that, rather than dismiss workers when demand began to fail, employers continued to produce for stock. Such evidence as is available would seem to show that stocks with manufacturers did increase considerably during this period.8 The growth of the depression is described in the Labour Gazette of January 1921. A brief extract might usefully be quoted here: Those first affected were boot and shoe manufacture and leather tanning and currying, in April, followed, in May, by cotton weaving and, in June, by the hosiery and jute industries. 1 2 Percentage unemployment in trade unions rraking returns. For table showing monthly figures of unemployment from 1919 to 1921, see later, p. 21. 3 There is no official coordination of statistics of stocks in Great Britain. Certain individual industries, however, publish returns. There is also a valuable attempt on the part of the London and Cambridge Economic Services to compile continuous statistics of stocks of raw products. — 20 - In July and August, though employment was still good, on the whole, the decline continued, and spread to other industries; and in September slackness and short time were reported in most of the textile trades, and in the readymade clothing, boot and shoe, and leather industries. By the end of September the percentage unemployed had risen to 3.8 in the insured trades and to 2.2. among members of Trade Unions making returns. In October the national strike of coal miners and the consequent shortage of fuel seriously affected unemployment in the principal industries, and at the end of that month, and in the first half of November, most of these industries were very slack. On the basis of such information as io available, it would appear that between 8 October and 4 November there was an increase of at least 350,000 in the total number of workpeople unemployed, and, in addition, large numbers were placed on short time. The settlement of the dispute was followed by a partial recovery, but at the end of November employment was still considerably worse than at the beginning of October. There was a further decline during December, and at the end of the year there was serious depression in mo t of the principal industries. The percentage of trade union members reported as unemployed had risen to 6.1 and the lecords of workpeople out of work in the industries * (embracing about 11,900,000 workpeople) covered by the new Unemployment Insurance Act, which came into operation in November, showed about 5.8 per cent, as unemployed in these industries at the end of the year. In addition, large numbers of workpeople in the textile, boot and shoe, clothing, engineering, papermaking, and other industries were on shoit time. The total number of workpeople on the Live Register * of the Employment Exchanges at the end of the year was approximately 748,000, of whom 500,000 were men, 188,000 were women, nearly 29,000 were boys and over 31,000 were girls. The January 1922 number of the same Gazette continues the account : The decline in employment, which began in the summer of 1920 and was still in progress at the end of that year, continued at a rapid pace during the early months of 1921, and at the end of March there was serious depression in most of the principal industries. Of the 12 million workpeople covered by the Unemployment Insurance Act, the proportion unemployed rose from 6 per cent, at the beginning of the year to 11 per cent, at the end of March, and the proportion working systematic short time in such a manner as to entitle them to benefit rose from 4 per cent, to 7 per cent. During the same period the proportion unemployed among certain trade unions (mainly of skilled workpeople) which pay unemployment benefit to their members and make returns to the Department rose from 6 per cent, to 10 per cent. In April the effects of the general slackness in trade were rendered much more acute by the stoppage of work at the coal mines, which began on 1 Aprii and continued for three months. The great coal-using industries were quickly affected by the increasing scarcity of fuel, and in May and June employment was bad in nearly all the principal manufacturing trades. In some industries, notably the heavy iron and steel trades, tinplate manufacture, and the pottery trade, work was almost completely suspended. At the end of June the proportion of unemployed, apart from the coal mining industry, had risen to 19 per cent. 1 a The principal employments excluded are domestic service and agriculture. As some unemployed persons, particularly among those not covered by the Unemployment Insurance Act, do not register at the Employment Exchanges, these numbers do not provide an entirely complete measure of the total amount of unemployment. — 21 — among insured workpeople and to 23 per cent, among members of those trade unions making returns. These figures are the highest ever recorded by the Department. Expressed in absolute figures, this enormous percentage corresponded with 2,171,288 workers applying for benefit in respect of total unemployment, and 832,340 workers claiming benefit in respect of systematic short time on 24 June-1921. l The following table shows the fluctuations in unemployment and the movement of wholesale prices from the beginning of 1919 to June 1921: Date Percentage Index of number of unemploy- wholesale2 ment i prices 1913 (average) 1918 » 2.1 0.8 100.0 226.0 1919 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 2.5 2.8 2.9 2.7 2.1 1.7 2.0 2.2 1.6 2.6 2.9 3.2 224.4 220.6 217.3 217.2 228.9 234.6 242.8 250.2 252.7 263.9 271.8 276.7 Date Index Percentage of number of unemploy- wholesale ment » prices 2 1920 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 2.9 1.6 1.1 0.9 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.6 2.2 5.3 3.7 6.1 288.6 306.3 308.0 313.1 305.9 300.8 299.5 298.2 292.6 282.2 263.3 243.8 1921 J a n . Febr. March April May June 6.9 8.5 10.0 17.6 22.2 23.1 232.0 215.3 208.5 199.8 190.8 183.3 i Percentage unemployment amongst trade unions paying insurance benefit. 2 The Statist. As in the case of the United States and Japan, statistics for Great Britain show a remarkably close relationship between the movement of wholesale prices and unemployment. In the period of boom, when prices rose 95.9 points 2 in twelve months, unemployment was at one stage reduced below 1 per cent. ; and in spite of a great increase in the number of strikes, of the conversion of industry from a war to peace basis, and of rapid demobilisation, 3.2 per cent, of unemployment was the highest monthly average reported by trade unions during the whole period of prosperity. 1 2 The Labour Gazette, J u l y 1 9 2 1 , p p . 359-360. The Statist. — 22 — The break in prices occurred at identically the same time as the decline of employment, i. e. May 1920. By the month of June 1921, unemployment had reached 23.1 per cent, and prices had fallen 129.8 points. As already indicated, unemployment figures did not reflect the intensity of the depression as rapidly as did the fall of prices. Moreover, in the year 1919, the period of "hesitation", marked by a fall of wholesale prices in the earlier part of the year, was reflected by only a very slight decline in employment. In general, however, the table published above gives evidence of a very close relationship between the trend of prices and unemployment. The fact that the outbreak of the crisis synchronised with the change from price inflation to deflation, coupled with similar evidence from America and Japan, would seem to be strong prima jade grounds for assuming that it was the monetary policy adopted which was mainly responsible for the restraint of feverish activity in the early summer of 1920. The belief that this restraint in Great Britain was due to causes of internal origin is strengthened by a comparison of figures for export and import. VALUE OF EXPORTS AND IMPORTS in thousands of pounds sterling Date Exports Imports 1919 1920 (monthly average) (monthly average) 66,553 111,297 121,784 142,861 1920 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 105,880 85,964 103,699 106,252 119,319 116,352 137,452 114,903 117,456 112,295 119,365 96,631 158,034 147,910 149,616 146,747 146,074 150,367 145,494 139,886 139,342 133,756 131,145 130,086 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. 92,756 68,222 66,809 59,868 43,088 38,152 43,172 51,346 55,248 62,265 107,096 88,970 84,854 81,472 79,076 81,100 71,396 78,583 78,524 74,356 Oct. — 23 — Thé above statistics of export would seem to show that the foreign market remained extremely active until the end of 1920. On the other hand, figures of import indicate that the internal market was beginning to weaken somewhat earlier. Later in the depression, and particularly during the spring of 1921, the export market showed considerable weakness. But it should be noted, in examining the figures, that the most serious decline occurred during May and June when internal trade was disorganised in Great Britain on account of the strike of the coalminers. There was a marked recovery in the summer and autumn of 1921. CANADA In approaching the problem of unemployment in Canada, it is necessary to bear in mind two characteristics which distinguish the industry of that country. In the first place, the employment market is of a highly seasonal nature, some degree of depression being invariably experienced during the winter months. In the second place, the industrial activity of that country is dependent almost entirely on harvest prospects. The anticipation of good crops in spring directly influences agricultural demand and stimulates trade throughout the land. The expectancy of good sales in the fall and the realisation of such returns is again reflected in the purchasing activity of the agricultural population, and trade once more booms in anticipation of the requirements of the following year. "Trade" in Canada is thus almost synonymous with "harvest". In consequence of this special characteristic, the crisis of 1920 was of a very dramatic nature in Canada. In the early months of the year all trade signs pointed to success. Demand for all products was intense and, in common with those of every other country, prices were rising rapidly. Harvest prospects were good and the farmers' purchases were stimulated by the universal optimism which these signs appeared to justify. Throughout the summer, crops gave satisfactory results, an excellent yield being transported to the head of the Lakes for sale and export. Here, however, disappointment was in store. Foreign buyers refused to take the corn at the price demanded. A rapid slump ensued, entailing serious loss to all sellers. Costs, including wages and freights, had been exceedingly high and could not be recovered in the price yielded by the corn. This collapse — 24 — of the market for grain immediately spread to other industries, "The effect of the slump in grain prices and the blocking of the disposal of the crop has been serious upon business. The farmers have been unable to make their usual purchases, and the retailers are disinclined to place further orders with wholesalers, the result is that the Winnipeg merchants report the dullest autumn trade for many years, and at least one of the large departmental stores in the city has been compelled to pay off a large number of its staff. Inevitably the reaction is being felt in lack of orders for factories, and the spectre of unemployment is raising its head in numerous industrial centres at an unfortunately early date in the year. It is now being generally realised that during the coming winter Canada must set her house in order and face a spell of trade depression." 1 That such depression did occur was evidenced by the high figures ot unemployment reported during the following winter, the situation being intensified by the fact that a seasonal decline invariably occurs during the same period. From a figure of 3.3 per cent, in September 1920, unemployment rose to 10.2 per cent, in November 1920, and to 16.1 per cent, in February 1921 2. In early December 1920, the Canadian correspondent of The Economist reported: The shipbuilding industry has pratically come to a standstill, and the sawmill and lumber business in British Columbia is in a similar condition. In Montreal the delegate of the metal workers told the Commission that 4.000, or about 40 per cent., of the members of the unions in that city were out of employment. In the same city there is general unemployment in the clothing business. It is the same in other industrial centres, and every city in Canada has to-day a serious contingent of unemployed. There is a good demand for unskilled labour in the mines and woods of the East, but the urban workers are loathe to face the hardships of a Canadian winter in the country. The situation is by no means desperate yet, and luckily many of the workers have accumulated some considerable savings. But it is already plain that Canada will have a serious unemployment problem upon her hands before the winter ends. s Although thè most serious development of the crisis in Canada occurred at the time of the sudden slump of corn prices, there were evidences earlier in the year that the condition of intense boom 1 2 3 The Economist, 6 Nov. 1920, p. 823. More complete figures are given later, see p. 25. The Economist, 4 December 1920, p. 988. — 25 — could not be sustained and that the internal market was beginning to weaken. Some anxiety was felt in the corn-growing areas of Manitoba on account of the unwillingness of rural credit banks to extend loans with the same liberality as heretofore. The stringency of the money market appears to have been general. In its issue of 29 May 1920 The Economist states: "The banks have taken rigorous action in the curtailment of loans, and speculation has been largely discontinued. It is thought that the upward movement in prices may have at least reached its peak. The first noticeable decline is in the clothing and apparel lines." According to the same publication, this state of extreme monetary stringency continued throughout the year. Moreover the Government itself redoubled its efforts to meet expenditure out of revenue and so restrain the tendency to inflation. In the year 1920, taxation was in fact increased and expenditure considerably diminished. The anticipated check to the rise of prices occurred about May 1920, the official index of wholesale prices culminating during that month. Once on the wane, prices fell rapidly and continued to fall until the summer of 1922. Unemployment increased slightly after June 1920 but, owing to seasonal activity and the continuance of the optimistic spirit, showed no serious development until late in the autumn. Date Index Percentage of number of unemploy- wholesale ment i prices 2 1919 J u l y Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 2.43 2.19 1.79 2.03 3.58 4.29 217.0 222.2 222.5 221.1 227.1 237.8 1920 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 4.02 3.96 3.13 2.52 2.40 2.14 2.35 2.37 3.26 6.09 10.24 13.05 249.7 253.5 257.6 260.6 263.2 257.8 255.9 243.7 241.0 234.4 224.5 214.4 Date 1921 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Percentage Index •of number of unemploy- wholesale ment » prices 2 13.07 16.12 16.48 16.27 15.46 13.15 9.10 8.71 8.47 7.42 11.06 15.09 207.6 199.3 194.2 187.2 182.5 179.0 176.1 174.5 171.7 169.2 167.7 170.3 i Percentages of unemployment reported by trade unions; published by the Labour Gazette. a Official index. Base: 1913 = 100. — 26 — It will be seen from the foregoing figures that seasonal fluctuations tend to mask the relationship between the movement of prices and the development of unemployment. However, the broad cyclical movements of the two indexes are very closely correlated. In particular, it is to be noted that the break in prices occurred in May 1920, and that unemployment began to increase as from the month following. By the end of 1921, prices had fallen 92.9 points. Heavy unemployment accompanied this movement throughout, at no time falling below 7.42 per cent. A USTRALIA The unemployment statistics quoted for the Commonwealth of Australia are not easily comparable with those of other countries, since they are calculated somewhat differently. The quarterly totals prepared in the various States and communicated to the Commonwealth department include unemployment due to sickness and accident. Moreover, they relate, not to the number of unemployed on a fixed date, but to the number of workers who have lost at least three days, employment during the last week of the quarter. The returns represent the figures supplied by the trade unions which suffer most heavily from unemployment, and exclude such industries as railways, tramways, public service, etc. where employment is relatively permanent. For these reasons the "normal" percentage of unemployment in Australia appears high. If this factor be taken into account, it will be seen that the amount of unemployment which may be attributed to cyclical depression in Australia has been comparatively slight. The following are the percentages quoted for 1912 and 1920-1921. Percentage of Unemployment reported by Trade 1912 1920 1921 1 End of year . First quarter Second » Third » Fourth » First quarter Second » Third » Fourth » Unions1. 5.6 per cent. 5.6 » 6.2 » 6.2 » 7.8 » 11.4 » 12.5 » 11.4 » 9.5 » Figures quoted from the Quaterly Summary of Australian Statistics, March 1922. Although the crisis in Australia has not been so severe as in other countries, the same broad phases of the phenomenon have been — 27 — experienced. The period immediately after the war was one of rapid inflation, the wholesale index number for Melbourne showing a rise from an average of 177.8 l in 1918 to 247.4 in August 1920. Prices fell during the following month and continued to fall until the end of 1921 when an index number of 154.8 was recorded. As in other countries, this movement was accompanied by severe unemployment, which began in the latter months of 1920 and reached its culminating point in the second quarter of 1921. The monthly average for exports for the year 1913 was £6,014,000, and for imports, £6,355,000. The figures given below for foreign trade during the period of crisis show that the severity of the unemployment situation could not be attributed primarily to the failure of the international market, since exports began to increase from the low level of August 1920, just at the time when unemployment began also to develop. This increase of export was partly seasonal, and the decline in June-October 1921 was also to some extent due to winter conditions. In order to estimate the importance of the factor of foreign trade during the subsequent years of depression, it would seem necessary to consult the annual figures of exports ». VALUE OF IMPORTS AND EXPORTS (IN THOUSANDS OF POUNDS STERLING) FOR 1920 AND 1921 1 1920 1921 TVTATif h l u Uli li i i Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Imports Exports Imports Exports 7,653 6,167 9,144 9,688 11,790 12,567 12,282 12,756 15,243 14,584 14,744 15,146 11,752 12,515 13,241 10,063 13,601 10,618 9,518 7,848 8,399 9,345 11,688 9,476 17,204 11,621 14,053 11,312 10,272 8,558 6,999 6,839 6,359 6,440 7.654 8,474 10,971 11,840 10,414 11,041 10,900 9,709 7,800 7,370 8,533 8,507 10,095 11,139 1 The monthly average for the year ending June 1919 was: £7,662,000 for imports, and £8,489,000 for exports. 1 s Base: 1913 = 100. See later, p . 104. — 28 — SOUTH AFRICA. In spite of certain very unique features which charaterise the industry of South Alrica, the depression suffered by that country has been similar in almost all respects to that experienced in European countries. It developed about the same period and has continued with great intensity for three years or more. The forecast of Mr. A. Crawford, Secretary General of the South African Industrial Federation, in February 1921 \ that the country was confronted by a financial crisis from which there would be little recovery for two or three years, has been realised to the full. Absolute statistics of unemployment are not available for the years of the crisis, but some conception of the development of depression can be gained from the totals of applications for employment at the labour exchanges, although the activities of the latter may not be fully representative. In 1919, 15,577 such applications were recorded; the number increased to 20,708 in 1920 and to 33,729 in 1921. Some improvement was evident in 1922 and 1923. The growth of the depression is also revealed in statistics of insolvencies : Year 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 (Jan.-Sep t.) Liabilities of insolvents (£'s) 657,905 832,164 1,704,393 6,666.461 3,776,795 As in other countries previously examined, the depression was accompanied by a rapid fall in the level of prices, the decline starting in the summer of 1920 and continuing until the end of 1921, after which comparative stability was maintained. The movement of wholesale prices is shown as follows 2: Date 1913 (average) 1919 » 1920 » 1920 Jan. April July Oct. 1 2 Index number of wholesale prices 100.0 164.8 223.3 214.6 223.0 232.3 223.2 Industrial South Africa, Febr. 1921. Official Index. Date 1921 1922 Jan. April July Oct. Jan. April July Oct. Index number of wholesale prices 188.1 165.5 150.0 138.0 130.8 . 127.6 126.5 129.0 — 29 — The decline of prices was preceded by a period of rapid inflation comparable with that experienced at the same time in Europe. Amongst the measures adopted for checking this process must be included the increase of taxation on the part of the Government for the budgetary year 1920-1921; and the action of the banks, which were understood to have "exercised greater discrimination in granting credit in consequence of the requirements of the Currency and Banking Act, 1920, as regards minimum cash reserves." 1 The "minimum advance rate" of commercial banks was raised from 6 y2 to 7 per cent, in March 1920 and subsequently to 7 % P e r cent. in August of the same year. The rise of prices, as noted above, was checked in the summer of 1920. Although the general cyclical trend of unemployment and the principal causal factors appear to have been largely the same as those of Western Europe and America, there are certain special features relating to South African industry which should be noted here. In the first place, all questions concerning conditions of labour in South Africa are complicated by the existence of a predominant native and coloured element in the population. "As the result of the presence of this large section of workers the position of the white worker has been limited to a considerable degree to the more highly remunerated lines of the skilled trades or to the work of supervising, overlooking, and controlling the unskilled labourers who are employed in practically every industrial or agricultural operation in the Union. The unskilled white worker has of necessity found himself almost inevitably in competition with the native or coloured labourer; forced to maintain a higher standard of living, but unable to command a sufficiently high rate of pay.2 " The situation tends to become more serious during a period of severe competition, for employers are frequently obliged at such times to effect economies through the employment of unskilled and lower paid coloured labour. The brunt of the depression is thus largely borne by the white population whose sufferings are aggravated to an intense degree. In the second place, owing partly to the high cost of transport and partly to the character of the country's natural wealth, South African industry is based largely upon the production of high value and luxury commodities. On the one hand the demand for South 1 LEAGUE OF NATIONS: Brussels Financial Conference, 1920. The Recommendations and their Application, Vol. I, p. 178. 8 Official Year Book of the Union of South Africa, No. 5, p. 289. — 30 — African gold is liable to fluctuation at any moment according to the requirements of the world's monetary systems and, on the other hand, the demand for articles of luxury, precious stones and metals, ostrich feathers, etc., tends to decline during depression more than the demand for necessaries. How far these influences may have been at work during 1921 and 1922 is difficult to estimate. There appears to have been a considerable recrudescence in the demand for gold at the end of the war, 1917 and 1919 showing the highest figures of export. From 1919 there was a continuous decline until 1923. The figures of export for other commodities show again that 1919 was the most prosperous year, and that 1921 was the period of most severe restriction of foreign demand. Value of Exports (in thousands of pounds sterling), 1917-1923. 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 (monthly average) » » » » » » » » » » » » Merchandise Gold 2,398 2,594 4,219 3,841 2,234 2,476 2,962 4,992 2,936 3,973 2,962 2,871 2,443 3,264 CHAPTER III SCANDINAVIA, FINLAND, the NETHERLANDS and SWITZERLAND SCANDINAVIA AND FINLAND The end of the year 1919 and the beginning of 1920 were marked by a general policy of credit restriction in Scandinavian countries, arising presumably out of a desire to restrain the process of inflation which was taking place with the same intensity as in the countries previously examined. In Norway, the Central Bank raised its rate to 6 per cent, in December 1919 and to 7 per cent, in June 1920. In the same month the Norwegian Exchange Council adopted a resolution to the effect that the Bank of Norway, private and savings banks, should be requested to restrict the issue of new credits and the re-issue of such as had expired, to strictly necessary objects.1 The rise of prices in Norway was checked in September 1920. In March 1920, the National Bank of Sweden raised its rate of discount to 7 per cent., with a further increase to 7% VeT cent. in September of the same year. In addition to this, it issued a circular in May 1920 to the private banks, urging them to restrict the granting of credits to the public in view of the difficult position of the Swedish money market. It was suggested that the restriction should apply to money required for speculative purposes, for the expansion of industrial concerns which were not urgently needed, for the establishment of new industrial enterprises, shipping services, railways, etc., and for the purchase of ships from abroad 2. These measures had the effect of restraining the expansion of credit in the summer of 1920, wholesale prices reaching their culminating point about the end of June 1920. In Denmark the Bank Rate was raised from 6 to 7 per cent, in April 1920. Prices began to fall in October 1920. In Finland 1 Sjôfartstidende, 22 June 1920. - Svensk Handelstiding, 29 May 1920. — 32 — the discount rate of the Central Bank was raised to 8 per cent, in March 1920 and to 9 per cent, the following November. The level of wholesale prices reached a culminating point in November 1920. As in the case of the previous countries discussed, the fall of prices, once started, was most precipitous in Sweden, Norway and Denmark, and produced the same results as in the case of the United States and Great Britain. Unemployment began to develop about the end of 1920 in all three countries. This increase was to some extent seasonal in character; but the spring of 1921 brought little or no revival from the seasonal trough, enormous percentages of unemployment being reported throughout the year. The following table gives evidence of the magnitude of the crisis in these three countries : PERCENTAGE OF UNEMPLOYMENT REPORTED BY TRADE UNIONS, 1919-1922 Norway Denmark Date Sweden 1919 March June Sept. Dec. 7.6 6.1 3.2 3.8 2.2 1.1 1.2 2.6 20.5 3.6 3.1 16.5 1920 March June Sept. Dec. 4.5 3.4 2.9 15.8 1.5 0.7 1.8 6.8 6.7 2.0 2.7 15.1 1921 March June Sept. Dec. 24.5 27.7 27.3 33.2 16.1 20.9 17.1 22.9 23.6 16.8 16.6 25.2 1922 March June Sept. Dec. 30.6 21.5 15.2 21.7 25.4 15.6 11.0 15.1 27.9 13.2 10.6 20.3 . In each country this vast swelling of unemployment was accompanied, as noted above, by an unprecedented collapse of wholesale prices. In Sweden prices fell from 375 in June 1920 to 175 in May 1922 ». The Norwegian price level fell from 425 in September 1920 to 225 in September 1922 2. In Denmark, there was a decline from 403 in October 1920 to 176 in September 1922 ». In each case a fall of about 200 points occurred in two years. 'Official. Base: 1913 = 100. * Okonomisk Revue. Base: 1913 = 100. 3 Finanstidende. Base: 1913 = 100. — 33 — In marked contrast to these three countries is the case of Finland. For in the latter country there has been neither precipitous fall ot prices, nor serious unemployment. The unemployment statistics quoted in the Bulletin of the Bank of Finland for the years 1919— 1922 are as follows: Number 1919 Jan Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 4,366 3,948 2,971 2,449 1,753 1,193 982 1,147 1,961 1,562 1,762 1,736 of Unemployed 1920 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. in Finland, 1919-1922. 1921 2,298 March 1,757 June 1,580 Sept. 1,11.4 Dec. 654 475 542 1922 749 837 March 1,034 June 1,282 Sept. 1,454 Dec. 2,927 937 1,369 2,127 2,861 799 791 1,294 Wholesale prices declined during the winter of 1920-1921, but the fall was arrested in the spring of 1921, and the level has been maintained comparatively stable since that date: Index Month Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. numbers of Wholesale 1920 1,075 1,054 1,024 1,035 1,056 1,113 1,178 1,266 1,298 1,385 1,422 1,400 Prices, 1920-1923 * 1921 1,223 1,188 1,203 • 1,249 1,182 1,247 1,259 1,293 1,364 1,361 1,305 1,295 1922 1923 1,263 1,254 1,244 1,260 1,241 1,229 1,219 1,230 1,224 1,186 1,140 1,149 1,134 1,127 1,108 1,096 1,093 1,095 1,080 1,080 1,089 1,077 1,070 — 1 Index of the Central Statistical Ofllce. See Monthly Bulletin of the Bank of Finland, Dec. 1923. The relative lightness of the crisis experienced in Finland is evidenced in the following account contained in the Monthly Bulletin of the Bank of Finland of April 1922. "The consequences of the general world crisis have not proved as disastrous to the banks in Finland as they have been in many other countries. Chiefly, this depended on the fact that the extraodinary fall in prices, which in other lands caused such numerous bankruptcies and losses to banks, did not occur in this country. On the opposite, prices averaged pretty much the same throughout the year. The index number for the cost of living was almost exactly the same at the end of the year as it had been at the beginning. The number — 34 — of bankruptcies in 1921 was only 358, the corresponding number in 1913 being 762." In the same publication of Februrary 1922, it is stated: "Contrary to what has been the case in other Scandinavian lands, labour conditions have been specially peaceful in Finland during the first months of the year. No strikes or lockouts of any size worth mentioning have occurred. Unemployment has continuously been of fairly small extent." Two conclusions would appear to stand out from the survey of Scandinavian conditions in the period 1920-1922: (1) the close connection between falling prices and unemployment; (2) the comparatively small influence of external conditions in a country like Finland which succeeds in pursuing an independent price policy. In the latter connection, it is interesting to note that the value of exports from Finland, expressed in Finnish marks, actually increased in 1921 and 1922, in spite of the universality of the depression in other countries. This may have been due partly to the fall in the exchange value of Finnish currency during this period ; but too much stress should not be laid on this factor, since imports into Finland also remained high in 1921 and increased considerably during the following years. Exports from the other Scandinavian countries show a considerable decline in monetary value during 1921; but when account is taken of the enormous fall of prices during that year in all countries, the diminution in the real value of the goods would appear to be ol less account. The failure of internal demand would therefore seem to be the most important consideration in each of the countries under discussion. The diminution of foreign demand during 1921 must none the less be considered an important intensifying factor, especially in the case of Sweden.x NETHERLANDS. In the Netherlands economic depression set in on the outbreak of war, and there has been no complete industrial revival since. It is perhaps the only country in which the depression has continued almost without a break for ten years, although the degree of acuteness may have varied. The unemployment percentage » 1 For a more detailed discussion of the influence of export trade, see later, pp. 96-97. 2 This percentage, established weekly by the Central Statistical Office, gives the proportion between the total number of days of involuntary unemployment and the total number of possible working days for all workers. It is therefore a much more accurate index of unemployment than the percentages of unemployed workers given by most other countries which fail to take account of each worker's period of unemployment. — 35 — which averaged 2.5 in 1911, 4.0 in 1912, and 5.0 in 1913, rose suddenly to 13.8 in 1914. It remained as high as 12.0 in 1915, fell to 5.1 in 1916, but rose again to 6.5 in 1917 and 7.5 in 1918. Towards the end of 1919 the situation improved slightly and still more so in 1920, but during the winter of 1921 unemployment increased heavily, and in spite of the seasonal improvement of the summer the average for the year was 9 per cent. The situation became still worse in 1922, and the year 1923 gave no evidence of permanent improvement. These fluctuations are shown in the following table which also gives the changes in wholesale prices: Year Index number of wholesale prices » 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 100 109 146 226 276 373 304 292 182 160 151 Percentage of Unemployment 5.0 13.8 12.0 5.1 6.5 7.5 7.7 5.8 9.0 11.0 10.8 2 s i Official. Annual average. > Maandschri/t. Annual average. » January-November. In view of the relation between the fluctuations of prices and unemployment observed in other countries, it is surprising that the considerable rise in prices during the war which took place in the Netherlands as elsewhere was not accompanied by a similar development of industrial activity and a similar reduction in unemployment. This exceptional situation is perhaps due to the difficulties with which Dutch industry had to contend owing to the proximity of the maritime war zone and the North Sea blockade. Whatever the reason may be, as from 1920 there appears to have been a well-defined connection between the fall in prices and the growth of unemployment. During the first ten months of 1920 prices were relatively stable, and unemployment was relatively slight. In November and December 1920 there was a sudden fall in prices and rise in unemployment. Both these phenomena became more marked in 1921 and 1922. In 1923 prices were relatively stable and at the same time the volume of unemployment, while still considerable, ceased to grow. — 36 — A comparison of the fluctuations in unemployment with the volume of foreign trade may be made from the following figures: Year 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 Average exports per month Metric tons 277,000 166,000 227,000 351,000 476,000 576,000 725,000 There was thus a marked and steady increase in the volume of exports from 1918 onwards; in 1922 it was more than twice as high as in 1919, which was a comparatively prosperous year. Under such conditions it seems difficult to attribute the outbreak of the crisis or the severity of unemployment in the Netherlands to the loss of foreign markets or to the competition of countries with depreciated currencies. SWITZERLAND. Switzerland has figured amongst those countries in which unemployment has been highest in proportion to the population. The number of unemployed increased progressively during the months following June 1920 *, from 3,856 to 25,000 in October, 36,000 in November, and 65,000 in December of that year. In April 1921, there were 144,000 unemployed, 49,000 wholly and 95,000 partially ; after a slight improvement in the situation during the summer months, the number of unemployed again increased, attaining its maximum in February 1922 with 146,302 wholly and partially unemployed persons. This total, though not markedly greater than the figure for April 1921 was, however, evidence of a much more serious situation, since it included 99,541 wholly and only 46,761 partially unemployed. Similarly, a closer examination of these figures shows that the improvement alluded to above as having occurred during the summer of 1921 was more apparent than real; for the decrease in numbers only applied to partially unemployed, whose number decreased regularly from May 1921 onwards, whereas the number of completely unemployed, on the contrary, showed a continuous increase. It will thus be seen that the unemployment crisis made itself felt in Switzerland very suddenly, and at once assumed an exceedingly tenacious character, for it only attained its maximum intensity after 18 months, during which the total number of unemployed 1 See The Swiss Labour Market, monthly publication of the Federal Labour Office. — 37 — remained almost constantly above 130,000, and even at one time attained 146,000 — a figure which is equivalent to 25 per cent, of unemployed of the total number of wage earners according to the Federal census of 1910. The following table shows the relation between the fluctuations in unemployment and the movement of prices and foreign trade. The index number of wholesale prices was established at the beginning of 1921 by Dr. Lorenz and published by him in the economic review Die Kurve. It comprises seventy-one articles, the base being: July 1914 = 100. The index number for retail prices (cost of living) is that published monthly by the Federal Labour Office. FLUCTUATIONS IN UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE MOVEMENT OF PRICES AND FOREIGN Unemployment End of month 1920 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Wholly unemployed Partially unemployed Total TRADE Exports i Prices Index number of wholesale prices Index In number In thou- millions of sands of retail of francs metric prices tons 240.7 245 253 253 262 258 249 243 325,550 325,550 325,550 299,500 299,500 299,500 243,470 243,470 243,470 230,547 230,547 230,547 77 90 90 90 67 67 67 4,640 4,979 3,878 3,561 3,813 3,100 4,330 5,353 7,275 9,814 13,436 17,623 368 373 646 756 5,388 8,949 10,379 15,512 22,743 47,636 4,640 4,979 4,246 3,934 4,459 3,856 9,668 14,302 17,654 25,326 ' 36,179 65,259 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 37,652 42,705 43,282 49,309 52,635 54,039 55,605 63,182 66,646 74.238 80,692 88,967 71,922 82,930 88,689 95,374 87,741 76,116 79,888 74,309 69,421 59,835 56,869 53,970 106,574 125,635 131,971 144,683 140,376 130,155 135,493 137,491 136,067 134,073 137,561 142,937 233.2 221.7 211.3 185.7 183.3 178.8 177.0 180.6 184.5 182.7 178.2 176.9 237 234 231 212 210 214 209 206 200 198 192 189 165,294 165,294 165,294 171,024 171.024 171,024 210,162 210,162 210,162 166,899 166,899 166,899 37 37 37 45 45 45 54 54 54 47 47 47 1922 Jan. Febr. 97,091 99,541 49,181 46,761 146,272 146,302 172.3 172.4 179 177 140,552 140,552 49 49 1 Monthly average for the quarter. 237 — 38 — It is scarcely necessary to emphasise the close relationship between fluctuations in unemployment and movements of prices: figures show with striking regularity that an increase of unemployment and a lall in prices have always occurred at the same time. During the whole period of the war, and until the end of 1919, currency inflation prevailed in Switzerland and was accompanied by a parallel rise in prices: fiduciary circulation increased from 270,000,000 francs just before the war to 1,036,000,000 francs on 31 December 1919. At that date, the index number of wholesale prices x was 327.79, and unemployment was almost non-existent. Early in 1920, however, a policy of deflation was inaugurated by the Federal Bank imitating the example of Japan, the United States and Great Britain, where a similar policy had been adopted in the spring of 1920. In Switzerland, the fiduciary circulation had fallen to 974,000,000 francs on 31 March 1920 and had further diminished to 954,000,000 francs by 30 June 1920 2. In spite of a certain increase in circulation during the second halt of the year, the effects of deflation began to make themselves felt in October 1920: prices fell rapidly and at the culminating point of the unemployment crisis in February. 1922, the index number was 172.3, or scarcely more than half the figure for the beginning of 1920 on the eve of the crisis. The increase in unemployment was accompanied by a considerable decrease in exports ; and the following table would seem to demonstrate that the decrease in exports preceded the fall in prices 3, and probably reinforced the effect of the deflationary policy mentioned above in causing this price decline. The decrease in exports, whilst constituting a partial cause initially of the fall of prices, may in the later stages have been itself exaggerated by the continuance of the price decline. For any marked lowering of the price level internally has the effect of increasing the value of the currency concerned as a means of purchasing goods, and consequently tends to raise its rate of exchange in the foreign money market. Moreover, an improving currency tends to be overestimated externally in anticipation of its greater future value; speculators and investors more willingly purchase the currency and, in fact, buy it at a price exceeding its 1 2 3 L O R E N Z : Die League Kurve, of Nations' 1 Jan. Currency 1923, p . 9. Memorandum, 1913-1922, p . 62 In spite of the absence of data concerning wholesale prices in 1920, the usual parallel relationship between wholesale and retail prices (the latter following the former after a certain interval! would appear to show that the fall in wholesale prices was first apparent early in the summer of 1920. — 39 — immediate value. Falling prices may thus lead to the over-estimation of a currency externally, a factor which has a restraining influence on export from the country concerned. In the case of Switzerland, for instance, whose currency was over-valued extern*ally during the whole of the period of crisis, foreign importers with depreciated currency had difficulty in procuring Swiss money to pay Swiss prices. Hence a diminution of exports from Switzerland. In January 1922, a period during which unemployment had reached its maximum, and when exports were particularly low, Dr. Lorenz' 1 calculations show that the index.numbers for the Swiss prices converted into foreign currency were 16.4 per cent. higher than prices in England, 16.7 per cent, higher than in Italy, 18.3 per cent, higher than in France and 53.6 per cent, higher than in Germany. The results of similar calculations made as regards the United States during different months in 1921 and 1922, by the Economic and Financial Section of the League of Nations, are contained in the following table: EXCHANGE FLUCTUATIONS AND RELATIVE PRICE MOVEMENTS HETWEEN SWITZERLAND AND THE UNITED STATES Date (a) Relative prices (6) Rate of exchange 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 139.4 142.2 139.7 134.1 127.2 127.5 126.2 125.9 129.5 129.3 128.0 126.9 123.2 118.2 113.2 110.9 108.0 113.3 116.7 114.8 112.3 105.6 102.9 99.7 — — — — — — — — — — — — •11.6 16.9 19.0 16.3 15.1 11.1 7.5 8.8 13.3 18.3 19.6 21.4 1922 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 126.5 122.3 US.7 114.2 109.8 108.9 106.0 106.6 107.9 108.8 109.8 111.1 99.4 98.9 99.1 99.2 100.4 101.3 101.0 101.3 102.5 104.5 105.0 102.2 — — — — — — — — — — — — 21.4 19.1 16.5 13.1 8.6 7.0 4.7 5.0 5.0 4.0 4.4 8.0 » Memorandum on Currency, p. 191. Geneva, 1Ï23 1 l Die Kurve, No. 12, Dec. 1923. (c) Percentage difference ' _ 40 — In this table, column (a) expresses the percentage which the Swiss index number bears to the United States price level : column (b) gives the cost of the dollar in Swiss francs expressed as a percentage of the par rate; column (c) gives the difference between (b) and (a) expressed as a percentage of (a). If the rate of exchange corresponded exactly to the relationship between Swiss and American prices, (a) and (b) would be equal. If, however, (a) is greater than (b), this indicates t h a t the Swiss franc is over-valued with reference to the dollar if the purchasing power of the two currencies is taken into consideration; and it will be seen that this was the case during 1921 and 1922 l. The joint effects on imports of the fall of prices on the home market, coupled with a rise in the Swiss exchange, is indicated in the two following extracts from reports of the Federal Bank: The economic position of Switzerland became considerably worse than in 1920, particularly in the second half of the year. The exchanges of the countries constituting our principal foreign markets continually declined, which resulted in the restraint of exports; and when the effects of the crisis due to the rapid and unforeseen fall in the price of raw materials made themselves felt, even countries with which the rate of exchange was normal endeavoured to cancel their purchase contracts. Industrial and commercial repoits are practically unanimous in stating that after a period of intense activity during the first quarter of the year, and a very considerable increase in prices, a period of general weakness prevailed, followed by a fall in prices which, although slow at first, soon assuired alarming proportions; trade was paralysed, output reduced, and some factories closed down entirely, as shown by the great increase in unemployment. a Jn the economic sphere, the most noticeable feature was the persistent fall in the price of raw materials and manufactured articles. Great hesitation prevailed among buyers and the difficulty in disposing of stocks and the necessity for restricting production leu to a world crisis causing intense unemployment and heavy depreciation of stocks of manufactured articles. The contrast between countries with high and low exchanges became greater and made it more difficult for the former to export their products, while their industry was, at the same time, threatened by competition from countries with a depreciated exchange. Switzerland suffered particularly severely from the effects of this general crisis, and the position of industries which are largely dependent on exports became steadily worse for the reasons mentioned above.8 1 In examining the table contained in the Memorandum on Currency, from which these figures are taken, it will be noticed that, as regards the Netherlands, where it was found that exports, unlike in Switzerland, had not decreased during the unemployment crisis, the differences between these two series of figures were sometimes positive and sometimes negative; and that figures themselves were never as high as in the case of Switzerland. This perhaps accounts partially for the difference in the position of the two countries as regards the development of export trade. 2 Swiss Federal Bank, hlth Report, 1920, p. 5. 3 Ibid., 58th Report, 1921, p. 4. — 41 — The general examination of the available statistics which has been undertaken would appear to demonstrate that the fall in prices and the decrease in exports, both of which contribute to unemployment, were phenomena closely related to monetary conditions. CHAPTER IV ITALY, FRANCE AND BELGIUM ITALY. Shortly after the Armistice Italy suffered, as in the case of most other belligerent countries, from an increase in unemployment, generally attributed to military and industrial demobilisation. In Italy, the lack of raw materials may also have been a partial cause of this momentary depression. The number of unemployed recorded during 1919 did not, however, exceed 400,000. Moreover, the situation improved rapidly during the following months and at the end of July 1920 there were only 88,000 unemployed. If reference be made to the following table with a view to comparing fluctuations in unemployment with the movement of wholesale prices, it will be noticed: (1) that wholesale prices fell at the beginning of 1919, at a time when unemployment was increasing; (2) that wholesale prices began to rise in March 1919, and that this rise continued during the whole period when unemployment was decreasing. In May 1920 the price curve again showed a downward trend, and three months later unemployment again began to increase, which marked the outbreak of a crisis of considerably greater magnitude than the demobilisation depression. The development continued until January 1922 when there were 600,000 unemployed1, whereas from July 1921 onwards prices again began to rise; this rise, however, which was of short duration, was apparently only a reaction from the abnormal fall which had occurred in April 1921 1 This figure compared to the approximative total number of wage earners corresponds to a proportion of 5.23 per cent.; but if a distinction is made between agriculture and industry, the proportion would be 2.1 per cent, in the former and 18 per cent, in the latter case. — 43 — owing to a change, in the "bread policy" of the Government 1 ; so that in reality, ignoring this incidental fluctuation, the general fall in prices appears to have extended from April 1920 (index number: 679.1), until May 1922 (index number: 523.5). End of month Number of totally unemployed Index number of wholesale prices ' Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 268,593 395,394 375,297 356,165 326,651 322,080 290,802 294,081 255,314 268,227 327.5 322.5 326.1 329.9 336.8 357.9 362.4 369.4 371.7 390.6 438.8 457.3 1920 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept, Oct. Nov. Dec. 270,487 261,947 235,486 202.002 115,098 105,831 88.101 93,241 115,736 100,758 107,112 102,156 503.7 556.3 619.0 679.1 659.0 614.8 613.0 631.7 660.5 662.1 658.0 635.4 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 1919 1922 — 388,744 435,194 463,108 473,216 492,368 512,260 541,779 642.5 613.3 603.6 583.9 546.9 508.9 520.0 541.8 580.0 599.1 594.9 594.6 006,819 577.2 — — 250,145 — Jan. i "Bachi". Base: average for 1913 = 100. Thus the general relationship between unemployment and price movements, which has already been noted in the case of other 1 Ernest LÉMONON: L'Italie d'après-guerre, p. 167. Bibliothèque d'histoire contemporaine. Alean 1922. — 44 — countries, is also strikingly manifest in Italy. It should further be noted that the period of rapidly falling prices which began in May 1920 was preceded or accompanied by two increases in the central rate of discount, from 5 per cent, to b]/2 per cent, in April, and from 5% per cent, to 6 per cent, in May. An examination of statistics of foreign trade shows that there was a considerable strengthening of the export market from July 1920 to the end of the year, that is to say, during the initial stages of the crisis. On the other hand, the year 1921, the worst period of the depression, was marked by an appreciable diminution in exports '. Date 1920 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aus;. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Value of exports in thousand lire 492,941 631,950 689,935 691,430 662,234 752,154 521,490 531,940 570,174 707,364 730.828 852,000 Date 1921 Jan. Febr. March April Value of exports in thousand lire 503.186 566,630 567,299 587,167 ' FRANCE. French statistics on unemployment are somewhat imperfect, a characteristic common to all countries in which there does not exist a fairly general system of unemployment insurance. Some indication of the degree of unemployment may, however, be obtained from the returns of the municipal or departmental unemployment relief organisations. The statistics of the Paris Unemployment Fund s in particular,, show that this important industrial centre did not escape the general economic depression. In November 1920, the number of workers in receipt of relief, after falling to an insignificant figure, rose suddenly from 700 to 2,000, and increased steadily to a maximum 1 2 For a further account of the movements of foreign trade, see later, p. 81. Bulletin du Ministère du Travail, passim. — 45 — of 44,000 in March 1921. That this was not the ordinary seasonal unemployment of the winter months is shown by a comparison with the corresponding figures for the previous and following years: 500 unemployed workers in receipt of relief in March 1920: 3,500 in March 1922 and 600 in March 1923. Although the Parisian industries suffered from the general depression in 1921, the resulting unemployment was not so great as that which occurred during the period of demobilisation after the Armistice. The maximum point of this latter wave of unemployment was reached in March 1919 when the number of workers in receipt of relief from the Paris Municipal Unemployment Fund was 70,000. Another characteristic feature of the 1921 depression, which is evidence of the very general nature of its causes, is that most of the industrial groups covered by the statistics were affected simultaneously by the crisis; the number of unemployed began to rise at about the same time (November 1920) for nearly all the different groups and reached a maximum at almost the same date, i.e., between 26 March and 8 April 1921, for men, and one month earlier, that is, between 26 February and 11 March, for women. The statistics of the unemployment funds for the country as a whole, although less reliable, since the number of active funds varies from time to time, give a similar picture of the rapid rise in unemployment at the end of 1920, a maximum having been reached in March 1921 when more than 90,000 workers were in receipt of relief. As in other countries, there is a striking coincidence in France between the fluctuations of unemployment and of prices. Even during the 1919 crisis, which must be ascribed essentially to military and industrial demobilisation, the price factor played a part. The index number of wholesale prices l fell from 416 in October 1918 to 376 in May 1919. This was the period of the first wave of unemployment after the war. During the second half of 1919 and the first half ol 1920, on the other hand, wholesale prices rose and unemployment diminished. By the beginning of June 1920 only 98 workers were in receipt of relief from the Paris Unemployment Fund. At that date the two curves changed their direction. The index number of prices fell steadily until the beginning of 1922, when, as has already been shown, the second wave of unemployment after the war commenced. If an attempt were made to ascribe the fluctuations in prices in part to monetary policy, and thereby attribute the unemployment 1 Statistique générale de la France. — 46 — to the latter, a reference to the Memorandum on Currency published by the League of Nations in 1923 will show that the fall in prices from April 1920 to February 1922 was not accompanied in its initial stages by a contraction in legal tender currency l. Date 1920 Index number of wholesale prices l Index number of fiduciary circulation 100.2 March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 100 93.6 83.9 84.3 85.3 89.5 85.6 78.4 74.0 1921 March June Sept, Dec. 61.2 55.3 58.5 55.4 103.1 100.4 99.6 97.9 1922 March 52.3 95.3 101.3 105.2 — 101.7 i Official. Base: April 1920 = 100 (the maximum point of the wholesale price curve). 2 Base: 31 December 1919 = 100. The above table shows that fiduciary circulation increased during the first nine months of 1920. The rate of fall of prices varied and at one point there was even a rise. In September the fiduciary circulation began to fall, while the decline of prices accelerated and unemployment increased. As regards the relation between credit facilities and the movement of prices, it is to be seen that some restriction was effected in the spring of 1920 by the raising of the central rate of discount from 5 to 6 per cent, in April and its maintenance at this level until June 1921. This movement corresponded with the restraint of rising prices in April 1920 and a subsequent decline until the year 1922. Statistics of foreign trade might also be examined with a view to discovering the part this factor may have played in unemployment. 1 Mr. Charles RIST indicates in his book La Deflation en Pratique (Paris, 1924), that the deflation of currency in France was rather the consequence than the cause of falling prices. — 47 — imports i Date In thousands of francs 1919 Monthly average 1920 Monthly average June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 2,983,272 2,950,412 1921 Jan. Febr. March Exports i In thousands of metric tons In thousands of francs 989,966 1,869,563 In thousands of . metric tons 2,800,453 2,627,876 2,595,445 2,672,178 2,948,257 3,204 4,245 4,251 5,483 4,201 4,341 4,511 4,510 5,763 2,399,508 2,151,573 2,332,552 1,883,598 1,660,896 464 1,039 1,352 1,092 1,299 1,276 1,096 1,251 931 1,982,468 1,613,931 1,742,908 3,703 2,579 2,827 1,882,618 1,889,444 1,686,426 1,117 1,414 1,069 i LEAGUE OF NJATIONS: Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, Special Trade. Evaluated at 1919 official rates. The import figures give no indication that the unemployment in France might be attributed to an excessive influx of foreign industrial commodities. There was, however, a considerable decline of exports at the end of 1920 and the beginning of 1921. A comparison between the figures showing the value and those showing the weight of exports seems to indicate that the diminution mainly affected manufactured articles. In conclusion, this period of unemployment in France coincided with the fall in prices. The latter was apparently not produced by a contraction in legal tender currency, though it may to some extent have been due to a restriction of credit. Furthermore, short though the period of unemployment may have been, it was perhaps accentuated in France by a loss of foreign markets, from which luxury trades in particular would have suffered, since they are responsible for a large proportion of French exports. BELGIUM. The unemployment crisis in Belgium began to assume an alarming aspect about the same time as in France and other Western European countries, that is, in September 1920; it reached its culminating point very rapidly, i.e., in May 1921, somewhat later than in France. The development of the crisis is shown in the following table giving the percentage of unemployed (wholly or partially) among members of Trade Union Unemployment Funds. — 48 — 1920 Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Per cent. 5.8 6.4 7.2 17.4 1921 Per cent. Jan. Febr. March April May 19.3 22.7 31.5 31.2 32.3 The unemployment crisis was preceded and accompanied by economic phenomena similar to those noted in other countries. Early in the spring of 1920 some restraint of credit occurred through the raising of the central discount rate from 3.5 per cent, in March to 5.5 per cent, in April 1920. This restriction of credit facilities appears soon to have been reflected in a diminution of purchasing power, of which the rapid decrease in the deposits on current account at the National Bank is perhaps some evidence : These accounts, exclusive of government accounts, showed a decrease from 1,694 million francs at the end of June 1920 to 1,100 millions at the end of December and 489 millions at the end of June 1921 1. No statistics of wholesale prices are available for the period immediately preceding the crisis, or during its first stages ; but the cost of living index number, which shows the fluctuations of retail prices, indicates that the latter began to fall in October 1920, and it may be supposed that a fall in wholesale prices had occurred a few months earlier. It is further to be noted that the official index number of wholesale prices calculated on the basis of October 1920= 100 shows a fall from 96.4 in January 1921 to 71.8 in August 1921, a decline of more than 25 per cent.. Statistics of foreign trade show that a considerable decrease in the value of exports, expressed in francs, occurred as from July 1920. This decrease continued in August, and was succeeded, until the end of the year, by alternate periods of rise and fall. In 1921 the value of exports, expressed in francs, continued to diminish, whereas exports calculated in tons showed a tendency to improve. This may be due, on the one hand, to a decrease in prices, and, on the other, to a decrease in the real value of the goods exported, corresponding to a lesser proportion of manufactured goods and to a larger proportion of raw material in the total volume of exports. 1 LEAGUE OF NATIONS: Memorandum on Currency, 1913-1922. — 49 — Imports Exports Date 1920 June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 1921 ' J a n . Febr. March April May 1 In thousands of francs In thousands of metric tons 842,665 769,832 750,963 774,800 760,628 727,881 769,655 950 941 960 1,119 966 893 974 1,149,490 857,714 891,713 841,904 896,222 886,013 926,424 997 895 1,022 954 1,129 1,292 1,249 647,663 647,663 647,663 614,574 614,574 1,107 1,107 1,107 1,750 1,750 914,787 914,787 914,787 774,216 774,216 1,407 1,407 1,407 1,365 1,365 In thousands of francs In thousands of metric tons From the beginning of 1921, monthly averages for the quarter. It might therefore be argued that foreign markets exercised a considerable influence on the development of the unemployment crisis in Belgium; nevertheless, the correlation is not continuous since it is to be seen * that there was subsequently little improvement in the value of exports, expressed in francs, in spite of the rapid revival of employment after May 1921. On the other hand, in considering import movements, whether expressed in francs or in metric tons, a tendency to increase during the period when unemployment was growing is to be observed; this increase, however, was comparatively unimportant and was not lasting. Consequently, the conclusion cannot be drawn that the unemployment crisis in Belgium was either due to, or considerably aggravated by the competition of foreign goods on the home market. 1 See later, p. 84. 4 CHAPTER V. CENTRAL EUROPE AUSTRIA. In the other countries already reviewed the unemployment crisis began to develop at the end of 1920, but in Austria no such development took place; nor was this peculiar situation modified during 1921, for it was only at the beginning of 1922, at a time when the situation elsewhere had begun to show signs of progressive improvement, that the first signs of the crisis began to appear in Austria. The fullest statistics dealing with unemployment in that country are those compiled in accordance with the Act of 24 March 1920 relating to compulsory insurance against unemployment. Despite the imperfect nature of these statistics, due particularly to modifications in the administration of the Act, they enable the general movements of the labour market to be followed with sufficient accuracy. After the conclusion of the war Austria suffered from an acute unemployment crisis in 1919, due partly to the labour market being flooded by large numbers of demobilised soldiers, and partly to the difficulty of adapting war industries to peace needs and to the lack of raw materials consequent on the break-up of the Austrian Empire. During the whole of 1919, the figure of unemployed was approximately 120,000; but this first crisis was of short duration, and by May 1920 the number of unemployed in receipt of relief had fallen to 19,000; the figure continued to decrease with some fluctuation, until the end of 1921. This improvement suddenly ceased in November 1921, at a time when the number of unemployed in receipt of relief had fallen to 8,700, the lowest figure reached. — 51 — From December 1921 the number increased rapidly, doubling from month to month until March 1922, when it became stationary a t about 40,000. During the summer, a certain improvement occurred, but towards the end of the year—at a time when the general economic crisis was becoming less acute in other countries—the number of unemployed in receipt of relief in Austria increased progressively from 57,000 in October to 84,000 in November, and to 118,000 in December 1922, finally reaching the maximum figure of 167,415 in the latter part of February, 1923. These fluctuations are shown in greater detail in the table below, which permits a comparison between unemployment movements and those ot prices during the same period. In the absence of any homogeneous statistics concerning wholesale prices, statistics based on retail prices must suffice; those which have been used for this purpose have been published since 1921 in Der österreichische Volkswirt by Mr. Philip Knab, and were drawn up on the basis of a consumption of 2,500 calories per day for an unmarried person living as a sub-tenant in a household of five members 1. Despite these imperfections, the figures in question have the advantage of covering a period sufficiently long to enable the fluctuations in the purchasing power of the crown at Vienna to be followed from month to month. In view of the phenomenon often noted in countries with a depreciated currency, namely, that stable foreign currencies have at times a higher purchasing power abroad than in their own country, an attempt has been made to take this fact into account by converting the Austrian index number of prices into dollar prices at the current rate of exchange. Thus, a fall in the index number expressed in dollars corresponds to an increase in the purchasing power of the dollar at Vienna, together with that of other currencies whose rate of exchange followed closely that of the dollar. 1 For this reason, the figures showing the amoint of rent included in Mr. Knab's index must be accepted with caution, since the rent may have been charged to the sub-tenant or modified at the will of the householder, whereas during the whole period under review the general level of rents has been regulated by law and has remained almost constant. Thus, in Mr. Knab's index, rent represents about one-fifth of the total, whilst according to the calculations of the joint commission on wage adjustments it should only figure as one-eightieth of the total if due account be taken of the legal regulation imposed. (See: Die Industrie, No. 1, 1924.) — 52 — STATISTICS OF UNEMPLOYMENT AND MOVEMENTS OF PRICES IN AUSTRIA. Date (commencement of month) 1920 Number of unemployed in receipt of relief Index numbers of prices In paper crowns In terms of dollars — — — — — — — — — — Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 69,427 61,851 53,999 45,833 19,155 22,403 23,970 22,705 19,768 14.733 16,073 — — — — — — — — — — 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 16,637 16,219 14,527 9,801 9.518 10,105 10,935 11,700 11,345 10,591 8,710 9,829 100 110.24 123.95 130.62 139.99 143.93 160.38 146.91 191.20 242.36 400.33 663.33 0.240 0.275 0.310 0.364 0.384 0.294 0.224 0.175 0.171 0.120 0.140 0.264 1922 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 16,687 33,642 41,761 42,261 44,275 38,563 33,486 30,971 31,243 37,999 57,304 84,283 989.21 1,444.53 1,672.85 1,725.40 1,988.78 2,726.18 3,671.52 7,132.22 16,548.40 20,550.80 21,352.20 20,537.18 0.297 0.432 0.260 0.221 0.220 0.189 0.146 0.147 0.224 0.280 0.294 0.280 1923 Jan. Febr. March April 118,525 161,225 167,415 152,828 19,932.18 20,130.19 20,070.35 20,376.62 0.280 0.280 0.280 0.280 From 1920 until the beginning of 1923, labour market conditions passed through three main phases in Austria: from the end of 1920 to November, 1921, an almost continuous decrease in the number of unemployed; from November 1921 to May 1922, the first stage of depression, followed by a period of comparative stability during the summer of 1922; finally, from October 1922 — 53 — onwards, the development of the crisis, attaining its culminating point in March 1923. The fact that Austria was scarcely affected by the general unemployment crisis from which nearly all other countries were suffering from 1920-1922 may be explained by the continuous and almost complete depreciation of its currency, due to incessant inflation. The Austrian crowrn, the par value of which is 1.05 gold irancs, was quoted at Zurich at 42 Swiss centimes on 31 October, 1918, when the Monarchy collapsed. The rapidity with which it depreciated until it touched the minimum figure of .00007 Swiss francs in August 1922 is well known. It was at this date that the intervention of the League of Nations occurred. This inflation of Austrian currency was reflected by a rapid upward movement in prices; and the first result oi this tendency was a great increase of industrial activity in Austria and a consequent diminution in the number of unemployed. The continual rise in prices constituted a powerful stimulus to production, on the one hand, while on the other, the incessant depreciation of the currency destroyed all possibility of saving, and led to the immediate conversion of all available money into goods \ Moreover, although the rise in prices, expressed in paper crowns, seemed to adapt itself almost immediately to the depreciation of the currency, this rise only took effect with a considerable time-lag as regards Austrian prices expressed in a stable external currency —-the phenomenon already alluded to. The advantage of the foreign trader in buying crowns and converting them immediately into Austrian goods tended considerably to favour exports, and the results of this bonus on exports are to some extent reflected in the curve of unemployment. It will be seen that during periods when the margin between the internal and external purchasing power of the currency was the widest, unemployment was decreasing. Thus unemployment attained its maximum dimensions in November 1921, at a time when prices, expressed in paper crowns, were four times as high as in January of the same year: when expressed in dollars, however, they were only 50 per cent. of their value in January. Similarly, the decrease in the number of unemployed, which occurred during the period April-August 1922, corresponds to the existence of a very wide margin between prices in Austrian paper currency and prices expressed in dollars. 1 LEAGUE OF NATIONS: The Financial Reconstruction of Austria. Report of the Financial Committee to the Council. Report of the Delegation sent to Vienna by the Financial Committee, p. 21. — 54 — It should also be noted, however, that this relationship was only intermittently apparent, and was subject to exceptions during the period under review. On the one hand, in April and in May 1921, although unemployment was diminishing, the purchasing power of the dollar at Vienna was at the same time decreasing; and, on the other, from October 1922 to April 1923, during the most acute period of the crisis, the purchasing power of the dollar at Vienna remained at the level it had attained during the months immediately preceding the crisis, although the number of unemployed quadrupled during this period. It would therefore appear that the stimulus to foreign trade due to depreciated exchange was not the only, factor which affected the Austrian labour market, and that others of an internal character must also be taken into account. In addition to the joint effect of currency depreciation and the rise in prices, account must also be taken of the fact that the difficulty of securing raw materials experienced by Austria after the armistice began to play a less important part at the end of 1920. and in 1921. Relations had been re-established by various commercial treaties with neighbouring countries which possessed the raw materials needed by Austria and formed its chief markets. No general statistics of production for the period under consideration are available, but the increase in the production of steei from 198,497,400 kilograms in 1920 to 293,881,600 kilograms in 1921 may be quoted as an example of this tendency. After a certain time, however, the inevitable results of inflation began to make themselves felt: and having for a long time been a stimulus to production, the continual inflation became itself ultimately a cause of unemployment. The rise in prices continued at an ever increasing rate, the prices of certain articles even exceeding those prevailing in world markets; in February 1922, prices expressed in dollars were nearly double those in January 1921, and the margin between the internal purchasing power of the croAvn and the external value of Austrian currency, which had acted as a stimulus to exports, no longer existed. In Austria itself, the general tendency for the depreciating currency to be converted immediately into tangible goods, developed into feverish speculation: and capital was also diverted from productive undertakings to speculative purposes. Capital was invested in foreign currencies, which instead of being employed for the purchase of raw materials (which owing to the depreciation of currency were continually increasing in price) were no longer available as — 55 — purchasing power on the Austrian market. It was at this period, from December 1921 onwards, that unemployment began to develop. This first phase of the crisis, however, was relatively short. During the summer of 1922 when there was a considerable bonus on exports, due to the margin between the purchasing power of the currency at home and abroad, the figures of unemployment decreased by nearly 30 per cent., remaining stable until November 1922, when the intervention of the League of Nations for the financial reconstruction of Austria took place. At that date inflation ceased suddenly and the Austrian crown was stabilised. Prices comparatively also became stable and the external purchasing power of Austrian currency tended more and more to equal that of its purchasing power in the home market, thus no longer providing a stimulus to export. This phenomenon was accompanied by the continued depreciation of the German mark, which increased the competitive power of Germany and raised the value of the Austrian crown in terms ot the mark. After October unemployment increased rapidly, attaining its highest point in March 1923 when there were 167,000 unemployed in receipt of relief. The manner in which the stabilisation of the currency resulted in removing the bonus on exports and thus restricting the Austrian foreign market can easily be understood. As regards the internal effects of the stabilisation of prices, attention has already been drawn to the general tendency existing in periods of rising prices to convert available currency into goods and thus constitute reserves of stocks. As soon as prices are stabilised, this fever of "conversion" is checked, demand falls off, and there is general stagnation of the market until stocks have been exhausted. Moreover, the stabilisation of prices removes the stimulus to production resulting from the high profits which can be realised during a period of inflation. Immediately the rise of prices is checked, there is a general tendency for all the undertakings which had only been able to come into existence under the stimulus of rising prices to collapse. On the whole, therefore, the conclusion may be drawn that the movement of prices in Austria, as in other countries, constituted an essential factor in the evolution of the labour market. Further evidence of its importance is revealed by the fact that prices in Austria did not follow the same curve as in the countries which have just been examined, and that the unemployment crisis also occurred at a different period. — 56 — CZECHOSLOVAKIA As in the case of Austria, the course of unemployment in Czechoslovakia was very distinctive. While unemployment in all Western European countries increased in 1921, it declined in Czechoslovakia. A relatively high minimum of 62,610 unemployed workers was reached in October 1921. During the first half of 1922 the volume of unemployment was still comparatively small, but it increased very rapidly after August, reaching a total of 436,000 at the end of the year, or four times the figures at the beginning of 1922. The number of wage-earners in Czechoslovakia being 4 million, this total indicates that approximately 11 per cent, of the workers were unemployed. The following table shows the fluctuations in detail and compares them with changes in the index number of prices. Date (end of month) 1921 1922 Number of unIndex numbers of wholesale prices 1 employed registered in the Professor Official employment exchanges Mildschuh's index i index 2 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 95,254 105,341 102,180 99,896 107,934 103,170 95,920 90,812 70,780 62,160 67,79.6 78,312 1,460 1,317 1,323 1,326 1,270 1,259 1,361 1,653 1,654 1,681 1,674 1,595 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 112,323 141,730 127,599 124,406 113,877 107,147 103,457 140,544 231,641 316,532 375,593 436,710 1,470 1,458 1,479 1,477 1,455 1,440 1,388 1,198 1,090 1,088 1,039 — — — — — — — — — — 1,520 1,552 1,491 1,471 1,471 1,464 1,386 1,155 1,059 1,017 999 1,003 1.019 1 The index number for the first day of each month has been taken as applicable to the2 last day of the previous month, so as to correspond with the unemployment statistics. Base: July 1914 = 100. — 57 — The parallelism between the movements ol prices and unemployment already observed for the other countries is also very clearly marked in Czechoslovakia. Prices, which in 1921 were 14.5 times as high as in 1914, fell slightly until June 1921, after which they increased rapidly, and the level reached in October 1921 was 16.8 times that of 1914. This month was also the date of minimum employment. In a general way it may be said that, apart from a slight depression in the period from April to July, 1921 was a year of rising prices and decreasing unemployment. At the beginning of 1922 the situation was reversed. Prices fell continuously and unemployment, apart from certain seasonal fluctuations, increased steadily, rising during the year from 112,000 to 436,000. The changes in prices were accompanied by corresponding fluctuations in the rate of exchange which alternately tended to restrain and stimulate export trade. From the end of 1921 till the end of 1922 the Czechoslovak koruna tripled in value on the New York Exchange, rising from 1.2 cents to over 3 cents. There must doubtless have been some relationship between this movement and the monetary policy of Czechoslovakia. After a period of inflation during which the fiduciary currency increased, reaching over 12 milliard koruna, a process of deflation took place, as a result of which the note circulation was brought down to about 10 milliard koruna at the end of 1922. Furthermore, the rapid appreciation of the koruna may have been due also to the floating oi loans in New York, London and Amsterdam and to the balancing of the national budget. The rise in the external value of Czechoslovak currency may have influenced the labour market in two ways. On the one hand by stimulating import, and by restraining export through the competitive disadvantage suffered by Czechoslovak merchants, it would tend to reduce employment within the country. In the second place, by turning the tide of investment towards Czechoslovakia instead of away from that country, it would accentuate the tendency for imports to exceed exports, thereby still further aggravating the internal situation. The depreciation of the koruna both at home and abroad which had tended to stimulate export during 1921 was no longer effective in 1922; on the contrary, Czechoslovak trade suffered restraint in 1922 through the appreciation of its currency. Thus it is to be seen that from 1921 to 1922 the value of Czechoslovak exports — 58 — fell by 30 per cent, from 27,312 million koruna to 18,086 million koruna. This fall may be attributed in part to the decline of prices, as would appear from the statistics of the weight of exports. These figures fell only slightly, the monthly average in 1922 being 791,000 metric tons, as compared with 812,000 in 1921. The fall in prices may not by itself explain the reduced value of exports. It might also be attributed to changes in the nature of the articles exported; that is to say, to an increase in the exports of raw materials as compared with those of manufactured goods. It should further be recalled t h a t the rise in the Czechoslovak koruna took place at the same time as the continued depreciation of the German mark, and t h a t this, combined with a certain similarity in the production of the two countries, may have enabled Germany to compete seriously with Czechoslovakia in world markets. This factor of foreign competition is of considerable importance in a country in which export industries are as developed as in Czechoslovakia. According to Professor Mildschuh, author of one of the index numbers of prices given above, one of the causes of fluctuations in exports, and therefore in unemployment, was the alternately too low and too high purchasing power of the Czechoslovak koruna abroad. In an article published in Industrial and Labour Information 1 he describes the comparative prosperity of the first half of 1921, and notes t h a t in May of t h a t year the under-valuation of the koruna as compared with the pound sterling was 68 per cent., and as compared with the dollar 42 per cent. This acted as a stimulus for foreign buyers, and by its effect on industries working for export, helped to bring down the number of unemployed. Towards the end of 1921 the position changed. Prof. Mildschuh writes as follows: The mark began to fall rapidly, and the Czechoslovak exchange rate thenceforward followed an independent course. Fluctuations of the exchange have become less acute, and prices have stabilised themselves. Thus, during the first half of 1922 the koruna ranged between 8 and 10 Swiss centimes. Prices fell slightly until they reached the level of 14% times pre-war prices. The value of the koruna abroad and its home purchasing power approximately balanced. According to my calculations the disproportion between the home purchasing power of the koruna and the dollar completely disappeared in December 1921, and the difference as compared with the pound sterling fell to 13 per cent. In spite of this, exports did not diminish, and unemployment did not increase to any extent. 1 Vol. V, No. 13, pp. 614 et seq. — 59 — In the second half of 1922, far-reaching changes in the situation occurred. The exchange rate of the koruna began to rise rapidly, reaching a maximum on 29 August 1922 when the koruna was quoted at 19.70 on the Zurich exchange. The exchange rate of the koruna was too high in comparison with other currencies. According to my calculations this over-valuation amounted on 12 September 1922 to 34 per cent, as compared with the pound sterling, 46 per cent, as compared with the dollar, 61 per cent, as compared with the lira and 145 per cent, as compared with the German mark. It was at this period that the cost of living in Prague was highest. The consequences of the situation were, of course, the contrary of those described above. Exportation was checked and industrial production fell. There was a great increase of unemployment from August 1922 onwards, as will be seen from the tables given above. The change in the situation was, however, in some ways beneficial, as foreign goods could be obtained much more cheaply and the cost of living in Czechoslovakia was therefore reduced. This was followed by a reduction of wages. According to the calculations of the Statistical Office there was a fall in prices from 14% times the pre-war level at the end of the first half of 1922 to 10 times the pre-war level at the end of the year. As the result of the fall in prices and wages on the one hand and of the fall in the Czechoslovak exchange rate from 18 centimes on the Zurich exchange in October 1922 to 15 or 16 centimes at the beginning of 1923 on the other, this discrepancy between thé value of the Czechoslovak currency abroad and at home completely disappeared. There appeared in fact a tendency in the opposite direction, the purchasing power of the koruna at home becoming greater than its value abroad. In conclusion it may be said that the striking coincidence between the fluctuations of unemployment and prices which has been noted for the other countries discussed, also appears in Czechoslovakia. Rising prices have accompanied and apparently stimulated high employment. Falling prices have been accompanied by unemployment. Furthermore, to the extent t h a t fluctuating prices may also have been responsible for wider fluctuations in the exchange value of the koruna, they have, in the opinion of several economists, contributed to the dislocation of the export trade. POLAND From the table below, showing unemployment in comparison with prices, foreign trade, and exchange fluctuations, it may be seen t h a t the unemployment crisis from which Poland has been suffering was closely related, both in point of time and character, to those which affected Austria and Czechoslovakia. Just as both these States, together with Germany, were spared an unemployment crisis during the years 1919-1921 (except during the period of demobilisation), in a like manner Poland was affected by the world unemployment crisis only at the end of 1921 and the — 60 — beginning of 1922; nor was this crisis either of an acute character or long duration. Being first evidenced at the end of October 1921, it reached its culminating point at the end of January 1922, when there were approximately 221,000 unemployed. This crisis came to an end as rapidly as it had developed, and in June 1922 the normal level prevailing before the crisis had been again attained. U N E M P L O Y M E N T IN COMPARISON W I T H P R I C E S , EXCHANGE F L U C T U A T I O N S , AND F O R E I G N T R A D E Date (end of month) 1921 1922 1923 Approximate figure on unemployment Index number registers of wholesale of public prices 1 employment exchanges Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 90,000 80,000 88,000 130,000 115,000 95,000 G5,000 70.000 78,000 120.000 178,368 218,368 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Foreign trade Imports (in thousands of metric tons) Exports (in thousands of metric tons) 602 655 586 570 183 200 180 196 234 494 485 667 1,500 926 894 702 410 430 485 461 280 477 438 350 469 271 321 379 119 174 147 168 115 155 195 177 240 221 147 170 221,444 206,442 170,125 148,625 128,916 98,581 85,240 69,455 68,481 61,178 61,674 75,262 592 534 737 751 786 878 1,016 1,358 1,524 2,013 2,756 3,463 813 945 951 933 962 1,082 •1,421 2,104 2,053 3,195 3,925 4,240 386 310 434 455 449 280 336 151 204 214 129 297 234 290 251 340 1,154 1,660 81,184 106,729 114,570 112,755 93,731 76,397 64,563 56,515 52,420 54,923 61,767 67,581 5,447 8,591 9,885 10,589 11,253 18,814 30,700 52,947 73,022 273,800 679,437 1,423,007 7,667 11.465 10,183 i Base: 1914 = 1. 2 Index number of rate of dollar expressed in Polish marks 1 Figures not available. — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — 2 • — — 220 260 300 285 253 290 471 239 204 214 347 189 V-l 5i 1,368 1,469 2,151 1,335 1,464 1,667 1,627 1,600 1,384 1,324 1,085 1,171 — 61 — The close relationship between price movements and unemployment in Poland appears with the same clearness as in neighbouring States. The official index number of wholesale prices has only been calculated since September 1921, but from an examination of figures previously published by Mr. Fiedorowicz, or of the index number for the cost of living, which also shows broadly the fluctuations of wholesale prices, though with a certain delay, it appears that the beginning of 1921, a period which was marked by a decrease in the number of unemployed, was also characterised by a rise in prices. This relationship is so close that even the slight increase in the number of unemployed, which rose from 88,000 in March to 130,000 in April, corresponds to a period when wholesale prices had momentarily ceased to rise, the index numbers for the same months being 42,481 and 40,756 respectively (Index number F). The first symptoms of the unemployment crisis occurred in October 1921; the rise of prices was checked about this time and a rapid decline took place during the succeeding months, until the culminating point of the crisis wras reached. Since that period prices again began to rise, and continued to do so without cessation. The exchange factor, the importance of which has already been noted in the case of Austria and Czechoslovakia, also played a considerable part in the development of economic life in Poland, sometimes acting as a brake, sometimes as a stimulus to exports. For instance, the index number for the value of the dollar at Warsaw which had risen to 1500 in September 1921, the eve of the crisis, fell very rapidly during the succeeding months, finally touching 702 in December 1921. This decline of the value of the dollar was evidence of a very general rise in the value of the Polish mark in foreign markets. A similar fall in the index number of the value of the dollar also occurred at the beginning of 1923, at a time when unemployment was slightly on the increase. The movements of foreign trade appear to have reflected somewhat these alternations in the rate of the Polish mark. Both at the end of 1921 during the crisis and at the beginning of 1923, when the slight increase in unemployment above alluded to occurred, a rise in the Polish mark took place and was accompanied by a sharp decline in exports. It should be noted, however, that the decrease in exports may in part be due to difficulties of transporting certain goods, such as wood, by water, during the winter season. An apparent contradiction in the relationship between price movements and unemployment, similar to that previously noted — 62 — in the course of these studies, is to be observed from the fact that during the period from February to April 1923, at a time when unemployment was on the increase, prices were nevertheless rising somewhat. It will be seen, however, that the rate of rise of prices slackened very noticeably at the time, when unemployment was increasing. The same phenomenon as was observed in connection with Austria may also have played a part namely, that after a certain stage, currency inflation, which had previously acted as a stimulus to exports, ceases to exercise this effect on account of its very exaggeration. In the present case, account should also be taken of the parallel and continuous fall of the German mark, and the consequent increase in German competitive power, which appear to have contributed to the continuance of the Polish crisis. A certain recrudescence of unemployment was to be observed at the end of 1923 and at the beginning of 1924; this new development coincided with the measures taken by the Polish Government for stabilising the national currency. The textile and mining industries were most seriously affected during this outbreak of unemployment. However, the total number of unemployed did not exceed 114,000 in February 1924, a level which had been reached in the course of the previous winter during the seasonal depression. Reports of the situation in March and April indicate that some improvement is already evident. GERMANY The general wave of unemployment did not reach Germany until 1923, three years after Japan and the United States, and much later than the other Central European countries discussed above. In 1919, Germany, in common with all the belligerent countries) suffered a certain degree of unemployment as a result of post-war readjustments. The number of unemployed in receipt of State relief at the beginning of the year was over a million, while the proportion of trade union members totally unemployed was 6.6 per cent. The subsequent months witnessed a rapid recovery, and since then the curve of unemployment continued to fall steadily, apart from minor fluctuations due to seasonal unemployment in — 63 — winter, the absolute minimum being reached in June and July 1922, with only 0.6 per cent workers unemployed 1. During the whole of 1920, 1921, and 1922 unemployment was very slight, and the premonitory symptoms of the crisis did not appear until the beginning of 1923. The development was somewhat gradual at first, but became more defined as the percentage of unemployed continued to rise, even after the usual period of seasonal fluctuation. Since then, apart from a slight fall in JuneJuly 1923, the proportion of unemployed among trade union members rose continuously until a maximum of 28.2 per cent of totally unemployed was reached in December 1923. At the same date 42 per cent of the trade union members were partially unemployed, and the total number of workers in receipt of State relief was 5 million, of whom 3.5. million were in non-occupied Germany. The table below shows these fluctuations in same detail, and permits a comparison with changes in the index number of wholesale prices and the rate of the dollar on the Berlin exchange. The actual rate quoted for the dollar is given (nominal value), and also its value as a means of purchasing goods in Germany (real value). The comparison of the unemployment percentage with the index number of prices shows the same correlation as has been observed in the case of the other countries discussed. Prices consistently describe the inverse curve to that of unemployment, rising when unemployment falls. Each time there is a recrudescence of unemployment it is accompanied by a corresponding restraint of the rise of prices. In July 1920, the sudden increase in unemployment to 6 per cent. was accompanied by a rapid decline of prices from 16 times to 13.37 times their pre-war level. Moreover, these figures reproduce only imperfectly the total movement, which was partially concealed by the discontinuance of State control of prices. Movements in the exchange rate, which appear to be closely related to those of prices, show that during this period, the dollar rate which had risen from 65 marks in January to 99 marks in February, was as low as 39 marks in July 1920, the date of the outbreak of unemployment in question. 1 According to the author of the Indexzahlen der Frankfurter Zeitung, the increase of unemployment to 6 per cent, in July 1920 and its maintenance at a fairly high figure until the end of the year, were due partly to political reasons, more particularly the "Kapp Putsch", and partly to the temporary rise of the German n ark, the effects of which will be discussed later. (Cf. op. cit., Aug. 1921, p. 28.) _.. 64 — UNEMPLOYMENT IN COMPARISON WITH PRICES AND EXCHANGE Date (end of month) Percentage unemployed in t r a d e unions Totally unemployed Partially unemployed 1919 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 6.6 6.0 3.9 5.2 3.8 2.5 3.1 3.1 2.2 '2.6 2.9 2.9 1920 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 3.4 2.9 1.9 1.9 2.7 4.0 6.0 5.9 4.5 4.2 3.2 4.1 1921 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 4.5 4.7 3.7 3.9 3.7 3.0 2.6 2.2 1.4 1.2 1.4 1.6 1922 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 3.3 2.7 1.1 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.7 . 0.8 1.4 2.0 2.8 1.6 1.6 1.1 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.8 0.9 2.6 4.7 7.5 8.7 1923 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 4.4 5.5 5.6 7.0 6.2 4.1 3.5 6.3 9.9 19.1 23.4 28.2 12.6 14.9 23.6 28.5 21.7 15.3 14.5 26.0 39.7 47.3 i 47.3 i 42.0 ! 1924 J a n . Febr. March April 26.5 25.1 16.6 10.4 29.9 17.1 9.9 5.8 1 2 3 — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — 1.1 — • 1.3 FLUCTUATIONS Dollar r a t e in Berlin Official index (Par. 1 d o l l a r = 4.20 marks) n u m b e r of wholesale prices (Base: 1913 = 100) ¡Nominal value Real value — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — -— — — — — — -— — • • — • —• — —— — • • — 1,243 1,670 1,671 1,556 1,502 1,381 1,337 1,420 1,469 1,462 1,550 1,437 65 99 84 60 46 39 39 48 58 68 77 73 5.88 4.91 3.81 3.08 2 83 2.89 3.29 3.87 4.65 5.12 5.07 1,435 1,376 1,338 1,326 1,308 1,366 1,428 1,917 2,067 2,460 3,416 3,487 65 61 62 64 62 69 77 84 105 150 263 192 4.51 4.46 4.67 4.79 4.76 5.08 5.37 4 40 5.08 6.11 7.70 5.50 3,665 192 4,103 208 5,443 284 6,355 291 6,458 290 7,030 317 10,059 493 19,202 1,135 28,698 1,466 56,601 3,181 115,101 7,183 147,480 7,589 (thousands) 278 17,970 538 27,915 489 21,186 521 24,457 817 47,670 1,939 109,996 7,479 353,412 94,404 4,620,455 2,394,889 • 98,860,000 709,483,656 252,600,000 72,570,849,600 2,193,600,000 2 126,155,650,000 5.23 5.07 5.23 4.58 4.49 4.52 4.90 5.91 5.11 5.62 6.24 5.15 117.3 116.2 120.7 124.1 6.45 5.00 4.33 4.69 5.83 5.67 4.73 4.89 4.13 — — — 3 Approximate figures. Since December 1923, the dollar has been quoted in gold marks at par. Calculated in gold marks. — —. '— — 65 — A similar though much less marked fall in the index number of prices took place in February-May 1921, a period when the depreciation of the mark was again checked and unemployment remained relatively high. After June the mark again depreciated1 and prices began to rise, the latter movement being accentuated in July and August by the removal of control of the wheat market. Subsequently, the rise continued without a break and was accompanied until the end of 1922 by a reduction in unemployment. At that date it seems that the stimulus to trade provided by the rise of prices began to fail through the very exaggeration of the rise, and that the incessant inflation, as in the case of Austria, became a cause of industrial dislocation and unemployment. It is a frequent phenomenon in countries with a depreciating currency —'discussed already in the case of Austria, — that the rise in prices, which at the beginning of a period of inflation fails to adjust itself sufficiently rapidly to the fall in the exchange value of the currency, in the long run catches up and even exceeds the external depreciation. Thus there is a gradual disappearance of the advantage to foreigners in buying marks for immediate conversion into German goods. Ultimately, German prices have even been placed at a disadvantage. Thus, in July 1920, when unemployment rose to 6 per cent., the real value of the dollar in Berlin, that is to say, its purchasing power in Germany, was only 2.89 marks, or 30 per cent, below par. When unemployment was lower, on the other hand, as for instance in November 1921, the purchasing power of the dollar in Berlin was 7.70 marks, or almost double its par value. Corroboration of this is to be found in the fact that the index number of wholesale prices in gold at that date was 54.5 as compared with the 1913 average of 100*. The stimulus given to German export through the external undervaluation of the mark from 1920 to 1922 thus partly explains the relatively privileged situation of the German market. Certain other factors of an internal character appear also to have contributed very largely to the maintenance of industrial activity. Among these factors reference may be made to the tendency, when prices are rising rapidly and currency is depreciating, to convert such 1 A number of German writers attribute this fall of the mark in the middle of 1921 to the London Conference of 5 May 1921, at which the German reparations payments were fixed; cf. Wirtschaft und Statistik, 1924, No. 1, p. 21, and Die Wirtschaftskurve mit Indexzahlen der Frankfurter Zeitung, Jan. 1922, p. 8. 2 Wirtschaft und Statistik, 1913, No. 11, p. 350. 5 — 66 — currency as soon as possible into commodities of stable value, and to save as little as possible in cash. The belief that home consumption, due to this stimulus and others, was a more important cause of the abnormal activity of the German labour market than was the increase of foreign demand resulting from the depreciation of the mark, is supported by the fact that the period when unemployment reached its minimum, — the summer of 1922, — was also the date when the purchasing power of the dollar in Berlin was at a comparatively low level and consequently reduced the advantage of foreign buyers on the German market. This view would also appear to be confirmed by statistics of export. The year 1922 was the period when the greatest exporting advantage accrued from the external under-valuation of the mark. During 1923 the exporting advantage diminished until it became almost negligible. In spite of this, the year 1923 showed an export level of 506,596,000 gold marks per month as compared with only 330,833,000 in 1922. A further paradoxical circumstance is that the year of small exports, 1922, was one of great internal prosperity and little unemployment; whereas in 1923, with a high figure of exports, unemployment developed rapidly and culminated at the end of the year in the most intense depression. Although the statistics given may be subject to certain inaccuracies, the broad movement of export, compared with that of the exchange rate, would seem to point to the comparatively small influence exchange fluctuations have exerted on foreign trade, and the equally small influence of changes in the volume of exports on the internal market. If it may be assumed, therefore, that external trade has played a minor part in the determination of employment in Germany, still greater emphasis is thrown on the importance of fluctuations in home demand. In certain countries previously examined, and especially in the case of Austria, attention has been drawn to the manner in which a rapid rise of prices causes individual purchasers to invest their depreciating money in goods, merchants to buy up stocks as rapidly as they can in order to avoid the higher price later, and manufacturers to increase their plant with a view to taking all possible advantage of the enormous profits to be made. This continuation of feverish demand from producers and consumers may for a long time spur on industry to greater and greater activity. But there enters also the element of speculation: speculative purchase of goods, speculative extension of enterprise, and speculative buying — 67 — and selling of shares and of currency, all of which tends to introduce a process of industrial disintegration and uncertainty. All such activity can continue so long as the rise of prices remains unchecked, but as soon as this is effected, as it ultimately was in Germany by a process of drastic currency reform, then all enterprise based upon highly speculative calculations must collapse. All merchants who have bought large stocks at high costs in anticipation of. a still higher level of prices, and all manufacturers who have extended their enterprise on the assumption that prosperity would continue unchequered, become involved in serious loss. Bankruptcies and partial liquidations ensue and stocks are hurriedly pressed forward for sale so that they may be realised whilst the market is yet strong. Some fall of prices almost inevitably ensues; the market is glutted with goods; workers are thrown out of employment; and the demand of the consumer and producer alike suddenly contracts. Such are the symptoms of depression, symptoms which have made their appearance in Germany in a most intense form at the end of 1923 and the beginning of 1924. CHAPITRE VI GENERAL SURVEY OF THE OUTBREAK AND DEVELOPMENT OF THE CRISIS The foregoing section of the report has dealt only with the first months of the crisis in the different countries. Consideration will be given later to the period of revival, during which unemployment diminished comparatively soon in certain countries, while in others it continued with the greatest severity. Inasmuch as very few industrial countries have escaped the unemployment crisis, it might justly be termed international. It is striking, however, that the development was not simultaneous in the various countries. Japan and the United States were among the first to be affected, i.e., in the spring or summer of 1920. Whereas in Japan the situation appears to have shown some improvement by the end of the year, in the United States unemployment continued with great severity during the whole of the following year. In nearly all west European countries and in the British Dominions the outbreak of unemployment was not pronounced until the end of 1920. One exception to the general movement stands out, that of Finland, which escaped almost entirely, while other Scandinavian countries, on the contrary, suffered acutely. Moreover, although unemployment remained very high in the majority of west European countries during the whole of 1921, and even in 1922, the crest of the wave was reached much more rapidly in France and Belgium and was followed also by a more rapid subsidence. Finally, most central European countries escaped the crisis in 1921 and were not affected until 1922, 1923, or even 1924. The first deduction which should be drawn from these differences of periodicity is that the more general factors, which have exerted — 69 — an almost constant influence on all the countries under consideration throughout the period in question, cannot be regarded as directly causing the unemployment crisis. As a concrete example, that t f the rupture of economic relations with Russia might be instanced. The isolation of this vast country from the majority of industrial nations cannot fail to have caused serious economic dislocation. It seems clear moreover that the resumption of trade with Russia, which has shown marked progress since 1920, will assist the recovery of certain trades in certain countries. It cannot be said, however, that the absence of economic relations with Russia was one of the predominant causes of the unemployment from which the world suffered from 1920 to 1923. For during the period when unemployment was universally of little extent, i.e., 1919-1920, imports into Russia were at their lowest level; whereas in the subsequent period when depression was widespread, imports into Russia were showing a marked increase. It is to be seen from the Enquiry into Production1 that, as compared with 100 in 1913, the index of imports into Russia was 0.044 in 1919, 2.1 in 1920, 15.3 in 1921 and 19.9 in 1922. It has been noted in the review of the situation by countries that unemployment developed at different times in different countries. Now since these developments were accompanied by no new decline in trade relations with Russia, it would be impossible to attribute the unemployment primarily to such a cause. The same argument applies to the problems of reparations, inter-allied debts, and the question of the economicre construction of certain central European countries. Indisputable though the influence of these factors on the labour market may be, they cannot be considered the immediate cause of the outbreak of unemployment. The development of the latter in different countries at different dates cannot be explained by factors which have had a practically constant influence throughout the world at all periods. The most striking feature of the foregoing survey is, however, the singularly close correlation observed in all countries between fluctuations in prices and unemployment'. The decline of employment in the United States in the summer of 1920 took place imme1 1 Enquêté sur la Production, tome III. Attention has been drawn to this correlation in the introduction to the general report of the Enquiry into Production (vol. I. pp. 81-89) in respect of certain countries, for 1920 and the first half of 1921. The results of the present investigation all confirm, for the period following, the observations already made, besides extending them to several other countries. BUREAU INTERNATIONAL DU TRAVAIL: — 70 — diately after the break in prices. Similarly the increase of unemployment in Great Britain in 1920 accompanied a precipitous decline of prices. The situation was the same in the British Dominions, in Sweden, Norway, Denmark, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Italy, France, and Belgium. All these countries were affected by unemployment at the end of 1920, and in each case the development was heralded and accompanied by a rapid fall in prices. In Finland, on the other hand, where prices remained stable, little unemployment was experienced. Similarly in the central European countries, where the general trend of prices was upwards, unemployment remained slight. In Czechoslovakia, prices fell at the end of 1921, and unemployment increased in 1922. In Austria and Germany the relation between unemployment and prices was slightly different. Here the increase in prices, after having for some time acted as a stimulus to trade, reached such extreme limits through disastrous inflation of currency that it tended to disorganise trade. In brief, it may be stated as a preliminary broad conclusion, to be analysed more carefully later, that the movement of prices and, in particular, a fall following a more or less prolonged rise, seems generally to have been the determining factor in the unemployment crisis in different countries. True, fluctuations in prices are themselves determined by other factors, the monetary factor, for instance. Certain striking evidence has been noted in this connection which will be reviewed later. In turn, monetary policy itself is largely influenced by the important international problems touched on above and shown not to have been the immediate or direct cause of unemployment, though they now appear in the chain of causation as indirect or more distant factors of the crisis. The present researches have merely confirmed this sequence of cause and effect, for the General Assembly of the League of Nations has already proclaimed that the only method of remedying the evils from which the world suffers : "disorganisation of the exchanges, economic chaos and unemployment is to put an end to the uncertainty regarding the means for the restoration of the devastated regions and the settlement of the Inter-Allied debts". The chain of causation connecting the political problems of the war and post-war period with the crises of unemployment which broke out from 1920 to 1923 may broadly be described as follows. In the case of all belligerent countries, and a number of neutral countries, the heavy expenditure entailed on account of political — 71 — dislocation during and after the war led to extensive borrowing by the Governments, which in turn brought about a rapid expansion of bank credit and of currency. This, coupled with the abnormal activity of industrial demand, produced a continuous and violent rise of prices. It appears that it was this inflation of prices which in all instances sowed the seeds of the reaction from which each country ultimately suffered. The outbreak of the crisis invariably synchronised with the adoption of measures for the restraint of this inflation. Thus, in almost every country reviewed above, unemployment followed the rise of prices immediately that rise had been checked (either by the restraint of the expansion of credit, or by the reduction of State expenditure, or both). Measures for monetary reform were adopted in a large number of countries in the course of the year 1920, and in each case where the measures were effective the rise of prices was checked in the same year and the crisis followed immediately after. In the case of Germany and Austria there was no restriction of credit in 1920 and no crisis ensued. Subsequently, when monetary reform was effectively applied in these two countries, the same phenomenon was produced: the restraint of rising prices followed by reaction and widespread unemployment. The various links in the chain of cause and effect may thus be analysed more fully as follows. Political instability led to instability of public finance, extensive Government borrowing and consequent inflation. The rise of prices which marked this inflation constituted the principal factor in the boom period in each country. The checking of the rise of prices put an end to the boom, the depression being the inevitable reaction after the unrestrained expansion. The point to which it is felt necessary to draw particular attention here is the price factor, which constitutes the intermediate link between the great international political problems emphasised by the League of Nations above, and the no less serious problem of unemployment under consideration here. Another important factor examined in the preceding chapters is that of foreign trade, and more especially the fluctuations in exports from the different countries suffering from unemployment. It has been shown that for most countries, and in particular the United States, Great Britain, the Scandinavian countries, Finland, the Netherlands, Belgium, France and Italy, the origin or outbreak of the unemployment crisis could not have been attributed to the failure of foreign demand. This may, on the other hand, have — 72 — been the cause in Switzerland. Moreover, it seems probable that the temporary increase of exports from certain central European countries contributed towards delaying their crises. It remains to be seen what part the reduction of exports may have played in prolonging or aggravating unemployment in other countries, this question being reserved for discussion in greater detail in the second part of the survey. PART II. The Period of Recovery The development of the crisis up to its maximum in the different countries has been discussed in Part I. There remains for examination the nature of its abatement, rapid in some countries, gradual in others. The countries in which revival was relatively rapid were the United States, France, Belgium, and Italy, and the survey will therefore begin with this group. The Central European countries will be considered next, for in these cases the crisis, although late in appearing, was speedily followed by revival. After these will be treated the countries in which the crisis was, on the contrary, both acute and prolonged — Switzerland, the Scandinavian countries and the Netherlands. The final chapter will be devoted to the British Dominions and Great Britain. It has been possible to make a rather more detailed examination of the situation in the latter country, largely as a result of the additional information provided by the recent unemployment conference organised in London by the Labour Section of the British League of Nations Union. As in the first part of the enquiry an attempt has been made, in spite of the complexity of the problem, to throw light on the international similarity of the factors which it is considered have played an essential part, either as a retarding or an accelerating influence, in the revival of employment. CHAPTER I. UNITED STATES, FRANCE, BELGIUM AND ITALY UNITED STATES Following the period of intense depression, of which some account was given in Part I of this Report, the recovery of trade in the United States has been remarkably rapid. This fact does not fail to find its reflection in unemployment returns. In the State of Massachusetts, for instance, the percentage of unemployment reported by trade unions fell from 20.0 in September 1921 to 3.8 in September of the following year. Percentage Unemployment in Trade Unions in Massachusetts. Date March June Sept. Dec. 1921 1922 1923 22.2 20.6 20.0 25.0 20.5 12.7 3.8 10.5 6.2 5.1 3.8 11.8 The employment index numbers given by the United States Bureau of Labour Statistics and the State of New York also show a remarkable recovery during 1922. — 75 — INDEX NUMBERS OF EMPLOYMENT AND WHOLESALE PRICES FOR 1922 AND 1923 Employment 1 Employment 1 Date 1922 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sent. OcL Nov. Dec. U.S. Bureau of New Labour York Statis- State tics 79 79 76 "76 78 80 84 84 85 89 89 91 81 82 82 82 84 86 86 90 89 92 93 95 Wholesale prices2 138 141 142 143 148 150 155 155 153 154 156 156 Date 1923 J a n . Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec. U.S.Bureau of New Labour York Statis- State tics 94 93 95 96 97 97 98 99 1 Base: average for 1919 = 100. Seasonal variation eliminated. Review oj Economic Statistics, Harvard, Oct. 1923. 2 Bureau of Labour Statistics. Base: 1913 = 100. 95 96 97 98 98 98 98 98 96 Wholesale prices2 156 157 159 159 156 153 151 150 154 153 152 151 Reproduced from T h e following e x t r a c t from t h e Federal Reserve Bulletin of M a y 1923 indicates t h e e x t e n t t o w h i c h this r e c o v e r y w a s reflected in t h e d e v e l o p m e n t of p r o d u c t i o n a n d general i n d u s t r i a l a c t i v i t y . In fact, the growth in the physical volume of production since the middle •of 1921 indicates a rate of industrial recovery almost without parallel in American business. Within a year and a half after recovery began the monthly output of 21 basic commodities, as measured by the Federal Reserve Board's index of production, increased over 67 per cent. The volume of goods produced and consumed during the first quarter of 1923 probably exceeds that of any similar period in the history of the country. Fuller employment of equipment and of labour has produced the additional income from which profits and wages •were realised. In fact, profits in many lines of industry have been dependent upon quantity production, the lower production cost per unit more than offsetting the increased cost of materials. It is partly in consequence of Jarger output that the prices of manufactured goods have not more fully reflected the increases in prices of raw materials. Larger pay rolls, also, until •quite recently have resulted chiefly from increased employment rather than from advances in wage rates. These increases in production and employment have thus far economically justified the increases in the total volume of bank credit. For credit extension does not result in over-expansion so long as the additional credit yields proportionate results in the larger production and marketing of goods. T h i s m o v e m e n t of recovery, following t h e d e e p depression, finds little reflection in e x p o r t r e t u r n s . I t will b e r e m e m b e r e d t h a t in t h e s u r v e y of t h e earlier p a r t of t h e crisis, e x p o r t statistics a p p e a r e d t o s h o w t h a t t h e origin of t h e u n e m p l o y m e n t depression — 76 — in the United States could not be attributed to the failure of foreign markets, since the volume of exports remained high for some seven months after the outbreak of the crisis. The annual statistics of export for the subsequent years give evidence of some decline in export trade during 1921 and of a much more serious diminution during 1922 and 1923. Such movements would tend to show that the influence of export trade on the general condition of the labour market in the United States is of minor importance; for there is little or no correlation between export returns and the movement of unemployment. The year 1921, with comparatively hight totals of export, was the period of most serious depression, whereas 1922 and 1923, with poor export trade, were marked by rapid recovery to a position of record production in the spring of 1923. EXPORT-TRADE FROM THE UNITED STATES Year 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 Price index number of Export Exports (monthly average) in dollars (000's omitted) (Fed. Res. Board) Recorded value Value calculated on basis of 1913 prices i 100 235 136 157 183 204,024 673,373 364,911 313,758 341,141 2 204,024 286,542 268,317 199,846 186,416 1 Example: In calculating the value of exports on the basis of 1913 prices, the recorded value of the merchandise is multiplied by i 00 and divided by the index number of the price of exported goods. Hence, for 1920 the 1913 monthly average value of the exports, i.e., 286,542,000 dollars = 673,373,000 X 100 4- 235. An estimate of this nature is only approximate, particularly in years when there are wide fluctuations in both prices and the monthly volume of exports. However, it affords a better measure of the true movement of export than is given by the totals actually recorded. 2 Provisional figure. As in the case of the early stages of the American crisis discussed in the first part of this report, a close relationship between the movement of prices and that of employment is also to be found during the subsequent period of revival and of stabilisation. From the indices of employment given by the United States Bureau of Labour Statistics, and by certain of the individual States, it is to be seen that a very rapid development of employment took place from the beginning of 1922 to the early summer of 1923, after which there was comparative stability for the rest of the year at the high level attained. Almost identically the same movement is to be observed in wholesale prices. From January 1922 to April 1923, there was a recovery of 15 per cent in wholesale — 77 — prices. In May and June there was a slight decline. A high degree of stability followed for the rest of the year. In the first part of the present report it was seen that movements in the central rate of discount frequently preceded important changes in the trend of business, and appeared in many cases to have some causal influence. In the period of revival of 1922 and 1923, further interesting coincidences of the same nature are to be observed. For instance, the Rediscount Rate of the Federal Reserve Banks was lowered by stages from 7 per cent, in May 1921 to 4 y2 per cent, in November 1921. Recovery of trade followed, being particularly marked as from the beginning of 1922. In June 1922 the Rediscount Rate was reduced still further to 4 per cent, and was maintained at that figure until recovery was almost complete. Such, then, was the situation prior to and during the period of revival: the price of credit low; the fall of prices checked; finally, a marked recovery of prices. Previous experience in almost all countries, and particularly in the United States, has shown that a rise in prices, if carried beyond a certain stage, becomes a danger rather than an advantage. Once the available forces of production are very fully employed, easy credit and rising prices can no longer be effective in stimulating further considerable increases of output. On the contrary, they tend to disorganise industry by introducing a tendency to speculative purchase and enterprise, negligence and mismanagement, factors which themselves cause immediate loss of economy and ultimately intensify depression. There was a very widespread appreciation in the United States that the period of healthy recovery of 1922 and early 1923 might, if unrestrained, develop into an inflationary boom giving rise to the same reactions as were experienced after the 1919-1920 boom. To what extent this fear inspired the action of public bodies is difficult to estimate. That certain restraints were applied is, however, unquestioned. In the first place, the rediscount rates of the Federal Reserve Banks were raised to 4 y2 per cent, in February 1923, one month before the culmination of wholesale prices. The restraining influence on the expansion of credit exerted by this measure was reinforced by the reduction on the part of Federal Reserve Banks of their earning assets. Through the sale of securities amounting to 435 million dollars in value, during the year ending 20 June 1923 l , the Federal Reserve Banks were able 1 See Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1923, p. 719. — 78 — to reduce considerably the cash basis of member banks and limit still further the expansion of credit. In addition to these financial measures, other forces were apparently being applied with a view to preventing the period of desirable expansion from developing into an inflationist boom. Professor Irving Fisher states, for instance, in an article contributed to the Manchester Guardian Commercial of 8 June 1923: It is a satisfaction to see that the rapid rise of prices has been checked. This was apparently due to a determined effort to check it. The rise of the discount rate by several of the Federal Reserve Banks, the warning of Mr. Hoover against reckless inflation, and the combined efforts of Mr. Franklin Roosevelt and the banks to limit loans for speculative building — the point where inflation was most active •— must have tended in this direction. This all indicates that inflation and deflation can be controlled, and also that, to control it, the information given by the index number is essential. Even though the results of these measures may appear somewhat fortuitous in part, they none the less form a suitable example for any country in the midst of depression to follow. The fortunate precedent of the United States would seem to show that, in the first place, every facility should be given to trade expansion by the easing of credit during the period of revival, and that, secondly, as soon as industry has recovered a high pitch of activity and absorbed to a large extent the available supplies of labour, an attempt should be made to stabilise. FRANCE It has already been seen that the unemployment crisis attained its culminating point in France in March 1921 when more than 90,000 unemployed were in receipt of relief. The acuteness of this crisis diminished rapidly as is shown by the following table: NUMBER Month March June Sept. Dec. OF UNEMPLOYED IN RECEIPT OF RELIEF 1921 1922 1923 91,000 47,000 22,000 10.000 8,000 5,000 3,000 2,000 1,900 1,000 500 650 — 79 However inadequate these figures may be considered a priori, they are confirmed by the parallel movement of the index number of industrial activity established by the Société d'études et d'informations économiques \ This index number is based on a combination ol twenty different components, including production of coal, iron ore, pig iron, steel; imports of coal, mineral oils, raw wool and raw cotton; exports of cotton thread, linen goods and automobiles ; railway and canal traffic ; loans and discounts of the Bank of France, etc., calculated on a basic figure of 100 for 1923, and covering the whole extent of existing French territory. This index number rose from 58.15 for the first quarter of 1919 to 89.9 for the last quarter of 1920, afterwards falling during the three following quarterly periods to 74.5, 67.9 and 66.1 respectively, subsequently rising rapidly to 81.2 during the last quarter of 1921, and finally attaining 102.2 during the fourth quarter of 1923. This development of industrial activity was accompanied by a continuous rise of prices, which confirms the corresponding relationship previously noted between a fall in wholesale prices and a decrease of industrial activity. The decrease of unemployment and the concurrent development in industrial activity, however, occurred considerably earlier than the corresponding change in the movement of prices : for the latter continued to fall during the first quarter of 1922, subsequently, however, increasing rapidly. INDEX First quarter Second » Third » Fourth » NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE PRICES 1920 1921 1922 1923 532 555 518 475 389 341 342 337 320 325 335 358 419 418 423 450 The general relationship between unemployment and price movements has inspired the following reflections on the part of the Société d'études et d'informations économiques*. 1 See Supplement to the Daily Bulletin of the Society, 17 Dec. 1923: L'évolution de l'activité industrielle de la France depuis l'armistice. 2 Loe. cit. — 80 — It is both interesting, and instructive to note the simultaneous development of industrial activity and price movements during the whole period of the crisis ; it is a remarkable fact that the fall in prices preceded a diminution of industrial activity, and that this fall should have continued for a certain length of time after signs of a renewal of industrial activity had already been displayed. But this difference in the extent of the two movements appears upon reflection to be perfectly natural. A first effect of the cessation in the rise in prices is a falling off in orders, as purchasers, whose capacity has already become unduly strained owing to the rise, prefer to wait for the effects of the fall: the manufacturer, however, continues to carry on for some weeks on previous orders, and he may even be in the position to produce for stock for a certain length of time as far as his financial reserves allow. Production is, in fact, his « raison d'être » ; and it is only with difficulty that he resigns his faith in the return of better times. For similar reasons, when the crisis appears to have attained its maximum intensity, he endeavours to resume production with all possible speed. In order that his undertaking, always burdened with irreducible overhead charges, may resume activity, the manufacturer endeavours to meet his customers with a view to inducing new orders: for this purpose he is ready to make additional sacrifices, and the diminution in prices may therefore continue after the time when industry has begun to revive ; it is even a necessary condition of such recovery. For these reasons, the depression of prices is of longer duration than that of employment. It would doubtless be unwise to generalise too hastily from the results of one set of experiences alone; however, a comparison of the index number of prices with those of our industrial barometer is not devoid of practical interest. A continued fall in the former constitutes a warning that an economic crisis is ahead; a rise in the index number of industrial activity would on the contrary justify the prediction of a rise in prices in the near future. Finally, a rapid and simultaneous rise in the two figures constitutes a symptom of inflation, in other words, of a state of artificial prosperity which cannot be permanently maintained. This has already been experienced in 1920, and the phenomena which have been noted in 1923 unhappily lead one to draw a similar conclusion. Since last spring, prices have been rising almost continuously; our exchange has been falling, and our industrial index number (the figures shortly to be published will demonstrate this fact) has risen considerably above 100 since August last. Past experience proves that a situation of this nature is not without danger, and that it calls for the greatest prudence. T h e i m p o r t a n c e of t h e s e conclusions for t h e p r e v e n t i o n of u n e m p l o y m e n t scarcely needs e m p h a s i s i n g . I n a d d i t i o n to t h e reasons given a b o v e b y t h e Société d'études et d'informations économiques t o explain w h y a r e s u m p t i o n of i n d u s t r i a l a c t i v i t y precedes a rise in prices, a n o t h e r i m p o r t a n t factor is t o b e n o t e d , n a m e l y , t h e i m p r o v e m e n t in c r e d i t c o n d i t i o n s since J u l y 1921, d u e t o t h e r e d u c t i o n òf t h e d i s c o u n t r a t e from 6 per cent, t o 5 y2 p e r c e n t . F o r it w a s after t h i s m e a s u r e h a d b e e n t a k e n t h a t a rise in t h e i n d e x n u m b e r of i n d u s t r i a l a c t i v i t y w a s first n o t e d . A fresh r e d u c t i o n in t h e d i s c o u n t r a t e t o 5 p e r cent, in — 81 — March 1922 followed, after which the price level showed a general upward tendency, the rate of rise increasing until the first quarter of 1923. Another important factor in the resumption of industrial activity was the state of the exchanges, or more strictly speaking, the undervaluation of French currency in proportion to its effective purchasing power, partly due to exchange speculation. The stimulating influence of this factor on exports has already been noted on several occasions, and French exports, as shown by the following table, increased very considerably during 1922 and 1923, in comparison with the two previous years during which the crisis was prevailing. INDEX NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE PRICES, EXCHANGE FLUCTUATIONS, AND •Year 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 Index number of wholesale prices i 115.6 588.9 398.8 377.6 484.3 EXPORT VALUES. Exports (monthly average) Percentage of undervaluation Value (in thousands of francs) of the franc Weight (in Calculated compared on the basis thousands Recorded of metric with the of price value dollar * tons) index number» 22.3 10.3 7.4 16.8 573,351 2,241,245 1,647,709 1,781,579 2,535,959* 495,978 380,581 413,167 471,816 1,840 1,039 1,336 1,887 2,066 is Basic figure: Average 1901-1910 = 100. The respective purchasing power being-taken into account. a By the same method as already employed in the case of the United States (see p. 76). As noted in the case of America, the method employed yields only approximate results. An additional imperfection in the method used here is that the wholesale price index number used as the basis for calculating the real value of exports comprises articles which do not figure largely in export returns. In spite of these defects the total3 are roughly comparable and are of greater value for this purpose than the absolute figures or recorded value of the exports. * Valued at 1922 official rate3. It seems clear, however, that the increase in exports which took place must be attributed to a greater extent to a real increase in the effective productive power of the country than to the artificial stimulus of the exchange. For, as is shown by the above table, the under-valuation of the franc with reference to the dollar, taking their respective purchasing powers expressed by the price index number into account, was greatest in 1920, at the very time when exports were lowest. It seems unquestionable, nevertheless, 6 — 82 — that this under-valuation continued to exert a certain influence. The question might be justified therefore whether the threatened crisis foreseen by the Société d'études et d'informations économiques as a necessary reaction from the boom of 1922-1923 will not be reinforced when the stimulus to exports disappears in consequence of the improvement in the financial situation. In this connection further interesting suggestions are made by the Société d'études et d'informations économiques1: At the end of the year 1923, France's monthly output of pig iron, steel, and coal exceeded that of 1913. Account must, however, be taken of the inclusion of the production of the mines and factories of Lorraine. But even without the additional output of these recovered areas, the figures are not much below those of 1913. The fact cannot be concealed, however, that our heavy industries have only produced in large quantities because their markets have been good, especially in foreign countries. Now, the increase of sales has been due largely to the continued rise of prices on the internal market and to the relatively good demand for French merchandise abroad, two phenomena which are merely the consequence of the continued depreciation of the franc in 1923 Does it follow, however, that the recent recovery of the franc must, as is sometimes feared, constitute a severe shock to our commerce and industry ? We do not think so. There is no doubt that our industrial activity will suffer to some extent from the appreciation of our currency, but only to a comparatively small extent, provided that this appreciation, after the necessary rebound, does not continue to an exaggerated degree. Finally, an important factor in the recovery of French industry was the continued expenditure of the State on the restoration of devastated areas. A considerable portion of this expenditure has been met, not out of taxation, but out of borrowings; and to the extent that this process of borrowing has led to the greater extension of bank credit, it has meant a corresponding inflation of purchasing power and a general increase of demand, facilitating the revival of industry and the rise in the level of prices. The policy of launching vast government enterprise with the aid of borrowed money would thus appear to provide a valuable stimulus to industry when in deep depression. But when the same policy is continued into the period of prosperity, there seems reason to fear that it may contribute to the intensity of the reaction which inevitably follows a period of over-extension and rising prices. 1 Bulletin quotidien, 25 April 1924. — 83 — BELGIUM The table below shows that from the summer of 1922 the unemployment crisis in Belgium began to subside and that since then the situation on the labour market has been very favourable. PERCENTAGE OF UNEMPLOYED WORKERS (Unemployment fund figures) Month Jan. Febr. March April Mav June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 1921 1922 1923 1924 19.3 22.7 31.5 31.2 32.3 22.9 21.4 21.7 17.7 13.6 13.9 11.4 11.2 10.1 9.2 8.9 7.0 6.0 5.3 4.4 3.8 3.9 3.8 3.8 3.9 3.1 2.6 2.4 3.6 2.6 2.2 1.9 1.5 1.9 2.7 3.6 3.7 3.6 — — — — •— This improvement in employment corresponded to an almost continuous rise in wholesale prices since April 1921. As in France, this upward movement did not start until a few months after unemployment began to diminish. From the end of 1922, during 1923, and until the beginning of 1924, Belgian industry enjoyed a period of boom during which unemployment was reduced to the lowest dimensions. Certain industries even suffered from a shortage of labour, and Belgium, in spite of the extreme density of her population, became a country of immigration as well as of emigration. The Revue du Travail, an official Government publication, stated that, in February 1924, in the mining industry "the shortage of labour was becoming more and more marked and that the mines could not maintain the desired output without employing foreign labour. As compared with a year ago the number of foreign workers (Italian, Polish, Moroccan, Algerian, etc.) employed in the mines had doubled." 1 1 Revue du Travail, 31 March 1924, p. 437. — 84 — INDEX NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE (Base: April 1914 = 100) Month 1922 1923 1924 366 356 350 344 348 . 356 .360 360 364 385 408 407 434 474 482 480 474 484 504 529 514 515 531 545 580 642 625 1921 Jan. Febr. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. — — — — — — 347 368 372 374 369 PRICES — — — — — — — • — The rise in prices corresponded to an almost continuous increase in the circulation of fiduciary currency from February 1921 (6,039 million francs as compared with 6,260 million francs in December 1920) until March 1924 (7,676 million francs), and a rise in the dollar exchange at Brussels which increased from 257.7 per cent. of par in February 1921 to 502.9 per cent, in February 1924, the fluctuations at certain periods being very marked. Simultaneously, the rate of discount was reduced from 5% per cent, to 5 per cent. in May 1921 and to 4% per cent in June 1922, being raised again to 514 per cent, in January 1923. The part played by export trade in the resulting industrial revival is illustrated by the following table. INDEX NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE PRICES, EXCHANGE FLUCTUATIONS, AND Year (monthly average) 1913 1920 1921 Î922 1923 Index number of wholesale prices 1 EXPORT Exports of goods Percentage of undervaluation Value (in thousands of francs) of the Weight franc as Calculated (in compared on the basis thousands Recorded with the of the index of metric 2 value dollar number of tons) prices s 100 5 366* 367 497 VALUES 5.3 14:5 302,882 737,675 605,408 519,636 738,041 302,882 141,590 148,499 1.740 884 1,438 .1,346 1,411 »Base: Average 1913 = 100. 2 The respective purchasing power being taken into account. 8 By the method indicated for France (see p. 81). 4 Average of the last five months. 5 As from May 1922, the export figures relate to the Union économique belgo-luxembourgeoise. — 85 — When it is realised that for part of 1922 and the whole of 1923 the export figures relate not only to Belgium but also to the Grand Duchy of Luxemburg, it is surprising to note that exports were slightly less in 1922 and 1923 than during 1921, the year of depression, in spite of the premium on export in the two later years due to the under-valuation of the Belgian franc, in terms of the dollar. At the same time it will be observed that the volume of exports in 1923, a year of full industrial prosperity, was still well below the 1913 figure. It must therefore be concluded that the solution of the unemployment problem in Belgium was found in the home market. As in France, the boom of 1923 naturally gave rise to serious apprehension as regards the possibility of ultimate reaction. The first effects of such a movement did in fact make themselves felt in April 1924. The movement of prices was reversed, and the exchange value of the Belgian franc, like that of the French franc, improved. According to Le Peuple of 26 April 1924 * "the consequences of this situation will almost inevitably be unemployment in the near future. This has began as usual in luxury industries; diamond workers are out of work for half their time. Certain industries producing for direct consumption, such as boot and shoe factories, are already threatened." ITALY After reaching a maximum of 606,819 in January 1922, unemployment fell fairly continuously in Italy until August 1923, when the number of unemployed was 178,612. The figure subsequently rose to 280,765 in January 1924, but fell again to 259,360 in February and to 218,740 in March, so that this increase would appear to be largely seasonal. The following table ' shows these changes compared with the movement of wholesale prices, fluctuations in which have been comparatively slight during the last two years. Although the rise from May to October 1922 was fairly extensive, exceeding 12 per cent., the subsequent fall until October 1923 was only 6 per cent. and was followed by an insignificant rise. 1 Official organ of the Labour Party. — 86 — Date (end of month) Number of workers totally unemployed Index number of wholesale prices i 1922 Jan. Feb. March April May June July AU£J. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dee. 606,819 576.284 498,606 432,372 410,127 372,001 304,242 317,986 312,714 321,011 354,238 381,968 577.2 562.5 533.4 526.8 523.5 537.4 557.5 571.3 581.7 600.8 596.2 579.6 1923 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 391,974 327,000 280,701 270,214 243,928 216,287 183,144 178,612 180,634 199,694 225.095 258,580 575.3 582.1 586.9 588.4 580.1 568.9 566.0 566.7 569.2 563.4 571.4 577.2 1924 Jan. Feb. March 280,765 259,360 218,740 570.8 572.8 578,7 i Bachi. Base: average 1913 = 100. Thus after the very marked rise of prices in 1919 and the subsequent rapid fall in 1920-1921, accompanied by widespread unemployment, 1922 and 1923 might in general be considered years of stable prices. This period was equally marked by monetary stability, as will be seen from the following table. 1 Year (average) Dollar rate at Rome Circulation of fiduciary currency ! (million lire) 1921 1922 1923 23.28 21.06 21.74 21,476 20,279 19,891 Rate of discount (Per cent.) 6 5.75 5.50 Bank notes plus State notes. This state of monetary stability is the more appreciated when it is seen that the tendency to deflation marked by a moderate reduc- — 87 — tion in fiduciary circulation was diminished by the increase in credit facilities due to the reduction in the rate of discount. The part played by exports in the revival of industrial activity is illustrated by the following table, which shows that exports were comparatively low both in 1921 and 1922, the former year being that in which the unemployment crisis began and the latter that in which it ended. Index number of wholesale prices 1 Year 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 . Percentage of undervaluation of the franc as compared with the dollar 2 100 624.4 577.5 562.3 574.6 41.2 14.3 8.2 12.5 Exports (monthly average) Value (in thousands of lire) Recorded value Calculated on the basis of the index number 3of prices 209,303 981,177 689,584 775,197 921,574 209,303 157,139 119,408 137,861 160,385 i2 Bachi. Base: average 1913 = 100. The respective purchasing power being taken into account. 3 By the method indicated for France (see p. 81). In view of the great importance of emigration in Italy, an attempt has been made to estimate the influence on the general labour market of fluctuations in migration during the last few years. They are shown in the following table : Emigration Repatriation Year Oversea 1920 1921 1922 1923 Continental Total 194,224 153,717 347,941 182,040 60,846 242,886 121,410 123,030 244,440 177,853 170,226 348.079 Oversea Continental 77,599 92,212 54,602 39,680 30,083 55,641 79,498 Total Total emigration less total repatriation 122,295 120,591 110,243 134,197 119,178 228,901 Although exact figures for 1920 are not available, the table shows that the excess of emigration over repatriation was much less marked in 1921 and 1922 (years ol unemployment) than in 1920 and in 1923. The setback to emigration in these two years would therefore appear to have aggravated unemployment. — 88 — In briel, it may be said that unemployment in Italy, following, as elsewhere, the change from rising to falling prices, was accentuated by a reduction in exports and emigration. Now that prices have been stabilised, as in the United States, the labour market would appear to have become normal again. Moreover, although no definite judgment can be given in the matter, it would seem that in Italy there are no symptoms of another crisis such as have been observed in France and Belgium as a reaction from the renewed rise in prices. CHAPTER III CENTRAL EUROPEAN COUNTRIES AUSTRIA As was seen in the first section dealing with Austria, that country was exempted, largely through incessant currency inflation, from the effects of the more general unemployment crisis which prevailed during 1920-1921; and after feeling the first effects of depression at the beginning of 1922, at a time when currency inflation, through its very exaggeration, had ceased to exercise a stimulating effect on trade, it experienced a period of feverish speculation which rapidly forced Austrian prices above the general world level. It was also shown that this crisis became considerably more acute in November 1922, at the time of the intervention ot the League of Nations for Austrian reconstruction, under which the Austrian crown was stabilised and the rise of prices temporarily checked. The culminating point of the crisis was reached in MarchApril 1923. It will be seen from the following table that soon afterwards prices again began to rise, and continued rising during the following months, though at a very much slower rate than formerly. Foreign trade Date 1 Number of unemployed in receipt of relief Trice index: paper crowns Value (in millions of gold crowns) Imports | Exports 1923 May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 132,000 109,002 92,789 87,155 83,891 78,801 75,810 77,782 23,032.09 23,280.03 24,457.13 23,284.57 23,909.12 24,408.60 25,376.71 27,086.69 98,192 116,755 122,823 134,981 137,907 141,635 169,029 265,985 71,241 70,896 76,921 87.331 79,518 82,930 83.807 120,638 1924 Jan. Feb. March April 98.069 119,613 125,816 106,264 27,776.07 29,813.22 30,110.00 164,237' 164,237' 70,451' 70,451' Monthly average for the two months. — 90 — Concurrently with this recovery of prices, a decrease in unemployment took place, and the end of the year 1923 may be described as a period of slow but steady improvement. The number of unemployed at the beginning of November was less than half that of the worst period of the crisis; and though a slight increase in their number occurred during December 1923 and the beginning of 1924, this fact may be attributed partly to seasonal causes. The examination of export figures shows that they increased fairly regularly during the whole of 1923 ; but the monthly average remained lower than it had been during the preceding year when the stimulus due to the margin between the internal and external purchasing of the crown had been exercising its full effects. CZECHOSLOVAKIA After reaching a maximum in December 1922-January 1923, unemployment diminished fairly rapidly during 1923. The gradual improvement in the labour market is shown in detail in the following table: Date Total number of unemployed registered at the employment exchanges on the last working day of the month Official index number of wholesale prices (Base: 1913 = 100) 1923 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 441,075 415,222 369,420 310,683 273,234 246,616 216,720 197,644 210,535 176,333 177,367 191,978 1,019 1,028 1,031 1,030 1,001 968 958 957 973 964 984 990 1924 Jan. Feb. . March 193.105 195,872 180,002 1,029 1,036 1,022 The index number of wholesale prices remained relatively stable, the fluctuation between the two extremes being not more than 7.5 per cent. This stability in prices was paralleled by similar stability in the Czechoslovak rate of exchange which varied very little during 1923, ranging on the Zurich Exchange between 16 — 91 — and 17 Swiss francs for 100 koruna. The very frequent adjustment of the rate of discount, which was lowered from 5 per cent. at the beginning of 1923 to 4% per cent, in May, then raised to 5 y2 per cent, in November and lowered again to 5 per cent, at the beginning of 1924, is of interest in that it may have contributed towards this stability of the koruna on the exchanges. Similarly there was very little fluctuation in the circulation of fiduciary currency, which amounted to 9,222 million koruna at the beginning of 1923, rose to 9,599 million koruna in December 1923, and was again reduced to 8,506 millions in February 1924. This rapid diminution of unemployment and the general stability of prices, rates of exhange, and circulation of fiduciary currency which accompanied it, indicating in general a sound financial situation, did not lead to the development of foreign trade which might have been expected. This may be shown by the following table: Year 1922 1923 Index number of wholesale prices i 1,355 992 Exports (monthly average) Percentage of overvaluation Value (in thousands of koruna) Weight of the (in koruna as Calculated thousands compared on basis Recorded of metric with the of 1914 value tons) dollar 2 prices 3 — 7.59 + 6.52 1,507,196 1.043,218 111,232 105,163 791 942 2» Official. Base: 3 The respective 1914 = 100. purchasing power being taken into account. By the method already indicated for France (see p. 81). GERMANY It has already been shown that the unemployment crisis, from which Germany had hitherto been exempt, developed in that country at the end of 1923, and some indication has been given of the principal causes affecting the depression. The first figures available for 1924 prove that the culminating point of the crisis was reached in December 1923, when the figure of total unemployed among members of trade unions attained 28 per cent. During January, February and March 1924 a considerable diminution .occurred in this percentage, accompanied by a rise in the index number for wholesale prices; this double movement is shown by the following table: — 92 — . Date 1924 Jan. Feb. March Percentage of unemployed among members of trade unions Total Partial 26.5 25.1 16.6 29.9 17.1 9.9 Index number of wholesale prices Frankfurter Zeitung. Base: 1 July 1914 = 1 (in milliards) Official figure. Base: . 1913 = 100 gold marks 1,430 1,470 1,584 117.3 116.2 120.7 Although the absence of adequate information respecting the export trade at the beginning of 1924 renders it difficult to draw any definite conclusions, it would appear that the improvement which occurred in the labour market was due less to an increase of export, which suffered some handicap through the high level of German prices and, in a lesser degree, through the temporary depreciation of the French franc during February and March 1924, than to increased purchasing power in Germany itself. For whereas exports decreased from an average monthly figure of approximately 545 million gold marks during the last quarter of 1923 (the most acute period of the crisis) to 430 million gold marks during January 1924, imports on the contrary increased by more than 20 per cent., from a monthly average of 452 million gold marks during the last quarter of 1923, to 565 million gold marks in January 1924. CHAPTER III SWITZERLAND, SCANDINAVIA, FINLAND, AND THE NETHERLANDS SWITZERLAND The unemployment crisis in Switzerland was slow in its development, for it started in the autumn of 1920 and the maximum was not reached until February 1922, that is, after a period of eighteen months. The revival was equally gradual. During the whole of 1922 and the beginning of 1923 unemployment was acute, the number out of work remaining over 10 per cent, of the total number of wage-earners (1910 census) *; improvement was slow until the spring of 1923, as will be seen from the following table: Index numbers of prices Number of unemployed Date Workers totally unemployed Workers partially employed Total Wholesale prices (Dr. Lorenz) Base: July 1914 = 100 1922 March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 89,099 80,799 71,100 59,456 52,180 51,789 49,512 48,218 51,128 53,463 40,315 39,249 34,292 30,629 28,279 25,538 23.352 21,585 21,900 20,429 129,414 12 1,048 105,392 °0,985 80,459 77,327 72,864 69,803 73,028 73,892 164.5 162.1 162.8 163.9 164.7 165.7 164.5 170.6 171.9 174.7 167 158 157 158 158 156 157 160 160 161 1923 J a n . Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 56,275 52,734 44,909 35,512 30,228 25,583 22,722 22,554 22,830 24,013 27,029 26,873 19,868 21,791 19,779 17,767 15,640 13,585 12,592 13,507 14,422 14,662 14,368 12,800 76,143 74,525 64,688 53,279 45 868 39,168 35,314 36,061 37,252 38,675 41.397 39,673 175.3 181.0 185.9 186.6 181.0 179.8 175.3 173.4 181.1 181.6 182.5 183.2 160 158 161 164 166 168 167 167 168 170 171 170 1924 J a n . Feb. March April 28.480 27,120 21,380 16,730 12.661 11 ¿ 8 5 8.164 6,465 41,141. 39,105 29,544 23,195 183.4 180.2 181.5 181.0 172 170 i 1 Cf. Dr. L O R E N Z : Die Kurve, 1 passim. Retail prices, cost of living. Base: July 1914 = 1 0 0 — 94 — The parallelism observed in the earlier part of the crisis between the fluctuations of unemployment and those of wholesale prices was in general maintained during the period of recovery. It is to be seen, however, that the fall of prices persisted for three or four months after the culminating point of the crisis had been passed, a fact which may be due in part to the sudden and rapid reduction of the price of milk and dairy products in the spring of 1922 owing to large stocks remaining unsold 1. As from July 1922, prices again began to rise and continued thereafter, with slight fluctuations, to pursue an upward course. From the financial point of view the yeais 1922-1923 were characterised by a period of rapid liquidation, so that the Banque Populaire Suisse was able to reduce its rate of discount from 4 to 3y2 per cent, on 2 March 1922, then from 3% to 3 per cent, on 17 August 1922 2. On 14 July 1923 it was raised again to 4 per cent., possibly with a view to restraining the export of capital and the fall in the Swiss exchange. The note circulation which amounted to 1,009 million francs at the end of 1921 fell to 725 million francs in August 1922, rising again to 1,005 million francs on 1 December under the influence of withdrawals made in the fear of a capital levy. It amounted to 976 million francs at the end of December 1922 and 982 million francs at the end of December 1923. It should be added that during 1922 over 200 million francs gold currency were restored to circulation. The Banque Populaire Suisse3 remarks that "judging from the weekly reports of the Banque Nationale Suisse, a considerable proportion of Swiss notes and currency is hoarded both at home and abroad, for our fiduciary circulation does not correspond to the present economic requirements of the country 4 ". INDEX NUMBERS OF WHOLESALE PRICES AND VALUE OF EXPORTS Exports (monthly average) Year 1921 1922 1923 1 2 1 index number of wholesale prices 1 191.2 167.5 180.6 Value (in thousands of francs) Calculated Recorded on hasis of index number value of prices 2 178,345 140,794 146,684 93.276 87,638 81,220 Weight (in thousands of metric tons) '46 62 60 Dr. Lorenz. Annual average. Base: July 1914 = 100. By the method employed in the case of France (see p. 81). Cf. Fifty-fourth Annual Report of the Banque Populaire Suisse, for 1922, p. 8. Ibid., p. 8. Annual Report, for 1923, p . 9. * On 31 December 1913 t h e total circulation a m o u n t e d to 314 million francs. 2 3 — 95 — The above table shows the fluctuations in foreign trade during the last three years. It is surprising that in 1921, the year when unemployment was most acute, the value of exports appears to have exceeded the 1922 figure when the situation was already beginning to improve, and that the figures for 1923 are even lower than those for 1922, in spite of there being a marked improvement in the labour market. This would seem to confirm the opinion of Dr. Lorenz, supported by statistical evidence x, that the reduction in the number of unemployed should very largely be attributed to the revival of the home market. Some evidence of the difficulties encountered by Swiss export industries during the whole of this period is given by the following table showing the difference between Swiss prices and those of certain other countries trading with Switzerland, the disadvantage to Switzerland being expressed as a percentage of Swiss prices. DIFFERENCE BETWEEN SWISS PRICES AND THOSE OF OTHER COUNTRIES EXPRESSED AS A PERCENTAGE OF THE FORMER Date Great Britain France Germany Czechoslovakia Italy 1922 J a n . Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 16.4 13.7 12.9 9.5 8.9 6.4 6.7 6.7 8.2 8.3 6.1 5.6 18.3 13.9 8.0 5.3 0.8 0.4 5.8 7.5 12.3 12.0 16.3 14.2 53.6 51.4 48.1 53.7 46.7 37.6 48.7 44.4 48.0 32.0 30.0 39.5 — — — — — — — — — — — 16.7 17 2 5.5 8.8 5.0 5.4 13.4 12.7 14.5 14.9 16.4 H.8 1923 J a n . Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 6.7 3.8 6.2 11.5 9.5 6.3 7.3 11.0 7.6 6.4 6.8 3.6 10.4 15.7 14.5 11.0 10.8 12.5 15.2 18.6 17.9 9.4 13.3 28.7 28.9 20.3 20.7 22.6 30.7 12.6 0.0 35.2 1 Cf. Die Kurve, Febr. 1924. — — 11.8 15.2 14.6 15.6 15.5 15.8 12.7 17.4 17.8 15.6 21.4 18.5 19.3 17.3 8.4 6.4 6.8 7.8 13.1 15.3 14.5 11.6 •— 96— SCANDINAVIA AND FINLAND The earlier account of the trade crisis in Scandinavia showed that in three of the countries, Norway, Sweden, and Denmark, there had been a period of inflation in 1919 and 1920, followed by two years of intense deflation. This latter period was everywhere marked by severe depression and widespread unemployment. In none of these countries has recovery been very rapid, though in all cases the year 1923, whilst comparing unfavourably with the pre-war situation, has been better than 1922. The following percentages of unemployment have been recorded amongst trade unions in the different countries. Date Sweden Norway Denmark 1922 Marcii June Sept. Dec. 30.6 21.5 15.2 21.7 25.4 15.6 11.0 15.1 27.9 13.2 10.6 20.3 1923 March June Sept. Dec. 19.9 9.8 7.9 14.1 14.5 7.9 7.6 14.0 15.6 8.1 7.7 19.6 The prolongation and severity of the depression have sometimes been attributed to the failure of the export market. In the case of Sweden, for instance, Professor Cassel suggests that one reason for the exceptional suffering in that country is that its exports consist largely of building material used for constructional purposes in other countries, and that during a period of trade depression the demand for such material falls off more than proportionately \ Statistics show that the failure of export trade was unquestionably of importance in the case of Sweden and Norway during the worst year of the slump, 1921. Later in the depression, this factor appears to have been of comparatively little importance. For in the case of all Scandinavian countries, export trade in 1922 and 1923, measured in real values, showed an improvement on 1920, a year of great prosperity. Denmark appears to have been favoured from the point of view of foreign trade even in 1921, and throughout the whole subsequent period of depression. 1 Money and Foreign Exchange after 1914, p. 241. Constable & Co., 1922. — 97 — Index number of wholesale prices Exports (monthly average) (000's omitted) Percentage of unemployment 2 Recorded value Value calculated on basis of 1913 prices i 68,112 189,858 91,439 96,143 94,649 68,112 52,885 41,189 55,574 58,067 4.4 5.4 26.0 23.1 13.0 31,743 98,753 50,439 63,789 65,951 31,743 25,852 16,926 27,377 28,305 1.6 2.3 17.8 14.1 10.7 53,113 132,589 117,518 97,997 127,723 53,113 . 33,997 52,699 57,308 68,668- 7.5 6.1 19.7 19.3 12.7 33,482 241,343 278,491 369,733 363,142 100.0 68.6 69.0 93.5 94.6 8 Sweden 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 100 359 "222 173 163 Norway 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 100 382 298 233 233 Denmark 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 100 390 223 171 186 Finland 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 100 1,183 1,263 1,219 1,095 4 5 6 6 1 Example: 1913 value = recorded value x 100 4- price index number (when 1913 = 100). Thus the 1913 value of Swedish average monthly exports for 1920 = 189,858,000 X 100 -5- 359 = 52,885,000 kronor. (See note on p. 81.) 2 Percentages of unemployment reported by trade unions; annual average. 3 Kommerskollegium. * Ohonomish Revue. 86 Official. Index published by the Monthly Bulletin of the Banh of Finland. Taken as a whole, therefore, the condition of the foreign market would appear to have had relatively little influence on unemployment in Scandinavia, and it would seem necessary rather to examine internal conditions for evidence of the causes of continued depression. It is true that in Norway and Sweden exports have not yet reached their pre-war level. But it seems questionable whether it may be permissible to regard the pre-war situation as being "normal" or as providing a basis of comparison with post-war conditions. In the case of the United States it was seen that the volume of exports after the war was, on the average of 1920-1923, considerably higher than in 1923. This might possibly be taken to signify a lasting change in the nature or volume of American — 98 — export trade, due to war-developments or to increasing investment abroad. Similarly in Norway and Sweden, there may have been deep-rooted and lasting changes in industry during the war, due to their being obliged for a long period to be more self-supporting. A comparison of export figures for 1913 and for 1921-1923 might therefore be very misleading. The same argument might of course apply to comparisons between the years 1920 and 1921-1923, but, it seems, to a less extent. As regards the relation between price movements and employment it was pointed out in the previous section on Scandinavia that trade is of too seasonal a character in these countries to permit a very close comparison between the movements of the two factors. In the case of Sweden, the index number of employment (corrected for seasonal variation), published by the Board of Trade, shows that the lowest point of the depression was reached in January 1922 and that recovery was most pronounced as from April 1922. This recovery followed the checking of the deflation of prices, and continued very gradually throughout 1922 and 1923, while prices remained comparatively stable. The movement of recovery was preceded by the reduction of the Bank Rate of the National Bank from iy2 per cent, in April 1921 to 5 per cent, in March 1922, and was accompanied by a further reduction of the Bank Rate to 4% per cent, in July 1922 \ Compared with all countries previously passed in review, Sweden has suffered much longer and much more intense unemployment. The annual averages of unemployment reported by the trade unions of that country have been : 1920: 5.4 per cent. ; 1921: 26.0 per cent. ; 1922: 23.1 per cent.; 1923: 13.0 per cent. The reason for this intensity of unemployment may be found partly in the fact that Sweden has followed a policy of severe deflation with a view to restoring the kronor to pre-war parity with gold. In this policy it has been completely successful, the redemption of paper money in gold at the pre-war rate having been resumed as from April 1924. This financial success is widely recognised, however, to have been achieved at enormous sacrifice. One essential feature of that sacrifice has been unemployment on an appalling scale, with its concomitant privation for thousands of human beings. The justification for this policy from the point of view of labour will therefore be whether in the future it may yield to the worker an improved standard of living, and greater industrial security. 1 Swedish Economic Review, March 1924. — 99 — The new system adopted has one particular point in its favour, that is, it protects Sweden against inflation. Provision is made that the National Bank of Sweden shall have the monopoly of the import of gold, and may if necessary increase the gold parity of the kronor. In this way it is in the power of the National Bank to avoid inflation, in the face of a general rise of gold-prices elsewhere. On the other hand, if the value of gold should rise through the action of other monetary centres, i.e. if gold-prices should fall, Sweden would be compelled to follow the new movement and to force down Swedish prices in sympathy. This deflationary policy would be thrust upon the country regardless of the suitability of such policy for Swedish industrial conditions. Norway has suffered very sorely from unemployment, though apparently less intensely than Sweden. The worst period of the depression was during 1921 when the fall of prices was most marked. The rate of fall diminished in 1922 and the decline was completely checked at the end of the year. During the following year there was a considerable recovery of the price level from 222 in January to 247 in December \ The revival of trade was fairly extensive during the summer of 1922. This period was followed by a seasonal decline until the spring of 1923, after which a further improvement to 7.6 per cent of unemployment in September was recorded. The movement of the Bank Rate may be taken to indicate broadly the financial policy followed in the country. The reduction of the rate from 7 per cent, in June 1921 to 5 per cent, in August 1922 is thus evidence of a tendency to change the policy of rapid deflation for one of comparatively easy credit. In Denmark the central rate of discount was reduced from 7 per cent, in April 1921 to 5 per cent, in April 1922. The fall of prices was checked in September 1922, after which a considerable rise took place, proceeding almost continuously throughout 1923 9 . Employment improved during the summer months of 1922 and 1923 and gave evidence of a gradual diminution of cyclical depression. The situation in 1923 was still very serious, but much of the remaining unemployment must be attributed to seasonal rather than cyclical factors. A comparison between pre-war and post-war unemployment can be made from the following figures. 1 Official Base: 1913 = 100. * The Finanstidende index shows a rise from 176 in September 1922 to 210 in December 1923. — 100 — PERCENTAGES OF UNEMPLOYMENT REPORTED BY TRADE UNIONS: DENMARK Month Jan. April July Oct. 1911 1912 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 17.1 11.2 5.4 4.2 14.8 8.3 4.23.8 13.8 7.4 3.6 3.7 16.5 6.3 1.8 3.4 15.1 23.6 16.8 20.8 28.9 24.0 12.5 11.3 • 21.5 11.5 7.4 7.6 As regards Finland, it was pointed out in the earlier part of the report that little unemployment had been suffered in that country even in 1921, and that prices had been comparatively stable as from the peak of the boom in 1920. The year 1922 showed some slight decline in wholesale prices, but in 1923 a very high degree of stability was maintained. Exports, though still below the level of 1913 have shown continuous improvement since 1920 (see table on p. 97). FINLAND: NUMBER OF U N E M P L O Y E D 1 Month March June Sept. Dec. 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 2,971 1,193 1,961 1,736 1,580 475 837 1,454 2,927 937 1,369 2,127 2,861 799 791 1,294 1,242 512 676 779 i Monthly Bulletin of the Bank of Finland. The figures quoted do not give a complete review ot the number of unemployed, but may be regarded as symptomatic. In conclusion, it would seem that the development of foreign trade has had such an irregular and apparently indefinite effect on the state of the labour market in all the Scandinavian countries, that it cannot be regarded as of paramount importance in the general situation. On the other hand, there appears to be a very close conformity in all countries between the movement of the price level and the development of employment. Moreover, as in the first part of this survey, such evidences as exist of the monetary policy followed during the period of depression would tend to show that a policy of deflation has always been accompanied by unemployment; that, on the other hand, rising prices accompany and probably stimulate — 101 — recovery, and that, as in the case of Finland, a policy of stabilisation after a position of high activity has been attained may lead to continuous and uninterrupted prosperity. THE NETHERLANDS It will be remembered that the outstanding feature of the unemployment situation in the Netherlands was the existence of almost continuous depression since the beginning of the war. The great and almost universal slump of 1921 found some reflection in trade conditions in the Netherlands, but not to the same extent as in the United States, Great Britain, Sweden, Norway, and Denmark. The fall of prices was, however, also less extensive in the Netherlands than in the above countries during that period. The decline of prices continued except for a slight recovery in the winter of 1922-1923 until August 1923. The annual average for 1923 was 151 as against 160 in 1922. This almost uninterrupted decline was accompanied by an increase in unemployment in 1922, with no permanent recovery in 1923. It is of interest to note in fact that the Netherlands constitute the only country in which the third year of depression revealed no sign of improvement in the average of unemployment. As in the case of various other countries previously examined. statistics of foreign trade for the Netherlands give evidence of the comparatively small influence which international relationships appear to have exerted on the labour market. Exports calculated on the common price basis of 1913 show continuous and marked increases over the 1920 level during all three years of the slump, whilst employment followed an inverse curve. Year 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 i Official. a 3 Index number of wholesale prices i 100 292 182 160 151 Monthly average of exports (in thousands of gulden) I Value Recorded calculated value on basis of | 1913 prices» 255,453 * 141,791 114,133 101,769 108,602 255,453 * 48,559 62,710 63,605 71,922 Percentage unemployment 8 5.0 5.8 9.0 11.0 10.8 5 See note on p. 81. Maandschrift. * In 1917 there was a change in the method of declaring the value of exports; prewar6 figures are therefore not comparable with post-war returns. January to November; if the usual seasonal increase took place in December the average for the year would be above 11.0, the Dgure given for 1922. — 102 — The Netherlands thus yield still one further example of the close relationship between the movement of internal prices and the development of the labour market. The same country provides strong evidence in favour of the opinion that in a general way each country has an almost independent crisis and that internal conditions have far outweighed international complications in determining the extent and intensity of the depression. CHAPTER IV THE BRITISH EMPIRE CANADA Although evidence was given in Part I of the Report to show that the crisis in Canada was seriously aggravated as a result of the sudden collapse of corn prices, there seems little further indication that the failure of foreign demand contributed to the trade slump for the remainder of the period. The year 1920 itself shows a level of export as high as, if not above, the 1913 position. The year 1921, the worst period of the depression, was apparently marked by still further improvement in the export trade. Considerable increases were to be observed in the subsequent years until the level of export in 1923 was about 50 per cent, above the position at which it stood in 1913. Year Index number of wholesale prices (Official) Index number of prices of exports (Bank of Commerce) 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 100.0 243.5 171.8 152.0 153.0 100 262.7 154.2 150.0 154.8 Monthly average of exports (in thousands of dollars) Percentage unemployment Value calcu(yearly Recorded lated on average) value basis of 1913 prices 1 36,333 106,055 66.892 73,697 84,561 36,333 40,371 43,380 49,131 54,626 4.6 12.6 7.0 4.9 i Seenoteonp. 81. Canadian experience is thus evidence of the inappropriateness of taking the year 1913 as a basis of comparison in estimating the influence of foreign trade during the years of depression 1921-1923. It also tends to show that the relationship between foreign trade and the internal labour market has been somewhat indefinite, and has at no time, since the winter of 1920-1921, dominated the situation. — 104 — The rapid fall of prices which accompanied the development of the crisis in 1921, was arrested at the end of the same year and a high degree of stability was maintained throughout 1922 and 1923. It would seem, therefore, that the recovery of trade, which became pronounced in 1922 and continued into 1923, must be attributed to some such causes as the natural expansion of newly developing areas and the contagious influence of the revival in the United States, rather than to any stimulus given by the movement of prices. AUSTRALIA From the monthly figures of export from Australia given on p. 27, it was shown that the outbreak of the crisis could apparently not be attributed to the failure of foreign demand. Owing to the seasonal character of the export trade of that country, it is necessary to examine annual figures in order to show the relative importance of foreign trade during the years of depression. Year 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 1 2 Index number of wholesale prices (Official) 100 227.9 174.9 161.6 178.7 Monthly average of exports (in thousands of pounds sterling Recorded value 6,070 10,083 2 9,930 2 10,053 8,973 Percentage unemployment (yearly Value calculated average) on basis of 1913 prices i 6,070 6,221 5,021 6.5 6.5 11.2 9.2 7.0 See note on p. 81. Fiscal year, beginning 1 July. The fiscal year 1 July 1919 - 1 July 1920 showed a monthly average export of £11,501,000. The subsequent fiscal year, ending 30 June 1921 gave a monthly average of £10,083,000, a reduction of approximately 12 per cent. Averaged over the respective periods the fall of prices from the first period to the second was negligible. Hence, one aggravating factor in the first year of depression was the diminution of foreign demand. The calendar year 1922, however, showed a volume of exports which was equal to, if not greater than the export total of 1913, and considerably higher, calculated on a common price basis, than the export trade during the boom period of 1919-1920. This period of active foreign trade was, however, marked by an average unemployment — 105 — percentage of 9.2. The following year employment improved and, on the contrary, the export trade fell off considerably. In the case of Australia, therefore, the state of the foreign market appears to have exerted comparatively little influence on the general movement of trade, except in 1921 when, in common with almost all other countries, international trade relations were seriously depressed. Seasonal fluctuations in Australian industry prevent any very close comparison of employment with the movements of the price level. But the broad movement of recovery, marked by a change from 11.2 per cent, of unemployment in 1921 to 9.2 per cent, in 1922, with a further improvement to 7.0 per cent, in 1923, was accompanied by the checking of falling prices at the beginning of 1922, followed by a marked upward trend for the remainder oi the year and a further slight tendency to rise in 1923. SOUTH AFRICA In the case of South Africa, there are no accurate means of estimating the extent of unemployment or the degree to which recovery has been made in the course of the years 1922 to 1923. According to general indications, such as the extensive measures still being carried out by the Government with a view to relieving the situation, it would seem that the year 1923 was still abnormally bad. That some improvement took place during these years seems evident, however, from the reduction of loss through bankruptcies, ,the diminution of the number of applications for work at the labour exchanges 1, and an increase of foreign trade. Year Index number of wholesale prices (Officia!) 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 1 1 100 223.3 160.4 128.4 126.6 See note on p. 81. See Part I of the report. Monthly average of exports (in thousands of pounds sterling) Merchandise Recorded value 2,294 3,841 2,234 2,476 2,962 Value calculated on basis of 1913 prices i Gold 2,294 1,720 1,393 1,928 2,340 3,132 2,962 2,871 2,443 3,264 — 106 — This recovery was accompanied by the restraint of falling prices in 1922 and comparative stability in 1923, and by the reduction of the official rate of discount from 7 yz to 7 per cent, in May 1922 and to 6 per cent, in December 1922. GREAT BRITAIN In Part I of the present report, the description of the British crisis was carried as far as June 1921, when unemployment reached the highest figure attained during the depression. The enormous percentage of unemployment (23.1) recorded by the trade unions in that month was, however, seriously affected by the strike of the coal miners which, after lasting nearly three months, brought almost to a standstill a number of industries dependent on steam power. Immediately after the strike there was a brisk revival of trade continuing until September when unemployment fell to 14.8 per cent. This recovery was perhaps due to the necessity for fulfilling contracts delayed during the coal strike, and the improvement was only momentary. From the month of September 1921 there was a further gradual decline until April 1922 when 17.0 per cent, of unemployment was recorded. This can more truly be considered the lowest point of the depression. From that date the situation improved almost continuously, though very gradually. At the end of 1922, unemployment was still as high as 14 per cent., although in countries such as France, Belgium, and the United States recovery was by that time almost complete. UNEMPLOYMENT PERCENTAGE IN TRADE UNIONS PAYING INSURANCE BENEFIT Month 1921 1922 1923 1924 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 6.9 8.5 10.0 17.6 22.2 23.1 16.7 16.3 14.8 15.6 15.9 16.5 16.8 16.3 16.3 17.0 16.4 15.7 14.6 14.4 14.6 14.0 14.2 14.0 13.7 13.1 12.3 11.3 11.3 11.1 11.1 11.4 11.3 10.9 10.5 9.7 8.9 8.1 7.8 7.5 — — — — — — — — — 107 — The above table gives evidence of further improvement during the course of 1923 and at the beginning of 1924. But the situation should still be regarded as extremely critical. In previous depressions since 1900, the annual averages reached have been 6 per cent. in 1904 and 7.8 per cent, in 1908. Compared with these figures, 8 or 9 per cent, in the fourth winter of depression represents still intense hardship for a considerable proportion of the population. The total number of applicants for employment on the live registers of the Employment Exchanges in Great Britain and Northern Ireland on 17 December 1923 was 1,174,397. On 18 December 1922 the corresponding total was 1,408,008, of whom 1,129,569 were men and 203,119 were women. PRICE MOVEMENTS AND EMPLOYMENT. As regards the correlation of price movements and employment, it will be remembered that, in the earlier part of the report, unemployment was shown to have developed rapidly as prices fell. In the period of revival which followed there were three principal stages in the movement of recovery; the early summer of 1922; the late winter of 1922-1923; and the autumn of 1923. It will be seen from the table below that the marked recovery of the labour market from April to July 1922 was heralded by a rise of four points from February to June in the wholesale price level. Likewise, the periods of recovery December 1922 to May 1923, and August to December 1923, were each accompanied by an appreciable upward trend in prices. In the intermediate stages unemployment remained comparatively stable, and prices were also stable or else fell slightly. The upward movement of the British price level, taken as a whole, has however been very slight in comparison with that of the United States, France and Belgium, where revival of trade was very rapid. Its movement has resembled more that of Sweden where, as was seen above, the depression has been most severe and continuous. Changes in the rate of discount of the Central Bank constitute in most countries the principal tangible evidence of the monetary policy being followed. In the earlier section of the Report it was shown that the rate of discount of the Bank of England was raised successively from 5 to 6 per cent, in November 1919, and from 6 to 7 per cent, in April 1920, with a view to restraining the rapid — 108 — Percentage unemployment in trade unions Date 1922 1923 1 The 2 Bank2 rate 2.1 100.0 July • Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 16.7 16.3 14.8 15.6 15.9 16.5 186.1 181.5 175.8 162.8 160.8 157.2 5y, Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 16.8 16.3 16.3 17.0 16.4 15.7 14.6 14.4 14.6 14.0 14.2 14.0 155.9 155.5 156.8 158.6 159.4 159.5 157.6 152.5 150.5 153.1 153.6 151.9 5 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 13.7 13.1 12.3 11.3 11.3 11.1 11.1 11.4 11.3 10.9 10.5 9.7 153.2 155.2 156.1 157.6 155.5 150.5 146.8 147.1 150.4 150.2 155.8 156.7 1913 1921 Index number of wholesale prices i 51/2 5% 514 5 5 4i/ 2 41/2 4 4 sy 3 2 3 3 3 3 3 • 3 3 3 ' a 3 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 Statist. End of month. inflation which was then taking place. The restraint was effective, and a policy of deflation followed, being marked by a 7 per cent bank rate until March 1921. The rate was still as high as 5 per cent. in November 1921. This period of deflation showed a fall in wholesale prices from 313.1 * in April 1920 to 160.8 in November 1921. The reduction of the bank rate to 4 per cent, in April 1922 marked the beginning of a permanent improvement in employment and the cessation of the policy of deflation. A further reduction of the rate to 3 % per cent, in June and 3 per cent, in July 1922 brought the price of money lower than it had 1 The Statist. Base: 1913 = 100. — 109 — been for many years. In these conditions of easy credit, recovery was slow but fairly continuous. The rate was raised again a year later (July 1922) from 3 to 4 per cent. This movement was followed by a slight set-back in employment lasting roughly two months, after which there was a considerable revival until the end of the year.. Such correspondence between the movements of the bank rate, prices, and employment is not conclusive in itself, but none the less adds to the evidence which would indicate that monetary control may in the future prove a useful instrument for stabilising the development of industry and for sustaining the labour market. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND UNEMPLOYMENT. The point of essential interest in the problem of the failure of foreign markets is the relationship which the reduction of foreign demand may bear to the total diminution of the demand for labour in Great Britain. On the one hand, purchasing capacity abroad appears to have been considerably diminished as a result of depreciated currencies and general depression of trade. On the other hand, home demand has been restricted through the loss of the purchasing capacity of the unemployed, through stringency of credit (in the first year of the depression) and through the unwillingness of business leaders to purchase material for new capital expansion when trade prospects are poor. Which of the two factors must be considered the more important, the failure of foreign trade, or oi the domestic market ? This question is of interest for two principal reasons. First, the measure of the failure of foreign demand will show the proportion of unemployment which may be regarded as of long duration i.e., the proportion which may be due to complicating factors which can only be completely eliminated by the restoration of Europe to full prosperity and political solidarity. In the second place the relation between home and foreign demand will show the relative importance of measures for restoring international trade and measures for stimulating home demand. The problem of determining which sphere is the more important might perhaps be approached in three ways: (1) a comparison of the actual movements of export trade with simultaneous movements in employment; (2) a comparison of the volume of foreign etrade and unemployment in times of depression with the volum — 110 — of each in times of prosperity; (3) an examination of the nature of the industries most affected by unemployment. The first method gives somewhat inconclusive results. Date 1913 » Imports (in thousands of pounds sterling) Percentage unemployment (trade unions) Exports (in thousands of pounds sterling) 54,931 2.1 43,771 1921 July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 71,396 78,583 78,524 74,356 79,436 76,108 16.7 16.3 14.8 15.6 15.9 16.5 43,172 51,346 55,248 62,265 62,895 59,375 1922 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. 68,029 59,201 77,725 71,461 79,850 75,578 73,467 75,157 70,562 76,737 86,452 86,433 16.8 16.3 16.3 17.0 16.4 15.7 14.6 14.4 14.6 14.0 14.2 14.0 63,147 58,335 64,581 55,508 58,045 52,146 60,419 60,032 62,511 60,399 66,491 58,883 89,902 74,032 80,937 73,989 77,706 78,353 68,018 82,614 75,155 88,768 91,414 98,793 13.7 13.1 12.3 11.3 11.3 11.1 11.1 11.4 11.3 10.9 10.5 9.7 66,939 57,510 60,921 62,871 71,555 62,884 59,504 60,103 63,836 71,323 65,768 64,115 Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 1923 Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. 2 s 1 The figures for 1913 show the monthly average. ¡> From 1 April 1923, including the trade of Great Britain and Northern Ireland with the Irish Free State, and excluding the direct foreign trade of the Irish Free State. The period of serious trade decline from September 1921 to April 1922 shows little change in the level of exports. Taking into consideration the fall of prices which took place at this time, the real value of exports seems to have increased rather than diminished. During the months following, when employment was improving, exports showed little variation. This lack of relationship between export trade and employment is perhaps less pronounced in 1923 when it can be said at least that export trade and employment both showed general improvement in the course of the year. — Ill — Compared with the increase in imports, the development of export during 1922 and 1923 was of small extent. T h a t would seem to give prima facie support for the opinion that the internal market was showing greater recovery and was more responsible for the trade revival than was the export market. Since there was in fact a marked recovery of general trade in 1922 and 1923 and since exports reflected this movement only to a relatively small extent, it seems that the development of home demand was the more important factor in determining the revival. Is it possible then to determine the relative importance of the two factors during 1923 when home demand had already somewhat recovered ? For this purpose it might be well to apply the second method suggested. The following table shows the volume of visible exports calculated on the basis of 1913 prices, in relation to the average of unemployment reported by trade unions during the year 1. Year » 1913 1920 1921 1922 1923 Export of goods from the United Kingdom 2 Re-exports 2 Million pounds Million pounds 525.2 372.5 261.6 361.8 404.4 109.6 98.9 86.1 89.3 94.0 . Percentage unemployment 2.1 2.4 15.3 15.4 11.5 i After March 1923, the trade of the United Kingdom with the Irish Free State is included, and2 the exports of the Irish Free State are excluded. Value at 1913 price level. The volume of exports in 1923 is thus seen to be about 25 per cent, below the pre-war level. The total volume of exports has been estimated at about 30 per cent, of the total production 2 of the country. On this basis, a 25 per cent, reduction in exports would amount roughly to a 7% per cent, reduction of the country's measurable production. To attribute 7% per cent, of reduced production, and a broadly corresponding percentage of unemployment, to the failure of foreign markets, assumes, however, that pre-war conditions are 1 2 Board of Trade Journal, 24 Jan. 1924, p. 107. Presumably excluding services which cannot be computed e.g., municipal services, commercial and professional services. This estimate was the one given by Mr. E. F. Wise, Economic Adviser to the All-Russian Union of Consumers' Co-operative Societies, before the Unemployment Conference organised by the League of Nations Union in London on 25-27 March 1924. — 112 — "normal". Now, in certain countries previously examined it has been shown that the average of post-war export is considerably above (e.g. Canada and the United States) or considerably below (e.g. Sweden and Norway) the pre-war level and that such a state of affairs might be regarded as quasi-permanent, being the result of important and lasting changes in the nature of the country's industry or the extent of its foreign investments. In the case of Great Britain there has been a very marked diminution since 1914 in the rate of investment abroad. Furthermore, the country was obliged during the whole of the war to mould its industry to home requirements with a view to becoming less dependent on foreign trade. If, therefore, these changes are of a comparatively permanent character, the year 1920 should be regarded as more "normal" than the year 1913. What result then does a comparison between the year 1920 and the year 1923 yield ? In the first place unemployment averaged 2.4 per cent, in 1920 as against 11.5 per cent, in 1923. Exports, brought to the common price basis of 1913, amounted to £404 millions in 1923 as compared with £373 millions in 1920. In other words, in spite of a very considerable reduction in employment there has been a marked increase of exports since 1920 1. In view of this considerable improvement of the foreign market and of a simultaneous diminution of total demand, the depression of home demand over this period must have been very extensive, and presumably was, even in 1923, the most important consideration. This does not detract, however, from the importance of the failure of foreign demand regarded in an absolute sense. Moreover, the year 1920 may perhaps have shown a high figure of employment owing to the great development of home demand resulting from expenditure on post-war reconstruction, a development which temporarily masked the existing weakness of foreign demand. Subsequently, when both internal and external demand began to fail, the effect of reduced foreign demand was no longer masked and became an additional source of aggravation in an already intense depression. The evidence which may be drawn by the third method of approach, i.e. a comparison of conditions in different industries, lends some emphasis to the importance of the failure of foreign 1 The effect of the exclusion from the returns of exports from the Irish Free State and the inclusion of exports from the United Kingdom to the Irish Free State, is considered to be of minor importance and incapable of invalidating the general conclusion. — 113 — demand. The percentages of unemployed reported by trade unions of different industries at the end of December 1923 1 show that certain of the principal export trades, e.g. engineering, shipbuilding, miscellaneous metal, and cotton textiles, suffered comparatively heavily, though this is not the case with coal mining; and that those producing more particularly for home consumption, e.g. building, printing, bookbinding and paper manufacture, furnishing and woodworking, have fared somewhat better. (The pottery and tobacco trades form an exception to this group). Percentage unemployed in December 1923 Trade Building * Coal mining Engineering and shipbuilding Miscellaneous metal Textiles : Cotton Woollen and worsted Other Printing, bookbinding and paper Furnishing Woodworking Clothing: Boot and shoe Other clothing Leather Glass Pottery 3 Tobacco Total 4.1 0.5 18.7 10.4 7.5 2 2.2 3.7 4.3 6.4 4.8 Increase ( + ) or decrease (—) compared with December 1922 — — — — 3.4 6.3 8.2 0.7 + 0.5 + 1.— — + — 0.2 1.8 1.5 2.2 5.5 5.7 9.1 2.1 26.1 16.7 + 0.7 + 1.9 + 0.7 — 0.6 + 5.1 —14.6 9.7 — 4.3 1 The percentage is based on returns relating to woodworkers and plumbers, and as regards woodworkers, who constitute the bulk of the membership, the returns relate to the end2 of October. In addition to those shown, who were totally unemployed, a large number of the members of the unions reporting were "paid off part of each week, or alternate weeks or fortnights, or on temporary stoppage benefit". s The returns for the tobacco trade are supplied by unions whose members are mainly cigar makers. The fact must not be overlooked, however, that most of the export trades in question are also essentially producers of capital goods, trades which invariably suffer worst during depression even though they produce for home consumption alone. They are also the trades which were over-expanded during the war, and for the production of which there is now neither home nor foreign demand on the same scale as before. This expansion during the war is 1 The Ministry of Labour Gazette, J a n . 1924, p. 15. 8 — 114 — particularly noticeable in the case of engineering and iron-founding, and shipbuilding, as will be seen from the following table extracted from The Third Winter of Unemployment \ Industry Building and construction Coal mining Engineering and ironfounding Shipbuilding Numbers engaged in the industries Numbers Increase unemployed or decrease in eight years in October 1922 June 1914 Jan. 1922 908,000 1,134,000 870,000 1,180,000 — 38,000 + 46,000 142,325 84,000 790,000 242,000 1,127,000 315,000 + 337,000 + 73,000 249,000 121,000 Such conclusions as may be drawn from the foregoing survey of home and foreign trade must naturally be very tentative in character, But it would seem that, in the first place, the conditions of 1913 can no longer be considered as "normal", but rather some state intermediate between the 1913 and the 1920 situations. In such case, industry may be expected to recover completely without the pre-war level of export being reached; and the present level of exports, low in comparison with 1913 and high in comparison with 1920, should not be considered a cause for undue pessimism. Home demand successfully masked the failure of foreign demand for a period of two years after the war ; this was at a time when the foreign market was weaker than in 1923. Hence there seems reason to believe that the domestic market may continue to strengthen as it did in 1922 and 1923, leaving little margin of unemployment attributable to conditions abroad. To this note of optimism, might it not be wise to add one of caution ? Remedial measures, which may assist to some extent the revival of foreign trade, may at the same time have an adverse effect on home demand. Would it not be well, therefore, in the examination of proposals of this nature, such for instance as the preferential treatment of certain industries, or the reduction of wages, to consider carefully all the possible repercussions of the action recommended both upon the foreign and the home markets ? From the basis of the foregoing generalisations, it would be well to proceed to some further discussion of the separate factors which affect the labour market either through their influence on 1 The Third Winter of Unemployment. London, P.S. King & Son, 1923. — 115 — international trade or on domestic consumption. As far as possible the factors bearing principally on international trade will be grouped together and treated first. FACTORS AFFECTING INTERNATIONAL TRADE Wages and Unemployment A comparison of wage changes with movements in employment from 1920-1923 may be made from the following statistics quoted by Professor A. L. Bowley before the London Unemployment Conference organised by the League of Nations Union in March 1924. 1920 Month Jan. Feb. March April May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. • 1921 1922 A B A B A 100 100 101 98 101 104 104 102 102 98 102 104 2.9 1.6 1.1 0.9 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.6 2.2 5.3 3.7 6.0 110 114 118 6.9 8.5 10.0 115 115 118 114 113 107 107 107 102 100 100 100 (Coal strike) 114 110 113 115 114 116 16.7 16.5 14.8 15.6 15.9 16.5 1923 B 16.8 16.3 16.3 17.0 16.4 15.7 14.6 14.4 14.6 14.0 • 14.2 14.0 A B 100 100 102 104 105 104 102 100 100 100 100 98 13.7 13.1 12.3 11.3 11.3 11.1 11.1 11.4 11.3 10.9 10.5 9.7 A = Real wages, United Kingdom, i.e., weekly money wages index^divided by cost of living index number. B = Trade Union Unemployment Percentage. EXAMPLE: In January 1921 the cost of living index number was 251 and the money wages index number was 277, both in relation to 100 in July 1914. 100X277*251 = 1 1 0 approx. Hence the entry in the table. The evidence which these figures yield was summarised by Professor Bowley as follows : In spite of the reduced working week, wages from February to September 1920 were, as nearly as can be estimated, equal to those in 1914. After the outbreak of the crisis, wages continued to rise during 1921 and unemployment increased. Employment began to improve in May 1922, the date at which real wages began to fall. By October 1922 real wages were at the same level as in 1914 and remained at that level till the end of 1923. The improvement in employment continued till it was checked in the summer 1923, but rapid further progress has been made since September. Throughout the period the real wages included are those payable for the reduced working week. The relation between wages and unemployment is not conclusively established. The two main points were that employment began to improve — 116 — when real wages fell, but after real wages had got back to their pre-war level, while they remained there employment continued to improve. The correlation was broken, but it ought to be said that the sudden break at the beginning of 1921 was not solely or even primarily due to the height of wages. At present these seems a prospect of unemployment being reduced to the pre-war average without a fall in real wages; but the synchronism in the fall in wages and unemployment in the summer of 1922 appears to be significant. In view of this somewhat conflicting evidence and of the elementary state of research into the relation between wages and employment, it would seem impossible to do more than throw out a few suggestions as to the possible reactions between the two factors. Rising wages, through their relation to costs, obviously tend to render production difficult in the industries immediately affected and thus contribute to the factors making for greater unemployment. Through their relation to demand, rising wages stimulate production and thereby lead to greater employment. Whether these two considerations cancel out would seem difficult to determine *. But at all times both factors must be taken into account when questions of wage policy are under consideration. The diminution of wages has sometimes been suggested as a means of alleviating the situation in exporting industries. The immediate effects of such diminution would appear to be to assist the industries concerned in securing foreign markets. Such relief as might be given in this way must, however, be essentially at the expense of domestic trade; for the reduction of wages will be reflected immediately in a diminution of home demand. Whether such preferential treatment of the exporting section is desirable or not depends to some extent upon the relative importance of domestic and foreign demand and the conditions in the respective industries supplying the demand. A further complicating element in the reaction between domestic and foreign trade and their relation to wage changes is as follows. The reduction of wages by reducing demand within a country will tend to diminish its imports. Now, when a foreign exporter sends goods to Great Britain, he requires to be paid for those goods. His claim for payment is one which can only be realised ultimately in British goods, i. e., by an increase of British exports. Thus the diminution of imports means a diminution in the claims of foreigners 1 There is a further factor for consideration. If rising wages create a tendency to rising prices, and if rising prices are the usual accompaniment and to some extent the stimulus of recovery, the evidence would seem weighted in favour of the belief that rising wages' lead to greater, rather than less, employment. — 117 — on British goods, which is reflected to a greater or less extent 1 in the failure of demand for British exports. In this way the reduction of wages proposed initially as a means of stimulating export trade may, through its restraint of imports and consequent diminution of exports, have the reverse effect from that originally intended. Viewed internationally, the argument for the reduction of wages as a stimulus to employment fails completely. Whatever momentary alleviation may be secured by one country through the reduction of its costs in this way, the advantage would be lost immediately its competitors followed the same course. The total result would in fact be a world-wide reduction in the demand of wage-earners and a gradual and painful reduction of prices until the purchasing power of the community, diminished in this way, was again adequate to absorb all the goods brought on to the market. Commercial Barriers The evidence given before the London Unemployment Conference by Dr. T. E. Gregory, who has made a special study of international trade in the post-war period, was to the effect that in view of the universal increase of prices compared with the pre-war level, the effective tariff wall was no higher in present times than it had been before the war. In point of fact, until the rates of specific duty had been raised, the tariff walls of the world were only one-half as high as in 1913 ; the raising of the rates merely had the effect of making them correspond with the new level of prices. It seemed probable, therefore, that the influence which tariff barriers had exerted had been considerably exaggerated, One striking example of the comparatively small effect of the increased duties wras that of the Fordney tariff in America. In spite of the new customs rates, there had been an increase oí exports to America since their application. Dislocation of the Exchanges There is little need to emphasise the importance of stable exchange rates from the point of view of international trade. The results of exchange dislocation are obvious and undeniable; and they have been singled out in every treatise on the subject of unemployment as one of the most important aspects of the problem. 1 The question of changes in foreign investment is to be taken into consideration. — 118 — From an examination of the general situation in world trade, it is to be seen that the countries which have suffered worst are for the most part those whose currencies have been continuously over-valued externally. This has been the case with Great Britain, since sterling has been over-valued in relation to most European currencies during the entire period of the crisis. This appreciation of the value of sterling on foreign money markets sets in operation two forces: greater ability of British merchants to buy foreign goods, in view of the low prices of those goods when expressed in sterling: and greater difficulty in selling British goods in foreign markets, in view of the inability of the foreign trader to buy sterling and pay British prices. There is thus created a tendency for exports to diminish and imports to increase, with consequent unemployment. In Great Britain this tendency is reflected in the actual returns of the Board of Trade, which show that whereas visible imports are approximately at their pre-war level, visible exports expressed as real values are about 25 per cent, below the 1913 level. These facts, however, require a little further investigation before it can be assumed that the o ver-valuation of a currency must invariably lead to unemployment at home. In the first place, in a country like Great Britain, whose industry is largely dependent upon imported raw materials, any exporting disadvantage it may suffer through the appreciation of its currency must, to a certain extent, be off-set by the cheapness with which it can import raw materials. This would not appear to eliminate entirely the handicap on export but would at least remove a part of it. In the second place, there can only be a permanent change in the relation between exports and imports provided there is a corresponding change in the direction of investment. If, for instance, imports into Great Britain are immediately increased through the stimulus given by the external over-valuation of sterling, the foreign exporters of those British imports thereby secure an additional claim on British goods, which can only be satisfied by an ultimate increase of British exports — unless those foreigners or other foreigners forego their claim. This they might do by investing their claim permanently in Great Britain. Some such change in the direction of investment appears to have taken place in the post-war period. Before the war, Great Britain maintained an exceedingly high annual balance of investment abroad. Since 1920 there has been a considerable diminution — 119 — of this rate of investment, the annual balance having fallen appreciably. Moreover, a further point of perhaps less importance in itself, but of considerable significance in its implications, is that deposits in British banks increased very considerably during 1921 relatively to those in many European countries whose currencies were undervalued externally. This may have been the result of a general tendency for foreigners to transfer their balances to a country in which the currency was appreciating. These facts would seem to be very strong evidence that whenever a country's currency is overvalued externally in consequence of its high national credit there is a tendency for further investment in that country and for foreign traders to leave their idle balances in its banks. The result of such an inward flow of investment would be to reduce the country's exports in proportion to its imports, and so cause unemployment. This conclusion appears to yield a satisfactory explanation of one of the most extraordinary post-war paradoxes, namely that the higher the national credit of a country and the greater its political stability, the worse it has suffered from loss of trade in the postwar period. A minor incident in the recent history of British currency which has some bearing on this matter was that of the "inflationist scare" which occurred at the beginning of October 1923, and was responsible for a rapid though momentary depreciation of sterling in foreign money markets. This movement was apparently in no way detrimental to British trade, since improvement in employment was marked during October and the remaining months of the year. Political Uncertainty For similar paradoxical reasons the effect of political uncertainty seems to be to stimulate rather than to reduce employment. In the case of many countries already examined it has been seen that the effect of political insecurity has been to reduce the exchange value of its currency and to turn the tide of investment outwards from that country, so that its export trade has been considerably stimulated and the demand for labour increased. In the case of Great Britain the reverse process seems to have been effective. Owing to the sound political and financial situation of that country it has been a centre of investment from countries offering less — 120 — security, and its currency has been considerably overvalued abroad, both factors contributing to the tendency for British imports to exceed exports. The unemployment resulting from such a change would thus arise from a circumstance which is in all other respects eminently desirable and should be preserved at whatever cost to the nation, namely, its political and financial stability. All these paradoxical situations would perhaps appear to justify a pessimistic outlook. Of the factors affecting international trade some brief discussion has been given above to wage movements, customs tariffs, exchange dislocation and political insecurity. And in no case does there seem a possibility of immediate solution. Wage movements offer little prospect of alleviation, since their twofold effects seem to cancel out. Customs barriers are said to be roughly where they were before the war. Political security would seem too valuable an asset to barter for improvement in the labour market. If it is true, however, t h a t Great Britiain is suffering unemployment through the very solidarity of its position, its high national credit and its overvalued currency, these must be a consequence less of absolute than of relative security; in other words, it suffers through the fact that compared with other countries its position has greater strength and offers better prospects. One way of reducing this relative advantage without losing the absolute security would be to increase the political and financial stability of Europe so that the currencies of Central European countries may no longer be undervalued and t h a t capital investment may no longer be diverted from their borders. Hence, those who urge, as a panacea for all ills, the restoration of a true spirit of peace in Europe, would certainly find therein a part solution for British unemployment *. There remain for examination those factors which have a more direct bearing on conditions of home demand. In this connection, some suggestions are made below as to the relations between unemployment and (1) over-population; (2) taxation; (3) monetary policy. 1 There is little need to emphasise in this connection the part which has already been played by the League of Nations through the Economic and Financial Organisation in restoring the financial and economic stability of huge tracts of Central Europe (see Appendix to the Director's Report for the 1924 Conference). The continuance of such work, which depends largely upon the realisation of its importance in the several countries, is unquestionably of the greatest concern for the future of British trade and employment. — 121 — FACTORS AFFECTING THE DOMESTIC MARKET Over-Population and Unemployment The population of England, Scotland, and Wales increased b y roughly two millions, from 40,831,396 in 1911 to 42,767,530 in 1921. This rate of increase is very gradual in comparison with previous decades, but there appears to be evidence t h a t the rate of development of the country's productive capacity has also considerably diminished since the end of the 19th century. The problem thus presented by the growth of population has been given considerable prominence of late, as a result of an interesting controversy between Sir William Beveridge and Mr. J. M. Keynes \ Briefly the line of argument followed by Mr. Keynes is this: Unemployment is a phenomenon of maladjustment, and the maladjustment may be due to causes which have nothing to do with population: as, for example, the maladjustment due to a transition, through deflation of purchasing power, from a higher to a lower price-level, or that due to the necessity of changing over from supplying one type of outside market to supplying another because of a sudden change in the relative wealth and requirements of the rest of the woiId. Each of these influences is probably responsible for an important part of the existing unemployment in Great Britain. But on the other hand, unemployment may be a symptom of a maladjustment very closely connected with population —- namely, that which results from an attempt on the part of organised Labour, or of the community as a whole, to maintain real wages at a higher level than the underlying economic conditions are able to support. The most alarming aspect of the prolongation and the intensity of the existing unemployment is the possibility that transitory influences may not wholly explain it, and that deep causes may be operating which interfere with our continuing ability to maintain in these islands an expanding population at an improving standard of life 2. Sir William Beveridge considers, however, that when overpopulation is beginning to make itself felt, that is, when numbers are increasing so rapidly as to press heavily upon the raw materials available, and when it becomes increasingly difficult to secure the same rate of output per unit of effort, then "a more probable effect (of over-population) would be pressure to work more than before in order to obtain the same comfort." 3 Illustrating his point of view from historical evidence, Sir William Beveridge shows that, although the latter part of the nineteenth century was marked by comparatively heavy unemployment in Great Britain, there could be no ground for saying that this was due 1 2 3 The Economic Journal, Dec. 1923. The Nation and the Athenaeum, 6 Oct. 1923, p. 10. The Economic Journal, Dec. 1923, p. 448. — 122 — to excessive increase of the population or declining efficiency of production. It was, in fact, accompanied by a phenomenal rise both in the numbers supported and in the standard of living enjoyed by each individual l. In view of the very gradual manner in which the law of diminishing returns would operate it would seem rash to attribute a large proportion of unemployment to re-adjustments consequent on such a slow process of change. However, there is one important factor for consideration in relation to population and cyclical depression. One of the usual outlets for surplus population is emigration, and although this is never a comprehensive cure for unemployment, it offers a fairly regular way of escape for a certain number oi workers from over-crowded areas. During periods of world-wide depression, however, immigration restrictions are greatly increased and, in consequence, over-populated regions have even less opportunity of relief than during the more prosperous times.2 It seems probable that through the loss of their customary outlet for a certain proportion of unemployed during depression, countries of emigration would tend in general to be worse affected than neutral or immigration countries. This fact may account to some extent, though not very largely, lor the great intensity of unemployment in Great Britain as compared with countries of immigration. Taxation and Unemployment It is frequently stated that an increase of taxation raises the cost of production of goods, and that the competitive disadvantage incurred, by depressing trade, increases unemployment in the country concerned. It is also stated that taxation, by absorbing a certain proportion of the purchasing power of the community, reduces the effective demand for goods, and so gives rise to unemployment; or, alternatively, by interfering with the accumulation of capital, hinders the revival of industry. 1 2 The Economic Journal, Dec. 1923, pp.447-448. The figures for emigration from Great Britain during 1920-1923 are as follows : 1920 1921 1922 1923 285,105 199,177 174,096 256,284 The year 1908, a period of serious depression, showed a very marked worldwide diminution of emigration (see I. FERENCZY: Rapport sur le chômage et les migrations internationales de travailleurs. Ghent, 1912. •r — 123 — A further argument which seems worthy of consideration is one which relates to the use made by the Government of the revenue collected through taxation, and the possibility of purchasing power available from savings for capital investment being supplemented from, other sources, such, for instance, as the creation of additional bank credit. In the first place, it would seem that in a country such as Great Britain, where the budget is balanced annually, all revenue collected is offset by expenditure on goods and services (except that part which is used for the cancellation o¡ floating debt). Consequently an increase of taxation produces automatically an increase of Government expenditure. The purchasing power withdrawn from one section of the community is transferred to another section, and total effective demand would appear to be unchanged. However, since taxation constitutes to some extent a reduction of savings, that is, expenditure on capital investment, and since Government expenditure is rapidly reflected through wages and unemployment relief in demand for consumable goods, one effect of the increase of taxation may be a change in the direction of the community's total expenditure. From the purchase of capital goods, a certain proportion of the community's buying capacity may be diverted to the purchase of consumable goods. The total demand for consumable goods may thus be increased at the expense of the demand for capital goods. Which of the two factors is the more important during depression ? It is an accepted phenomenon of trade slumps that goods for final consumption glut the market during this period, and that until they can be absorbed industry must continue to be sluggish. From this point of view the diversion of expenditure to the purchase of consumable goods would appear to give a definite advantage. At all times, moreover, it is the demand for the final commodity which regulates the general activity of trade, and if, during depression, it is possible, by heavier taxation and greater state expenditure, to increase the demand for final goods, this would produce as an initial effect a general desire to meet this demand by further expansion throughout the process of production. But it has been shown that the demand for final goods was only increased at the expense of savings — i. e. the reserves available for capital expansion. If private reserves are thus reduced, will this not impede the expansion of capital ? Or are there other resources which may replace private savings ? It would seem probable that in this period of rising prosperity the necessary — 124 — supplementing of private savings might be effected through a general increase of bank credit. In this way, it might be possible to argue that an increase of taxation would be followed by greater state expenditure, which would be reflected in increased demand for final goods. This in turn would stimulate the general expansion of industry which would entail for its operation a certain development of bank credit to take the place of savings initially reduced by taxation. This argument appears incomplete without much qualification at different stages; but in general there seems reason for believing that increased expenditure for the relief of the unemployed during depression would act as a spur to production rather than constituting, as is sometimes thought, an unqualified burden on industry. British experience during the existing depression has shown that whereas extensive cuts have been made in taxation and expenditure, unemployment has continued with the greatest intensity. Revenue and expenditure for the years 1919 to 1923 were as follows 1 : Year 1919-1920 1920-1921 1921-1922 1922-1923 1923-1924 » 1 Revenue (in pounds sterling) Expenditure (in pounds sterling) 1,339,571,000 1,425,985,000 1,124,880,000 914,012,452 818,500,000 1,665,773,000 1,195,428.000 1.079,187,000 812,496,604 816,616,000 Budget estimates. Monetary Factors and Unemployment The relation between monetary policy and unemployment may be expressed in very simple terms. Without money, the community cannot buy. If the community does not buy, production ceases and unemployment begins. This idea might be carried a stage further as follows. The control over money will permit a certain control over demand, since demand can only find expression through the medium of money. Is it possible therefore, by the control of money, to stabilise the growth of demand and so lead to the greater stability of industry itself ? This somewhat theoretical conception may be reduced to practical terms in this way. "Money" means every possible instrument of purchase, whether it be legal tender currency or instrument of 1 Whitaker's Almanac, 1924. — 125 — credit. And all such money flows to and from the community almost exclusively via the banks. "Virtually, every instrument of purchase, be it cheque, note, or coin, finds its way into circulation through the intermediary of the banks; and, in so far as the ebb and flow of these instruments is under the control of the institutions issuing them, to that extent the latter are responsible for one of the most vital factors in industrial production" \ But to what extent are the banks actually in a position to control the volume of instruments of purchase which pass to and from their vaults ? It is a truism to say that a very considerable percentage of industry is directly dependent on loans and cash borrowings secured from the banks, and that even those firms which are not directly dependent are indirectly affected by the volume of money released by the banks throughout the community. But these facts do not obviate certain difficulties experienced by the banking system in securing adequate control over the flow of money into the community and over the use which the community makes of that money. Expressed in practical terms, the problem of the monetary control of industry is that of determining whether the banks are in a position to exercise control over the money borrowed and used by the industrial community, thus to regulate the community's total effective demand and, by so doing, counteract tendencies to fluctuation of trade. Is it possible in this way to replace the régime of fluctuation, those alternations of feverish and stagnant demand — the trade cycle, in fact — by one of comparatively stable demand, leading to stable production and stable employment. This conception is now being discussed as a practical possibility and no longer the academic dream of the economic recluse. Judging from the experience of the United States in the last twelve months, the new system is already being given a trial and is proving eminently successful. The manner of its application to Great Britain was examined at some length at the London Unemployment Conference previously mentioned, and some of-the discussions might suitably be reproduced here. Mr. H. D. Henderson, Editor of The Nation and the Athenaeum, opened the debate on the question by explaining the rôle played by the monetary factor in the various phases of the cycle: The " normal trade conditions " which existed before the war were not even steady conditions of active business and full employment, but "a recurring sequence of ups and downs, an incessant rotation round a cycle of phases — 1 "Bank Credit and Unemployment", International Labour Review, Vol. IX, No. 1, Jan. 1924, p. 79. — 126 — from depression, through the phase of general recovery, in which we find ourselves at the present moment, marked by a certain recovery of prices, an increase in production, and the reabsorption of unemployed workers — through that phase, until a condition of full activity is reached with employment good, but with demand and supply for a time in general equilibrium and with the price level steady. Then unfortunately on to the next phase, on to the boom, when demand outstrips supply in almost every direction, outstrips the maximum output of which the resources of production are capable, so that there seems a general shortage of everything, and prices — wholesale prices, wage rates, retail prices — shoot upwards and speculation comes in and stimulates the tendency. That stage is followed by the crisis and then the slump, when everybody is trying to sell and hardly anyone is willing to buy, so that prices tumble and production is restricted and workpeople are discharged. Then a slow and painful stage of liquidation, and so back to the depression from which we started. That is the trade cycle. That was the normal course of things in those normal days before the war ; and that contributed more than any other single factor to unemployment, and not to unemployment alone, but to many other social evils associated with it. And that has played — let there be no mistake about this — a very large part in the unemployment from which we have suffered during the last 3% years, though I do not suggest for a moment that it is the whole story. T h i s c o n d i t i o n of fluctuation could, in Mr. H e n d e r s o n ' s opinion, b e v e r y largely eliminated b y s h a p i n g t o t h a t e n d t h e m o n e t a r y policy of t h e c o u n t r y . I n t h e first place, it would b e possible, b y l a y i n g s u i t a b l e r e s t r a i n t s on t h e g r o w t h of b a n k credit, largely t o a v o i d t h e period of b o o m . F o r a n increase of b a n k credit w a s a n "essential c o n d i t i o n " of a n y b o o m in t r a d e . I n e x p l a n a t i o n of this point, t h e s p e a k e r showed t h a t : At any time, quite apart from a boom, a very large amount of business is carried on and financed by means of overdrafts and advances granted by the banks, and during a boom prices rise (that, of course, is an essential feature of them), so that in order to finance the same volume of puchases at a higher price level a larger bulk of bank credit is required than before. Actually, during the boom business men are buying, or trying to buy, larger quantities of goods traders are increasing their stocks, manufacturers expanding their plants, speculators buying simply in the hope of selling again at a profit from prices that have risen further, so that actually during the boom people are buying or trying to buy a larger quantity of goods than before, and they are buying them at higher prices. They, therefore, require more purchasing power and, in so far as they pay for their purchases by means of bank credit, they require a larger volume of bank credit than before, As a matter of fact, during every boom the volume of credit, of advances, overdrafts, discounts and so forth, invariably increases. The banks grant the necessary purchasing power, which is an essential condition of the boom. I say an essential condition, I do not say the cause, though it may very well be the originating cause. But that is as it may be. What matters is that the boom could not continue, or even get under way, if the banks did not make it possible by supplying the necessary credits. In view of this essential relationship between expanding credit and rising trade, it was therefore possible to restrain the boom and — 127 — control it b y t h e judicious r e g u l a t i o n of credit facilities. A s r e g a r d s t h e depression, it i n v a r i a b l y h a p p e n e d t h a t in t h e earlier critical stages after t h e c h e c k i n g of t h e b o o m , c r e d i t r e m a i n e d t i g h t a n d was m o r e difficult t o o b t a i n t h a n e v e r : T h e policy w h i c h Mr. H e n d e r s o n a d v o c a t e d w a s t h e r e f o r e : Let credit be so controlled as neither to permit the boom nor to induce the slump. When the stage of full activity is reached, let the banks hold trade there and hold the price level steady. The moment there are signs that a boon is in progress, even though it be merely a cloud no bigger than a man's hand, let the brake on credit be at once imposed before any harm is done. The moment that there are signs that a depression is under way, let credit be at once offered more freely and on easier terms, and then this vicious circle of reactions will be reduced to a narrower and narrower radius, until ultimately it may disappear altogether. Professor E . C a n n a n of t h e L o n d o n School of E c o n o m i c s expressed his a g r e e m e n t on t h e desirability of d a m p i n g d o w n b o o m s , as h e h a d for m a n y y e a r s held t h a t this w a s t h e o n l y m e t h o d of a v o i d i n g depression. B u t h e was n o t confident of t h e efficiency of t h e m e a n s a v a i l a b l e . As r e g a r d s t h e effectiveness of m o v e m e n t s in t h e b a n k r a t e , Professor C a n n a n s t a t e d : It does not seem to me to follow that because these booms often happen to be, so to speak, finally knocked on the head by a spectacular rise of the bank rate, they could have been kept under and prevented from getting to any considerable height by moderate rises earlier. When you come to think of it, the expenses incurred in borrowing money are only one of the numerous expenses in running any kind of business, and in a great many they are not a very large proportion of it. They are not nearly so important constantly as, other expenses. You talk about the poor builder being unable to build a house because the bank rate nas gone up ; it may have been only a very moderate advance that he wanted for a couple of months perhaps, and to pay 1 or 2 per cent, higher per annum upon that advance is not really a very serious matter — not, probably, anything like so serious as a penny on wages. That is why I think the movement of the bank rate as an expense in production is constantly very much over-rated, and I should say in consequence of that you must not expect a moderate rise of the bank rate at an early period of a boom to have so much effect as il is often supposed that it would have. In fact, when such a thing is talked of you will constantly find it asserted — and I think quite truly — that business men are not going to be prevented from borrowing when they see chances of a profit by the fact that they have to pay a somewhat higher bank rate for a short time. You may ask: How is that consistent with the fact that the final rise constantly breaks up the boom ? I think it comes about in this way. When you get this final rise, no matter how, it serves for the business world as a kind of warning given out by what they consider (when they are not grumbling) the highest authority, that the boom is about to come to an end. It is not really such an awful thing to have to pay 7 or even 10 per cent, per annum for a month. It is not that this is such an awful thing, it is the fear of disaster inspired by the rise. The bank rate has gone up to 7 or 10 per cent. The idea is that the boom is coming to an end. "Where shall we be ? Prices are going to fall. We are not going to be able to sell; somebody else is not going to be able to buy. We must ask you to pay." And so you have all the things which cause people to think they must draw in. — 128 — Mr. J. M. Keynes dealt in three stages with the question of the monetary factor in relation to unemployment : the importance of the influence of financial policy on unemployment; the measures available for carrying out an approved policy ; and the policy which could and should be adopted in the near future. As regards the importance of the influence exerted by financial factors, Mr. Keynes was of opinion that in the case of a 12 per cent. unemployment situation such as obtained in the autumn of the preceding year the effect of financial policy was unquestionably of chief importance. One way in which the financial factor played a serious part in the development of employment, was through its relation to price movements. The manner in which price movements affected trade were briefly as follows: The business world has to provide for the considerable period which elapses between beginning the process of production and the consumer getting the goods and paying for them. In different industries that interval of time varies, but in many industries it is not less than six months from the beginning to the end of the process, and, where long distances are concerned, it is very often a great deal more. All through that time the entrepreneur is engaged in paying out money for wages and in other ways which he will recoup when, at the end of the process, he sells his article for money. Now if prices have fallen during this process the costs of production may not be recouped and the anticipated profit may be completely wiped out. For this reason it is only to be expected t h a t whenever a fall of prices is anticipated, enterprise tends to be considerably restrained. Therefore I should say that one of the principal ways in which the financial factor operates is to cause, rightly or wrongly, an expectation in the minds of individual persons that prices are going to move in a certain direction; and if the business world as a whole is widely of the opinion that prices are going to fall, then there will be numerous individuals who can only protect themselves from loss by throwing their employees out of work, although the things those employees would make if they were in work are necessary and useful and desirable, at that cost of effort, to the "community as a whole. So the method of curing that would be to prevent, so far as one could, that there should be any reason why business men should expect that prices aie going to fall. Dealing then with the second point, that of determining whether there were adequate measures available for influencing the movement of the price level and so sustaining the anticipation of healthy markets, Mr. Keynes considered that this was possible through the regulation of the credit supplied to the business community by Joint Stock Banks. The amount of credit issued by these institutions could be controlled very largely by the Bank of England, — 129 — partly through movements in the Bank Rate (that is, the discount payable on the money lent to the Joint Stock Banks for the repletion of their cash reserves) and partly by influencing the volume of the cash reserves of the Joint Stock Banks (through the sale of securities and other assets held by the Bank of England). By influencing both the volume of bank reserves and the cost of their repletion, the Bank of England had an effective double control over the expansion of bank credit in general. Mr. Keynes wished to emphasise also the very important psychological effect of movements in the Bank Rate. Suppose the business world believed that this policy (of credit control) was going to be put through with determination, so that when there was a tendency for prices to rise all the forces of the financial world would be brought to bear to prevent them rising further, then the kind of expectation of which I have spoken would never arise strongly enough to make them go out of business and reduce the extent of employment to the degree they do now. It is not the actual rise or fall of prices that causes unemployment, although the actual rise and fall of prices causes profits and losses to business men. What chiefly causes unemployment is the anticipation of falling prices. If, therefore, this policy can be put strongly into force, so that the business world knows that when prices have risen more than a certain amount every possible measure will be taken to prevent them rising further, that will very much diminish the expectation of falling prices which they would otherwise entertain. It might be noted that at the end of the discussion, Mr. Henderson deprecated somewhat the drawing of distinctions between the different measures available for influencing credit. All the different methods could be used at the same time, and in point of historical fact had been used effectively by the Bank of England. When one measure seemed ineffective, the Bank of England went on to others until the control was complete. Speaking, finally, of the immediate policy to be adopted, Mr. Keynes said that he considered the time might soon be opportune for giving effect to the new idea for control and stabilisation. The experiment might be started as soon as the slump was thoroughly over and the boom beginning, the new policy being that of putting on dearer money at a very early date compared with previous occasions and avoiding the impending boom of 1925 or 1926. Such a policy as is here indicated would be equivalent to following the precedent set by the United States in which, as has already teen seen, every facility was given, by the easing of credit, to the revival of trade until ultimately recovery was complete. Then an attempt was made to prevent the development of a new boom and to stabilise industrial conditions at the high level of activity reached. 9 — 130 — As far as immediate action is concerned in Great Britain it would seem eminently desirable that not only should the price of credit be kept low until recovery is further advanced, but that industry should have full confidence in the continuance of this policy. For as Mr. Keynes has pointed out, whatever industry is led to expect as regards the future, the expectation tends to be realised. And had it been possible to adopt officially a fully recognised policy of easy credit at an early stage in the depression when industry was nervously anticipating the possibility of further deflation and was consequently unwilling to expand enterprise, a valuable stimulus might perhaps have been given to trade revival. CHAPTER V GENERAL SURVEY OF THE PERIOD OF RECOVERY The general correlation between changes in unemployment and prices observed in the first part of this enquiry continued throughout the period of revival; for the reduction of unemployment was generally accompanied by a rise in prices. In the first group of countries considered, namely, the United States, Italy, France and Belgium, this relation was very clear, though there was a marked difference in the nature of the movement as between the United States and Italy on the one hand and France and Belgium on the other. In the two former countries the rise was of fairly short duration and was followed by a period of comparative stability. In France and Belgium, on the contrary, the rise in prices continued until the spring of 1924, perhaps justifying the apprehension that the boom accompanying this movement would be followed by depression. In the United States and Italy, on the other hand, where comparative stability of prices has been secured, labour market conditions appear to be normal. This evidence should be associated with that noted in the case of Finland where prices remained stable in 1921-23 and there was no depression, although the neighbouring Scandinavian countries suffered very severely. Similarly, the stability of prices appears to have favoured the Czechoslovak labour market in 1923, the number of unemployed having been reduced by half during the year. In Austria a similar effect accompanied a moderate rise in prices, a movement which bore no resemblance, however, to the violent rise that had preceded the stabilisation of the currency. Even in Germany, after the depression at the end of 1923, the first symptoms of revival were indicated in June 1924 by a return to a slight rise in prices. — 132 — The other counts ies reviewed above are those in which the depression has been most acute and lasting. They are also those in which the recovery of prices was longest delayed. In the Netherlands the decline continued until 1923, that country being the only one in which unemployment continued to increase, apart from seasonal fluctuations, until the year 1923. In Sweden also, the fall in prices continued almost without a break until the beginning of 1923. During 1921 and 1922 the proportion of unemployed workers remained at the very high average of 26 per cent, and 23 per cent. Revival set in as soon as the fall became less marked. (The annual average of prices was only 5.7 per cent, lower in 1923 than in 1922.) The volume of unemployment in 1923 (13 per cent.), although only half that of 1921, was still very high as compared with the pre-war situation (4.4 per cent, in 1913). The fall in wholesale prices was also very prolonged in Norway and D.enmark, lasting from 1920 until September 1922 in Denmark and January 1923 in Norway. The labour market showed little sign of recovery until 1923 when the situation still remained very bad (average unemployment percentage of 10.7 in Norway as compared with 1.6 in 1913, and 12.7 in Denmark as compared with 7.5). In Switzerland the fall in wholesale prices continued until April 1922. In Great Britain, finally, the slight rises in prices which took place at the beginning of 1922 and 1923 were accompanied by a fall in unemployment, but in each case they were followed by a compensatory fall, and a more clearly marked tendency to rise did not appear until September 1923. In brief, it may be said that there has been a very close relation in the different countries between the severity and duration of unemployment on the one hand and the extent of the fall in prices on the other. The longer the fall in prices, the more acute and prolonged was unemployment. This positive conclusion may be supplemented by certain evidence of a negative character which is perhaps rather more unexpected: the relatively unimportant part played by export trade in the revival of employment. Some indication of this circumstances has alreadj been given in the first part of this survey. Apart from certain exceptions, it was shown that the outbreak of the unemployment crisis could not be attributed to a reduction of foreign trade. It is true that the depression, once begun, was aggravated by the diminution of exports, and it is not suggested here that the — 133 — difficulties confronting foreign trade have not considerably complicated the situation. In general, however, the international situation does not appear to have played a leading role either in prolonging or in abating the crisis. In the United States the volume of exports was less in 1922 and 1923, years of economic revival and prosperity, than in 1921, a year of depression. This would also appear to have been the case in Belgium. Similarly in Czechoslovakia, exports in 1923, a year of revival, were slightly less than in 1922, a year of severe unemployment. As regards the Scandinavian countries, there was a considerable reduction of exports in Norway and Sweden in 1921, the first year of the crisis, but in 1922, during which year the depression continued with disastrous severity, exports rose to a level as high as, if not greater than that of 1920, a year of great economic activity. In Denmark, even in 1921, exports were heavier than in 1920. This was also the case in the Netherlands, where from 1920 to 1923 exports rose from year to year, while unemployment increased. In Switzerland, exports were less in 1922 than in 1921, and less in 1923 than in 1922, while at the same time unemployment decreased. The only countries covered by the enquiry which show exception to this paradoxical relation are France and Italy. In Great Britain it would seem that the reduction in exports in 1921-1923 as compared with 1913 was a serious factor in the severe unemployment which still oppresses that country. Nevertheless, exports in 1923 were larger than in 1920, in which year the unemployment percentage averaged only 2.4. The above observations have been presented with a degree of reserve in view of the somewhat general character of the calculations and of the statistics available for estimating the volume of foreign trade. It would nevertheless seem clear that in the majority of countries the state of the foreign market has had much less influence than generally thought on the development and abatement of unemployment. PART III Conclusions. FLUCTUATIONS OF PRICES AND UNEMPLOYMENT, 1920 TO 1923 The relationship between unemployment and price fluctuations observed in the foregoing survey for the period 1920 to 1923 may be analysed as follows: (1) A rapid fall in prices has always been accompanied by a marked increase in unemployment. (2) A rise in prices not exceeding certain limits has almost invariably been accompanied by a marked reduction of unemployment. (3) A violent rise in prices such as has taken place in certain countries as the result of catastrophic inflation has ultimately led to a crisis of unemployment. (4) A period of price stabilisation following such a rise has been characterised first by an increase in unemployment but soon after by a gradual revival of employment. (5) When the stabilisation of prices has followed a period of falling prices the reduction of unemployment has been slow. (6) When the stabilisation of prices has followed a moderate rise, the rapid improvement in the labour market which had accompanied the rise has continued or the high level of activity reached has been maintained. These relationships are not peculiar to the period under consideration but have previously been recognised as a characteristic feature of the cyclical fluctuations and crises of unemployment experienced before the war. THE MOVEMENT OF PRICES AND THE TRADE CYCLE In almost all explanations given of the trade cycle, however varied they may be, it is to be seen that the movement of prices — 136 — plays a certain part. A brief description of some of these theories might be given here \ The Competition Theory of Trade Cycles The essential motive of industry as at present organised is the desire for gain. When there is prospect of good profit, industrial expansion is stimulated. Competitive forces are thereby set up, one business leader vying with another for a large share of the market and also for the raw materials and capital goods upon which enterprise depends. This competition of producers for material and plant causes an intensification of demand and a further stimulus to production. The process has thus a cumulative tendency, every new demand increasing the prospect of gain and every new gain adding stimulus to demand. Industry may thus develop the highest pitch of activity before satiation point is reached. However, as the new plant and capital outlay is brought more and more fully into operation, increased quantities of goods are forced on to the market, and ultimately overshoot the demand of the consumer, causing a glut. The competition then becomes that of sellers rather than of buyers, prices being forced down precipitately. Depression follows and continues until the surplus of goods is taken up by the market. Theories relating to the Failure of Demand The theory of diminishing "utility" or "value in use" has some relation to the foregoing explanation, but emphasises more particularly the part which the consumer, rather than the producer, plays in the general movement. It starts with the assumption t h a t consumers' demand is satiable or, at least, may reach a point of comparative satiation. When goods are produced in ever-increasing quantities, each successive addition has a somewhat less "value in use" compared with previous supplies. In the long run, this means that supply cannot be increased indefinitely with1 In the classification of the different theories of the trade cycle the summaries and critical surveys given by Professors Mitchell, Aftalion, and Hansen have assisted the study from original sources. In view of the necessity of combining and summarising a large number of different theories, it has -been impossible to retain fully the original conceptions of each separate writer. The main purpose of the present outline is to distinguish as clearly as possible the principal classes of causes which may be responsible for fluctuation. In this way, a comparatively wide view may be secured, though there must inevitably be considerable omissions of detail. — 137 — out outrunning demand. The periodical checking of industrial process is, as it were, a final consequence of the gradually diminishing utility or value in use of the increasing quantities of commodities produced, leading ultimately to a general price decline. Other theories relating to the failure of demand depend less on the assumption that demand is itself satiable than on the belief that it is limited for other reasons, such, for instance, as the insufficiency of wages. The argument is sometimes stated thus. During the periods of revival and prosperity real wages do not increase as rapidly as total production. For, on the one hand, profits are diverted to the production of capital goods rather than distributed as wages ; and on the other hand, stocks of finished goods are amassed in warehouses and stores rather than released for sale on the market. This two-fold process of storing up reserves leads ultimately to overproduction, followed by temporary stagnation. But such overproduction is considered in this case to be essentially a result of under-consumption. The stabilisation of prices would appear to have comparatively little relation to such theories as the three outlined above. However, it will be seen that in the one case fluctuation is considered to be caused through alternations in the competitive demand of producers, and in the other cases through changes in the demand of the final consumer. If it is true then that demand can only find effective expression through some form of money or "purchasing power" (since no man can buy unless he has money or credit) the regulation of the community's purchasing power in accordance with price movements would result in the regulation of its total effective demand, and would seem to counteract to a certain extent any fluctuations arising out of the changing character of demand, whether it be that of consumers or of producers. Theories relating to Business Confidence The central factor in many theories of the trade cycle is the state of confidence in business. Whenever the industrial world in general develops either optimism or pessimism with regard to trade prospects, the anticipation, whatever it may be, is usually realised. For if, on the one hand, industry has reason to believe that profits will be good in the future, this leads to the very expansion of enterprise on which the future prosperity depends. On the other hand, when there is general lack of confidence, expansion is restrained and depression does in fact follow. — 138 — For various reasons, this spirit of confidence tends to be a com- munal force affecting all alike. Industries and firms are interdependent to a very high degree, the success or failure of one infecting, as it were, its neighbours. Moreover, captains of industry are in close personal touch, read the same trade journals and watch the same trade signs. In consequence, any factor which affects the state of confidence in business will, through its. widespread diffusion throughout the industrial community, exert a powerful influence for activity or decline. Amongst the factors which do so influence business confidence, the trend of prices must be considered of some importance. An upward movement of the price level yields an additional premium of profit for the producer, which stimulates enterprise and leads to greater optimism. Conversely, a fall in the price level reduces profits and begets pessimism. The stabilisation of prices, particularly if it were carried out officially as a recognised policy, would tend to reduce fluctuations in business confidence and, according to the above theory, would thereby render industry itself more stable. Speculation Theories Amongst the factors which make for instability of production, emphasis is sometimes laid on the tendency amongst merchants and retailers to increase their stocks during a period of rising prices and reduce them when prices fall. It is in their immediate interests to follow such a course; and thus it will be seen that movements in prices, by causing fluctuation in the demand of merchants and retailers, produce instability in the volume of production and employment. In the same way it will be seen that price changes affect also the extent of speculative expansion of enterprise, at one time stimulating, at another time restraining new development. Theories of Over-capitalisation It has been observed in the past that during a period of trade revival, after serious depression, there frequently occurs a sudden outburst of capital expansion. This new development is favoured because reserves of plant and machinery require renewal, having become very largely exhausted through lack of replacement during the depression. Moreover, interest rates and other costs, including wages, are low. The feeling is that everything has "touched — 139 — bottom" and that the time is opportune for new expansion whilst costs are still low. Under such a stimulus capital expansion continues progressively. Employment increases and with employment grows the demand for consumers' goods. This in turn stimulates further production, justifying and encouraging greater capital expansion. The process might, it seems, continue indefinitely. But if, during the development, a stage is reached at which the large accession of new capital begins to turn out goods in excess of the effective demand of the final consumer, stocks will inevitably pile up and the phenomenon known as overproduction will be gradually produced. There must then follow a check to production and to capital expansion accompanied by unemployment and depression. This method of explanation appears to be largely independent of the movement of prices; however, since it postulates, for its initial operation, the actual existence of wide fluctuations of trade, of which it is merely an exaggerating feature, it would not seem to invalidate the conclusion reached through the study of other causes of instability, that price movements contribute materially to the factors producing fluctuations of economic activity. Monetary Theories Finally, the monetary theories, whilst accepting for the most part the influence of the factors reviewed above, give special prominence to the part played by currency and credit facilities in stimulating or restraining activity. If there arises a tendency towards economic expansion, such development can only be effectively realised provided there is a corresponding increase in monetary accommodation. According to these theories, the boom is essentially dependent upon the over-extension of credit and currency, and the depression is aggravated by the too rapid contraction of these facilities. In the period of prosperity, the rise of prices is thus stimulated, and subsequently the fall is accelerated in the slump. The solution to which the monetary theories lead is thus that currency and credit should be controlled with the essential object of maintaining the stability of the level of prices, thereby eliminating the possibility of an inflationist boom and the subsequent reaction to depression. It has been felt expedient thus to outline certain of the principal theories of industrial fluctuation, without, however, associating — 140 — them with the authors concerned, or entering into details which would exceed the scope or purpose of this report. It might be of advantage, however, to quote here the opinions of certain eminent economists relating to the rôle played by the instability of the price level in determining the fluctuation of economic activity. Professor Charles Gide emphasises more particularly the bonus which rising prices confer on the manufacturer and retailer as a result of the lapse of time between the purchase of raw material and sale of final product. The function of every merchant, and indeed of every manufacturer, is to purchase raw materials or wholesale stocks at a certain price and then sell them again in the form of manufactured goods or articles of consumption. If there is a rise of prices in the interval between the two operations, this is all profit. This is why rising prices have always been considered by all producers — the entire active section of the community — as a stimulant, a tonic, or a rise in temperature, as it were, which speeds up activity; whereas a fall in prices acts as a refrigerator: it depresses trade. Those who have bought goods tobe sold at the end of three months find, if prices have fallen during this period that all their profit has thereby been swallowed up or that loss has even been sustained l . Professor Gustav Cassel has frequently urged the necessity of avoiding a policy of deflation on account of its paralysing influence on trade. It is no use speaking of gradual deflation. Once it is made clear to everybody that prices are to be brought down to a fraction of what they are now, enterprise will very generally come to a standstill, borrowers must suffer terrible losses, banks will show themselves unable to resist the shock and the working classes must be exposed to unemployment to a degree which is in itself a severe evil and which involves a great danger for the maintenance of social order 2. Mr. J. M. Keynes shows that since industry is working in a money economy, the all-important motive of production is the prospect of monetary profit which, in turn, is dependent on the money price obtained. Ultimately wemake goods to exchange them for other goods ; but imm ediately we make them for money. An interval of time elapses between production and sale. If therefore there is an expectation that the money-price prevailing at the date of sale will be lower than the money-cost during the period of production, obviously no one will produce. Since some of the money-costs of production are fixed for long periods and others, particularly wages, cannot be changed without a struggle, the productive process is bound to be brought •ASSOCIATION POUR L'ENSEIGNEMENT DE LA COOPÉRATION: Les mouve- ments des prix et leurs causes, p. 22. 1922. 2 Speech before the International Chamber of Commerce, Rome, 18-24 March, 1923. — 141 — "to a standstill whenever a fall in prices is widely anticipated amongst merchants. If the anticipation is correct, everyone who is able to put off giving an order will profit by doing so. When prices are expected to rise, the opposite is the case; everyone whose credit permits him to place his order in advance will profit by doing so. In both cases the action of individuals endeavouring to take advantage of the anticipated movement is cumulative, and tends in itself to turn the anticipation into a fact *. Professor Irving Fisher considers that the manner in which trade fluctuations are intensified by price movements is this: When prices rise, great profits are made because, as we have seen, the ' profiteer ' or stockholder wins without effort from the bondholder and from the employees on salary or wages. His easy profits lead him to 'extend himself until, when interest charges, rents, salaries, and wages do catch up, his prosperity ceases, he gets caught in debt, becomes a bankrupt, and involves others in a chain of bankruptcies a The wage-earner also is involved in the catastrophe. Primarily a gainer when prices are falling, because his wages fall more slowly than prices, he nevertheless suffers more unemployment during the lowered cost of living than during rising prices, and in the mismanagement, at the end, he suffers with the rest 3. Professor Fisher has described the trade cycle as being largely a "dance of the dollar" and shows graphically that movements of trade in America from 1914 to 1922 have followed almost exactly movements in the rapidity of change of prices. 4 Professor Aftalion, whose theory of trade cycles is largely independent of the monetary factor, considers, however, that the movem e n t of prices may react cumulatively on the state of business confidence : A rise in prices conduces to a spirit of optimism which in turn exaggerates the upward movement. A fall in prices may give rise to excessive pessimism which further aggravates the fall5. Mr. F. Lavington, of the University of Cambridge, believes the state of confidence in business to be a factor of outstanding importance and explains as follows the manner in which price movements react upon it. Rising prices, by conferring a bounty on the entrepreneur, react upon and reinforce the rise in business confidence. In this way there is generated a powerful cumulative stimulus to trade activity. But within this movement are causes tending to destroy the confidence on which it is based ; for on the one 1 2 3 4 Reconstruction in Europe, 18 May 1922, p. 66. Stabilising the Dollar, p. 66. The Macmillan Co., 1920. Ibid., p. 77. Quarterly publication of the American Statistical Association, Dec. 1923, pp.5 76-80. Crises périodiques de surproduction, Vol. I, p. 294. M. Rivière & Cie., 1913. — 142 — hand rising prices are sapping bank reserves and, on the other, the artificial profitableness of business and the excessive confidence accompanying it, leads to errors in business forecasts which sooner or later must be exposed 1. Professor Pigou d r a w s a t t e n t i o n a m o n g s t o t h e r t h i n g s t o t h e relation b e t w e e n prices a n d t h e fund available for t h e p a y m e n t of wages, s t a t i n g t h a t The liability of general prices to vary, or, in other words, the instability of the standard of purchasing power, is a cause tending to expand the range of the movements that occur in the aggregate wage-fund. Consequently, the introduction of any arrangement capable of counteracting this cause would, pio tanto lessen the fluctuating character of the demand for labour and, therewith, the average volume of unemployment 2 . Professor F . W . T a u s s i g gives p a r t i c u l a r emphasis t o t h e effect of price m o v e m e n t s u p o n speculative b u y i n g . A curious part, and one too much neglected in discussions about the course of crises, is played by the distributing middlemen — the wholesalers and jobbers and retailers. These constitute the immediate purchasing public for the 'producers'. When they buy freely, business is brisk; when they hold off, business is dull. They are not only subject to psychological contagion; they are also moved by very simple calculations of profit and loss. Their operations are almost exclusively in the simple purchase and sale of goods, and their success depends almost solely on prices. They buy freely when they think that prices will rise, and cut down purchases when they think that prices will fall. The very fact that they so think, and accordingly act, accelerates the rise of prices in the one case, and accelerates the fall in the other. During an upswing period, they add to their stocks, thinking to sell them at an advance, or at least to protect themselves against a later rise in the prices of what they buy. Then comes the shock — a bad failure, a financial panic. They jump to the conclusion that 'things are going down', countermand old orders as far as possible, give no new ones, live from hand to mouth in their purchases and sales, and wait until they think that prices have touched bottom 3. Similar a r g u m e n t s m i g h t be q u o t e d from a large n u m b e r of o t h e r a u t h o r i t i e s , t e n d i n g t o show t h a t t h e t r a d e cycle, even i n t h e less intense form experienced before t h e war, w a s seriously a g g r a v a t e d b y price fluctuations a n d t h a t a policy of price s t a b i l i t y would lead t o m u c h g r e a t e r e q u i l i b r i u m in i n d u s t r y as a w h o l e . T H E RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE UNEMPLOYMENT CRISES OF 1920 ,TO 1 9 2 3 AND THE GENERAL TRADE CYCLE The fact that fluctuations in prices were one of the principal features of economic fluctuations both before and after the war favours the presumption that the post-war crisis was not funda1 2 3 The Trade Cycle, p. 51. P. S. King & Son. 1922. Unemployment, p. 122. Home University Library. 1913. Principles of Economics, pp. 405-406. The Macmillan Co. 1921. — 143 — mentally different from pre-war depressions. The unemployment from which most industrial countries suffered between 1920 and 1923 would seem to be chiefly due to one of those general depressions which, alternating for more than a century with periods of intense industrial activity, constitute what might be described as the cyclical pulsation of industry. Often irregular and sometimes violent, these rhythmical fluctuations seem to some extent measurable by the general movement of prices. Thus the post-war depression might be considered a natural economic reaction corresponding in severity with the abnormal degree of price inflation and industrial expansion preceding it. It would follow that the great political problems which have oppressed the world for several years, although exceptional in character and duration, can only be regarded as the indirect cause of the severe unemployment from which the world has suffered. In reality this post-war unemployment would thus be a symptom, accentuated much beyond pre-war limits, of some permanent defect in the economic system. Certain important differences are indeed to be noted between the situation before and after the war. For instance, before the war industrial countries were generally affected by unemployment almost simultaneously and in a fairly uniform manner. This has by no means been the case in the post-war period. It would seem therefore as if some previously existing bond of solidarity had slackened since the war. In this connection, it was to be seen from the review of the situation country by country that fluctuations of international trade have had very much less bearing on unemployment in most countries than fluctuations in home prices; in other words, that in the present crisis the loss of markets within the frontier has been of much greater importance than fluctuations in foreign demand. Hence, the purely commercial link between countries appears to have been of little influence in uniting the economic activity of the several countries in the post-war period. However this may be, there is another international link which existed before the war and has now disappeared, namely, that arising out of the monetary system which was then common to almost all industrial countries; the gold standard, the effect: of which was to internationalise price fluctuations. That standard has since been abandoned, through force of circumstances, in very many countries, and each of them has adopted an independent currency policy. This has doubtless accounted for the lack of uniformity of price fluctuations in the various countries, and cor- — 144 — responding differences in the dates of the crises in these countries (if the fairly general opinion may be accepted that there is a close connection between price fluctuations and industrial activity). In final analysis, however, this post-war irregularity of movement relates only to differences in price fluctuations as between the several countries, the fluctuation in each individual country having invariably borne out the relationship previously established between the movement of prices and the movement of industrial activity. This continued correlation thus provides further corroboration for the view that the acute and prolonged unemployment experienced in many countries after the war is in essence part of the more or less regular cyclical fluctuations which have hitherto characterised the present economic system. THE STABILISATION OF PRICES Price fluctuations may certainly not be regarded as the only factor producing involuntary unemployment, and in the present crisis, especially, other factors have been by no means negligible. There would seem no question, however, that if price movements could to some extent be controlled and stabilised, the alternations of feverish activity and depression from which industry has suffered for a century or more would be considerably diminished, and that the risk of unemployment would thereby be much reduced. In the present report, no pretence is made of definitely pointing the solution to the difficult problem of the manner in which prices can be stabilised. It has nevertheless been thought expedient, with a view to the future more detailed study of these problems. to show briefly that there is an important current of opinion supporting the view that the attainment of a high degree of price stability is both desirable and possible. The movement for regulating the level of prices can be traced back to some of the earliest economic writings of the nineteenth century. But it was probably not until the year 1911 that definite efforts were made on an international scale to lead to some action by public bodies in this matter. It was in this year that Professor Irving Fisher opened a campaign for the international discussion of the means for stabilising the cost of living. He gained the support of many leading economists in Europe as well as in America and Japan. The proposal did not, however, materialise before the outbreak of the War. — 145 — The vast economic upheaval caused by the fluctuation of prices during and since the War has drawn economists, business men and labour leaders alike into the movement for the stabilisation of prices. In the United States, so great was the need felt for securing some fixity in the value of money that a powerful organisation known as the National Monetary Association has sprung up with the sole object of devising measures for securing greater stability of the price level in the United States. The motives of this Association are well expressed in the following extract from a speech by Professor Wesley C. Mitchell delivered at the Richmond meeting of the American Economic Association in 1919: One cannot conclude a survey of the violent changes in prices during the war and of the grave uncertainties of the near future without reflecting upon the badness of the best existing monetary systems. The United States has maintained the gold standard without serious limitation and has reorganised its banking system on approved lines. Nevertheless we have had price fluctuations almost as violent as those of the greenback period. These fluctuations have caused unmerited suffering to millions of families and have heaped unearned riches upon thousands. They have caused wasteful struggles, encouraged extravagance among some, and created the class of 'new poor'. They have promoted speculation and reduced the efficiency of management and labor. We are poorer in goods, more quarrelsome in spirit, less ready to work because of these fluctuations. All this has happened and is irretrievable. But within a few years fresh changes may happen just as evil in their consequences. This wretched record and this wretched prospect are a grave indictment of our present form of economic organisation. Have we not sufficient constructive imagination and practical sagacity to develop a better monetary system? Another organisation expressly established with a view to investigating the influence of monetary and price movements and through its researches to lead to the adoption of measures for the maintenance of unchequered industrial activity or, in the terms of the above resolution, to "measures taken with a view to sustaining economic activity, and thus stabilising the labour market", is the Pollak Foundation for Economic Research, organised under the direction of Dr. William T. Foster. In Europe the same movement for the stabilisation of the price level gains the support of such prominent leaders of thought as Professors Cassel and Wicksel of Sweden, Professor Gide of the Collège de France, Professor Pigou and Mr. J. M. Keynes of Cambridge, Mr. R. G. Hawtrey, Professor Verrijn Stuart of the University of Utrecht, and numerous other personalities whose names are current in international economic literature. 10 — 146 — The need for checking the violent rise of prices which was taking place in 1920 figured as perhaps the most prominent Recommendation of the Brussels Financial Conference. Serious warnings were also thrown out by the same body against the dangers of deflation, once inflation had been restrained. The Genoa Conference goes even further and states : "The essential requisite for the economic reconstruction of Europe is the achievement by every country of stability in the value of its currency." ' All these movements for the stabilisation of the value of money, i. e. of the level of prices, have one principal object, the maintenance of industry at its maximum permanent efficiency. In certain minds, however, the stabilisation of prices would seem to signify the stagnation or even the compression of trade. The evidence given in the earlier part of this report would seem to show, on the contrary, that even when industry is in the depth of depression, and confidence is very widely shaken, recovery can take place on a stable level of prices. In times of greater activity there is a still more powerful incentive, inherent in industry itself, towards greater and continuous development. For at all times, and more particularly in periods of prosperity, every unit in the business world, which is directed and propelled by human aspirations, tends to enlarge itself and contribute to the general increase of productivity. The stabilisation of prices is thus felt to constitute no restraint upon healthy expansion. What it does purport to restrain is that proportion of enterprise which can only prosper when rising prices yield an excess profit, a kind of enterprise which is uneconomic even in the boom and which, by its ultimate collapse, tends to aggravate depression. Again, the stabilisation of prices aims at eliminating the piling up of stocks, which not only reduces consumption and stimulates the rise of prices during the boom, but eventually reacts upon the market causing a glut and temporarily seizing up the wheels of industry. If, then, the stabilisation of prices may be interpreted to mean the stable and continuous expansion of industry, it would seem that not only would it yield a higher permant level of production, but also a higher permanent level of employment; and for this reason the question of securing the greater stability of this price level is especially pertinent to a study of the "measures taken 1 Resolution (1) of the Financial Commission. — 147 — with a view to sustaining economic activity, and thus stabilising the labour market." The various measures proposed for achieving price stability have one common feature : they recognise that the only practicable means for controlling the level of prices is through the monetary factor. The level of prices is subject to the influence of many factors, but in the present state of industrial organisation it is considered to be susceptible to efficient control by this one factor alone, and for that reason the regulation of money has been singled .out in all proposals for reform, as the one possible line of development. It is important, therefore, to consider how the promoters of the stabilisation movement consider the price level to be affected by the volume of money. The relation between money and prices might perhaps be most simply illustrated thus: if a rise of prices occurs, more money is required to purchase the same volume of goods; if there is a fall of prices, less money is required to buy the same amount of goods. The price level thus expresses the relationship between money and goods; and the stabilisation of prices means therefore the stabilisation of this relation between money and goods. If, then it were possible to regulate money so that its volume grew at identically the same rate as the volume of goods coming on the market, then the level of prices would tend to remain constant. Stabilising prices thus becomes essentially the problem of adjusting the volume of money to fluctuations in the other factor, the volume of production available for sale. By the term "money" used in this sense, is meant every kind of purchasing instrument, be it cheque, note or coin, and thus the regulation of money includes the regulation of credit in all forms. How then can such regulation be achieved ? As explained in an earlier paragraph of this report ', almost every form of purchasing power passes into the community through the intermediary of the banks. New purchasing power is created by the extension of new loans to business men by the banks. The repayment of such loans and their non-renewal constitute the cancellation of purchasing power. Now these loans when issued may take the form of credit accounts against which the borrower may draw by cheque, or they may consist of notes and coin, according as the borrower may wish. Thus the policy of the banks with regard to the issue of loans determines largely the »See p. 125. — 148 — volume of new money which is issued to the community in the form of credit, notes and coin. And, moreover, it is the most direct way in which the regulation of any of these forms of purchasing power can be effected *. The loan policy of the banking system in general is thus the essential feature in any proposal for monetary control. Carrying this idea one step further, it will be seen t h a t the most direct way to regulate the volume of money in circulation is to bring some influence to bear simultaneously on the loan policies of all the different units of the banking system. This is possible in countries in which banking is highly centralised. A central bank, by virtue of its holding a proportion of the legal tender reserves of commercial and other banks and having a certain control over the further issue of legal tender notes and coin, can, subject to certain limitations, direct the loan policy of the general banking system. It is for the purpose of securing such control that the Genoa Conference urges that central banks should be established in all countries in which they do not as yet exist. One of the principal ways in which the central bank is able to influence the loan policy of the general system is by varying the rate at which it will lend cash to other banks in discounting their bills. When the latter are thus obliged to pay more for the repletion of their cash reserves, they must of necessity charge more for the money they in turn lend to their customers ; in other words, they must raise the market rate of discount. Thus the Central Bank, by varying the central rate of discount, can exert a powerful influence over the loan policy of the general banking system 2. This idea finds the fullest confirmation in the declaration of the Brussels Conference to the effect t h a t : In normal times the natural and most effective regulator of the volume and distribution of credit is the rate of interest which the central Banks of 1 Currency may be withdrawn from the community through the sale of securities or other assets by the banks or by the Government. But if the community is in need of more currency it can apply to the banks and, in return for any legal claims it may have upon these banks, demand currency in such quantities as it may require. Thus the only direct control over the issue of legal tender currency is provided by control over the total volume of credit or of claims which must be redeemed by the banks. This volume is dependent on the loan policy of banks. The loan policy of banks in turn can be influenced by affecting their legal tender reserves, but the loan policy itself is the direct influence which may be brought to bear on the borrowing community with a view to regulating the volume of currency they absorb into circulation. 2 There are other possible methods of control. By certain processes the central bank can directly affect the volume of bank reserves and, therefore, their ability to extend credit. Furthermore, the psychological influence of movements in the Bank Rate is of some effect. Not less important are the voluntary agreements amongst bankers whereby they cause the deposit rate to move automatically with the Bank Rate. — 149 — Issue are compelled, in self-preservation and in duty to the community, to raise when credit is unduly expanding 1. The evidence which may be drawn from a survey of the years 1918-1923 adds some support to the belief that the Bank Rate may be used as a means of controlling credit and, through credit, the level of prices. Violent inflation was proceeding in almost all countries in the world during the years 1918-1920 and the whole situation threatened to get out of control. In order to check the expansion of credit, central banks followed the customary policy of raising the bank rate. In Japan the rise of wholesale prices 2 was checked in March 1920 after the raising of the central rate of discount to 8.03 per cent, in November 1919. Prices * began to fall in the United States as from May 1920 after the raising of the rediscount rate to 7 per cent, in the same month. In Great Britain the price-level * ceased rising in April 1920, the Bank Rate having been raised to 7 per cent, in the same month. In Sweden, prices 6 culminated in June 1920, the central rate of discount having been moved to 7 per cent, in March 1920. Similarly, the turn in prices followed the raising of the central discount rate in Norway, Denmark, Finland, Belgium, France, and Italy. There was no movement of the central rate during 1920 in either Germany or Austria, in both cases the rate remaining stationary at 5 per cent. Although the bank rate may be effective "in normal times" in controlling the volume of credit and the movement of prices, there may arise abnormal circumstances which tend seriously to limit its efficiency. If banks are to be in a position to control the issue of loans, they must be able to render borrowing either unprofitable or unwise for their clients. Now the Government is a borrower over whom the banks have no control and, in turn, the Government is compelled to borrow either from the banks or the public whenever it cannot meet its expenditure out of taxation. Through this train of causation it will be seen that, in order that banks may have satisfactory control over credit, it is essential first that the national budget should be approximately balanced. In this connection the Brussels Conference declares: The chief cause (of inflation) in most countries is that the Governments, finding themselves unable to meet their expenditures out of revenue, have 1 2 8 Report of the Conference, p. 18. Bank of Japan. Bureau of Labour Statistics. *6 The Statist. Official. — 150 — been tempted to resort to the artificial creation of fresh purchasing power, either by the direct issue of additional legal tender money, or more frequently by obtaining — especially from the Banks of Issue, which in some cases are unable and in others unwilling to refuse them — credits which must themselves be satisfied in legal tender money. We say, therefore, that. Governments must limit their expenditure to their revenue. (We are not considering here the finance of reconstructing devastated areas.) Banks, and especially Banks of Issue, should be freed from political pressure and should be conducted solely on the lines of prudent finance 1. The Genoa Conference endorses the same view, stating that: So long as there is a deficiency in the annual budget of the State which is met by the creation of fiduciary money or bank credits, no currency reform is possible, and no approach to the establishment of the gold standard can be made. The most important reform of all must therefore be the balancing of the annual expenditures of the State without the creation of fresh credits unrepresented by new assets. The balancing of the budget requires adequate taxation, but if Government expenditure is so high as to drive taxation to a point beyond what can be paid out of the income of the country, the taxation itself may still lead to inflation. Reduction of Government expenditure is the true remedy 3. There seems reason to believe, therefore, that whenever banking is centralised and is free from political pressure, the central institution can exercise a considerable influence over the movement of prices through the medium of its credit policy. In further corroboration of this view, it is to be noted that the fall of prices in 1921 and 1922 was only checked in a large number of countries after credit had been eased by the lowering of the bank rate. This was the case in the United States, Great Britain, Sweden, Norway, Denmark, France and Belgium 3. Finally, there is the case of the United States in which, intentionally or unintentionally, stability was achieved in 1923 after a rapid recovery of the level of prices in 1922. The process of credit restraint, which was necessary to prevent the period of rising prosperity from developing into an inflationist boom, was effected 1 s 8 Report of the Conference, p'. 18. Resolution 7 of the Financial Commission. Although France and Belgium fall strictly within this group it seems probable that the rapid recovery of the price level was due rather to Government financial policy than to the easing of industrial credit. It should further be noted that it is not justifiable to compare the level of the bank rate in one country with that of another with a view to comparing their respective monetary policies. In certain countries the central rate is much less effective in controlling the credit situation of the general system and cannot therefore be considered such a clear indication of the actual state of the money market. In countries such as Japan, Finland and Latvia, the customary rate of discount demanded by the central banks appears to fluctuate about a figure of 8 per cent. It is therefore the movement of the bank rate, rather than the level at which it stands, which gives the clearest indication of the monetary policy being followed. — 151 — partly by a slight rise in the Rediscount Rate and partly by the sale of securities and other assets by the Federal Reserve Banks, both methods forming part of a general conscious policy of credit control which resulted in the maintenance of a high degree of price stability in the latter half of the year 1923. Since such eminent success has attended the monetary policy of the United States during the last two years, it might be well to give an account of some of the proposals for future guidance which emanate from the economists of that country. The most complete system for the control of industry through the regulation of credit is probably that worked out by Mr. Carl Snyder, General Statistician of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The system he has evolved comprises: (1) an objective — the stabilisation of prices; (2) the means for securing that objective; (3) satisfactory Information and forecasting indices to permit "anticipatory" action to be taken in the application of the proposed measures. In the first place Mr. Snyder proposes as the objective of monetary policy the stabilisation of prices around a definite "normal"; he would aim at preventing prices from rising or falling more than 3 per cent, above or below the given normal price level \ The principal means he suggests for carrying out this purpose are the same as those which were adopted in 1923 with a view to checking the impending boom: the manipulation of the Rediscount Rate and the purchase or sale of securities by Federal reserve banks 2. Finally, in order to control the movement of prices it is necessary not only to have an accurate measure of the movement itself when it actually takes place, but also, if possible, the means of forecasting the probable future trend of prices. Preventive action may then be taken, instead of purely compensatory action after the movement has occurred. For such a purpose Mr. Snyder and his staff have worked out two indices, an index of the volume of trade s and an index showing the rate of turnover of average bank deposits 4. Both these indices render possible to a certain extent the forecasting of the probable future trend of prices 5 . 1 American Economic Review, June 1923, p. 284. ' Ibid. Quarterly Publication of the American Statistical Association, Dec. 1923. * Journal of the American Bankers' Association, Feb. 1924. s One of the possible future uses of economic barometers is indicated here, namely, that of providing the central authority with the information necessary for the guidance of its credit policy. 8 — 152 — This combination of aim, means and information thus produces a system which appears to commend itself on many grounds. In the first place it adopts as its principle objective the stabilisation of prices, necessarily the first step for securing the stable expansion of industry. Secondly, it proposes control by measures which have already been put into operation with some degree of success. Thirdly, the promise which it gives of supplying the necessary information for enabling anticipatory action to be taken marks a very definite step in advance and would seem to justify a measure of confidence in the success of the scheme as a whole. It may be that there are still a number of countries in whioh a policy of price stabilisation would meet with difficulty. There may, for instance, be no means of securing control over the loan policy of banks owing to the lack of centralisation in banking or in the regulation of legal tender currency. Moreover, there may not exist a satisfactory system of measuring the movement of the price level itself. Finally, public opinion may be more generally educated to the desirability of securing stability of the exchange rate rather than stability of the level of prices. For such countries, the stabilisation of the exchange rate with a country in which the price level is already stabilised would, however, yield not only exchange stability but also a high degree of price stability. This might be illustrated from the measures recently adopted in Denmark * with a view to regulating the exchange rate with Great Britain. A fund of five million pounds sterling has been established by the former country, consisting partly of bills and other exchange instruments which can'be immediately realised on the British and Danish money markets. By the continuous purchase and sale of sterling bills it will be possible to eliminate temporary fluctuations of the exchange rate of the kroner and to a certain extent diminish long period fluctuations. However, if a rise in Danish prices relatively to British were to take place this would set up a permanent tendency for the kroner to depreciate in terms of sterling. The sale of sterling bills from the fund would stem the movement for a time but only at the expense of the gradual exhaustion of the fund. If, therefore, it were found that serious inroads were being made into the fund, the next action on the part 1 Revue commerciale danoise, March 1924, p. 49.| — 153 — of the Danish controlling authorities would be to raise the rate of discount or by other means to restrain the issue of industrial credit internally in order that the Danish price level might be brought back to parity with that of Great Britain and thus remove the tendency for continuous depreciation of the kroner. It will thus be seen that Denmark, by stabilising its exchange rate with sterling, binds itself to approximately the same price policy; and, in consequence, if Great Britain has been successful in stabilising its price level about a given normal, the Danish price level will also be restrained in its fluctuations about a corresponding normal. If, therefore, one central country were able to secure an almost unvarying level of prices internally, and if subsequently other countries were to stabilise their rates of exchange with the central currency, not only would exchange stability be secured, but also price stability over the whole area affected. This system, universalised, is in fact in all essentials the one proposed by Mr. J. M. Keynes in A tract on Monetari/ Reform 1. Mr. Keynes recommends that the United States and Great Britain should separately endeavour to secure internal stability of the price level and that other countries might then conveniently use the dollar and the pound sterling as a basis for the stabilisation of their exchange rates. An earlier proposal for securing both price and exchange stability is the system recommended by the Genoa Economic Conference. This would entail the general resumption of the gold standard, or, as an intermediate stage, of the gold exchange standard 2. The purpose of the recovery of the gold basis, with a monetary unit of unvarying gold content, would be to secure exchange stability on the same footing as existed before the war. Stability of the value of gold, i.e. of gold prices, would be secured through the control of credit, effected by the central banks of the several countries working in conjunction. In order that there should be no shortage of gold which, by limiting monetary reserves, might impede the desired credit policy, the Genoa Conference proposes a system of international regulation of the world's supply of monetary gold. 1 KEYNES, J. M.: A Tract on Monetary Reform. The Macmillan Co. London, 1923. 2 By "gold exchange standard" is inferred a system under which a certain number of countries maintain the gold standard in complete form and other countries undertake to maintain the value of their currencies at a constant value in relation to one or more of the gold currencies. — ibi — It is to be seen, therefore, that the application by various methods of an international policy of price stabilisation is considered by numerous experts to be immediately practicable. The foregoing survey gives evidence of the capital importance of such a policy from the point of view of unemployment, and it is felt that no effort should be spared to discover the means for overcoming the difficulties which still confront its immediate application.