INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE PROBLEMS OF WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES GENEVA 1956 STUDIES AND EEPOETS New Series, No. 43 PUBLISHED BY THE INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE GENEVA, SWITZERLAND Published in the United Kingdom for the INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE by Staples Press Limited, London PRINTED BY " L A TRIBUNE DE G E N È V E " , GENEVA (SWITZERLAND) PEEFACE This study is a revised version of a report prepared by the International Labour Office for the Asian Regional Conference of the International Labour Organisation held in Tokyo in September 1953. While this was the first time that the question of wage problems had been included in the formal agenda of an Asian Regional Conference, the preparatory Asian Regional Conference held at New Delhi in 1947 had adopted a resolution concerning wage policy and family budget inquiries calling attention to the need for improvement in the wage standards in various industries and occupations, as well as the desirability of standardising, as far as possible, in each country or area, the wages in each industry or occupation where conditions were similar. The resolution also stated that while collective agreements were normally the most satisfactory means for the adjustment of wages, various reasons, including the comparative lack of organisation among employers and, to a much greater degree, among workers in many of the Asian countries, made it necessary for governments to take an active part in the fixing and enforcement of fair wages. The Conference accordingly requested the governments of Asian countries to assist the conclusion of collective agreements and to set up wage boards. It also called for studies by the International Labour Office of the working of collective agreements, wage boards and industrial tribunals and of the further steps which might be taken to secure fair wages for all workers. 1 Problems of wage policy in Asian countries were further considered by the Asian Advisory Committee of the International Labour Organisation in 1950. The Committee was in general agreement that increased productivity was a paramount consideration in Asian countries ; that the immediate need was for a minimum wage structure which would secure a reasonable living standard, from which should emerge, 1 The full text of the resolution is given in Official Bulletin I.L.O.), Vol. X X X , No. 3, 15 Nov. 1947, p. 179. (Geneva, IV WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES as the economy developed, proper living standards, including a fair share for labour, through rising productivity ; and that, in determining wage rates, the capacity of industry to pay should be taken into account. The Committee also emphasised the desirability of enacting minimum wage fixing legislation and of establishing the necessary machinery in all Asian countries where such action had not yet been taken. Finally, the Committee attached the greatest importance to the technical assistance which the International Labour Organisation could render in the field of wage policy, including the establishment and operation of wage fixing machinery, and in the field of methods of raising productivity. The present report contains as an Appendix the text of the resolution concerning wages adopted by the Asian Eegional Conference (Tokyo, September, 1953). The report also takes account of the conclusions reached in the various I.L.O. meetings which have discussed problems of wage policy in Asian countries. I t opens with a brief survey of the general problem of income in Asia and then proceeds to analyse the objectives of wage policy, the existing systems of wage regulation, problems which arise in the regulation of minimum wages and the relation of the wage level to the needs and progress of economic development. A final chapter briefly recapitulates some of the main points discussed in the report. CONTENTS Page PREFACE m CHAPTER I : The General Problem of Income in Asia 1 Some Basic Facts The Occupation Structure The Eole of Wage Earners The Level of Income Per Head The Distribution of Income Wage Diflerences among Various Groups of Wage Earners . 1 1 3 8 10 16 The Basic Approach to Eaising Income The Conflict between Capital Formation and Consumption . Possible Lines of Action Conclusions 28 28 33 37 CHAPTER I I : The Objectives of Wage Policy 39 Abolition of Malpractices in Wage Payment The Fixing of Minimum Wages Wages and Economic Development 40 43 46 CHAPTER I I I : Existing Systems of Wage Begulation 48 Protection of Wages 49 Machinery for Wage Determination Minimum Wage Fixing Conciliation and Arbitration in Wage Disputes 49 49 52 Scope and Methods of Wage Régulation Coverage of the Laws Factors To Be Considered in Determining the Level of Minimum Wages Other Rules of Operation 57 57 Application of Wage Legislation Minimum Wage Legislation Wage Determination by Industrial Tribunals 61 61 69 CHAPTER IV : Problems of Minimum Wage Policy The Question of Uniformity Uniformity among Industries Uniformity among Various Categories of Wage Earners . . 58 60 74 76 76 80 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES VI Page The Level of the Minimum Wage The Workers' Normal Needs The Capacity to P a y Minimum Wages The Effects of Wage Increases 84 85 87 90 Machinery for Minimum Wage ^Regulation The Fixing of Minimum Wages Machinery for Inspection and Enforcement 107 107 109 CHAPTER V : Wage Policy and Economic Development 112 The Adjustment of the Level of Wages to the Progress of Economic Development. 112 Unemployment, Capital Shortage and the Wage Level . . . . 113 Wages, Economic Development and Inflation 117 Profit-Sharing 119 The Wage Structure and Economic Development Systems of Payment by Eesults The Adjustment of Wages to Changes in the Cost of Living . . . 122 123 126 CHAPTEE V I : Conclusions 128 The Content of Minimum Wage Eegulation 129 Inspection and Enforcement 131 Wage Policy and Economic Development : The Problem of Coordination 132 The Problem of the Supply of Essential Consumers' Goods . . . 133 APPENDIX : Besolution concerning Wages Adopted by the Asian Begional Conference of the International Labour Organisation (Tokyo, September 1953) 135 INDEX 137 CHÁPTEE I THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA The present chapter sketches the general economic background against which the problems of wage policy in Asian countries must be considered. I t consists of two parts. The first presents certain basic facts regarding the income and employment of the Asian working population. A brief survey of these facts should help to make clear the kind of wage policy most needed in these countries and give some indication of the role that wage policy as such might be expected to play in raising the living standards of the working population. The second part considers the problem of the allocation of resources between capital formation and consumption which confronts Asian countries in their effort to accelerate economic development. The question, is clearly of central importance for determining the appropriate levels of wages and the rates at which they might be increased in these countries in the years immediately ahead. SOME BASIC FACTS In order to obtain the broad perspective necessary for the discussion of wage policy, an attempt is made below to bring together certain basic facts about (a) the occupation structure of the working population, (b) the role of wage earners, (c) the level of income per head, (d) the distribution of income and (e) the wage differences among various groups of wage earners. The Occupation Structure The central feature of the occupation structure of the working population in Asia is the predominance of agriculture and the small proportion engaged in manufacturing activities. Table I gives the percentage distribution of the working population in 12 Asian countries classified according to the 2 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES three broad divisions of production : primary, secondary and tertiary. 1 Although these figures may involve a substantial margin of error, they at least tend to show that in all these countries primary production absorbs by far the largest number of people and that tertiary production is numerically far more important than secondary production. The only notable exception to this general pattern is Japan, where the proportion engaged in secondary production is considerably higher, and in primary production lower, than in other countries in the region. By way of comparison, the occupational distribution in the United States in 1950 showed 12.5 per cent. of the working population in primary production, 37 per cent. in secondary and 50.5 per cent, in tertiary. TABLE I. PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF THE WORKING POPULATION IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Country Burma . . Ceylon . . China 1 . . India2 . . Indo-China Indonesia : Java . . Rest . . Japan . . Korea . . Malaya . . Pakistan . Philippines Thailand . Year Primary production Secondary production Tertiary production 1931 1946 1931 1931 1930 69.0 53.0 70.0 67.3 71.0 14.0 10.4 10.0 10.5 — 17.0 36.6 20.0 22.2 — 1930 1930 1950 1930 1947 1951 1948 1947 71.7 3 81.9 3 47.5 78.0 3 < 64.5 77.5 65.6 88.5 12.8 8.5 20.9 6.0 9.2 7.0 8.1 1.9 29 16.0 9.6 31.6 16.0 26.3 15.5 26.3 9.6 Sources : Japan, Malaya, Pakistan, the Philippines and Thailand—I.L.O. : Year Book of Labour Statistics 1954 (Geneva, 1954), pp. 21-23 ; India—idem : Year Book of Labour Statistics 1951-52 (Geneva, 1952), p. 17 ; Burma, China, Indonesia and Korea— Colin CLARK : The Conditions of Economic Progress, 2nd ed. (London, MacMillan and Co. Ltd., 1951), p. 399 ; Ceylon—Government ol Ceylon, Ministry of Finance : Economic and Social Development of Ceylon, 1926-1950 (Colombo, Government Press, 1951), p. xlii ; Indo-China—League of Nations : Industrialization and Foreign Trade (1945), p. 27. 1 Excluding women attributed to agriculture. ! Covering former British India, the Indian States and Burma. " Including mining. « Had fallen to 75 per cent, by 1936. 1 Primary production includes agricultural and pastoral production, fishing, forestry and hunting. Secondary production covers mining, manufacturing, huilding construction, public works and public utilities. Tertiary production consists of all other economic activities, the principal of which are distribution, transport, public administration, domestic service and all other activities producing a non-material output. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 3 The Role of Wage Earners One characteristic of the working population in Asia particularly relevant to the question of wage policy is that the majority of the working population are self-employed. The proportion of wage earners is considerably smaller than in the economically advanced countries. According to recent estimates salaried employees and wage earners, taken together, form 40 per cent, and 38 per cent, of the total working population in the Philippines and Japan respectively. For purposes of comparison it may be cited that the corresponding percentages are 91 in the United Kingdom, 82 in the United States and New Zealand, 77 in Australia, 75 in Sweden, 72 in Denmark, 65 in France and 50 in Italy. Leaving out salaried employees, wage earners alone form only 28 per cent. in the Philippines as compared with 53 per cent, in Denmark. In India in 1931 it was estimated that about 36 per cent, of the population engaged in all occupations depended on wage labour as a means of livelihood. 1 In other Asian countries, although similar estimates are at present not available, it can safely be said that because of the preponderance of smallscale family enterprises the volume of wage-earning employment is also much smaller than that of self-employment. For most Asian countries there are no accurate statistical data to show the distribution of wage-earning employment either among the three broad divisions of production or within each of these divisions. As a background for the consideration of wage policy the following observations can, however, be made : (1) In some Asian countries the majority of wage earners are agricultural workers. In India it was estimated that, of a total of 56.5 million wage earners in 1931, 31.5 million or 56 per cent, were agricultural labourers. 2 In the Philippines the corresponding percentage for 1948 was 65. 3 In Burma and Ceylon, although the figures are not available as a percentage of the total number of wage earners, agricultural wage earners are known to form, numerically, the largest single class of 1 In India in 1931 the total number of wage earners came to about 56.5 million out of 156 million persons engaged in all occupations. (See Kadhakamal MTJKERJEE : The Indian Working Glass, 3rd ed. (Bombay, Hind Kitabs Ltd., 1951), p. 2. 2 The Indian Working Class, loc. cit. 3 Figure computed from I.L.O. : Year Book of Labour Statistics 1951-52 (Geneva, 1952), p. 32. 4 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTEIES the rural working population. 1 The situation in other Asian countries is less clear owing to the absence of adequate data. Only in Japan is there definite evidence that agricultural wage earners as a class are relatively unimportant. 2 Among the agricultural wage earners in South-East Asia a distinction must be made between those employed on subsistence farms and those employed on plantations. The distinction is, however, not always clear, because in certain areas the same wage earners may work both on subsistence farms and on plantations at different seasons. Another difficulty in ascertaining the relative importance of these groups of agricultural wage earners lies in the instability of plantation employment, which tends to fluctuate markedly between years of prosperity and years of depression. Eecent information gathered by the I.L.O. gives the following figures on plantation employment in some of the Asian countries : in India, tea, coffee and rubber plantations together employ about 1,150,000 workers ; in Ceylon, tea and rubber plantations, about 620,000 ; in Indonesia, rubber, tea, sugar and coffee plantations, about 785,000 ; in Malaya, rubber plantations, about 288,000 ; in the Philippines, sugar plantations, about 217,000.3 In India the number of plantation workers is fairly small compared with the number of wage earners employed on subsistence farms. In other countries in South-East Asia the data available are not sufficient for statistical comparison. Nevertheless, in the light of the structure of their agrarian economies it might be a reasonable conjecture that, as a class, wage earners in subsistence agriculture are probably more numerous than plantation workers in Ceylon and the Philippines and vice versa in Indonesia and the Federation of Malaya. 1 In Burma in 1931 agricultural labourers represented 40 per cent, of the agricultural working population, whereas cultivating owners and tenantcultivators formed respectively 37 per cent, and 23 per cent. (See J. Russell ANDKUS : Burmese Economic Life (Stanford, California, Stanford University Press, 1948), p. 40.) In Ceylon a recent rural survey shows that of the agricultural families investigated " 48 per cent, were dependent on agricultural labour, 32 per cent, on owner-cultivators, 17 per cent, on tenant-cultivators and 3 per cent. on landlords of agricultural holdings ". (See Government of Ceylon, Department of Census and Statistics : Preliminary Report on the Economic Survey of Rural Ceylon, 1950 (Colombo, 1951), p . 10.) 2 In Japan in 1950 agricultural salaried employees and wage earners formed about 7.5 per cent, of the total number of salaried employees and wage earners. (See Tear Boole of Labour Statistics 1951-52, op. cit., p . 18.) 3 Basic Problems of Plantation Labour, International Labour Organisation, Committee on Work on Plantations, First Session, Bandung, 1950 (Geneva, I.L.O., 1950), p. 22. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 5 (2) As far as secondary production is concerned, the most significant fact is the small volume of factory employment. In nearly all Asian countries, except India, China and more particularly Japan, modern factory industries using motive power are still in the stage of infancy ; the number of wage earners employed in these industries accounts for only a small fraction of the total volume of wage-earning employment. Even in India at its wartime peak in 1944 the number employed in industrial establishments was only about 2.6 million; it fell to 2.3 million in 1947 and by 1951 had recovered to 2.5 million only. 1 When this figure is compared with a total of 56.5 million wage earners and with approximately 25 million non-agricultural wage earners in India in 1931, it will be readily seen that the role played by modern factory industries in creating wage-earning employment has so far been extremely limited. Employment in registered industrial establishments using mechanical aids or employing at least 50 workers in Indonesia in 1951 was estimated at 551 thousand. 1 In pre-war China it was estimated that modern factories employed no more than 1 million workers. 2 In Japan of a total of 13.9 million salaried employees and wage earners in 1950, about 4.4 million, or approximately 32 per cent., were engaged in manufacturing which, however, covers also handicraft and cottage industries. 3 Although no estimate is available showing the proportion of wage earners employed in modern factories, it must be considerably higher in Japan than in other Asian countries. Manufacturing activity in most Asian countries is still carried on mainly in the traditional handicraft or cottage industries. The number of persons engaged in those industries is far greater than the number of factory workers. In pre-war China the number of handicraft workers was estimated at 10 million. 2 In India it has been estimated on the basis of census figures that in 1931 there were 6.1 million persons 1 United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs : Processes and Problems of Industrialization in Under-Developed Countries (New York, 1955), p . 135. The expression " industrial establishments " in this source excludes public utilities, mining, building and transportation enterprises. 2 Pao-san Ou and Foh-shen WANG : " Industrial Production and Employment in Pre-War China", in Economic Journal (London, Royal Economic Society), Vol. LVI, Sep. 1946, pp. 428-429. 3 I.L.O. : Year Book of Labour Statistics 1954 (Geneva, 1954), p . 20. 6 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES engaged in cottage industries as against 1.5 million workers in large-scale industries. 1 What is of special relevance for wage policy is, however, not so much the number of persons engaged in these industries as the number of wage earners employed. On this point statistical data are practically non-existent. Generally speaking the relative importance of wage-earning employment is likely to differ greatly in different cottage industries and possibly in different localities, even for the same industry. In some cases the producing unit consists only of the proprietor and members of his own family ; in others a few workers are also hired ; in still other cases the owner may employ a hundred workers or more. 2 Furthermore, certain cottage industries are so organised that the workers usually work in their homes for wages paid on a piece-rate basis by merchants or middlemen who supply them with materials and sell their products. I n view of the complexity of the employment situation, there seems to be a need for thorough investigation in this much neglected field. In India, at the instance of the All-India Cottage Industries Board in 1950, a pilot survey was conducted of the cottage industries of the Aligarh-Harduaganj area. The survey disclosed that more than half of the total number of persons employed in the cottage industries in the urban area were paid workers, the balance being proprietors and their dependants ; the same proportion applied in the rural area. It is interesting to note that in the urban area, while the lock manufacturing, moulding and many other industries hired a large number of workers and paid substantial sums in wages, in the weaving, earthenware and Sirici Khas-lci-Tatti industry there was not a single hired labourer. 3 In the case of the hand-weaving industry, the absence of hired labour does not necessarily mean that the workers employed in the industry were independent weavers. It has been observed that in 1 The Economic Background of Social Policy Including Problems of Industrialisation, Report IV, International Labour Organisation, Preparatory Asian Regional Conference, New Delhi, 1947 (New Delhi, I.L.O., 1947), p. 57. 2 Cf. Labour Policy in General Including the Enforcement of Labour Measures, Report II, International Labour Organisation, Preparatory Asian Regional Conference, New Delhi, 1947 (New Delhi, I.L.O., 1947), pp. 17-18. 3 " Pilot Survey in Aligarh-Harduaganj Area ", in Journal of Industry and Trade (New Delhi, Ministry of Commerce and Industry), June 1952, Special Cottage Industries Number, pp. 675-676. Sirici Khas-ki-Tatti is a handicraft industry in India which makes fibre screens used in homes for protection against heat. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 7 India " formerly each weaver was an independent worker but today . . . the great majority of them work for a wage under a master-weaver, mahajan or Icarhhanadar ", 1 Although the employment situation in the handicraft or cottage sector of the economy tends to vary in different Asian countries and adequate information is not available, there is a strong presumption that a considerable proportion of non-agricultural wage earners in these countries is employed in this sector. (3) Among the numerous occupations falling within the division of tertiary production the two largest groups are commerce and services. The relative importance of wageearning employment, however, differs greatly in these two groups. In commerce the majority of workers are self-employed. In services, on the other hand, most of the workers are wage earners. Por instance in Japan and the Philippines, for which recent data are available, while the group " salaried employees and wage earners " constitutes 40 per cent, and 43 per cent, of the total working population engaged in commerce, the figures for the same group are respectively 75 per cent, and 98 per cent, in services.2 In most Asian countries the kind of services which provide most wage-earning employment are personal services, particularly private domestic service. An analysis of the available data on occupational distribution of non-agricultural working population shows that in terms of the size of labour force employed (including both wage earners and the self-employed) " personal services " was the largest single non-agricultural occupation in Korea and the second largest in Ceylon, India, the Philippines, and Thailand. 3 In India, according to the 1931 census, there were then about 11 million wage earners in domestic service as compared with a total of about 15 million persons (including both wage earners and the self-employed) engaged in industrial manufacturing (cottage industries and factories combined) and construction. In Japan (1950) and Malaya (1947), where separate numbers for " personal services " were not given, " services " as a whole also constituted the second largest non-agricultural occupation. 4 1 Government of India : Beport of the Fact-Finding Committee (Handloom and Mills) (Calcutta, 1942), p. 35. 2 Tear Booh of Labour Statistics 1954, op. cit., pp. 20-23. 3 The sources of data for this analysis are the same as those for table I. 4 Year Book of Labour Statistics 1964, op. cit., p. 21. 8 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES The above observations regarding the role of wage earners in Asian countries may now be briefly recapitulated. In the first place wage earners form a much smaller proportion of the total working population in these countries than in the economically advanced countries. Secondly, in most Asian countries by far the largest part of wage earners are engaged in agriculture. Among the agricultural wage earners, except in one or two countries, the number employed on subsistence farms seems to be far greater than the number employed on plantations. Thirdly, in secondary production the volume of wageearning employment provided by modern factory industries is relatively very small. On the other hand a considerable proportion of wage earners seem to be employed in the handicraft and cottage industries, and in some of these industries such as the Indian hand-weaving industry the ratio of wage earners to the self-employed has been steadily increasing as a part of the secular change in the structure of the industry. Finally, in tertiary production the largest single group of wage earners is found in personal services, particularly in private domestic service. The Level of Income per Head In Asia the central economic fact is the low average productivity of the working population. Because productivity is so low, real income per head is among the smallest in the world. On a regional basis it has been estimated that in 1950 Asia, with about half of the world's population, produced about 10 per cent, of the world's income. 1 Table I I gives figures of income per head in United States dollars in 1949 in ten Asian 1 United Nations, Department of Social Affairs : Preliminary Beport on the World Social Situation (New York, 1952), p. 131. Clark has recently made the following estimates of real product per head of population for certain Asian countries measured in " oriental units ", defined as the quantity of goods and services exchangeable directly or indirectly for one rupee in India in 1948-49 : China (1929-33) 173 India (1948-49) 191 Philippines (1939) 294 Ceylon (1947) 306 Indonesia (Java) (1938) 321 Japan (1919) 322 (See Colin CLARK : " The Measurement of Real National Incomes of Under-Developed Countries ", in Review of Economic Progress (Brisbane), Vol. 4, Nos. 2 and 3, Feb.-Mar. 1952, p . 8.) THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 9 countries, in comparison with the corresponding figures in ten selected economically developed countries. Great caution needs to be exercised in comparing these figures : they are subject to a wide margin of error and, furthermore, do not take into full account the differences in prices and cost of living. Nevertheless, even if allowances are made for the inadequacies in the methods of estimation, these figures still suggest a rough quantitative notion of the glaring disparities between the average standard of living in Asian countries and that in economically developed countries. TABLE II. INCOME PEE. HEAD IN TEN ASIAN COUNTRIES AND TEN ECONOMICALLY DEVELOPED COUNTRIES, 1 9 4 9 (United States dollars)1 Asian countries Indonesia Pakistan Income 36 67 27 57 25 100 35 51 44 36 Other selected countries United States United Kingdom Belgium . . . Income 1,453 870 856 849 780 773 689 679 587 582 Source : Statistical Office of the United Nations : Nalional and Per Capita Incomes of Seventy Countries in 1949 Expressed in United Slates Dollars Statistical Papers, Series E , No. 1 (New York, Oct. 1950), p p . 14-16. 1 The conversion of income in national currency into United States dollars of 1949 was m a d e a t t h e 1938 exchange r a t e adjusted for relative changes in cost of living between 1939 and 1949 in the United States and in the country in question. The poverty of Asia is an obvious phenomenon requiring no elaborate evidence to prove its existence. Here it may suffice to adduce certain facts indicating the low average standard of food and fibre consumption in the region. According to a recent estimate, food supplies in Asia and the Far Bast in 1950-51 represented an average of only 1,950 calories per person per day, compared with an average of over 3,000 calories in Western Europe, ÌTorth America and Oceania. Total proteins averaged 54 grammes per day as against 69 grammes in Latin America, 86 in Western Europe, 92 in the United States and Canada and 99 in Oceania. 1 The annual consumption, per 1 United Nations, Department of Economic Affairs : Recent Changes in Production, Supplement to World Economic Report, 1950-51 (New York, Apr. 1952), pp. 57-60. 10 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES head, of major apparel fibres (cotton, wool and rayon) in Asia in 1950 amounted to 1.5 kilogrammes as compared with a world average of 3.8 kilogrammes. 1 In respect of other essential consumers' goods and services, the differences in supply per head are even greater. A more disturbing fact is that the present average standard of living in many Asian countries is even lower than before the war as a result of the failure of production to catch up with the increases in population. The disparities between the average standards of living in Asia and the economically developed areas have consequently been widening. As the income and living standards of the working population in Asia are limited by the amounts of goods and services that they can produce, it appears clear that the basic way of raising their income and living standards must be to expand the volume of total national output as rapidly as possible and, above all, more rapidly than the increase in population. This is the primary aim of economic development. It should, however, be noted at this stage that different methods of promoting economic development may have very different effects on workers' incomes and living standards in the course of development. The issues involved will be discussed at some length in the second part of this chapter. The Distribution of Income The facts about average real income or consumption do not, however, by themselves provide an adequate indication of the material welfare of the majority of the population. This depends also on the distribution of income. 2 Given the 1 Food and Agriculture Organisation : Per Caput Fiber Consumption Levels, Commodity Series, Bulletin No. 21, Supplement No. 1 (Kome, 1952), pp. 4-5. 2 In this connection attention may be drawn to the following challenging statement made recently by an eminent economist : " Were I to insist, however, that the reduction of mass poverty be made a crucial test of the realisation of economic development, I would be separating myself from the whole body of literature in this field. In all the literature on economic development I have seen, I have found not a single instance where statistical data in terms of aggregates and of averages have not been treated as providing adequate tests of the degree of achievement of economic development. I know, moreover, of no country that regards itself as underdeveloped and that assembles the necessary statistical data to discover whether or not the growth in aggregate national wealth and in per capita income are associated with a decrease in the absolute or even the relative extent to which crushing poverty prevails." (Translated from the Portuguese version of the sixth lecture on the theory of international trade delivered by Professor Jacob VINER at the (Footnote continued opposite) THE GENERAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 11 same average income, the more unequal is the distribution of income the lower will be the level of material welfare of the majority of the population. Where marked inequality of income distribution exists, it should be possible to promote the material welfare of the lower income groups not only by expanding the volume of total national output but to some extent also by achieving a more equal distribution of income. I t should, however, be borne in mind that a redistribution of income, if it is to be effective at all, should be accompanied by a corresponding shift in the pattern of output. For example, if those whose incomes fell reacted by reducing their " conspicuous consumption " (such as the employment of large staffs of domestic servants) while those whose incomes were raised wished to spend their extra income on food, unless food production could be expanded rapidly the result of the redistribution might well be a fall in total real income, namely in the sector of domestic services, and a rise in food prices, without any significant benefit to the lower income groups. In most countries, to achieve this objective, main reliance has so far been placed on transfer of income from the rich to the poor by means of fiscal policy, that is by taxation and by public spending for the benefit of the poor. Another instrument might be a wage policy designed to ensure an increase in the share of national income going to wages rather than profits. In appraising the final incidence of such policies it is, however, necessary to consider the secondary repercussions they may entail, for example, on incentives to workers and investors, on the rate of capital accumulation and on the level of employment. These problems will be examined later in this report in so far as they relate to wage policy. Before considering the extent to which the material welfare of the majority of the Asian population might be improved by a more equal distribution of income, it is essential first to know something about the actual income distribution in those countries. Unfortunately the lack of adequate statistical data in this field makes a factual analysis peculiarly difficult. Nevertheless, on the basis of general observation and economic reasoning, a hypothesis may be advanced to the effect that in National University of Brazil in July and August 1950 and published in Revista Brasileña de Economia, Vol. 5, No. 2, June 1951, pp. 181-204, with an English summary, pp. 204-214.) 12 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES an agricultural economy where productivity does not rise and there is increasing population pressure on the land and little enterprise for industrial development, the income distribution is likely to be highly unequal and tends to become more so with the passage of time. There are several economic forces working in that direction. First, the increasing population pressure on land will in the course of time lead to an increasing concentration of land ownership together with a secular rise in agricultural rent. 1 Secondly, because of the increasing poverty due to population pressure, the proportion of the agricultural population resorting to distress-borrowing becomes greater and greater. This imperative demand for cash keeps on pushing up the rate of interest and gives rise to usury. As a result the share of total agricultural income going to the small class of landlords and money-lenders continues to increase, and the share that is available for distribution among the majority of the agricultural population continues to fall. This process also explains why in several Asian countries an increasing part of the agricultural population has sunk to the status of agricultural wage earners. Statistical data relating to China and India in the 1920s and 1930s seem to suggest, for instance, that the distribution of income in these countries was then highly unequal. In China a survey of landholding distribution on the mainland made by the China Eural Economy Besearch Institute in 1936 showed that 4 per cent, of the farming population held about 50 per cent, of the cultivated land, while 70 per cent, of the farming population held only 17 per cent, of the land. 2 1 The process may be briefly described as follows : as a result of the continuous growth of agricultural population and the repeated subdivision of holdings, the average amount of land owned per family tends to decrease steadily. As the income from their own land falls, the majority of agricultural families will find it increasingly necessary to rent additional land from others in order to maintain their income. The total amount of cultivated land being limited, the increasing demand for land will bring about a secular rise in agricultural rent. Purchase of land will then become an increasingly profitable outlet for the savings of the wealthy. At the same time, because of the deterioration of their economic position, a growing number of agricultural families will find it necessary to sell their land in order to obtain cash to meet their pressing consumption needs. Land ownership will therefore gradually pass from the cultivators to more wealthy people. Some of these new owners, by investing their entire fortune in land, will become entirely dependent on income from rent and will then form a distinct social class as landlords. 2 Agricultural Wages and Incomes of Primary Producers, Keport IV, International Labour Organisation, Asian Kegional Conference, Nuwara Eliya, Ceylon, 1950 (Geneva, I.L.O., 1949), p . 23. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 13 In India, an estimate of the distribution of the national income according to income groups in the 1920s was attempted by two economists. The results of their investigation were that— More than a third of the wealth of the country is enjoyed by about 1 per cent, of the population, or allowing for dependants about 5 per cent, at the most ; that shghtly more than another third, about 35 per cent, of the annual wealth produced in the country, is absorbed by another third of the population allowing for dependants ; while 60 per cent, of the people of Provincial India get about 30 per cent, of the total wealth produced in the country. This means that for the 60 per cent., or majority, of the population any gross figure of the average national income per head must be exactly halved to represent what it actually gets.1 More recent data on income distribution are available for Ceylon, Japan and the Philippines. These data are reproduced in table I I I . In the case of Ceylon and the Philippines, however, it is not clear what methods of estimation were used or what the data cover, since the studies which contain these data were inaccessible at the time of writing. In the case of Japan the data are known to refer to taxable income of entrepreneurs only, with a coverage of about 7.6 million persons. According to the table, in Ceylon the upper 10 per cent, of income receivers received 33.3 per cent, of the total income, while the lowest 10 per cent, received 1.5 per cent, of the total income ; in the Philippines the upper 10.6 per cent, of income receivers received 32 per cent, of total income, while the lowest 39.4 per cent, received about 15 per cent, of the total income. A statistical comparison of these data with similar data for the United States in 1949 shows that, as compared with the United States, the distribution was shghtly less unequal in the Philippines and somewhat more so in Ceylon.2 Direct comparison does not, however, give a true picture and the observations that follow are equally applicable to the figures in table I I I . 1 K. T. SHAH and K. J. KHAMBATTA : Wealth and Taxable Capacity of India (1924), p. 307, quoted by S. CHANDRASEKHAR : India's Population : Facts and Policy (New York, John Day Co., 1946), p. 54. 2 The concentration ratios, or coefficients of inequality, as calculated from the Lorenz curves, are : Ceylon 42, United States 40, Philippines 39, Japan 34. (See Economic Bulletin for Asia and the Far Fast (Bangkok, united Nations), Vol. I l l , Nos. 1-2, Jan.-June 1952, p. 24. 14 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES TABLE H I . INCOME DISTRIBUTION IN CEYLON, JAPAN AND THE PHILIPPINES Percentage of income receivers Percentage of total income Income range simple cumulative simple cumulative 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1.5 3.6 4.7 5.4 6.2 7.6 9.4 12.4 15.9 33.3 1.5 5.1 9.8 15.2 21.4 29.0 38.4 50.8 66.7 100.0 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 2.9 4.3 5.6 6.4 7.4 8.4 10.1 12.0 15.3 27.6 2.9 7.2 12.8 19.2 26.6 35.0 45.1 57.1 72.4 100.0 39.4 32.7 17.3 9.0 1.2 0.4 39.4 72.1 89.4 98.4 99.6 100.0 14.9 27.5 25.6 22.2 5.7 4.1 14.9 42.4 68.0 90.2 95.9 100.0 Ceylon (Dee. 1950) : (rupees per jnonth) 0 26 36 46 57 69 83 103 138 to to to to to to to to to 26 36 46 57 69 83 103 138 198 Japan (1949) : (thousand yen per year) 0 to 42 to 55 to 69 to 81 to 94 to 112 to 134 to 165 to 42 55 69 81 94 112 134 165 218 Philippines (1948) : (pesos per year) 0 600 1,080 1,800 3,600 6,000 to 600 to 1,080 to 1,800 to 3,600 to 6,000 and over Source : Economic Bulletin for Asia and the Far East (Bangkok, United Nations), Vol. Ill, Nos. 1-2, Jan.-June 1952, p. 22, and the sources there quoted. Writing of studies of the distribution of family income in India in 1949-50, Ceylon in 1950 and Puerto Rico in 1948, Kuznets in a recent article concludes that— While the coverage is narrow and the margin of error wide, the data show that income distribution in these underdeveloped countries THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 15 is somewhat more unequal than in the developed countries during the period after the Second World War. Thus the shares of the lower three quintiles are 28 per cent, in India, 30 per cent, in Ceylon, and 24 per cent, in Puerto Eico—compared with 34 per cent, in the United States and 36 per cent, in the United Kingdom. The shares of the top quintile are 55 per cent, in India, 50 per cent, in Ceylon, and 56 per cent, in Puerto Eico, compared with 44 per cent. in the United States and 45 per cent, in the United Kingdom. This comparison is for income before direct taxes and excluding free benefits from governments. Since the burden and progressivity of direct taxes are much greater in developed countries, and since it is in the latter that substantial volumes of free economic assistance are extended to the lower-income groups, a comparison in terms of income net of direct taxes and including government benefits would only accentuate the wider inequality of income distributions in the underdeveloped countries.1 A knowledge of the inequality of income distribution is essential for the framing of any general policy of income redistribution, especially through fiscal measures. Inasmuch as it is attempted, for example through minimum wage regulation, to improve wage standards in particular industries it is, moreover, desirable to ascertain the actual levels of net profits earned in such industries in relation to the levels of wages paid to the workers. The relationship between wages and profits is likely to vary significantly among different industries and among different firms within the same industry. In some cases low wages may be accompanied by equally low net profits ; in other cases where wages are low the net profits earned by the industry may be exceedingly high. The extent to which profits can be shifted to wages, therefore, may vary greatly from industry to industry. Factual investigation in this field presents a host of complicated problems in methodology as well as interpretation. In most Asian countries such investigation has not yet been attempted, and there exist few data to throw light on this question. In India, however, the United Provinces Labour Enquiry Committee recommended the fixing of minimum living wages in the province and also certain specific minimum wage rates for different categories of workers. In appraising the capacity of industries to pay these minimum wages, the Committee undertook a detailed investigation of the financial position of nine organised industries in the province, namely cotton textiles, hosiery, jute, sugar, leather, oil, engineering and electrical supplies and glass. The 1 Simon KUZNETS : " Economic Growth and Income Inequality ", in American Economic Review, Vol. XLV, No. 1, Mar. 1955, pp. 20-21. 16 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES results of this investigation led to the conclusion that " most industries are in a position to bear the additional burden thrown on them by our proposals in respect of minimum wages, dearness allowance and bonus. The only industries which appear to be in somewhat straitened circumstances were jute and leather." l Wage Differences among Various Groups of Wage Earners The general level of real wages in any country is limited by the country's capacity to produce, of which the size of output and income per head is a generally accepted indicator. In the countries of Asia, where output and income per head are so small, it is inevitable that the general level of wages should also be extremely low. However, it needs to be emphasised that the incomes of the majority of wage earners are, in fact, much lower than the average income per head and their living standards are even lower than is suggested by figures showing the average consumption of, say, food and clothing. At present the lack of adequate comparable wage data makes it virtually impossible to analyse systematically the differences in the real wages and earnings received by different groups of wage earners in different sectors of the economy in Asian countries. The commonly held view is that in towns the level of money wages of industrial workers is higher than in villages, that the level of wages in factories is higher than in handicrafts, and that the level of wages in plantation estates is higher than those paid by cultivators. " In other words, money incomes have a tendency to decline the more one moves from town to village, or from modern factory systems to traditional handicrafts." 2 This view, based mainly on general observations, affords a useful guide to further investigation into the wage structures of Asian countries. Any such investigation, if it is to throw hght on differences in real earnings, will of course have to take into consideration the differences in cost of living, in payment in kind and in continuity of employment, and many other factors. 1 Government of the United Provinces : First Beport of the United Provinces Labour Enquiry Committee, 1946-48, Vol. I, Part I : Wages, Dearness Allowances and Bonus (Allahabad, 1948), p. 297. 2 Agricultural Wages and Incomes of Primary Producers, op. cit., p . 58. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 17 In what follows a limited number of factual data are presented which bear upon certain aspects of wage differences in these countries. Agricultural and Industrial Wages. Most of the available data tend to indicate that the average earnings of agricultural wage earners are lower than those of industrial wage earners. In India the differences are particularly great, as shown in table IV. In each of the seven states covered the average annual income per earner of agricultural workers' families in 1949 (including home-grown produce and payment in kind) amounted to only a fraction of the average annual earnings of a factory worker and was in most cases substantially below those of the factory worker in the lowest paid factory industry. 1 TABLE IV. AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS OF AGRICULTURAL WORKERS IN SEVEN STATES IN INDIA, 1 9 4 9 Agricultural workers Factory workers State Village Magupara Dorwan . . . . . . . Madhya Pradesh U t t a r Pradesh Vandalur . . . Khuntuni . . . Khalispur . . . Per family Per earner All industries Lowest paid industry 477.11 4MA 312.8 2 322.5 Í 267.6 3 1 | 347.4 4 ) 754.0 5 488.3 6 339.0 261.6 186.2 165.5 951.1 946.2 841.9 726.6 284.3 335.9 325.4 373.8 152.1 527.0 151.7 280.4 993.0 652.5 364.5 839.0 676.1 1 251.6 8' J West Bengal . . Brindabanpur . . 1 464.6 1 \ 641.7 » | Source : Average annual earnings of agricultural workers from reports of t h e preliminary inquiry into the conditions ot agricultural workers u n d e r t a k e n b y t h e Ministry of Labour in 1949 ; average annual earnings of factory workers from Indian Labour Gazette, Vol. I X , No. 5, Nov. 1951, p . 362. 1 Agricultural worker with land. ! Casual worker w i t h o u t land. • Attached worker. 4 Casual worker. * Attached worker with land. • Attached worker without land. ' Landless casual worker. • W i t h land. * W i t h o u t land. 1 Part of the difference in annual earnings may be due to a difference in the number of man-days worked during the year. It should also be borne in mind that in Asian countries the term " industry " covers a mixture of more or less modern large factories and more primitively equipped and operated small establishments, and that wages in these two sectors often differ very substantially. For example in 1953 minimum daily wages in the cigarette factories in Indonesia were approximately 10 rupiahs while (Footnote continued overleaf) 18 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES For other Asian countries some of the relevant data on agricultural and industrial wages are summarised in table V. The data are too fragmentary for close comparison. Eoughly, however, it appears that in Ceylon, Malaya, the Philippines and Thailand average industrial wages were higher than average agricultural wages. In Japan average daily earnings in manufacturing in 1949 were higher than in agriculture for male workers but were lower for female workers. In pre-war Indonesia the average wages earned by plantation workers in Java did not seem to compare unfavourably with the average wages in some manufacturing industries such as rice mills, and biscuit and textile factories. Since the average industrial wages include the high wages earned by skilled industrial workers, a more significant comparison will be between the wages of agricultural workers and those of unskilled non-agricultural workers. In Ceylon one investigator observed that the wages of the lowest grade workers in port transport trade (which ranged roughly from 1.75 to 2 rupees per day in 1951) were comparable to the wages of the plantation workers. 1 In the Philippines the average daily wage rate of unskilled industrial workers in 1950 was 1.87 pesos compared with 1.70 pesos for agricultural labourers. 2 As the agricultural labourers are provided with two free meals a day in addition to the money wage, the real earnings of unskilled industrial workers seem to be even lower than those of .agricultural labourers. In Burma the data given in table V suggest that in terms of monthly real wages the unskilled workers in unregulated factories or unorganised industries before the war earned less than agricultural workers, though those in organised industries appeared to earn a good deal more. In India a pre-war comparison disclosed that the wages of the lowest grade of workers employed on manual work in factories were substantially higher than the wages in small cigarette works, where the trade unions have far less influence, the daily rate was often not higher than 3 rupiahs (Bank Indonesia : Report of the Governor of Bank Indonesia for the Financial Year 1953-1954 (Djakarta, 1954), p. 143). 1 K. P . MUKBRJI : " Agricultural Labour in Ceylon ", in Ceylon Trade Journal (Colombo, Department of Commerce), Vol. XVI, No. 7, July 1951, pp. 411-412. 2 Abstract of Philippine Statistics (Manila, Department of Commerce and Industry, Bureau of the Census and Statistics), Vol. I, No. 2, Jan.-Mar. 1951, pp. 8 and 10. T H E G E N E R A L P R O B L E M OF INCOME I N ASIA T A B L E V. AGRICULTURAL AND I N D U S T R I A L W A G E S I N C E R T A I N ASIAN (Daily Country 19 COUNTRIES wages unless otherwise indicated) Average agricultural wages Average industrial wages Burma (pre-war) 100 to 140 baskets of paddy (approximate cash equivalent 100 to 140 rupees) plus board for 7 months Unskilled labour : unorganised industries : 15 rupees per month ; organised industries : 30 to 35 rupees per month Ceylon (1948) Plantation workers x : adult male : 1.49 rupees ; adult female : 1.16 rupees Match manufacturing : adult male : 2.20 to 2.86 rupees ; adult female : 1.84 t o 2.40 rupees Indonesia (pre-war) West J a v a : male preparers of cinchona bark : 0.23 florins ; male harvesters : 0.35 florins J a v a and Madura enterprises, 1939 : skilled worker in metal industries : 0.60 to 0.80 florins ; male soap maker : 0.30 to 0.40 florins ; male printer in European-type shops : 0.34 to 0.45 florins ; male wage in rice mills for milling work : 0.20 to 0.30 florins ; men and women weavers : 0.14 to 0.32 florins ; male wage in biscuit factory : 0.18 t o 0.20 florins ; Outer Islands : basic wages for casual male estate labourer in 1939 : 0.27 to 0.32 florins Japan (1949) Regular day labourer (including b o a r d ) : m a l e : 236 y e n ; f e m a l e : 185 yen Manufacturing : m a l e : 374 y e n ; female : 165 y e n Malaya (pre-war) Unskilled plantation worker : $0.35 to $0.60 Skilled male factory worker : $0.80 to $1.20 (in some cases as much as $3) Philippines (1950) Agricultural labourers : 1.70 pesos plus two free meals Industrial workers : from 3.07 pesos in East and West Visayan to 4.27 pesos in Southern Luzon Thailand (pre-war) Rural wages : 0.50 to 1 baht Coolies : 0.80 baht ; other workers : up to 2.50 bahts Sources : Burma—ANDRUS : Burmese Economic Life, op. cit., pp. 263 and 266. CeylonGovernment of Ceylon : Labour Commissioner's Report, 1948. Indonesia—Virginia THOMPSON : Labour Problems in Southeast Asia (New Haven, Yale University Press, 1947), pp. 141-143. Japan—I.L.O. : Year Book of Labour Statistics 1949-50 (Geneva, 1951). pp. 157 and 207. Malaya and Thailand—Indian Council of World Affairs : Labour in South East Asia, edited by P. P. PILLAI (New Delhi, 1947), pp. 148-151 and 200. Philippines—Abstract of Philippine Statistics, op. cit., pp. 8 and 10. 1 Average daily wage rates were fixed by the wages boards and include special allowances. Those for plantation workers cover tea, rubber, cocoa, cardamom and pepper growing and manufacture. 20 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES earned by field labourers in agriculture. 1 Another investigation showed that the ordinary monthly wage rates paid to railway coolies in the United Provinces in 1944 varied between 16 and 20 rupees and that these rates were almost at par with the monthly wage rates of ploughmen in the North-West Eegion of the Provinces (15 to 20 rupees) but were higher than the latter in the Central Eegion (8 to 10 rupees) and considerably higher than those in the Eastern Eegion (3 to 6 rupees). 2 A few general remarks may be made on differences between agricultural and industrial wages. First, the differences in wages alone do not provide an adequate indication of the differences in annual real earnings. The annual real earnings of agricultural wage earners are probably much smaller than their monthly or daily wages would suggest because of long periods of seasonal unemployment that the majority of industrial workers do not suffer. On the other hand, the cost of living is usually higher in towns and cities than in the country, and in certain industrial districts the housing conditions of industrial workers are perhaps worse than those of agricultural workers. Where the annual money incomes of industrial workers are higher than those of agricultural workers, the differences in living standards are likely to be reduced appreciably by these factors. Secondly, industrial wages are lowest where the industrial workers still maintain a close connection with agriculture. In India this is evidenced by the especially low wages earned by workers in seasonal factories such as rice mills, and cotton ginning and pressing factories, and also in collieries.3 Most of 1 The comparison is as follows : AVERAGE MONTHLY WAGES, 1 9 3 7 - 3 9 (Rupees) Provinces Unskilled workers in factories 17 9 9 7 6 8 7 Source : R a d h a k a m a l M U K E R J E E : The Indian 2 Working to to to to to to to 20 12 12 10 9 12 10 Agricultural labourers 7 6 5 4 4 5 4 to to to to to to to 9 8 8 7 6 7 6 Class, op. cit., p . 192. Government of the United Provinces, Department of Economics and Statistics : Sural Wages in the United Provinces by S. C. CHATURVEDI (Allahabad, 1947), p . 105. 3 For a comparison of wages prevailing in those industries with agricultural wages see The Indian Working Class, op. cit., p . 7. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 21 these workers are cultivators who expect to earn in factories and mines only a supplementary income during the off seasons. Thirdly, in time of inflation the real earnings of industrial workers with weak bargaining power are likely to fall in relation to those of agricultural workers, since the latter are better protected by payments in kind. Thus it was observed that in China during 1940, when the cost of living was rapidly rising, a skilled factory worker in Kunming " did not earn much more than the unskilled farm labourer and the position of the unskilled factory worker was decidedly inferior ". 1 Plantation and Farm Wages. The general observation that plantation wages are, on the average, higher than wages paid to non-plantation agricultural workers appears to be true in Ceylon and Malaya. In Ceylon one observer, referring to the wage situation in 1951, states that 40 rupees per month or 1.35 rupees per day (i.e. the daily wages of a casual farm labourer) may be taken as the average daily income of the non-plantation agricultural worker, and 2 rupees per day that of the plantation worker. 2 Pillai also reported that the wages paid to estate labourers in Malaya were higher than those of men employed on small holdings. 3 While productivity on plantations is generally greater than in peasant agriculture, it does not follow that workers on plantations are necessarily paid higher wages than those hired on farms. In South India, as far as the wage data for 1947 indicate, the reverse seems to be true ; in Nilgiris, Malabar, Wynaad, Coorg and Cochin the daily wages (including district allowance and grain compensation allowances) of workers on tea, coffee and rubber plantations were lower than the daily wages of agricultural workers paid by cultivators in the surrounding areas. The comparative wage figures for these two groups of agricultural workers in South India are given in table VI below. From the point of view of wage policy it would be particularly useful to ascertain the degree of correspondence between fluctuations in plantation wages and fluctuations in the prices 1 Kuo-Heng SHIH : China Enters the Machine Age (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1944), p. 76. 2 K. P . MUKEEJI : " Agricultural Labour in Ceylon ", in Ceylon Trade Journal, op. cit., p . 411. 3 Indian Council of World Affairs : Labour in South Hast Asia, edited by P. P . PILLAI (New Delhi, 1947), p. 148. 22 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES TABLE VI. DAILY WAGES OP PLANTATION WORKERS AND OF FARM WORKERS IN SOUTH INDIA, 1 9 4 7 (1 rupee=16 annas ; 1 anna=12 Plantation wages pies) 1 District Farm wages Tea Nilgiris : Skilled men . . Men Women . . . . Malabar : Skilled men Men Women Women Ooorg p. Rs a. 1 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 11 2 0 12 64 2 2 0 9 64 2 1 0 11 . . . . p. Rs. a. 2 p. Rs. a. 2 1 4 1 0 2 0 15 6 6 2 2 2 2 0 10 6 2 2 0 03 2 2 1 0 p. 2 2 0 0 2 2 . . . . Rubber Rs a. . . . . Wynaad : Skilled men Men Coffee 1 4 to 8 0 1 1 0 0 0 2 1 4 to 0 1 8 1 0 0 0 : Men Women 0 0 2 2 . . . . 11 8 6 6 0 0 85 85 10 10 to 0 Gochin : Skilled men Men Women . . . . . . 1 1 0 1 0 12 0 0 0 9 9 I 2 1 0 0 12 }_. 2 0 0 0 0 10 9 68 08 7 • Source : Government of India, Ministry of Labour, Labour Bureau : Report on an Enquiry into the Cost and Standard of Living of Plantation Workers in South India (Calcutta, 1948), p . 58 and p p . 99-100. 1 Daily wages in plantations include basic wage, district allowance and grain compensation allowance. • N o t available. 3 Plus 6 lb. of potatoes. ' A bonus of 1 anna per day is also given if t h e y work for six days a week. 6 The wage applies to tappers ; wages for other workers averaged R s . 0—9—8. • R s . 20 per m o n t h with free board ; casual labourers, R s . 2 per d a y without food. ' There are two scales, viz. : Trichur : men, R s . 1—8—0 ; women, R s . 1—0—0 8; Interior : men R s . 1—4—0 ; women, R s . 1—0—0 ; figures for skilled m e n not available. Figures relating to non-resident workers ; for resident workers t h e average wage was R s . 0—11—6 for both men and women. of plantation products and also the indirect effects of these fluctuations on the wages of non-plantation agricultural workers in areas adjoining the plantations. The data at present available are, however, not sufficient for an adequate analysis of this problem. Handicraft and Factory Wages. Information on wages in handicraft and cottage industries is more scanty than that on wages in other sectors of the THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 23 Asian economies. It can, however, be taken for granted that the wages prevailing in that sector vary considerably with the craftsmanship required of the worker and also with the level of activity in the industry in question. In the case of the Indian handloom industry where wages and earnings declined drastically during the 1930s, a thorough investigation undertaken by a fact-finding committee during the war revealed that in the majority of the districts investigated weavers working in Tcarhhanas (i.e. wage earners in hand-weaving workshops) in 1941 earned about 10 rupees a month during busy seasons, while in some districts their earnings were even smaller. 1 It may be noted that in the same year the average annual earnings of textile factory workers amounted to 314 rupees or about 26 rupees per month. 2 Thus the weavers in Tcarlchanas appear to have earned less than half the average earnings of workers employed in modern textile factories ; their relative position was even worse owing to seasonal underemployment which often lasts for three or four months. The committee observed that, in spite of their considerable hereditary skill, the majority of the hand-weaver s were receiving only the income of unskilled labourers. 3 The lack of current information makes it difficult to find out how far their position has changed since the end of the war. In Indonesia pre-war data indicate that, in cottage industries controlled by baTculs (i.e. a special class of middlemen who supplied home worker s with materials, paid them wages and sold their products), wages were especially low. One competent observer described the pre-war situation as follows * : In the section of cottage industry controlled by bakuls, the sums earned were so unbelievably small that they could hardly be termed wages ; rather they were simply spare-time contributions to the family exchequer. Although earnings wherever cottage industries were allied to the Centrals [co-operatives] were also insignificant, they still compared favourably with what was derived from cultivating the soil. Wages paid in small-scale industry were, in general, appreciably higher, although they varied greatly according to the industry and the locality. In the Centrals and in the new industries established during the 1930s, wages ranged from 0.30 to 0.10 florins 1 Report of the Fact-Finding Committee (Handloom and Mills), op. cit., pp. 82-83. 2 Figure from I.L.O. : Year Booh of Labour Statistics 1949-50 (Geneva, 1951), p. 187. 3 Report of the Fact-Finding Committee (Handloom and Mills), op. cit., p. 201. 4 Virginia THOMPSON : Labour Problems in Southeast Asia (New Haven, Yale University Press, 1947), p. 143. 24 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES an hour whereas in the Ja&wZ-controlled enterprises they amounted to only about half these sums. I t would seem desirable to investigate whether or not this situation has improved in recent years, since, according to the pre-war estimates, no less than 40 per cent, of the total number of workers in small and cottage industries earned their livelihood through the medium of bakuls.1 Unskilled and Skilled Wages. In Asian countries, while there is an abundant supply of unskilled labour, the supply of skilled labour is exceedingly small. It is therefore generally believed that the wage differentials between unskilled and skilled labour are greater in these countries than in the economically developed countries. A systematic comparison of wage differentials by skill in the Asian countries and those in other countries encounters many practical difficulties. First, in most Asian countries there is a lack of comprehensive wage statistics for different occupations. Secondly, where such data exist, the job content of the occupations in question is not always clear. Thirdly, even where the occupations are clearly defined it is often difficult to ascertain the elements of remuneration covered by the term " wages " or " earnings " used in the statistics. Finally, wage differentials by skill in the same industry are likely to vary in different localities and even greater variations exist from industry to industry. While recognising all these difficulties, it still seems instructive to make some rough comparison of the wages earned by certain categories of skilled workers in relation to those of unskilled workers in a few selected industries in several Asian countries and in several economically developed countries. The results of this comparison are given in table VII. In the three selected industries—construction, textile manufacture and manufacture of machinery—the wage differentials between unskilled labour and skilled labour in certain Asian countries do seem to exceed those prevailing in many economically advanced industries. This is particularly noticeable in the construction industry. While the above comparison supports the commonly held view, it is difficult to generalise for several reasons. First of all it is necessary to distinguish between workers in tradi1 The Economie Background of Social Policy . . ., op. cit., p . 57. TABLE VII. U N S K I L L E D AND S K I L L E D WAGES I N T H R E E I N D U S T R I E S I N S E L E C T E D ASIAN AND INDUSTRIALISED C O U N T R I E S , OCTOBER 1 9 5 3 (Hourly wage rates, adult Î males) Q Construction industry Country Currency Unskilled labourers Electrical fitters (A) (B) (B) as % of (A) Manufacture of machinery Textile manufacture Unskilled labourers Weavers (C) d» (D) as % of (C) Unskilled labourers Pattern makers (E) (F) W (F) as % of (E) t» O x China (Taiwan) . . . . Hong Kong 3 India ( B o m b a y ) . . . . Indonesia ( D j a k a r t a ) 3 . . East Pakistan (Dacca) . . United States (NewYork) Canada U n i t e d K i n g d o m (Manchester) 3 Germany (Federal Republic) ' " Source : Year Book of Labour Slatistics Yuan HK$ Rs. Rupiahs Rs. 2.50 0.38 4.00 0.75 160 197 5.50 0.22 15.00 0.44 273 200 2.45 1.18 3.30 1.96 135 166 Shillings 3.08 e 3.58 116 Marks 1.30 1.80 138 1.63 0.38 0.44 5.00 0.19 : 1.79 0.50 0.53 8.50 0.28 a 4 110 132 120 170 147 1.20< 1.03 1.21 117 w 1.94 0.43 2.97 0.83 153 193 5.50 17.50 318 O 1.47 1.13 1.72 152 G O 2.69 3.50 130 1.18 1.84 156 !» 1954, op. cit., p p . 226 ff. ' E a r n i n g s . ' E x c l u d i n g free lodging provided. ' M i n i m u m rates. « Cotton ; woolweavers 0.78. ' C o t t o n and woo ) industry. « S t a n d a r d rate. ' M i n i m u m rates in highest seniority class a n d wage zone. fco 26 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES tional handicrafts and those in modern industries. I t is conceivable that in many of the handicraft industries, as a result of their secular decline, the wages of skilled labour have been greatly reduced in relation to the wages of unskilled labour. The most conspicuous case, as already noted, is the income position of the Indian hand-weavers. Secondly, as regards modern industrial skills it should be pointed out that wage determination in the majority of modern industrial enterprises is hardly based on scientific methods of job evaluation. The wage scales in operation often contain many anomalies and do not fully reflect the differences in skill requirements. Thirdly, the inadequacy of collective bargaining and of effective wage fixing machinery in Asian countries makes it difficult for skilled workers to secure wages in accordance with their skill. Finally, the mere fact that the present supply of certain types of industrial skill is small does not necessarily mean that these skills are scarce in relation to the existing demand. In some cases the demand for such skills may be equally small and consequently the wages paid for them may also be relatively low. Only when industrialisation is proceeding at a rapid tempo will the scarcity of skilled labour become increasingly felt and be reflected more and more clearly in the scale of wages. The relevance of the facts discussed above for the consideration of wage policy in Asian countries may now be briefly indicated. (1) The extent to which wage policy as such may be expected to raise the living standards of the working population in Asian countries will be limited basically by these countries' low capacity to produce, as evidenced by their small output and income per head. (2) Por those members of the working population whose incomes are below the average some improvement in living standards may be possible through measures, including wage policies, which reduce inequalities in income distribution. It is, however, important to recognise that in Asian countries the majority of the working population with sub-average incomes are self-employed, the proportion of wage earners being considerably smaller than in economically advanced countries. Thus the benefits of wage policy are likely to reach only a relatively small proportion of the working population. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 27 For the majority, to redistribute income in their favour will require other forms of social policy such as fiscal policy and agrarian reform. (3) The available data tend to show that in most Asian countries the majority of wage earners are engaged in agriculture—on plantations and on small holdings ; that in secondary production a considerable proportion of wage earners are employed in the handicraft and cottage industries and only a very small proportion in modern factory industries ; and that in tertiary production the largest single group of wage earners is in personal services, particularly in domestic service. (4) In the absence of adequate data it is difficult to establish firm conclusions on the question of relative wages. However, certain tentative observations may be made on the basis of the limited data available. First, in nearly all Asian countries agricultural wages are among the lowest—lower than average industrial wages. The annual earnings of agricultural wage earners are even smaller than is reflected in their monthly or daily wages, because of long periods of seasonal underemployment. Secondly, the relationship between plantation wages and farm wages seems to vary in different countries and perhaps also in different localities ; in some countries plantation wages are higher than farm wages and in others lower. Thirdly, althoiigh wage statistics concerning handicraft and cottage industries are particularly meagre, such pre-war information as is accessible reveals that in industries that are in a state of secular decline or are subject to exploitation by middlemen the earnings of wage earners were exceedingly small compared with the average earnings of industrial workers. Fourthly, a rough comparison tends to confirm the common view that the differences in wages between unskilled and skilled industrial labour are greater in Asian countries than in economically advanced countries. The unskilled industrial workers are the lowest-paid industrial workers and their living standards are deplorably low. As in the case of agricultural workers, very many of them have to resort to continuous borrowing in order to meet the minimum requirements for subsistence. Finally, there is practically no information available on wages in personal services ; the income position of this important group of wage earners is therefore not clear. 3 28 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES T H E BASIC APPROACH TO EAISING INCOME In Asian countries, as elsewhere, substantial and continuing increases in the general level of real wages will depend on the expansion of total national output. The crux of the matter lies in the rate of economic development. To accelerate economic development is now the central objective of economic policy in all the Asian countries, and in each country concrete plans have been made and are being carried out to achieve this objective. However, while economic development, by expanding national output, will eventually raise workers' living standards it is important to recognise that, because of the great need for resources to build up capital equipment, the amount of resources available for current consumption may for some time remain small during the process of development. During that period workers' living standards may not significantly improve and may possibly fall if some of the resources formerly geared to workers' consumption are diverted to capital formation. This issue is often raised in connection with the appraisal of capital requirements for economic development, but so far no attempt has been made to explore fully all the possible approaches to its solution. Since Asian governments are pledged to accelerate economic development, the kind of wage policy to be adopted by those countries in the years ahead will need to be closely related to the manner in which this vital issue is to be resolved. The Conflict between Capital Formation and Consumption The issue is usually stated in the following way : The rate at which national output and income may increase depends to a large extent on the rate at which productive equipment and facilities can be built up. Productive equipment and facilities consist of many different things : railways, roads, rolling stock, harbours, power installations, irrigation and drainage works, factories, mines, machinery and tools, public utilities, and so on. If national output and income are to increase, the stock of all these things, constituting the community's productive capital equipment, must first of all be expanded. To expand the stock of capital goods, however, requires resources in the form of materials, labour, equipment T H E G E N E R A L P R O B L E M OF I N C O M E IN ASIA 29 and organising ability. In the countries of Asia the difficulty is that the resources at present available for production are so limited that the bulk of them are used up in meeting the basic consumption needs of the population. The issue of policy confronting these countries is : to what extent and in what ways could capital formation be accelerated without diverting resources from production for current consumption, which is already so very low 1 In an admittedly highly abstract and oversimplified way the problem might be conceived of as dependent on the following quantitative relations : (1) the capital-output ratio, i.e. the probable amount of additional output and income that will be created as a result of a given amount of capital formation ; (2) the planned increase in national output and income ; (3) the additional amount of capital formation required to bring about the planned increase in national output and income ; (4) the ratio of the additional amount of capital formation thus required to the present national income ; (5) the ratio of present capital formation to present national income. The concept of the capital-output ratio, when applied to the economy as a whole, raises a number of conceptual problems which need further exploration. In the first place it is worth remembering that capital investment does not yield income automatically, and that the amount of income yielded will depend upon the soundness of investment decisions and the care subsequently devoted to the maintenance of equipment. Unsound investment decisions—for example the choice of unsuitable equipment or a bad site—or faulty maintenance may involve a serious waste of scarce capital. In fact, there is not one but a large number of capital-output ratios, the size of the relevant ones being dependent, for example, on the direction that capital formation takes and on the time period considered. Thus the substantial investments required in most underdeveloped countries for the improvement of communications and basic facilities are likely to result in a slowly increasing annual " ratio " between the income created by new investment and the amount of such investment, as complementary investments in manufacturing and the like are made. While in the first few years the " ratio " in such cases may be very low, 30 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES in the long run it may rise to a higher level. Also, the capitaloutput ratio for any particular industry is not usually given but, at least to some extent, is a matter of choice and decision. Similar products may be produced with more or less capital and less or more labour per unit of output. Inasmuch as economic planning is usually limited to periods not exceeding five or ten years, " ratios " computed on the basis of long-term, secular developments are of restricted use for the purpose of such planning. Nevertheless, on the basis of the estimated ratios of value of national stock of capital goods to value of annual national income (the former estimated at between three to five times the latter) for several industrial countries, one recent study 1 indicated that " a l per cent, per annum increase of national income seems to be associated with somewhere between 3 per cent, and 5 per cent, net annual capital formation ". While accurate data on' net capital formation are scanty for most Asian countries, it has been roughly estimated that the current levels of net capital formation in Asia are around 5 per cent, of national income per annum. As population in Asian countries is increasing by 1.5 per cent, or more per annum, the same study concluded that this rate of net capital formation is not enough to raise the standard of living and that an annual net capital formation of 15 per cent, or more of national income will be necessary if the average standard of living is to increase by 1.5 to 2 per cent, per annum. How would such a rate of capital formation affect the current level of consumption? Obviously, if the resources needed for the increased rate of capital formation are transferred from resources previously employed, then at the initial stage current consumption would be reduced by about 11 per cent. True, after this initial decline consumption would again rise steadily. But it would take a number of years before consumption was restored to its former level, and only after the lapse of these years would consumption per head begin to exceed its 1 " Some Financial Aspects of Development Programmes in Asian Countries " in United Nations : Economic Bulletin for Asia and the Far East, Vol. I l l , Nos. 1-2, Jan.-June 1952, p. 1. Clark, in his recent report on the economy of Pakistan, estimates on the basis of the experience of a number of countries at different dates and different stages of development that a new capital investment of 4 rupees will raise real national income by 1 rupee per annum. (See Colin CLARK : " No Tax on What Is Saved ", in Pakistan Economist, Vol. V, No. 1, 10 Jan. 1953, p. 11.) THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 31 former level and continue its upward trend at 2 per cent. per annum. 1 The above quantitative formulation of the issue, though highly simplified and based on estimates subject to wide margins of error, at least brings into relief the magnitude of present sacrifice in terms of reduced current consumption which might be required if consumption and living standards are to be raised in the future. Of course, some contribution to the solution of this problem can be expected from measures for the improvement of industrial productivity, inasmuch as such measures result in a more effective use of materials, fuel and equipment. Indeed, the fact that productivity improvement thus constitutes, as it were, a partial substitute for capital formation through reduced consumption or capital imports is the basic case for productivity work in underdeveloped countries. But while productivity improvement may make unexpectedly large contributions to the solution of the problem of capital shortage it cannot by any means be expected to solve this problem by itself, and other sources of capital formation will be needed. In the light of historical experience it appears that in some at least of the countries that are now highly industrialised the process of rapid capital formation was for a long time accompanied by low levels of mass consumption. In England in the early years of the Industrial Eevolution the level of real wages and mass consumption remained low and there was an almost total absence of social services and social legislation. 1 In actual practice the problem is, of course, far more complicated than the simple arithmetic presented in the text might suggest. For example, it is by no means certain that if any country succeeded in bringing consumption down by something of the order of 10 per cent, private enterprise would actually find profitable outlets for the large additional savings thus becoming available. The very fact that consumers' demand had fallen substantially would probably discourage investment. Another factor affecting the economic feasibility of a drastic increase of capital formation on the basis of domestic saving is the lack of mobility of productive resources between industries producing consumption and investment goods respectively. For example, a reduction in the consumption of food, while it might make some resources engaged in the output of agricultural implements available for the production of manufacturing equipment, would not necessarily result in the availability of substantial resources for railroad construction. In other words, there are technical limits to the feasibility of substantial shifts in the ratio of output of consumption and investment goods. The fact that such limits become less narrow if possibilities of foreign trade are taken into account (if savings on food consumption could be exported in exchange for foreign steel, rice could, indeed, be converted into rails) points to the importance of the balance of payments, referred to in Chapter IV below. 32 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Though statistics are lacking, the income distribution is believed to have been highly unequal. Industrialisation gave birth to numerous private fortunes, which supplied the necessary savings for productive investment. Another case is that of Soviet Eussia during the period of the First Five-Tear Plan. The rapid capital formation achieved in Soviet Eussia during that period was made possible chiefly by direct limitation of output of consumption goods through state planning. The resources thus released were directed into public investment. A third example is Japan. As in England, during its early stage of industrialisation, the level of real wages in Japan remained low and income distribution was highly unequal. But in Japan the Government played an important role in initiating and quickening the pace of capital formation and economic development. 1 A close and careful study of the experience of these and other economically advanced countries should be of assistance in forming a clear conception of the problem which confronts the Asian countries today. Whatever the economic forces or mechanism that kept down mass consumption in other industrialised countries during their early period of rapid capital formation, the social conscience of the underdeveloped countries today demands that the workers should obtain their full share of the fruits of economic development and that their living standards should improve as rapidly as possible in the course of development. Under the dictates of this new social conscience the policies of capital formation and economic development to be adopted should, therefore, be radically different from those followed in many countries in the past. The first and most important contribution that economic development can make to an increase in workers' living standards undoubtedly is the provision of more, and more productive, employment opportunities. I t is likely that only after some substantial progress has been made in the elimination of structural unemployment will it be possible to raise rates of remuneration substantially. Meanwhile, there is room for rectifying existing glaring inequities and exploitation of labour, for example through minimum wage regulation. 1 Cf. H. W. SINGÉE : " Development Projects as Part of National Development Programmes ", in United Nations : Formulation and Economic Appraisal of Development Projects (1951), Vol. I, pp. 79-85 ; and G. D. H. COLE : Introduction to Economic History, 1750-1950 (London, Macmillan and Co., 1952), pp. 40-138. THE GENEKAL PROBLEM OP INCOME IN ASIA 33 Possible Lines of Action All the important problems of policy raised by this approach to capital formation and economic development obviously cannot be considered here without straying too far afield. Nevertheless, the following possible lines of action may be briefly indicated. Effective Utilisation of Surplus Labour. In most Asian countries there is a large reservoir of surplus labour. If this surplus labour could be put to work to create additional real capital, the additional capital thus created would be a net addition to national output and income. I t requires no previous saving and no cut in the community's total consumption, although it does require some shift in real income and consumption, in favour of the labour employed on such projects. 1 Further, if the capital construction projects to be manned by the surplus labour are of such a nature as to yield an early increase in consumer goods, the workers' living standards will soon improve. One clear example is the construction of simple local irrigation works. In planning for capital formation in Asian countries there is considerable scope for projects of this nature. The speed with which such capital construction projects can be extended depends not so much on the availability of materials as on the organising ability of the government and the enterprise and initiative of the people. The development of rural community projects now in progress in several Asian countries is a step in this direction. Work in this field, however, needs to be greatly expanded in order to bring about substantial results. Rapid Spreading of Improved Techniques Requiring Little Additional Capital. So far, most of the planned increases in national output in Asian countries are projected on the basis of the expected results of new capital investment. Not enough emphasis has yet been given to the possibilities of increasing national output from the existing volume of capital stock. In view of the 1 On this point, see particularly Maurice DOBB : Some Aspects of Economic Development, Occasional Papers, No. 3 (Delhi, Delhi School of Economics, 1951), pp. 38-48 ; and Kagnar NURKSE : Some Aspects of Capital Accumulation in Underdeveloped Countries, National Bank of Egypt, 50th Anniversary Commemoration Lectures (Cairo, 1952), pp. 20-35. 34 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES limited resources available for capital formation in these countries, the exploration of such possibilities is clearly a matter of prime importance. In agriculture, according to expert opinion, the yield per acre of the existing land in most Asian countries could be considerably increased by introducing simple improved methods that involve little additional capital. In industrial sectors—both traditional and modern—there are also great possibilities of increasing the output of existing units without much new capital investment. The same equipment can produce more per unit of time if work is better organised. More finished products can be got from the same amount of raw material if waste is reduced. For no more than the original cost of old equipment, new and more productive equipment can be installed when depreciation allowances are reinvested. These are only some of the ways to raise the output of existing industries without additional investment. The extent to which the national output of Asian countries can be increased in this way will be determined, first, by the amount of effort that these countries put into the search for such methods and, secondly, by the rapidity with which these improved methods, once devised, are actually adopted. If these countries can make a concerted national drive towards increased output by such means, it can reasonably be expected that substantial additional amounts of national output will be created simultaneously with and independently of the execution of their programmes for new capital investment. 1 Careful Selection of Appropriate Projects for Capital Investment. The specific projects to be selected for execution at various stages of capital formation are bound to differ from one Asian country to another. There are, nevertheless, certain general criteria that may be suggested from the point of view both of raising workers' living standards and of economy in the use of resources. First, if workers' living standards are to be improved early in the process of development, emphasis should be placed on investment in industries producing indispensable consumers' goods. Secondly, investment should be directed towards removing bottlenecks in the supply of basic materials essential to capital construction. Coal, iron and steel, timber 1 The I.L.O. is contributing in this field through the productivity projects which are being undertaken in several countries under its technical assistance programme. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 35 and cement may be expected to fall into this category. Such investment will, of course, need to be closely co-ordinated with import programmes. Thirdly, since shortage of industrial skills presents an equally serious obstacle to development, investment in technical training must also be given a high priority. Finally, in so far as there is plenty of surplus labour to be employed, the capital investment projects should, as a rule, be so designed as to equip additional labour for productive work rather than to replace labour. The present industrial technology in Asian countries consists broadly of two types : the traditional and the modern. The traditional type, as typified by handlooms, is inefficient, since the net output per worker is extremely low, but the amount of capital required per worker is also very small. The modern type, borrowed from the West, has the. opposite characteristics : high output per worker accompanied by a large amount of capital required per worker. On the whole neither type meets the twin objectives of economic development in the region, namely a rapid expansion in both output and employment. To achieve these twin objectives, it appears essential to develop in many types of production a new industrial technology—substantially different both from present cottage and handicraft industries and from present large-scale factory industries—which for the same amount of capital investment can simultaneously produce more than the former and provide more employment than the latter. The application of this conception of technological progress to different branches of manufacturing industry raises numerous technical problems which will not be easy to solve. A sustained effort of imagination and ingenuity is required. In directing and organising collective and individual efforts in this important field of industrial invention and innovation governments will have a pivotal role to play. A wider exchange of information on technological matters among the countries of the region, and between them and other countries that have recently undertaken programmes of industrialisation, could also quicken the emergence of the new industrial technology. While the countries themselves should mobilise to the full their own technical talents, they need external assistance as well. In this connection the Expanded Programme of Technical Assistance of the United Nations and specialised agencies can make a particularly useful contribution. 36 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Full Use of Imported Resources. Economic development and capital formation require increased imports of capital goods and possibly also of essential consumers' goods. The problem of policy here is to ensure that the amount of domestic resources hitherto allocated to the production of exports will not have to be increased too much to meet the higher imports. Some of the many different forms of action that might be taken to achieve this end may be indicated. First, in countries whose nationals have accumulated considerable amounts of foreign assets and internationally accepted media of exchange such as gold, consideration might usefully be given to the feasibility of mobilising such assets and exchanging them for goods essential to economic development. To the extent that this could be done, the draft on hitherto employed domestic resources could be correspondingly reduced. Secondly, in many Asian countries capital formation has been greatly hampered by violent fluctuations in export earnings resulting from the instability of world prices of primary products. There is, therefore, an urgent need for concerted international action to promote a reasonable degree of stability in the prices of such products. But it is important to recognise in this connection that the ability of Asian countries to finance their import programmes will depend not only upon stability of their export prices but also upon the terms of trade. Thirdly, it is now increasingly recognised that in most Asian countries the high cost of planned capital formation is due in large measure to the fact that " much of the equipment has to be imported from abroad at prices which are high in relation to local productivity". 1 An essential problem of planning that faces these countries, therefore, is to find ways and means of keeping expenditure on imported equipment as low as possible, e.g. by avoiding the use of imported machinery for work that can very well be done by local unskilled labour. Another possible solution would be for foreign firms to set up plants designed especially for the manufacture of simpler and less costly equipment to meet the specific 1 " Some Financial Aspects of Development Programmes in Asian Countries ", loc. cit. THE GENERAL PROBLEM OF INCOME IN ASIA 37 needs not of their home market but of the economically less developed countries. Still another way would be for Asian countries to make all possible commercial and financial arrangements to purchase their imported equipment in markets offering the lowest prices without sacrifice of quality. Finally, it should be emphasised that while the lines of action considered above all aim at making the fullest and most effective use of domestic resources for capital formation and economic development, they will still have to be supplemented by action to secure capital imports from abroad. All possible steps should be taken to encourage the inflow of foreign capital into Asian countries so long as it does not jeopardise their sovereignty and economic independence. Restriction of Non-Essential Consumption and Investment. Even when full and effective use has been made of domestic resources together with such foreign capital as it may be possible to attract on reasonable economic and political terms, it may still be necessary to restrict the use of resources—materials and equipment, as well as human skills—for non-essential consumption and investment. A variety of measures may be adopted to achieve this end, including import controls, high taxation on non-essential consumers' goods, direct allocation of scarce materials and licensing of building construction. With proper planning and co-ordination of activities in the public and private sectors of the economy, any reduction in the supply of non-essential consumers' goods may be accompanied by increases in the supply of essential consumers' goods even in the early stages of rapid capital formation. The above brief discussion suggests that the less favourable aspects of the experience of countries now economically advanced need not be repeated in Asian countries in the course of their economic development. CONCLUSIONS In the period immediately ahead, as Asian countries make increasing efforts to accelerate capital formation and economic development, one important function of wage policy will be to bring about a proper balance between workers' effective demand and the available supply of essential consumers' goods. 38 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES A basic objective of economic planning in this connection will be to ensure that the supply of these goods will not fall but expand during the period when increasing amounts of resources will be needed for capital formation. In this chapter several different lines of action have been suggested which, if followed simultaneously, should go a long way towards achieving this objective. When, as a result of these and other steps, the supply of essential consumers' goods expands, the aim of wage policy will be to ensure that the purchasing power of workers increases commensurately. CHAPTER II THE OBJECTIVES OF WAGE POLICY The term " wage policy " is used in this report to refer to legislation or government action calculated to affect the level or structure of wages, or both, for the purpose of attaining specific objectives of social and economic policy. Methods of wage determination through which wage policy may be implemented include statutory wage regulation, collective bargaining and the settling of wage rates through procedures for conciliation and arbitration. The social objectives that wage policy may be instrumental in attaining may include the elimination of exceptionally low wages, the establishment of " fair " labour standards, and the protection of wage earners from the effects of rising prices. Such results are sought primarily in order to promote the well-being of the wage earners themselves. l The second aim of wage policy is to increase the economic welfare of the community as a whole. Wage policies may, among other things, help to maintain the country's strength in international competition, to allocate the labour force to industries or regions where it is most needed, to increase the total effective demand for consumer goods, and to provide an incentive for workers to improve their productive performance. In Asian countries the most obvious general economic objective of wage policy would be to establish a level and structure of wages conducive to accelerated economic development. As will be seen from the brief description of existing systems of wage regulation in Chapter III, most Asian countries have'' hitherto concentrated their efforts on the fixing of statutory minimum wages, on the abolition of malpractices in wage payment, and on the provision of facilities for conciliation and 1 " Social policy " should not, of course, be identified with action on behalf of wage earners only. More generally, social policy is concerned with the well-being of any economically weak group of the population. To the extent that wage policy is related to social objectives, it is, however, primarily concerned with wage earners' interests. 40 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES arbitration in wage disputes. Measures adopted under the first two of these headings are mainly intended to attain objectives of social policy. Conciliation and arbitration may also be instrumental in establishing fair or equitable wages, but in addition they may serve to reduce social unrest and thereby help to avoid economically undesirable stagnation in production. Although several Asian countries have drawn up plans for economic development, it would appear that comparatively little attention has been given to the question of determining and establishing the level and structure of wages most appropriate to attaining the objectives or targets under these plans. The social and economic aspects of wage policy are normally inter-related : measures inspired by social considerations inevitably have economic effects, and action designed to achieve specific economic results has social implications. For example, the raising of wages through statutory minimum wage fixing will normally affect production and employment in the industries concerned ; and measures calculated to keep costs of production at a competitive level may frustrate the aspirations of trade unions. When the social and economic implications of measures of wage policy conflict, a choice has to be made. As indicated in the previous chapter, the most important conflict of this nature is likely to be that between efforts to improve workers' living standards immediately and the need for capital formation as a basis for long-term economic development. ABOLITION OF MALPRACTICES IN W A G E PAYMENT One of the important consequences, but in itself also a cause, of the weak position of Asian wage earners has always been the existence of malpractices in the payment of wages. These include unduly high exactions made by recruiting agents and subcontractors, the payment of wages at irregular and long intervals and the resultant indebtedness of the workers, arbitrary and unjustified deductions from the worker's earnings, and payment of wages in kind. The problem inherent in these questions is that, to some extent, the customs that have degenerated into malpractices are in themselves quite natural and, given the specific structure of the labour market in Asian countries, even useful. For OBJECTIVES OF WAGE POLICY 41 example, the system of recruitment by middlemen is closely connected with the importance of migrant labour in industries like plantations and mining. Thus Indian, Chinese and Javanese labourers have for a long time been employed in a number of countries in South-East Asia. Another factor responsible for the persistence of indirect labour recruitment in the region is the fact that many workers consider employment for wages as only a supplementary source of income. So long as there are no well organised employment services in these countries the middleman can perform a useful function. But in practice recruiting agents, often also acting as foremen, have in many cases been responsible for much of the misery suffered by the workers. They have often given a false picture of the conditions of work in order to persuade hesitant workers to accept employment ; in other cases they have charged the workers heavy commissions for their services and have profiteered unscrupulously from the sale of food and other necessities to the workers or, where gang wages were paid to them for distribution among the workers in their gangs, have withheld part of the earnings for their own benefit. In recent years considerable progress has been made toward the elimination of malpractices of this sort in several countries. Payment in kind is still prevalent in certain industries in Asian countries, especially in agriculture, because of the importance of simple subsistance farming. To a smaller extent payment in kind is also found in modern industries (plantations, transport and manufacturing) and in traditional handicraft industries. Again, payment of part of the workers' wages in kind is not necessarily a bad thing. On the contrary, when the workers have been recruited from distant areas and are resident on or near the undertaking, the provision of board and lodging may be indispensable. Moreover, in times of rising prices payment in kind (for example, a rice allowance) may be an effective device for protecting the workers' income. But there are limits to the benefits of this system of wage payment. The disadvantages are most obvious where the workers are paid entirely with the employer's products and have to try to sell these goods themselves. But when the payment is in commodities that the worker can himself use, the system may also lead to abuses if the employer is free to determine the value of the goods supplied and make corresponding deductions from the worker's nominal earnings. In other 42 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES cases where the worker is paid entirely in kind he will be unable to pay off his debts and may be forced to stay with one employer, often also his creditor, in a status that does not greatly differ from bondage. The effects of paying wages at long and irregular intervals may also be very serious. When the worker does not receive his earnings at sufficiently short intervals he will be induced or forced to incur debts in order to live from one pay day to the next, or he may be restricted in his liberty to abandon his job and take up employment elsewhere. In some cases it is for these very reasons, i.e. so as to retain an undue hold over their labour force, that employers deliberately delay the payment of wages. In other cases, notably in small indigenous handicraft firms employing wage labour, the payment of wages sometimes depends upon the sale of the product because of a chronic shortage of cash. A related aspect of wage protection is the question of attachment and seizure of the worker's earnings once he is in debt. I t is of special importance in Asian countries where indebtedness is widespread. Sometimes, as was remarked above, indebtedness among the workers is deliberately encouraged by those who find it a convenient way of tying the workers, and even their families, to their jobs. Once a wage earner is in debt the chances are that, in view of the often exorbitant rates of interest charged by private money-lenders, he will become more and more deeply involved, until he may even lose part of his personal freedom. One possible way of counteracting this process consists of limiting the amount that can legally be seized from the worker's earnings for the repayment of debts, in such a way that the wage earner will be left with enough to pay for his current needs. A similar safeguard is the limitation of the amount that may be deducted by the employer from the worker's earnings as a penalty for bad or negligent work or for breaches of discipline and as compensation for damage to the employer's property, or for the payingoff of debts incurred in stores operated by the employer. The broad aim of wage policy with respect to malpractices in the payment of wages is to ensure that the worker actually receives what he has earned. As long as malpractices exist, measures affecting the determination of wages are likely to have only a limited effect ; they should therefore be closely co-ordinated with measures designed to abolish malpractices, OBJECTIVES OF WAGE POLICY 43 if not actually preceded by them. A number of Asian countries have already adopted such measures, some of which will be mentioned in Chapter III. * T H E FIXING OF MINIMUM WAGES In most Asian countries the majority of wage earners are in a very weak position in the labour market. The first and most important cause of this condition is the large and rapidly increasing surplus population on the land, which provides the labour market with an almost inexhaustible supply of unskilled labour. This, incidentally, is also one of the most important causes of the low level of labour productivity in these countries. Opportunities for employment, on the other hand, are increasing slowly and the resulting keen competition for jobs keeps wages low. Furthermore, the comparatively recent development of trade unions has not yet gone far enough to give effective support to the large masses of workers in such industries as agriculture and the handicrafts. For example, in India, where landless agricultural labourers with their dependants are about as numerous as the combined populations of France and the United Kingdom, the membership of agricultural unions is only about 5,000.2 In some countries the ignorance and illiteracy of the workers add to the weakness of their position. Protection of the workers against the consequences of their weak bargaining strength through minimum wage regulation seems to have been accepted as a major objective of present-day wage policy in Asian countries. Thus, the preparatory Asian Regional Conference in 1947 considered that " with a view to achieving a living wage for every worker, every effort should be made to improve the wage standards in industries and occupations where they are still low ". 3 The Asian Advisory Committee of the International Labour Organisation meeting in December 1950 agreed that the immediate need in Asia was for a minimum wage structure which would secure a reasonable living standard, from which should emerge, as the economy developed, proper living standards, including a fair 1 The Philippines is one of the countries that have ratified the Protection of Wages Convention, 1949. 2 United Nations, Department of Economic Affairs : Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East, 1950 (New York, 1951), p. 100. 3 Official Bulletin, Vol. X X X , No. 3, 15 Nov. 1947, p . 179. 4 44 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES share for labour through rising productivity. The Asian Eegional Conference of 1950 recommended that minimum wage fixing machinery should also be established for agriculture, though minimum wage regulation should be " restricted to undertakings of such size as renders enforcement practicable "-1 Finally, the Asian Eegional Conference held in Tokyo in 1953 considered that " it should be the common objective of governments, employers and workers to establish wages at the highest possible level which the economic condition of each country permits and that in future such wages should aim to provide the worker with a fair share of the increased prosperity of the country as a whole resulting from economic development " ; and that " pending the general development of effective systems of collective negotiation in each country, there is a pressing need for the immediate introduction of statutory measures to regulate wages in occupations in each country in which collective bargaining is not effective or is non-existent and as a preliminary step towards the development of systems of collective negotiation ".2 The objectives of minimum wage policy may be more or less far-reaching. The regulation adopted may aim at fixing the minimum wage in a particular industry at about the average level already prevailing in that industry so as to ebminate the payment of exceptionally low wages in individual firms. Or a uniform minimum wage may be fixed for a group of industries, again at about the average level already prevailing in these industries taken together, in which case the wages paid in particular occupations or whole industries may have to rise substantially. Again, the regulation may be designed to raise real wages in all industries above their current level. Clearly, these various possible objectives raise increasingly difficult problems of providing the economic resources from which a " reasonable " standard of living, however that may be defined, can be supported without reducing employment or at least without adverse effects on the rate of capital formation for general economie development. While it seems to be generally agreed that the first task of protective wage policy in Asian countries is to provide 1 Industry and Labour (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. I l l , No. 7, 1 Apr. 1950, p. 251. 2 Ibid., Vol. XI, No. 1, 1 Jan. 1954, pp. 30-32. The complete text of the resolution is reproduced in the Appendix. OBJECTIVES OF WAGE POLICY 45 minimum wage legislation, there is also fairly general agreement that minimum wage regulation is only a second best, and that wage determination on the basis of collective bargaining is to be preferred. Thus the preparatory Asian Eegional Conference of 1947 stressed that collective agreements are " normally the most satisfactory means for the adjustment of wages " and requested " the Governments of Asian countries to assist, by all means in their power, the conclusion of collective agreements wherever feasible... ". Similarly the Asian Eegional Conference of 1950 recommended that " measures should be taken to safeguard the freedom of association of workers and employers and to encourage the growth of workers' and employers' organisations " with a view to the eventual creation of conditions in which agricultural wages may be effectively regulated by collective bargaining instead of by minimum wage fixing machinery. In 1953 the third Asian Eegional Conference considered that " collective agreements between employers and workers are normally the best means for the determination and adjustment of wages, and the development as soon as possible of free associations of employers and workers and systems of collective negotiation based on such associations, if possible on an industry-wide or regional basis, or both, should be actively promoted and encouraged by all concerned ". The encouragement of trade unionism and collective bargaining is thus seen to be one of the immediate objectives of (indirect) wage policy in Asian countries. This does not mean that direct government intervention in wage determination through the fixation of minimum wages should not be considered an urgent task. The growth of workers' and employers' organisations and the development of collective bargaining are likely to take some time ; and it would therefore seem that in the near future governments which are concerned about workers' living standards will have to rely more heavily on direct action while simultaneously building up machinery through which the parties directly concerned will eventually be able to determine wages themselves. A further point to be kept in mind when measures of wage regulation are being considered is the relation of such measures to developments in other fields of social policy, such as social insurance, family allowances, free education, and hours of work and overtime payment. In some of these fields, notably 46 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES social insurance and hours of work and overtime payment, labour legislation has already shown substantial progress since the war in most countries of the region. 1 While a discussion of these matters would be beyond the scope of the present report it may be suggested here that government activities in the field of wage policy should be carefully co-ordinated with those in other fields of social policy. There are two main reasons why such co-ordination is desirable. First, the costs of social benefits have, in general, to be borne either by employers or the government, or by both. If they are borne by employers the problem of industry's capacity to pay wage costs has to be taken into consideration from the point of view of the total financial implications of minimum wage and other social regulations taken together. Secondly, in determining minimum rates of pay sufficient to guarantee the worker a reasonable standard of living, the authorities responsible must of necessity take account of existing or planned non-wage benefits accruing to the workers, since these benefits are themselves important elements in the standard of living of those who enjoy them. Another consideration in this connection is that a high level of non-wage benefits may, by limiting the share of wages proper in the workers' total remuneration, reduce the scope and effectiveness of incentive payments. It is known, for example, that the existence of large flat rate dearness allowances has substantially blurred the effectiveness of systems of payment by results in the Indian textile industry. A precise statement of the objectives of minimum wage policy as indicated in the above-mentioned resolutions must deal with at least the following points : (a) the level of the minimum wage to be determined ; (b) the categories of workers to be covered ; and (c) the way in which the level of the statutory minimum wage should be adjusted to changes in the social and economic conditions of the country, such as changes in the cost of living and increases in general welfare as a result of economic development. Some of the problems involved in these three questions are discussed in Chapter IV below. WAGES AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT The first objective of wage policy in Asian countries is to ensure that the level of wages will be sufficiently high to 1 Cf. Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East, 1950, op. cit., pp. 80 fi!. O B J E C T I V E S OF WAGE POLICY 47 enable the workers to maintain a reasonable standard of living. What living standards can be called reasonable depends, of course, to a large extent upon the real income per head of the country. More precisely, the level of wages which it is attempted to establish by means of direct and indirect measures of wage policy will be related to the current supply of essential consumers' goods. The larger this supply, the higher the level of real wages can be. The resolutions quoted in part above suggest that minimum wage regulation in Asian countries might also be instrumental in raising the wage level in accordance with improvements in general economic conditions, through higher productivity or otherwise. In several Asian countries the present level of output and imports of essential consumers' goods is still distressingly low and the first necessary condition of a substantial improvement of workers' living standards is therefore a considerable increase in the production of these goods. The rate at which this production is to be raised is one of the main objects of general policies for economic development. It is important to ensure that wage policy is consistent with the need for economic development and that it does not, through lack of co-ordination of government action in different fields, run at cross-purposes with other policies designed to raise total output and to develop the economy. The relations between the level and structure of wages on the one hand and economic development on the other are obscure and controversial even in industrialised countries, and relatively little is known of them in the special conditions that prevail in underdeveloped countries. It is not possible to undertake a detailed analysis of the problem in this report, but some general observations on the possibility and desirability of raising the national wage bill in step with progress in economic development are submitted in Chapter V. A second aspect of the relation between economic development and wage policy concerns the contribution that the latter can make to the acceleration of the former. This contribution must be of such a nature as to help expand production. This question is also briefly discussed in Chapter V. CHAPTER I I I EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION In most Asian countries the attention of governments and the activities of labour organisations tended, before the Second World War, to be concentrated mainly on organised industries, including factories subject to legal regulation, mines, transport and plantations. Accordingly wage earners in these industries who, as was noted in Chapter I, form only a small part of the wage-earning population, enjoyed a measure of protection and support that was not available to workers in agriculture, unregulated small industrial establishments, handicraft and cottage industries, commerce and domestic service. Developments during and since the war led governments in a number of Asian countries to take a more active part in wage determination and to assume wider responsibilities for the payment of suitable wages. A number of new sovereign States have come into existence, with governments elected on a wide franchise and responsive to popular aspirations. At the same time there has been a strong development of social consciousness and a genuine desire to raise the standards of living of the poorest sections of the community. As a result of these and other factors more attention is being given to the living and working conditions of wage earners. Questions of wage policy have consequently come to the fore in virtually all Asian countries and in a growing number of them legislation has been enacted to serve as the basis for carrying through such policy. A wide gap still exists, however, between the provisions of the legislation and the steps taken to give effect to them. Some of the laws enacted have not yet come into force while others are being applied only to a limited extent, if at all. That such a gap exists is not surprising. The shaping of a new social policy—for that is what in most cases the operation of the wage laws amounts to—needs time, especially if it has to be done by relatively young administrations struggling with EXISTING SYSTEMS OP WAGE REGULATION 49 a discouraging lack of financial and other resources in the critical economic and political conditions prevailing in many countries. In all the countries concerned wage policy, in the sense of a well considered, precise and comprehensive approach to wage problems in the light of clearly defined objectives of social and economic policy, is still in a process of early and rather slow development. In the following sections a summary is given of the legislative and operational work already carried out under four headings, viz : protection of wages, machinery for wage determination, scope and methods of wage regulation and the actual application of wage legislation. P R O T E C T I O N OF W A G E S Provisions prohibiting excessive deductions from wages and other provisions designed to ensure that the worker receives the amounts to which he is entitled are contained in the wage laws of most Asian countries. Among other things these laws regulate the wage period, the deductions that can legally be made from wages, and the amount of fines and the manner in which they may be imposed ; prohibit attachment of the costof-living allowance ; require that wages must be paid on a working day ; prohibit employers from compelling employees to buy goods at shops specified by them ; and impose penalties for offences under the law. Some or all of these protective provisions are contained, for instance, in the Payment of Wages Acts of Burma, India and Pakistan, and in the ordinances, decrees and other wage regulations of Ceylon, Indonesia, Japan and the Philippines. MACHINERY FOR WAGE DETERMINATION Minimum Wage Fixing Burma. The Burmese Agricultural Labourers' Minimum Wages Act, 1948, which is not yet in force, is one of the first attempts in Asian countries to regulate the wages of agricultural workers paid in kind. Indeed, it prescribes payment in kind by providing that seasonal agricultural labourers (hyiwin) shall receive a minimum wage of 35 per cent, of the produce of the 50 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES land they work and that the employer must also feed them during the period of employment. Payment in cash can be agreed upon, however, provided that certain rules concerning the computation of the money wage are observed. The wages of other classes of agricultural labourers may be fixed by the President at suitable rates in comparison with those of Jcyiwin labourers. Under the Minimum Wages Act, 1949, the President may establish wage councils, consisting of an equal number of representatives of employers and workers and of three independent members, in respect of any class of workers for the regulation of whose remuneration he is satisfied no adequate machinery exists. The councils may submit to the President proposals for the statutory fixing of minimum wages. Ceylon. Under the Wages Boards Ordinance, 1941, wages boards may be established in Ceylon, consisting of the Commissioner of Labour, representatives of employers and workers in equal numbers and nominated members, for the determination of minimum rates of wages for time work in particular trades. The boards may also determine minimum piece rates, guaranteed time rates for piece workers and overtime rates. The boards' decisions require ministerial approval. China. The Minimum Wage Act adopted in China in 1936 concerned factory and home trades in which no arrangement existed for the effective regulation of wages by collective agreement or otherwise, and wages were exceptionally low. In each district or municipality minimum wage committees were to be established, consisting of one or two representatives of the local authorities, one independent person appointed by each of the parties (employers and workers), and representatives of the employers and workers. The Act, however, was not applied. Hong Kong. The Governor of Hong Kong may, under the Trade Boards Ordinance, 1940, fix minimum rates of wages for any trade in any case in which he is satisfied that the minimum rates paid are unreasonably low. He may establish, for any trade, a EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 51 trade board consisting of equal numbers of employers' and workers' representatives and of appointed members whose number must be less than half the number of representative members. The boards are required to make inquiries in connection with time work and recommend minimum wages for it ; they may also recommend minimum rates for piece work and overtime rates. India. The Minimum Wages Act, 1948, requires the central Government of India or state governments to fix minimum rates of wages for 12 scheduled, non-agricultural employments and for agriculture. State governments may add to the schedule any employment where in their opinion minimum wage rates should be fixed. The central Government is required to appoint a Central Advisory Board, composed of equal numbers of employers' and workers' representatives from the scheduled employments, and independent persons not exceeding one-third of the total number of members. Similarly composed advisory committees and subcommittees may be set up when minimum wages are fixed for the first time and must be appointed for the periodic revision of the rates prescribed by the Act. The Fair Wages Bill was introduced in Parliament in 1950, but consideration of it has been postponed. It provides that wages boards would have to fix minimum rates of wages payable to employees in any class of establishment ; these rates would have to be sufficiently high to enable the worker to provide a standard family with food, shelter, clothing, medical care, and education of children, appropriate to his station in life, but the rates should not exceed the wagepaying capacity of the class of establishment concerned. Again, they should not be less than the minimum wage if such a wage had been fixed for the workers concerned. Fair rates of wages would also have to be related to fair workloads ; if a worker did not turn out a fair quantity of work his wages could be proportionately reduced. Japan. Under the Conditions of Employment Act (Labour Standards Law), 1947, the " competent office " may fix minimum wages for certain enterprises and occupations. For the purpose 52 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES of investigating wage questions, central and local wage committees and, in case of necessity, special committees may be established. The committees must consist of representatives of labour, management and the public interest in equal numbers. Federation of Malaya. The Wages Councils Ordinance, 1947, empowers the High Commissioner in Council to establish wages councils, consisting of independent and representative members, when he is of the opinion that no adequate machinery exists for wage regulation. Central co-ordinating committees, similar in structure to the councils, may be set up to co-ordinate the work of wages councils dealing with allied industries. The councils have to submit proposals to which the High Commissioner in Council may give effect. Philippines. The Minimum Wage Law, 1951, empowers the Secretary of Labour of the Philippines to appoint a wage board for any industry if, after investigation, he is of the opinion that a substantial number of employees in that industry are receiving wages that are less than sufficient to maintain them in health, efficiency and general well-being. The Law itself prescribes the minimum wage rates payable to agricultural workers for a three-year period and to non-agricultural workers for a period of one year after its effective date. The wage boards may not recommend for any industry a minimum wage less than those prescribed in the Act or lower than those prevailing on the effective date of the Act. The Secretary of Labour must either approve or reject the boards' recommendations ; he is not permitted to modify them. Conciliation and Arbitration in Wage Disputes1 Arbitration is referred to as voluntary or compulsory according to whether it is resorted to with or without the 1 See in this connection E. DATA : " Freedom of Association and Industrial Relations in Asian Countries ", in International Labour Beview (Geneva, I.L.O.), Vol. L X X I , No. 4, Apr. 1955, pp. 364-393, and No. 5, May 1955, pp. 467-497. EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 53 consent of both parties to the dispute, though the award or decision may in either case have binding legal effect. Voluntary arbitration is a method of settlement used in Hong Kong, the Federation of Malaya and Singapore and compulsory arbitration in Burma, the Philippines and VietNam. Both methods are employed in Ceylon, India, Indonesia, Japan, the Republic of Korea and Pakistan. In most countries where voluntary arbitration is employed proceedings can only be instituted by the competent authority, and the parties' consent to arbitration is generally obtained after a dispute has arisen. In both Japan and the Eepublic of Korea the parties may apply directly to the permanent arbitration machinery to settle their dispute ; their consent may also be given in advance by means of a stipulation in a collective agreement, in which case it is sufficient for one party to make the request for arbitration. As regards compulsory arbitration, the regulations in the different countries provide for varying conditions under which the competent authority may refer a dispute to, or proceed to settle it by, arbitration. This method is applied in Japan to disputes in public corporations and enterprises and in the Philippines to disputes in industries deemed indispensable to the national interest. In Indonesia the Central Committee for the Settlement of Labour Disputes may resort to compulsory arbitration in the case of a dispute that affects an important concern and may endanger the public or national interest. In Burma and Ceylon all disputes of a serious character may be referred to compulsory arbitration, but generally in these countries, as well as in India, the Eepublic of Korea and Pakistan, the competent authority has discretionary powers to resort to compulsory arbitration. Moreover, in India and Pakistan the competent authority is required to refer a dispute to compulsory arbitration if it involves a public utility and notice of a proposed strike or lockout has been given by either party, even if other proceedings for the settlement of the dispute have been started. In most countries, however, compulsory arbitration is a last resort. In Viet-Nam, in particular, it is applied only when conciliation fails. In Ceylon referral to compulsory arbitration is conditional upon the parties' not being able to agree to voluntary arbitration. 54 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Burma. The Trade Disputes Act, 1929, as amended in 1947, 1948, 1950 and 1951, provides for the investigation and settlement of trade disputes through courts of inquiry and boards of conciliation, the former consisting of one or more independent persons, the latter of an independent chairman and members who may be independent or may represent the parties. A Court of Industrial Arbitration, consisting of independent members, has been established under the Act. It may make awards binding all parties to the dispute. Penalties are provided for non-compliance by either party with the terms of such awards. The Act prohibits strikes and lockouts without notice in certain public utility services. Ceylon. Under the Industrial Disputes Act, No. 43 of 1950, when an industrial dispute exists or is apprehended, the Commissioner of Labour has to take, after inquiry, the steps necessary for settlement. He may endeavour to settle the dispute himself, or refer it to a conciliation officer, propose arbitration, or refer it to an industrial court for arbitration even without the consent of the parties. A request for the replacement or the alteration of an award will be examined only if the Commissioner deems that the economic situation warrants such request. Strikes and lockouts are forbidden in essential industries unless at least 21 days' notice is given. India. Under the Industrial Disputes Act, 1947, the appropriate government (i.e. the central Government or a state government) may refer any existing or apprehended dispute to a court of inquiry, consisting of independent persons. Alternatively it may refer the dispute to a tripartite board of conciliation empowered to promote a settlement or to an industrial tribunal, composed of independent members, for adjudication. An award of a tribunal may be enforced either wholly or in part for a period not exceeding one year. Conciliation is compulsory in all disputes in public utility services and optional in other cases. State governments may declare any industry mentioned in a schedule attached to the Act to be a public utility service. While conciliation and adjudication EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 55 proceedings are in progress and during the period when settlements and awards are in operation, strikes and lockouts are prohibited. Moreover in public utility services any stoppage of work without 14 days' notice is forbidden. In 1950 a Labour Appellate Tribunal for hearing appeals from the awards or decisions of industrial tribunals was set up. Indonesia. The Emergency Law concerning Labour Disputes, 1951, which is intended to be a temporary measure, provides for the settlement of labour disputes through mediation officials of the Ministry of Labour, committees for the solution of local labour disputes, arbitrators and arbitration councils, a Central Committee, and the Minister of Labour. The Central Committee, which is of great practical importance, consists of the Minister of Labour as chairman, and a number of other ministers as members. The local committees consist of representatives of various ministries. If parties to a dispute cannot settle it between themselves, they must inform the competent mediation official who, if he finds himself unable to solve it, must transfer the dispute to the local committee. If the latter cannot solve it either, the dispute may be referred to the Minister of Labour or to the Central Committee. Three weeks' notice must be given of strikes and lockouts ; if necessary the Central Committee may extend this period. Japan. The Labour Belations Adjustment Act, 1946, contains rules of procedure governing mediation and arbitration by labour relations commissions, established under the Trade Union Law, 1949. The commissions consist of an equal number of persons representing employers, workers and the public interest. In the case of disputes the commission concerned must set up a tripartite mediation committee on which employers and workers are equally represented. Arbitration is to be carried out by the commission itself ; its awards are binding. In essential industries strikes, slowdowns and lockouts are prohibited until 30 days have elapsed after a request for mediation, which is compulsory in these industries. Special provisions for public corporations are contained in the Public Corporation and National Enterprise Labour 56 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Eelations Law, 1948, and for public utility services in the Local Public Enterprise Labour Eelations Law, 1952. Federation of Malaya. Under the Industrial Courts Ordinance, 1948, the Commissioner of Labour may refer for settlement to the standing Industrial Court any existing or apprehended dispute. The Court consists of independent persons as well as employers' and workers' representatives. Alternatively the dispute may be referred to the arbitration of one or more persons appointed by the Commissioner, or to a board of arbitration consisting of an independent chairman and equal numbers of employers' and workers' representatives. According to the Trade Disputes Ordinance, 1949, strikes and lockouts may not be declared in public utility services without notice, or while conciliation proceedings are pending. Pakistan. The Industrial Disputes Act, 1947, was taken over from pre-partition India, and was amended in 1948 to add certain services and undertakings to the schedule of public utility services. Philippines. The Court of Industrial Eelations Act, 1936, provides for the appointment of a Court of Industrial Eelations, consisting of a presiding judge and four associate judges, for the settlement of disputes affecting employers and employees or landlords and tenants. Before hearing the dispute the Court has to attempt conciliation. Pending investigation, settlement or arbitration by the Court, strikes are not permitted. The Act to Promote Industrial Peace, 1953, substantially modifies previous legislation dealing with labour organisations and the settlement of industrial disputes. I t limits compulsory arbitration in that it provides that no court shall have the power to set wages, rates of pay, hours of work, or other conditions of employment except where provided by law. It thus cancels a provision in the Court of Industrial Eelations Act, 1936, to the effect that a dispute involving more than 30 workers could be submitted to the Court of Industrial Eelations for arbitration by the Secretary of Labour or by either or both of the parties. EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 57 When in the opinion of the President of the Philippines there exists a labour dispute in an industry indispensable to the national interest and such dispute is certified by the President to the Court of Industrial Relations, the Court may forbid the employees to strike or the employer to lock out any employees pending investigation by the Court, and if no other solution to the dispute is found the Court may issue an order fixing the terms and conditions of employment. The Act leaves the right to strike or to lock out otherwise untouched. The Act establishes an advisory Labour-Management Council in the Department of Labour, to be composed of a member representing the public and equal numbers of representatives from management and labour. The Council will advise on the avoidance of industrial disputes and on questions of mediation and arbitration. The President of the Philippines may, from time to time, call a national conference of representatives of employers and workers for the consideration and adoption of voluntary codes of principle in regard to management-labour relations designed to prevent or minimise industrial disputes. The Secretary of Labour is also authorised to call, from time to time, a conference of representatives of employers and workers in any industry or region for the same purpose. SCOPE AND METHODS OF W A G E REGULATION Coverage of the Laws Some of the minimum wage laws and decrees mentioned in the previous section indicate only in very general terms the workers they are intended to cover. Others are limited in scope to specified territories, industries or occupations. For example, in India and Japan the classes of industries in which minimum wages may or must be fixed are listed in schedules ; in India the schedule may be extended. On the other hand, some of the laws explicitly exclude certain categories of workers. Thus the Burmese Minimum Wages Act does not apply to persons employed casually and otherwise than for the purpose of the employer's business, or to government officials. In the Philippines employees of retail or service 58 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES establishments which employ not more than five wage earners, those employed on farms of 12 hectares or less, and domestic servants are not covered by the Minimum Wages Law. In India the Government " shall not be required " to fix minimum wages even for scheduled employments, when the total number of workers concerned in the state is less than one thousand. Apart from the formal exclusion of workers covered by other regulations, such as agricultural labour in Burma and government officials in Japan, the object of such exemptions in most cases is obviously to limit wage regulation to employments in which enforcement would be practicable. A related question concerns the employment of certain categories of workers—women, apprentices and physically handicapped workers—at wages lower than the general minimum rates fixed. With regard to wage differentials by sex most Asian wage laws are silent with the exception of the Philippines Minimum Wages Law and the Indian Fair Wages Bill, both of which stipulate the principle of equal pay for equal work. Various laws provide for special treatment of apprentices. In India different minimum rates may be fixed for adults, adolescents, children and apprentices. In the Philippines the Secretary of Labour is authorised to issue special certificates permitting the employment of learners or apprentices at wages lower than the applicable minimum though generally not lower than 75 per cent, of the minimum. With respect to physically deficient workers the Burmese wage councils may grant permits authorising employment at less than the statutory minimum remuneration. In Ceylon similar permits may be issued by the Commissioner of Labour or any officer authorised by him, while in India the appropriate government may direct that minimum wage regulations shall not apply to the wages payable to disabled employees. In the Philippines the Secretary of Labour may provide for the employment of disabled persons at a reduced wage, which may in no case be lower than 50 per cent, of the applicable minimum. Factors To Be Considered in Determining The Level of Minimum Wages It follows from the very purpose of minimum wage regulation that one of the main criteria for the fixing of minimum EXISTING SYSTEMS OP WAGE REGULATION 59 rates should be the cost of maintaining a certain standard of living. The second principal factor is, of course, industry's capacity to support a particular wage level. While several laws and decrees mention the criterion of a minimum standard of living, most of them are silent on capacity to pay. I t is in effect left to the wage boards and councils to determine to what extent conditions in the industry or industries concerned permit the raising of exceptionally low wages to a level sufficient to ensure to the workers a certain minimum standard of living. The various laws and decrees are designed primarily to create the necessary machinery for fixing minimum wages and do not attempt to specify at all precisely at what levels these wages should be fixed. The Burmese Minimum Wages Act prescribes that the minimum wage should enable the workers " to maintain themselves suitably " ; in Japan it must be such as to " meet the need of the worker who lives a life worthy of human being " ; in the Philippines the minimum wage should be " as nearly adequate as is economically feasible to maintain the minimum standard of living necessary for the health, efficiency, and general well-being of employees ". The translation of such general formulae into actual wage rates is a difficult task and progress in this respect has necessarily been rather slow. A number of the problems involved will be discussed in some detail in Chapter IV. Some Asian wage laws also provide for the periodic revision of minimum wage rates in order to adjust them to changing conditions, in particular to changes in the cost of living. In Ceylon and India any minimum rate of wages may consist of a basic rate and a special allowance to be adjusted, at such intervals and in such manner as the appropriate authority may direct, to accord as nearly as possible with the variations in the cost-of-living index applicable to the workers concerned. In India the appropriate government is also required to review the minimum rates fixed at such intervals as it thinks fit, but not exceeding five years, and to revise them if necessary. In a few laws indications are given concerning the way in which actual remuneration has to be computed for comparison with the minimum rates fixed. Under the pre-war Chinese law, for example, board and lodging supplied by the employer might be included at their value, averaged over the preceding three months ; but bonuses, allowances and extra pay for overtime 5 60 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES could not be taken into account. In the Philippines the wages paid to any employee also include " the fair and reasonable value, as determined by the Secretary of Labour, of board, lodging, or other facilities customarily furnished by the employer to the employee ". Other Bules of Operation While most of the laws and decrees do not specify the dates at which minimum wage regulations have to come into force, some do. In India the Government is required to fix the minimum wages, in the case of employments specified in the original schedule attached to the law, before the expiry of three years from its promulgation, and in the case of an employment subsequently added to the schedule, two or three years from the date of notification, according to whether the employment concerned is or is not agricultural. The Malayan Wages Council Ordinance declares that it is to come into force on 1 September 1947. The Minimum Wages Law of the Philippines, which came into effect on 4 August 1951 except for government employees, prescribes specific minimum wage rates from the effective date of the Act. A number of the laws provide an opportunity to persons likely to be affected by decisions on minimum wage rates to raise objections against proposed regulations. In Burma, Ceylon, India, Japan and the Philippines the competent authority has to publish its proposals, and specify a date up to which objections will be considered. Wage legislation in Ceylon, India and the Philippines renders null and void any contract or agreement stipulating wages lower than those fixed by wage regulations. Moreover most of the wage laws lay down the penalties that may be imposed on persons who fail to comply with their provisions. In Burma, Ceylon, Hong Kong, India, the Federation of Malaya and the Philippines fines, imprisonment or both may be imposed for offences in connection with the keeping of records or the non-payment of prescribed minimum wages. I t may be noted that the Payment of Wages Acts of Burma, India and Pakistan also provide for penalties for non-observance of the rules relating to wage periods, payment in cash, deductions, and like matters. EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 61 In Burma, Ceylon, Hong Kong, India, the Federation of Malaya and the Philippines provision is made for the appointment of inspectors or the creation of special inspection services. The inspectors are usually authorised to examine registers, records of wages and notices required to be kept or exhibited ; and to examine employees and require them and their employers to supply information with respect to wage payments. APPLICATION OF WAGE LEGISLATION Minimum Wage Legislation Agriculture. Actual wage regulation in Asia lags rather far behind legislation. This is particularly true of wage regulation in agriculture, where practical difficulties are serious. In Burma the Agricultural Labourers' Minimum Wages Act, 1948, is not in force at present. The cultivation of crops has been seriously affected by insurgent activities and in these circumstances the Government has had to postpone the enforcement of its minimum wage legislation. In areas where normal conditions and agricultural production have been restored, wages are usually determined, as before the war, by voluntary agreements. When introducing the Minimum Wages (Amendment) Bill, 1951, the Indian Government stated that most state governments had been unable to fix minimum wage rates in agriculture within the time prescribed by the 1948 law, namely before 15 March 1951. In view of the difficulties encountered the central Government had concluded that state governments should be allowed some discretion in the matter, particularly as regards the date of enforcement and the areas and workers to be covered. This latitude has been taken advantage of and some state governments have fixed minimum wages for a part of the state only, while some have excluded farms below a certain size. The time limit for the fixing of minimum wages in agriculture was extended until 31 December 1953. The Ministry of Labour of the Government of India has undertaken, in collaboration with the state governments, a country-wide inquiry into the conditions of agricultural workers with the purpose of introducing measures, includ- 62 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES ing the fixation of minimum wages, to improve these conditions. 1 In the course of the 13th Session of the Indian Labour Conference (Mysore, January 1954), a paper on wage fixing machinery reviewed the efforts that had been made to apply the Minimum Wages Act, 1948. The Planning Commission had recommended in the First Five-Tear Plan that " full and effective implementation of minimum wages legislation should be secured ", and that " the enforcement of minimum wages for agricultural workers in low wage pockets, for the larger farms and in areas selected for intensive development should be regarded as an important aspect of the programme for improving the conditions of agricultural workers and should receive high priority ". It had, however, suggested that " in view of the paucity of data and the administrative difficulties pointed out by various state governments, a limited beginning should be made with regard to the fixation of minimum wages for agricultural workers, and the scope should be extended further as experience is gained ".2 The memorandum stated that in view of the importance of implementing the measures and in the fight of the recommendations of the Planning Commission, substantial progress in the fixation of minimum wages should be gradually achieved in as many areas as possible. Because of the difficulties involved, however, particularly with regard to the collection of the necessary information and to the short time available for those states to which the Act was last applied, it was proposed to amend the Act so as to extend the time limit for the fixation of minimum wages in areas where the Act was not yet fully implemented to 31 December 1954 for both agriculture and non-agricultural activities. 3 The Minimum Wages Act provides for the review of the minimum wage rates at intervals not exceeding five years. 1 Some results of a preliminary investigation were reproduced in table IV (p. 17). Meanwhile agricultural minimum wages have been fixed for the whole state in the states of Ajmer, Bilaspur, Coorg, Delhi, Himacbal Pradesh, Kutch (farms below 5 acres being excluded), Pattala and East Punjab States Union, Punjab, and Rajasthan. Minimum rates of wages in a part of the state have been fixed in the states of Assam (Cachar district), Bihar (Patna district), Uttar Pradesh (12 districts, only farms over 50 acres being covered) and Vindhya Pradesh (Sidhi district). 2 Government of India, Planning Commission : The First Five Year Plan (New Delhi, 1952), pp. 206 and 585. 3 The time limit was subsequently extended to 31 December 1954. E X I S T I N G SYSTEMS OF WAGE R E G U L A T I O N 63 In this respect the paper issued at the Mysore Conference stressed the need of suitable index numbers of the cost of living in rural areas. A scheme for the preparation of cost-ofliving index numbers for rural areas was under consideration. In Ceylon minimum wage regulations are issued by the wages boards for the tea and rubber plantations, as well as the coconut growing and manufacturing trades. The data given in table VIII on wage rates and the cost of living indicate that since 1939 the former have risen faster than the latter. The improvement in the condition of the estate workers in particular is largely attributed to the successful operation of the wages board machinery and the activities of the trade unions operating in the plantations. TABLE V I I I . AVERAGE D A I L Y WAGE KATES AND I N D E X N U M B E R S OP M O N E Y AND R E A L W A G E S I N TEA AND R U B B E R E S T A T E S I N CEYLON, 1939-50 Average daily wage in rupees Index numbers Year Men Women Children Average wages Cost of living Real wages 1939 . . . . 0.49 0.39 0.29 100 100 100 1941 . . . . 0.54 0.43 0.32 109 119 92 1950 . . . . 1.78 1.39 1.21 372 274 136 Source : Ceylon Labour Gazette, Vol. II, No. 2, Feb. 1951, pp. 4-5. The Philippine Minimum Wages Law, 1951, fixes the following minimum wage rates for agricultural workers : (1) on the effective date of the Act and for one year thereafter, 1.75 pesos a day, no allowance for board and lodging to reduce this wage below 1.50 pesos in cash during that year ; (2) one year after the effective date of the Act, 2.00 pesos a day, no allowances for board and lodging to reduce this wage below 1.75 pesos in cash ; (3) one year thereafter, 2.50 pesos a day, no allowances for board and lodging to reduce this wage below 2.25 pesos in cash. 64 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES These rates may be compared with the average daily wages (in pesos) of agricultural labourers in recent years, which are as follows : 0.56 pesos in 1941, 2.05 in 1947, 1.66 in 1948, 1.73 in 1949, and 1.70 in 1950.1 On 15 January 1953 a wage board for the raw rubber industry was created by the Secretary of Labour to study ways and means of raising the wage level for workers in raw rubber enterprises without causing undue hardship to the industry. Non-agricultural Employments. As a sequel to technical assistance provided to Burma by the International Labour Office, the first wage council, for the cigar and cheroot manufacturing industry (Rangoon and Pegu), was established by the Government in 1953. This council has prepared proposals for fixing minimum rates of wages for the main processes of the industry and regulating holidays and payment for holidays. These provisions were the result of agreements between the representatives of the employers and workers on the council, with the assistance of the independent members. After sufficient experience has been gained of the results of this first wage council, the Government of Burma plans to extend the system progressively to other industries and other parts of the country. It appears that the minimum wage rates fixed by the Government from time to time for its own employees tend also to have the effect of minima in private industry, though not in agriculture and the unorganised traditional industries. As from 16 February 1947 the minimum monthly wage of government employees in Burma was put at 35 rupees flus cost-of-living allowance ; as from 1 March 1951 the minimum wage was raised to 40 rupees plus a cost-of-living allowance varying for different categories of workers. A survey of average monthly wages of permanent workers in a number of selected industries in Burma showed that wages ranged, by June 1951, from 45 rupees in fodder manufacturing to over 90 in rice milling, 164 in soap manufacturing, 183 in oil winning and over 233 in banking. 2 1 See Abstract of Philippine Statistics, Jan.-Mar. 1951, op. cit., p. 8. Besides the money wage, agricultural labourers receive two free meals. 2 Burma Labour Gazette, Vol. V, No. 2, Feb. 1952, p . 11. 65 EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION I n Ceylon a sample survey of wage changes for nonplantation workers in coconut manufacturing and tea and rubber export, for which wage boards have been established and minimum wages fixed, gives the figures shown in table I X for the period from 1939 to 1950. TABLE IX. INDEX NUMBERS OF MONEY AND REAL WAGES OF WORKERS OTHER THAN THOSE ON PLANTATIONS, CEYLON, 1939-50 Year 1939 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 Average •wages Cost of living (Colombo working class) Real wages 100 198 274 276 294 301 301 313 100 185 205 212 233 241 239 252 100 107 134 130 126 125 126 124 Source : Ceylon Labour Gazette, Vol. II, No. 2, Feb. 1951, p. 7. It will be noted from table IX that a significant increase in both money and real wages occurred in 1945, the year in which wage boards fixed minimum wage rates for these workers. The greater part of the increase in real wages then secured has been retained, in spite of the continuing rise in the cost of living. The index of real wages for these workers in 1950 was 24 per cent, higher than in 1939. It is probable that the upward trend of the wage level in these trades, for which wage boards have been established, has contributed to the rise in wage rates in other occupations as well. Wages of unskilled workers in government service have also risen substantially. Average monthly wage rates for this group increased from 16.16 rupees in 1939 to 83.11 rupees in 1950, that is by over 400 per cent. In India the Minimum Wages (Amendment) Act, 1951, mentioned in the previous section, extended the time limit by which minimum wages should be fixed in non-agricultural employments to 31 March 1952. Although no precise information is available, it is known that several state governments have been active in giving effect to the Minimum Wages Act. 66 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES For example, committees of inquiry have been set up in Bombay State (public motor transport) and Mysore (textile mills). The Government of Orissa appointed an Advisory Board to assist it in the fixing and revising of minimum wages and to co-ordinate the work of the committees and subcommittees that may be appointed under the Act. Proposals for minimum wage rates have been published by the Governments of Ajmer (snuff and bidi making), Madras (tanneries and leather manufacturing) and Madhya Pradesh (rice, flour and dal mills, local authorities, road construction and building, stone breaking and crushing). In several states minimum wage rates have actually been fixed : in the Punjab for woollen carpet making and shawl weaving, tanneries and leather manufacturing, rice, flour and dal mills, road construction and building operations, stone breaking or crushing, and oil mills, and for local authorities ; in Madras for rice, flour and dal mills, oil mills and tobacco manufacturing ; in Madhya Pradesh for tobacco manufacturing, public motor transport, oil mills, the cement industry, potteries and the glass industry ; in West Bengal for rice and flour mills ; in Bihar for woollen carpet making and shawl weaving, rice, flour and dal mills, bidi making, oil mills, road construction and building operations, stone breaking or crushing, public motor transport, tanneries and leather manufacturing ; in Ajmer for tobacco manufacturing ; in Delhi for flour and dal mills ; and in the Andaman and Mcobar Islands for timbering operations. Mention should also be made of the measures taken by the Indian Government to ensure that fair wages are paid to contract labour engaged on the work of the Central Public Works Department. Previously, a fair wage clause in the standard agreement for the Department's contracts had provided that the contractor should pay his workers not less than the wages paid for similar work in the neighbourhood. Under a revised clause the daily wage to be paid is the one notified, at the time of calling for tender, as the prevailing wage in the locality. If no such wage is notified, the " fair " wage is prescribed by the Department for the district in which the work is done. A request was made to all state governments to consider adoption of similar provisions for employment on their public works. The memorandum submitted to the 13th Session of the Indian Labour Conference referred to above (p. 62) dealt EXISTING SYSTEMS OP WAGE REGULATION 67 also with the need for setting up wage boards for particular industries. The Planning Commission had indicated that " for important industries separate wage boards would be found very helpful ". It had recommended that " permanent wage boards with a tripartite composition should be set up in each state and at the centre to deal comprehensively with all aspects of the question of wages, to initiate necessary inquiries, collect data, review the situation from time to time and take decisions regarding wage adjustments suo moto or on reference from parties or from the Government ". 1 In 1950 the Government of Japan decided to establish a Central Wage Council, which in the following year reached decisions on : (a) the establishment in principle of minimum wages on a dual system, one designed to cover workers in the majority of industries and the other to cover workers in lowerwage industries ; (b) the establishment of minimum wages first for the lower-paid categories ; and (c) a study to be undertaken concerning minimum wages for domestic workers. After careful consideration it was decided in 1952 to establish " special deliberation councils " for each of the following industries in which relatively low wages were paid : silk and rayon weaving, furniture and fixtures, Japanesepaper manufacturing and dupion yarn reeling. The special deliberation councils were to submit to the Central Wage Council reports on the conditions surrounding the establishment of minimum wages. In the Philippines the Minimum Wages Law came into effect only on 4 August 1951. The minimum rates prescribed by the Act for employees who are employed by an enterprise other than in agriculture are as follows (a) 4.00 pesos a day on the effective date of the Act and thereafter, for employees of an establishment located in Manila or its environs ; and (b) 3.00 pesos a day on the effective date of the Act and for one year after the effective date, and thereafter 4.00 pesos a day, for employees of establishments located outside Manila or its environs. The figures in tables X and XI enable some comparison to be made between the prescribed minimum wage rates and the average wage rates for the period preceding the fixing of the minimum wage rates. 1 The First Five Year Flan, op. cit., pp. 579 and 585. 68 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES TABLE X. AVERAGE DAILY WAGE RATES OP INDUSTRIAL WORKERS IN THE PHILIPPINES, 1 9 4 0 - 5 0 (pesos) 1940 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1.41 0.96 3.21 1.78 3.29 1.87 3.34 1.89 3.52 2.03 3.46 1.87 1.41 Central Luzon including Zambales 1.47 Southern Luzon : Bicol including 1.37 1.26 1.53 2.93 4.12 3.00 4.19 3.06 4.08 3.08 4.18 3.16 4.21 4.12 2.70 2.62 4.35 2.91 2.66 4.27 3.08 2.77 4.39 3.27 3.19 4.27 3.07 3.07 Region Whole country : Skilled Luzon : Hocos including mountain Source : Abstract of Philippine Statistics, Vol. I, No. 2, Jan.-Mar. 1951, op. cit., p. 10. TABLE XI. WAGE RATES OF LABOURERS IN INDUSTRIAL ESTABLISHMENTS IN MANILA, 1 9 4 1 - 5 0 (pesos) Year 1941 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 Source : Abstract o/ Philippine Skilled labourer Unskilled labourer 2.29 6.73 7.54 7.47 7.61 7.59 1.24 4.53 4.66 4.69 4.90 4.29 Statistics, Vol. I, No. 2, Jan.-Mar. 1951, op. cit., p. 10. A Wage Administration Service has been set up primarily to take over the responsibility of administering the Minimum Wage Law. A wage board was appointed to make investigations in the mining industry in order to determine whether or not to extend the application of the minimum wage for six months after 4 August 1952. It is stated that some 25,000 mineworkers in about 29 producing mining firms will be affected by the decision of the board. In response to a petition of the Lumber Producers' Association on behalf of its 29 lumber company affiliates, a wage board for the lumber industry was created on 11 July 1952.1 1 According to the latest available data, there are 342 sawmills in the country and it is estimated that the mdustry employs about 70,000 workers. EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 69 In Indonesia, Pakistan and Thailand, wage rates are fixed by individual or collective agreements and awards or decisions of industrial tribunals. However, the Governments, in their capacity as employers, fix minimum wage rates for workers in government service. For instance, in Indonesia the Government decided to increase the minimum wage rates of labourers employed by the provincial and local administrations in Central Java with effect from 1 January 1952. According to this decision, wages under 3.50 rupiahs a day were increased to 4.50 rupiahs, while wages from 3.50 to 4.50 rupiahs were increased by at least 0.75 rupiahs per day to a maximum of 5.50 rupiahs. The minimum wage of women was increased from 2.80 to 3.60 rupiahs. In Pakistan the Government has adopted measures to ensure the payment of " fair wages " to workers employed by contractors in the Public Works Department on government works. A fair wages clause and the " Pakistan P.W.D. Contractors' Labour Eegulations " are included in the government Public Works Department contract forms for contractors. Wage rates sanctioned by the Government as payable to contract labour are inserted in the contract. Wage Determination by Industrial Tribunals The machinery created in several Asian countries for the prevention and settlement of industrial disputes has been of considerable importance for the determination of wages and other conditions of employment in various trades and industries. In those countries where other wage regulations are not yet in force, this machinery usually represents the only authority for the statutory fixing of basic wage rates, special allowances, paid leave, etc. As an instrument of wage policy conciliation and arbitration differ widely from minimum wage legislation. The purpose of machinery for the settlement of disputes is primarily to avoid harmful industrial unrest rather than to improve the lot of the lowest-paid groups of workers. Indeed, since industrial disputes usually arise only after some degree of organisation among the workers has been attained, arbitration could hardly be of much use for the improvement of labour standards in industries which consist largely of small establishments or in which for other reasons the labour force is unorganised. 70 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES The judge or arbitrator may, of course, include in the considerations on which his award is based the factors underlying minimum wage legislation, but in most cases he is not required to do so ; still less are different adjudicators required to apply uniform economic and social principles of wage determination in their awards. In a few cases the conditions under which arbitration takes place are such as may eventually permit the development of a real " wage policy ". For example, in Indonesia the Central Committee for the settlement of disputes has considerable practical influence. It is entirely composed of Ministers, while the local committees are composed of government officers. In such conditions arbitration might very well be used as an instrument of government wage policy. In most Asian countries, however, industrial awards show a great diversity in the arguments used and the decisions reached by the various tribunals, even on almost identical questions. Unless a fair degree of uniformity in the awards of the industrial courts and tribunals is assured through the operation of an easily accessible appellate tribunal, it is hardly to be expected that any comprehensive wage policy will evolve from such a system. 1 In some countries the increase in industrial disputes and the profusion of committees, commissions, boards and tribunals for settlement have given rise to some concern. In January 1953 the Burmese Minister of Labour, in an address to labour officers and labour leaders, stated that the Government had to intervene frequently in industrial disputes, but he was of the opinion that disputes should be settled through direct negotiation and collective bargaining. Such an approach, he believed, would strengthen the trade union movement, and thereby reduce the need for strikes. 2 Similarly, the Indian Minister of Labour, addressing the 12th Session of the Indian Labour Conference, said that it was far better for management and labour to settle their differences between themselves than to go as litigants and opponents before a labour court or 1 Beference should, in this connection, be made to an interesting publication of the Indian Ministry of Labour : Industrial Awards in India : An Analysis (Delhi, 1951), where a large number of awards have been brought together under various headings in order to show divergencies and parallels and to bring out the main principles underlying the decisions of the various labour judiciaries. 2 See Industry and Labour, Vol. IX, No. 8, 15 Apr. 1953, p. 229. EXISTING SYSTEMS OP WAGE REGULATION 71 tribunal. Compulsory arbitration, he found, had caused the spirit of self-confidence and self-reliance engendered by healthy bargaining to give place to a habit of importunity and litigation. He also mentioned the generally felt need for reducing the multiplicity of authorities connected with the settlement of industrial disputes. In reply to a questionnaire on industrial relations, he had received suggestions for the elimination of registering offices, standing conciliation boards, commissions of inquiry, labour courts and appellate tribunals. Bodies and authorities whose continued existence had not been called in question were works committees or joint committees, conciliation officers, boards of conciliation, and industrial tribunals or courts of arbitration. 1 * * * As has been seen, wage legislation has been enacted in most of the Asian countries. In an appreciable number of them the wage regulations provide specifically for the determination of minimum wages in different trades and industries. Burma, India and the Philippines, conscious of the particular needs of agricultural workers, have included provisions in their wage legislation to cover employment in agriculture. In Indonesia and Thailand there is still no comprehensive wage legislation in existence. In Pakistan, although there is no minimum wage legislation, a Payment of Wages Act is in force. The degree of enforcement and application of minimum wage legislation, however, varies greatly. In a few countries, Ceylon for example, wage fixing machinery has already been established and minimum wage rates have actually been fixed for a number of years. On the other hand, in countries such as India and the Philippines, where the wage legislation has come into force comparatively recently, wage fixing machinery is in the course of being created and the determination of minimum wage rates is being extended to cover more employments or trades. In Burma only the first steps have thus far been taken to carry into effect the recent minimum wage legislation. The great majority of Asian workers, however, have still to be covered by any form of wage regulation. This is parti1 Industry and Labour, Vol. IX, No. 3, 1 Feb. 1953, pp. 85-87. 72 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES cularly the case in agriculture, in which wages are so low as to leave little margin beyond mere subsistence. For the majority of workers wages continue to be fixed by individual agreements. A much smaller number are paid wages according to awards made by tribunals in the course of settling disputes. So far, collective agreements have played a very limited role in wage determination in most Asian countries. The few wage laws, of limited scope, which existed in some Asian countries before the Second World War primarily concerned wage earners engaged in organised industries such as regulated factories, mines, transport and plantations. These workers, who formed only a small part of the gainfully occupied, received some legal protection, while workers in the unorganised industries (unregulated factories and small industrial establishments, handicrafts and cottage industries, commerce, domestic service and agriculture) remained unprotected and received exceedingly low wages. Since the Second World War, many governments have enacted wage legislation not only for the organised and the more important industries but also for workers in unorganised industries, including agriculture. In many of the regulations increases in the minimum wage are related to cost-of-living index numbers. In several countries the wage consists of a rather low " basic " wage, which is the same as or only slightly higher than the pre-war rate, plus an allowance called " dearness allowance ", " cost-of-living allowance ", " special allowance ", or " family allowance ", which in quite a few cases amounts to about the same as the " basic " wage, if not more. Where the allowance is linked with cost-of-living index numbers, the periodic adjustment varies from a fraction of the rise in the index to full compensation. Some of the minimum wage laws provide for the determination of minimum wage rates by committees, boards or councils in different areas or regions, or for certain trades or employments. Industrial tribunals in many Asian countries fix wages, grant bonuses and allowances, and decide on many other aspects of wages in the course of settling disputes. Some of the difficulties that arise in connection with this system have been mentioned. I t has been found, for instance, in India that in the absence of any co-ordinating authority or guiding principles several tribunals have expressed divergent views on EXISTING SYSTEMS OF WAGE REGULATION 73 important issues referred to them. The varying decisions made by tribunals in different states and sometimes in the same state have caused discontent among both employers and workers. Another source of dissatisfaction regarding the work of industrial tribunals is that they can usually act only in cases where an industrial dispute already exists or is likely to arise. Accordingly, wage earners employed in industries in which the organisations of workers are weak have gained little from the awards. It is also feared that progress in collective bargaining may be retarded by the regular use of industrial tribunals. Most workers in most Asian countries are employed under individual agreements based on terms of employment set by the employer. When such workers seek an increase in wages, leave pay, overtime pay or allowances, they must address themselves to their employer and, if their claims are refused, refer the " dispute " to the industrial tribunal. Having regard to the advantages that may accrue in the long run from the development of effective machinery for collective bargaining, it is therefore a matter of some importance that consideration should be given to methods of offsetting any unfavourable effects that the operation of industrial tribunals may have on the process and development of collective bargaining. CHAPTEB IV PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY In this and the next chapter some problems of wage policy in Asian countries are further analysed. Broadly speaking, these problems fall into two categories concerning respectively the definition of wage policy in terms of the level and structure of wages, and methods of implementation and enforcement. In connection with the first category it has been pointed out in Chapter I I that wage policy must be consistent with accepted policies in other fields. This requirement may strictly limit the possible choice of targets. For example the rapid expansion of employment may be incompatible with a programme calling for a rapid and considerable increase in real wages for a substantial proportion of the employed labour force. The aims of wage policy can be achieved through statutory wage regulation and, in certain conditions, conciliation and arbitration procedures. The extent to which the latter can be made effective instruments of wage policy depends on the one hand on such questions as whether arbitration is compulsory and binding or not, and on the other hand on the degree of control exerted by the authorities responsible for formulating wage policy over the bodies to whom the settlement of labour disputes is entrusted. In countries where arbitration is widely resorted to, any party to an industrial dispute may turn to the arbitrator whenever he feels that the demands or offers put forward by the other party are " unreasonable " or " unfair ". Indeed, in extreme cases parties may scarcely attempt to reach a voluntary agreement at all, preferring to refer the question of wage determination to the arbitrator as soon as the existing agreement or award expires. I n such circumstances it may be found necessary to define generally applicable criteria of " fairness " or " reason ", and the government may, through the persuasive influence of public pronouncements on these questions or through formal prescriptions, seek to guide PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 75 the process of wage determination by the tribunals. In this way it may succeed in introducing into this process certain principles of general economic expediency, such as the need to avoid inflation or to safeguard the balance of payments. In other cases arbitrators may themselves take account of considerations of this nature, though possibly in a more or less unsystematic and unco-ordinated fashion. 1 A somewhat similar situation exists with regard to the fixing of statutory minimum wages. As was observed in Chapter III, while the various laws and decrees establishing machinery for the fixing of minimum wages usually mention certain criteria to be applied in wage determination—criteria reflecting broad concepts of fairness and reason—they do not generally provide the wage fixing bodies with much guidance on how these criteria should be applied in practice. If the existing legislation were fully applied it could have a considerable effect on the general economic and social situation in most Asian countries ; it would therefore be highly desirable if certain principles could be developed for the implementation of this legislation. The discussion which follows is designed to serve as a starting-point for the formulation of such general principles. It is limited to problems of minimum wage policy in the first instance because the fixing of minimum wages is clearly the most popular objective of wage policy in Asian countries. Part of the analysis could, however, also apply to questions of wage policy in a more general sense. The first problem of minimum wage policy is whether it should aim at the establishment of a nationally uniform minimum wage or whether a more differentiated system of minimum wages should be established to take account of differences in prosperity in different industries and areas, and of other circumstances. Whichever course is followed, the actual level (or levels) of the minimum wage must be fixed on the basis of a simultaneous consideration of both the workers' recognised needs for maintaining a certain standard of living and the economic possibility of ensuring them such living standards through minimum wage regulation. As the Philippine Minimum Wages Law of 1951 puts it, " a minimum wage to be established under this Act shall be as nearly adequate as is economically Cf. Industrial Awards in India, op. oit. 6 76 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES feasible to maintain the minimum standard of living necessary for the health, efficiency and general well-being of employees ". How these two criteria of social desirability and economic feasibility shall be combined and applied in determining the level of the minimum wage is a second basic problem of minimum wage policy. The third question to be taken up in this chapter concerns the establishment of appropriate machinery for the determination and enforcement of the minimum wage. The problem of enforcement is especially difficult at the present stage of development. As was noted earlier in this report, the bulk of Asian wage earners are employed in agriculture, in the handicraft and cottage industries and in domestic service. These are precisely the industries in which, in countries with limited administrative resources, it is most difficult to introduce and enforce wage or other regulations. T H E QUESTION OF UNIFORMITY Uniformity among Industries The scope of any particular minimum wage regulation may be wide or narrow. One extreme possibility is to issue a single general regulation fixing a uniform minimum rate of remuneration for the whole country covering all workers in all industries. In practice, however, even the most general regulation provides for more than one minimum wage so as to allow, for example, for inter-regional differences in the cost of living ; or in order to establish or maintain certain wage differentials between workers of different age or sex ; or in order to establish a higher level of minimum earnings for workers on piecework as compared with those paid according to time. At the other extreme it is possible to have separate regulations specifying minimum wages for every single industry and for every economically distinguishable region. The system adopted in the Philippines, for example, is more or less of the first type. In most Asian countries, however, the systems adopted tend towards the second type, regulations on an industry or regional basis or both being issued as circumstances require or permit. Even then the question arises whether such a gradually expanding system of minimum wage regula- PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 77 tions of limited scope should aim at the eventual establishment of a fairly uniform level of minimum real wages for the country as a whole or whether the level of the minimum wage should be permanently linked to the particular conditions prevailing in each industry or region. The choice between a uniform and a more diversified wage level will depend in part on the general purpose of the minimum wage policy. If that purpose is to ensure to every worker a certain minimum standard of living, the uniform basic or minimum wage will be preferred. If, however, the purpose is to ensure that every worker or group of workers shall receive a reasonable share (however that concept may be defined) of the revenue of the particular firm or industry in which he is employed, a more diversified minimum wage system will be more appropriate. The latter approach has been recommended, for example, in discussions in India concerning the " fair wage ", in the sense of a wage that would at least be equal to the minimum wage, but should be higher if circumstances in particular industries permit. 1 In practice minimum wages have sometimes been deliberately differentiated so as to take account of differences in the state of prosperity of different industries, in addition to the standard of living. It would seem, however, that in Asian countries the basic purpose of minimum wage regulation is generally the establishment of a uniform " wage floor " to ensure that all those employed for wages shall receive an income sufficient to maintain the standard of living considered to be the socially acceptable minimum. Under this conception those who would benefit first and most from minimum wage regulation would be the lowest-paid workers. Especially in Asian countries, where the resources available for a more general rise in standards of living will be small for a number of years to come, the giving of such priority to the worst cases of poverty would yield an important social gain. 1 See, for example, the views of the Indian National Trades Union Congress and of the Government of Bombay, quoted in the Report of the Committee on Fair Wages (Simla, Government of India, Ministry of Labour, 1949), paragraphs 12 ft. It may be noted that uniformity and diversity are not mutually exclusive : the determination of " fair wages " might consist of the fixing of a more or less uniform minimum wage supplemented by allowances varying with the state of prosperity in different industries. 78 "WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Apart from this consideration there are further arguments that support the adoption of a more or less uniform minimum rate of pay. First, a uniform minimum wage might help to reduce the unnecessarily wide wage differentials that exist in a number of Asian countries and that have been reported to be a cause of wasteful labour turnover and of labour disputes. Secondly, if a diversified minimum wage system were adopted and the most productive and progressive industries were obliged to pay the highest minimum wage on the ground that their capacity to pay is higher than that of less productive industries, the result would be that efficiency and high productivity would be taxed and inefficiency and low productivity subsidised. Although this happens, in a sense and to some extent, under most systems of profits taxation, and although the result is not necessarily " unfair ", the imposition of higher wage costs on more prosperous industries might hamper the expansion of production and employment in them, while at the same time hindering the contraction of production and employment in less prosperous and less productive industries. Furthermore, the need for minimum wage fixing may be relatively small in more prosperous industries, since these industries may in any case be inclined to pay higher wages in order to attract and keep the pick of the workers, or because collective bargaining may develop more easily in prosperous and expanding industries than in backward or stagnant ones. Finally, the machinery required for the fixing, periodic revision and enforcement of one or a small number of minimum wage rates will be simpler and smaller than that required for a complicated system of prescriptions specifying different rates for a large number of separate industries. Hence a more or less uniform minimum wage, if it could be applied, would appear to have certain important advantages over a more complicated pattern of wage regulation. On the other hand, such a uniform minimum wage rate would probably have to be very low indeed, in view of the large variation in capacity to pay in different firms, industries and regions. I t has been observed in Chapter I that substantial differences exist, at least in those countries for which some information is available, between wages paid in indigenous agriculture, the plantation industry, the handicraft and village industries and modern manufacturing. A large part of these differences prob- PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 79 ably reflects nothing but the capacity to pay of these broad industrial groups. This problem will be taken up in more detail below, but it is clear that, if a general minimum wage is to be established, the existence of a wide variation in capacity to pay poses a dilemma. Either the minimum must be set at such a low level that even the least productive section of the economy can afford to pay it (in which case very few workers could be made to benefit) or the problem must be faced that either employment will have to be reduced in some industries or they will have to be helped, in one way or another, to pay the minimum wage fixed. It is not likely that a workable solution to this problem can be found in any near future. Many, perhaps all, of the countries concerned will for a long time find it nearly impossible to establish a general minimum wage rate to be applied in all industries. This does not mean that the objective of ensuring about the same minimum standard of living to all workers would have to be abandoned ; but the attainment of that objective would become the terminal rather than the starting point of a rather long and gradual programme of general social and economic development. Under such a programme the establishment of a general minimum standard of living for all wage earners would rank as one of the objectives, for the attainment of which it would be a function of economic policy to create the necessary conditions. During the initial stages of programmes for protective minimum wage regulation in Asian countries, it might perhaps be preferable to establish different minimum rates of remuneration for various sectors of the economy. This would imply the continued acceptance of lower minimum living standards for wage earners in, say, agriculture and the cottage industries than for those employed in more modern small-scale or largescale industries or on plantations ; there might even be differences within these broad categories—for example between tea and sugar plantations or between jute and steel mills. At the same time the levelling-up of these various minimum wage rates towards a national, general minimum wage might be maintained as the eventual objective of policy but made dependent on the progress of economic development and on the structural adjustments in the pattern of production and employment which this would entail. There is, in fact, a case for expecting that economic development will more or less 80 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES automatically create the necessary conditions for substantial uniformity in minimum wage rates. 1 Uniformity among Various Categories of Wage Earners Men and Women Workers. The essential purpose of minimum wage regulation (i.e. to ensure a socially acceptable minimum standard of living to all workers) implies that, in principle, the same minimum wage should eventually apply to all industries. I t does not necessarily imply that the same minimum wage should be fixed for all categories of wage earners within these industries. For instance, the fact that the family responsibilities of various groups of workers are different may be considered a reason for corresponding differences in minimum wages. I t has been argued, for example, that minimum wages might for that reason be set lower for female workers than for males and in India some awards by industrial tribunals have indeed provided for wage differentials based on sex. 2 The Committee on Fair Wages already referred to notes, however, that there has been an increasing tendency on the part of industrial tribunals and courts to uphold, in their awards, the principle of equal pay for work of equal value. The Committee itself appears to favour general application of this principle, though they are willing to accept lower minimum wages for female workers in those cases where " women are employed on work exclusively done by them " since " it can then no longer be said that the wage earned by a woman is lower than that earned by a man for the same or similar work ". 3 The preamble to the Constitution of the International Labour Organisation specifically mentions recognition of the principle of equal remuneration for work of equal value as one of the means by which labour conditions can be improved and the Equal Eemuneration Convention, 1951 (Article 2), 1 A basic principle of efficient allocation of resources is that the marginal productivity of labour, land and capital should be made equal for their alternative uses. To the extent that programmes for economie development conform with this principle the marginal productivity of labour would become more or less equal in all industries and all regions of the country. This in turn would mean that about equal wages could be paid in all industries and regions. 2 Industrial Awards in India, op. cit., pp. 26-27. 3 Beport of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., pp. 21-23. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 81 singles out " legally established or recognised machinery for wage determination " as one of the means by which this principle may be applied. This suggests that the possibility of attaining equality of remuneration through the operation of minimum wage regulation might be adopted as one of the guiding principles for the application of such regulation. I t is, however, generally conceded that progress toward the goal of equal remuneration for work of equal value should be gradual. One of the basic purposes of minimum wage policy is to improve the living standards of the worst-paid workers. Where the wages commonly paid to men and to women differ substantially, immediate and full application of the principle of equal pay might make it more difficult to attain this basic purpose. The goals of improving the living standards of the worst-paid workers and of equal pay for work of equal value are, to a certain extent, competitive : the increase in wage costs which would follow the application of the equal pay principle would reduce the employers' capacity to pay higher wages to male workers. Another factor to be considered is the effect of abolishing wage differentials based on sex on the relative employment opportunities for men and women. I t may be that the demand for female workers would fall and that the supply of female labour would increase. The net result might be either a rise or a fall in female employment. This may be either desirable or undesirable according to circumstances. It might, for example, be considered desirable to have fewer women employed in order to leave more employment opportunities for male heads of families, a situation presenting certain advantages from the point of view of raising the living standards of some of the poorest families. But in other cases or from other points of view a reduction in employment opportunities for women may be considered undesirable. Again it would seem that the principle of equal remuneration for work of equal value might be expressly recognised as one of the objectives of minimum wage regulation, and the gradual equalisation of wages for male and female workers, where they are still different, made dependent on the progress of economic development. This progress would eventually make it possible to attain both the objective of adequate minimum living standards for all workers and that of equal remuneration. 82 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Different Occupations and Levels of Skill. Wage differentials based on the worker's skill, his responsibility, the disagreeableness of the job, and similar considerations are fixed by wage regulating authorities in various countries (e.g. Australia). In a number of Latin American countries the " kind of job and its conditions " must be taken into account by such authorities. The Indian Fair Wages Committee recommended that wage differentials be established on the basis of the following considerations : the degree of skill, the strain of work, the experience involved, the training required, the responsibility undertaken, the mental and physical requirements, the disagreeableness of the task, the hazard attendant on the work, and the fatigue involved. 1 This recommendation, however, concerns the establishment of fair wages, which the Committee apparently considered something more advanced than minimum wages. According to the Indian Planning Commission " differentials for various jobs should be maintained at the minimum levels justified by " the criteria mentioned above, which had been suggested earlier by the Fair Wages Committee. 2 I t would appear therefore to be the view of the Planning Commission that the minimum wage regulation should provide for such differentials. The problem of establishing a rational wage structure is an important one in most Asian countries, not only because the present pattern of wage differentials between various industries and occupations is often rather unsystematic but also in view of the setting up, under programmes of economic development, of entirely new industries, for which entirely new vocational nomenclatures and wage scales have to be established. Whether minimum wage fixing machinery is the most appropriate means of tackling this problem is another question. When wages are fixed by an arbitration court in order to settle a wage dispute the arbitrator will, of course, usually fix the wage differentials for various occupations or functions at the same time, if these are also the subject of litigation. In Australia, for example, where many of the decisions usually taken in other countries in the course of 1 2 Tief ort of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., p. 20. The First Five Tear Plan, op. cit., p. 584. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 83 ordinary collective bargaining procedure are taken by conciliation commissioners associated with the Arbitration Court, the awarding of differentials based on skill is a natural corollary of the system of wage determination. Normally, however, differentials based on occupation and skills will result from the operation of market forces reflecting the relative supply of and demand for various skills and other special qualifications. As observed in Chapters I and II, such forces have probably been responsible in part for the existing substantial wage differential between rural and urban wages and for the existence of larger differentials based on skills in underdeveloped countries than in industrialised areas. In certain cases market forces may result in unacceptably low wages in particular occupations and there may be a need for statutory minimum wages. But in Asian countries the problems of minimum wage regulation proper, which are formidable enough in themselves, would probably become very unwieldy indeed if complicated by job evaluation and wage standardisation designed to establish wage differentials based on criteria such as those mentioned above. The carrying through of minimum wage regulations would certainly be seriously delayed and, unless the problem of wage differentials is considered at least as urgent as that of improving the living conditions of the poorest workers, this would in itself justify postponing action with regard to differentials or shifting it to some other branch of wage policy administration. There are, however, a few special categories of workers for whom the fixing of special minimum wage rates might nevertheless be considered. First, workers performing exceptionally heavy or unhealthy duties might be granted somewhat higher minima on the ground that their dietetic or other normal needs are greater than those of the average worker. Secondly, special provision might be made for workers whose performance, because of physical or mental deficiencies, is below normal. Thirdly, it has sometimes been suggested that higher minimum rates might be fixed for piece-workers, on the ground that they usually work at greater intensity than time-workers. For example it might be decided that the system of payment should be such as to make the average worker paid by results earn 10 or 20 per cent, more, under normal conditions, than the average worker paid by the hour or by the day. 84 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES T H E LEVEL OE THE MINIMUM WAGE Generally speaking, the problem of selecting the appropriate level for the minimum wage consists in striking a balance between the workers' recognised needs for maintaining a certain minimum living standard and the economic and social feasibility of ensuring them such a standard of living. Both concepts are highly elusive and their practical application raises difficult problems of analysis and policy. Speaking of the parts that the improvement in the standard of living and the conditions of the economy have to play in the fixing of minimum wages, the Bombay Industrial Court found that " it is not possible to lay down, in any well-defined terms, a basis for the fixation of the minimum w a g e . . . . I t is not possible to define... in a precise manner either of these concepts or to indicate the weight that should be attached to each." 1 The difficulty is that neither of the two criteria in itself suffices to determine the proper level of the wage : they must be taken into account together. There would be little sense in simply drawing up a household budget satisfying a number of nutritional, medical, hygienic and cultural standards, and decreeing that the minimum wage should correspond to the total cost of that budget, without considering whether the economy would be in a position to supply the goods and services postulated. On the other hand, the capacity to pay wages is not a uniquely determined quantity either. For example, among the criteria suggested for assessing this capacity have been " fair profits " or " a fair remuneration to capital and management " ; both are rather elastic concepts, since the " fairness " of the remuneration going to management and capital will usually be judged, among other things, in the light of the prevailing wages. Furthermore, a level of wages that may not be tolerable in a certain industry at the current selling prices of its output might come within its capacity to pay if these prices were raised. It is thus seen that the problem of minimum wage regulation, conceived as a large-scale programme designed to affect a large proportion of the wage-earning population, is related to questions of consumption (and therefore also of savings and 1 Industrial Awards in India, op. cit., pp. 19-20. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 85 investment), price policy, and the general approach to the question of the distribution of the national income. Most of these matters are of major importance to the problem of economic development. The above considerations concern the broad principles governing the determination of the general level of the minimum wage. It has been pointed out in a previous section that in practice, at least during the period immediately ahead, it will probably be found impossible to establish a nation-wide minimum wage rate for all industries. Therefore, if a set of general principles of minimum wage policy is established, such principles will serve only as a guide to the agency responsible for fixing mimmum wage rates for a particular industry in a given region. In the actual fixing of minimum wage rates the principles established will, of course, have to be supplemented by careful consideration of the particular circumstances of each case. This means that the bodies in charge of the actual fixing of rates will again be faced with the problem of comparing and reconciling the workers' needs with the economic feasibility of satisfying them in the industrial section concerned, even though their freedom to assess, interpret and weigh facts and circumstances may be limited by general directives emanating from a central agency responsible for minimum wage policy in general. The Workers' Normal Needs The determination of the workers' normal needs, which minimum wage regulations aim to satisfy, consists essentially in drawing up a household budget, taking account of certain nutritional, medical and other relevant standards, and computing its cost. The list of items included in the budget may be short or long according to whether it is to represent, say, a minimum subsistence level or a minimum level of health and frugal comfort. As indicated above, the length of the final list, and hence the minimum wage finally decided upon, cannot be determined arbitrarily but must be the result of a careful analysis and comparison of the workers' needs and some standard of the country's or industry's capacity to pay. One of the most decisive elements of these family budgets is, of course, the size of the standard family for whom they 86 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES are drawn up. 1 In determining this size the guiding principle will ordinarily be that the largest possible number of the most urgent family needs must be met by the minimum wage. Attempts have therefore been made to improve on the simple statistical average of family size, for instance by taking into account the following factors : (a) the relative frequency of various sizes of family in a region, among low-income families dependent on wage income ; (b) the numbers of wage earners in families of various sizes ; (c) the age structure of families of various sizes, to be taken as the basis for determining, on the one hand, the number of " consumption units " per family and, on the other, the number of what might be called " wage-earning units ", children and women being taken, in both cases, at some lower value than adult males. On the basis of these and similar considerations some appropriately weighted average of family sizes might be decided to be the standard family. But whether a simple or a more complicated average is used, the standard family will suffer from its being an average, adequately representative at best for a majority of the actual families concerned, but never for all. There will always be families with more children or fewer wage earners than was assumed for the standard family ; and in other cases provision will be made for non-existent wives and children. It might therefore be asked whether the worker's minimum wage income could not be made directly dependent on the size of his family. It would, of course, be difficult to fix different minimum wage rates for workers with different family responsibilities, since that would unduly hamper the heads of large families in finding employment. This difficulty does not arise where family allowances are paid out of the compulsory contributions made by all employers or all taxpayers to a general fund. The standard family for purposes of wage determination could then be very small ; moreover, a system of family allowances might also be applied to self-employed persons, thereby making a first contribution to the solution 1 Cf. Beport of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., pp. 17-18 ; and Industrial Awards in India, op. cit., pp. 24-26. PROBLEMS OP MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 87 of the problem of income in this category. Some countries have in fact tried to moderate the effect of different family sizes on the determination of wage earners' needs by establishing extensive systems of children's allowances. This is not, however, a universally accepted solution. In any case administrative and financial difficulties are likely to make it difficult for Asian countries to adopt such schemes for some time to come. The Capacity to Pay Minimum Wages Perhaps the only clear and unambiguous property of capacity to pay is that it, too, is not an absolute concept. Eeference has already been made to such relative criteria as the maintenance of " fair profits " and to the possibility that an industry's capacity to pay higher wages may be enlarged by raising its selling prices. Another consideration affecting general decisions regarding the level of the minimum wage will be the need for savings and investment within the framework of a general programme for economic development. The larger these needs, the less rapidly consumption can be permitted to rise. But this would have to be a flexible standard : there are various different possible levels of consumption and savings from which a choice must be made. Again, while a given increase in wages might be beyond the industry's capacity to pay at the existing level of productivity and efficiency, it might be borne if productivity were raised. The simple statement that a certain minimum wage would be beyond industry's capacity to pay has little meaning. Any judgment concerning capacity to pay must necessarily be based on some explicit or implicit set of standards pertaining to (a) the anticipated effects of the introduction of a given minimum wage rate on prices, profits, employment, etc., and (b) the evaluation of these effects in terms of social and economic policy. For example, in one case it might be found that a given increase in wages would lead to a rise in wage earners' consumption inconsistent with the level of savings required for the economic development programme, and hence that the proposed increase would be beyond the country's capacity to pay. In another case it might be found that, while a given increase in wages would raise the costs of a particular industry to such an extent that production would have to be curtailed, 88 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES it would be possible to shift the workers thereby becoming redundant to other more productive industries, so that the proposed wage increase would be economically feasible. It thus appears that, in the final analysis, the problem of determining capacity to pay consists in deciding what weight can be attached to the social objective of raising the living standards of the worst-paid workers in the light of other objectives of economic and social policy, notably the level of employment and the rate of economic development. By way of illustration some of the references to the problem of wage regulation appearing in the first Indian Five-Year Plan may be quoted here. This plan does not contain, nor does it set out to give, any clear-cut programme of minimum wage regulation. Nevertheless, it advances a number of general propositions reflecting the broad approach to problems of wage regulation, adopted by the authors of the plan, against the background of their awareness and appreciation of the relationship between wages and economic development. The Planning Commission first observes, regarding workers' living standards, that " the rate of progress has to be determined not only by the needs of the workers but also by the limitation of the country's resources ". 1 It then proceeds to an exposition of its broad views concerning the consequences of a general wage increase and their impact on problems of economic development. " Too rapid changes or changes on a wide scale may result in financial, administrative and other difficulties which endanger new reforms and retard further development." Moreover, any rise in wages, which would be reflected in higher prices, would at this juncture jeopardise economic stability : the gains of the workers would in such cases, the Commission believes, soon prove illusory, and in the long run employment might be adversely affected. Nevertheless, the Commission felt that " full and effective implementation of the minimum wage legislation " should be assured during the period covered by the Five-Year Plan. The Commission found that certain broad principles which might help in the regulation of wages had already emerged from the work of various Indian commissions and committees. These principles had, for the most part, been embodied in 1 The First Five Tear Plan, op. cit., pp. 571 ff. The following quotations and other references have been taken from the same passage. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 89 existing and proposed legislation, but they did not, according to the Commission, form an adequate practical basis for a uniform policy in determining wage rates and effecting wage adjustments. I t is therefore recommended in the plan that a tripartite machinery " should evolve in as precise terms as practicable, the ' norms ' and standards, which should guide wage boards or tribunals in settling questions relating to wages, having regard to the claims of the various groups of workers inter se, of the other participants in industry and of the community as a whole ". The Commission itself also formulated a number of guiding principles regarding wage policy. In the implementation of the minimum wage legislation, " depressed areas " should receive prior attention. Moreover, all wage adjustments should conform to the broad principles of social policy, and disparities of income should be reduced to the utmost extent. The process of standardisation of wages should be accelerated and extended to as large a field as possible : there should be a progressive narrowing down of disparities in the wage rates of different classes of workers in the same unit, in similar occupations in different units of the same industry, in comparable occupations in different industries, and in the same industry at different centres. 1 Finally, it is recommended that wage increases should be granted to restore the pre-war real wage as a first step towards the establishment of a living wage, which would be reached through increased productivity resulting from rationalisation and the renewal or modernisation of plant. In short it will be seen that the Commission recommended a rather cautious approach towards problems of wage regulation, since it was keenly aware of the competitive character of an improvement in workers' living standards on the one hand and the other objectives of the Five-Year Plan on the other. It also pointed to the need for further specification of the prmciples by which wage regulation was to be guided and indicated which parts of the programme of wage regulation should receive first priority (depressed areas and anomalies in the existing wage structure). Steps towards the restoration of the pre-war real wage were also recommended. 1 See, however, the Commission's views on wage differentials on p . 82 above. 90 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES The Effects of Wage Increases It has been suggested above that, in testing the economic feasibility of plans for raising the living standards of the lowest-paid workers, it is necessary to analyse the most probable effects of a rise in wages and then to judge whether or not these anticipated effects are acceptable from a general economic and social point of view. The most important of these possible effects are, perhaps, a rise in productivity, an increase in demand for consumers' goods, changes in employment, the effect on the balance of payments, and a reduction in profits. The following analysis of some of these effects is in general terms. Their actual importance depends, of course, on the size of the wage increases that the minimum wage programme is designed to bring about. A modest programme, aiming at the improvement of living standards of small groups of wage earners only, would in most respects cause little or no incidental effects. When the objectives of the minimum wage policy are more far-reaching the consequences analysed below will also be more important. Wage Regulation and Productivity. The effect of wage regulation on productivity is discussed first, not because this is likely to be the most important effect but because the problem of capacity to pay in this case may be rather simple. If an increase in wages led to a sufficiently large and rapid increase in productivity, it would, as it were, create its own capacity to pay. There are two main ways in which an increase in wages through minimum wage regulation may affect productivity. First, a rise in wage costs may serve as an incentive to the employer to organise production more efficiently ; secondly, an improvement in the workers' living standards may raise their personal efficiency as a result of better health, education and increased incentive to work. Consider first the possibility of increased wage costs serving as an incentive to employers to organise production more efficiently. That there is often great scope for raising productivity through better organisation is beyond doubt. It is often found that firms paying the highest wages have the highest productivity. I t does not, however, necessarily follow that a general rise in wages will lead to a general increase in PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 91 productivity. Firms that pay higher wages than the average are for the most part able to do so because they are more efficiently managed than their competitors and because the high wages they pay help them to attract and keep workers of superior efficiency. These advantages would not accrue, as a result of a general rise in wages brought about by minimum wage regulation, to firms which had previously lagged behind the leaders. Moreover, raising minimum wages would be an incentive primarily to secure a more efficient use of unskilled labour. But there is already a large surplus of unskilled labour, and it is a more efficient use of scarce factors such as capital, land and skilled labour that would be the most desirable form of raising productivity in Asian countries. For this there would be no direct incentive from higher minimum wages. There might be some incentive to substitute labour-saving equipment for unskilled labour. But, as has been noted earlier, such a substitution will in general be wasteful, even though as a result the average output per person employed in the industry or industries concerned will rise. In the first place, some workers may lose their employment ; secondly, less capital will be available to create additional employment opportunities. Consider now the second way in which higher wages and living standards may raise productivity. I t is generally agreed that the worse the conditions under which a worker is living, the lower his personal efficiency is likely to be. By inference, an improvement in his standard of living might be expected to lead to an increase in his efficiency. This does not mean, of course, that any improvement in a worker's living standard would result in, say, a proportional rise in his performances nor, if it did, that total output would increase correspondingly. In some cases, for example in the Indian engineering, textile and coal-mining industries, workers enjoying better diets have indeed been reported to be more productive than those whose nutritional standards were lower. 1 In other cases less convincing results have been reported and one author goes so far as to say that in India a rise in productivity caused by a rise in wages " is the very rare exception rather than the rule ". 2 D. E. Gadgil, in a more refined analysis of the ques1 2 Radhakamal MUKERJEE : The Indian Working Class, op. cit., p. 274. E. DA COSTA : Indian Industry Today and Tomorrow (Calcutta, 1947), p. 53. 7 92 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES tion 1, first draws attention to the argument that a rise in wages might very well lead to a rather rapid increase in productivity if applied by an individual employer : if he pays wage rates that are distinctly higher than those of his competitors it is implied that he will get the pick of the labour supply. " If the complement of workers of an individual employer is specially efficient, then his cost of production per unit of output may even be less than that of his competitors in spite of his paying higher rates of wages." The author is more cautious, however, with regard to the effect on productivity if wages are raised for whole industries. He recognises that a rather general rise in wages may lead to the elimination of the least efficient workers (thus causing unemployment among these workers) and thereby give rise to an increase in average productivity. But he also believes that " changes in the standard of living . . . take place slowly, and the effects that they may have on efficiency can become apparent only gradually ". Whether, to what extent and how rapidly an increase in the workers' productivity may come about as a result of an improvement in their living standards thus appears again to be a question that would need careful analysis in any case in which it is to be taken into account as a separate factor affecting the assessment of the economic feasibility of a minimum wage. It cannot be simply taken for granted that a rise in wages will automatically increase capacity to pay through a rise in the workers' efficiency. To the extent that productivity does increase, however, a number of the difficulties discussed below would not arise, or would arise in a less acute form. Increasing Demand for Consumers'1 Goods. Generally speaking, a programme for minimum wage regulation will result in increased demand for essential consumers' goods. Such an increase in demand may have a number of different effects, such as an increase in domestic output of these commodities, a rise in prices, and changes in the state of the balance of payments. Among these, an increase in domestic output would obviously be the most desirable effect ; it is, however, not the most probable one. For example, a rise in 1 D. E. GrADGiL : Regulation of Wages and Other Problems of Industrial Labour in India (Poona, Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics, 1943), pp. 32-33. PROBLEMS OP MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 93 workers' purchasing power would presumably lead to a rise in the demand for food. (In any case, minimum wage regulation would, in most countries, be designed to stimulate an increase in the consumption of food by the worst-paid workers.) The raising of food production, however, requires improvements in methods of agricultural production, land reform and so on ; it cannot be expected that a mere rise in demand, even if that meant a rise in prices, would automatically lead to higher production. This consideration may be borne in mind when it is suggested, as it sometimes is, that the low purchasing power of wage earners in Asian countries is itself a cause of low production and that an increase in wages, because it would raise effective demand, would itself create the additional goods that the higher wages would buy. Lack of effective demand may sometimes be an important cause of low production and employment ; in Asian countries, however, lack of resources (other than unskilled labour) with which to produce additional goods may be a more important cause. Perhaps an increase in demand for other commodities, such as clothing and housing, might result in some increase in domestic supply. But for these commodities, too, it is likely that a more or less substantial rise in prices will occur. A rise in prices has several aspects. With money incomes remaining constant for those who do not directly benefit either by minimum wage regulation or by higher prices, a rise in prices means that the real incomes of those groups will fall. For the low income groups (for example the self-employed in handicrafts industries) this would probably mean a proportional fall in consumption. For the higher income groups it is likely to entail a reduction in savings. To the authorities responsible for the economy as a whole it would mean that an improvement in the living standards of the wage earners concerned is obtained through a deterioration in the consumption standards of other low income groups (including wage earners not benefiting by the regulation) and, if the additional demand is directed mainly at food, through a shift of income in the higher income groups in favour of landlords. Finally, the rise in prices may serve to stimulate the import of consumers' goods and to reduce the volume of exports. This would lead to a weakening in the balance of payments unless the terms of trade improved sufficiently.1 ¡"See pp. 100 fi. below. 94 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES Some of these possible effects of a rise in prices may not be thought desirable. A reduction in the living standards of self-employed persons with low incomes and of wage earners who are not benefited by the minimum wage regulation would probably be considered undesirable. For an increase in the incomes of other groups, for example the landlords, there would seem to be little justification. An increase in imports of consumers' goods may also be undesirable if it means that imports of goods that are essential for economic development have to be correspondingly reduced. It would probably be possible to counteract some of these undesirable effects of price rises. The most direct and radical way to solve the problem would be by the imposition of price control. I t is very doubtful, however, whether this would be an effective solution, if only because the problem of inspection and enforcement required to make the minimum wage regulation effective would presumably be more than doubled. An undesirable increase in imports of consumers' goods could be avoided through import restrictions. I t may also be possible, though administratively difficult, to tax away undesirable increases in the incomes of landlords and other groups benefiting by the higher prices. The problem of maintaining the standards of living of the self-employed and other low income groups, however, looks far more difficult to solve. In the absence of adequate data concerning the distribution of income in Asian countries, it is difficult to say exactly how serious this problem is. But it seems safe to say that as soon as the level of income of wage earners, which it is the purpose of minimum wage regulation to ensure, comes close to that of other large groups it will become difficult to make further progress in minimum wage regulation without a much more general rise in living standards. Wage Regulation and Employment. If it is the purpose of a minimum wage regulation to fix the minimum wage at about the average level already prevailing in the industry concerned, no serious problems of unemployment are likely to arise. The undertakings where wages are substantially below the average prevailing in the industry as a whole may be working at less than the average level of efficiency, or the employers may, for one reason or another, have succeeded in making abnormally high profits by paying PROBLEMS OF MINIMTJH WAGE POLICY 95 their workers substandard wages. In the latter case the imposition of a higher wage through a minimum wage regulation is not likely to result in any appreciable unemployment. When an abnormally low level of productivity is at the root of exceptionally low wages, the effect of the introduction of the minimum wage might be that a number of firms would have to curtail production and employment. In principle, this would mean that the other more efficient firms could expand their production and employment. Thus, the unemployment arising out of the contraction of production in the weaker firms would, after some lapse of time, be matched by an increase in employment elsewhere. This unemployment, which would not be likely to assume large proportions, would mainly be of the so-called " frictional " type. It might even be that, after production had been concentrated in a smaller number of more efficient firms, costs and prices of the product could be reduced and production and employment in these firms further expanded. This is not certain to happen, however. Employment in the industry as a whole may become somewhat smaller than before, even though the volume of production is maintained or slightly increased, for the very reason that productivity for the industry as a whole has been raised. ÎTor is it certain, of course, that if employment in some firms expands the new jobs will be taken by those workers who lost their jobs elsewhere in the same industry. Moreover, it cannot too easily be assumed that a rise in wages, by driving the least efficient firms out of the market, will automatically result in larger output at lower costs in the more efficient firms. Evidently, if some firms are able to support higher wage-costs, because of greater efficiency, while others are not, the former must presumably have been capable of undercutting their weaker competitors and driving them out of the market before the minimum wage regulation came into existence. Thus the question arises why they did not do so. If the answer is that they could not have expanded their output anyway, for example because it would have been impossible for them to acquire the necessary equipment, it may well be doubted whether the elimination of the less efficient firms through the wage regulation would really be of any advantage. In spite of this limitation, however, it would seem that the rather modest type of minimum wage regulation, which 96 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES would only result in the fixing of the minimum wage at the average wage level prevailing in a particular industry, will generally not have unacceptable repercussions on the employment situation. The case where a uniform minimum wage is introduced for a group of industries is, in some respects, similar to the previous one. Again it is possible that in certain industries the employers are in a stronger bargaining position than in others, the wage level is below the average for the group as a whole, and the employers are making more than average profits. It is difficult to say whether, and if so to what extent, this is the actual position in Asian countries, because no adequate data are available. I t is also possible that, although profits are not abnormally high, the wage level in a particular industry is unduly low because some employers, in an attempt to improve their competitive strength, deliberately keep wages low and thereby put pressure on all employers in that industry to pay wages below the general average. In such a case it may be possible for the industry as a whole to raise its selling prices without any substantial reduction in sales, output and employment. Indeed, it may be that several industries are in a position to raise their prices so as to increase their capacity to pay wages. But how far this may be true is again a question that would have to bê considered in the light of the circumstances of each particular case. Although it may be that no unemployment would arise as a consequence of such price and wage increases, some or all of the undesirable effects of higher prices mentioned in the previous section might make themselves felt. It is also possible, however, that a number of less efficient firms will have to curtail production and employment, or even to close down altogether. When the minimum wage is fixed at the average level, not of one particular industry but of a group of industries taken together, this problem may assume serious proportions. First, if the minimum wage is fixed at a level appreciably above the average paid in one or more of the industries concerned, the number of dismissed workers will be larger than if a separate minimum wage is fixed for each industry at the average level hitherto paid in that industry. It is even possible that whole industries will disappear. Secondly, the problem of expanding production and employment in industries with a higher capacity to pay will presura- PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM "WAGE POLICY 97 ably be far more difficult than that of shifting workers from an inefficient firm to a more productive firm within the same industry. In the latter case the global pattern of production and employment does not show material changes. In the former case, however, the economic structure of the country is affected and it is questionable whether sufficient capital will be available for the expansion of certain industries to such an extent that the loss of production and income in the contracting industries would be compensated. Eegarding this problem of fundamental differences in productivity and in the capacity to pay of different industries, some authorities, including the Indian Committee on Fair Wages, have taken the view that " an industry which is incapable of paying the minimum wage has no right to exist ".x It would seem that this approach needs some qualification at least in the short run. Fundamentally, the existence of substantial and more or less chronic differences in capacity to pay reflects a misallocation of productive factors. It means that labour is partly employed in rather highly productive occupations and partly in substantially less productive occupations, and that total output could, theoretically, be raised if at least some labour were shifted from the latter to the former. The more perfectly an economy is functioning, the nearer the actual pattern of production and allocation of productive factors will come to the best possible economic structure of the country. It might therefore be expected that differences in the capacity of industries to pay wages would be smaller in economically advanced countries than in underdeveloped countries. 2 The fact that 1 Report of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., p. 16. But until the 1930s some more advanced countries also found it necessary to take account of substantial differences in capacity to pay of agriculture and industry. For example, in Australia agricultural workers were originally not covered by the Commonwealth Conciliation and Arbitration Act, though after some time awards were made for certain groups of agricultural workers. In 1932 two Australian experts found that agricultural wages had been lower than industrial wages " largely because of the increased productivity per industrial worker following the adoption of machinery in the factories ". The authors also submitted that the Arbitration Court would " have to tread very warily if approached to make an award " in certain branches of agriculture. " Possibly it would be well advised to fix a very low basic wage which agriculture could support, leaving a margin within which the employer and employee could bargain." (D. B. COPLAND and 0. de E. FOENANDER : " Agricultural Wages in Australia ", in International Labour Beview, Vol. XXV, No. 6, June 1932, pp. 784 and 786.) In New 2 (¡oolnote continued overleaf) 98 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES an exceptionally low capacity to pay wages points to a misallocation of resources is a basic justification for the view already mentioned that industries which cannot support the minimum wage rate have no right to exist. This means, for example, that if a country, in the course of its economic development, is establishing new industries or expanding existing ones, it should preferably select those which promise to be productive and which, for that reason, can also be expected to be able to pay a reasonable wage. The position is different, however, if a country already has an economic structure in which less and more productive industries, like hand-weaving and weaving mills, co-exist. Here economic policy should certainly aim at a gradual reorientation of the pattern of production and employment designed to ensure that labour and capital will eventually be employed in such proportions and by such industries as will permit more or less uniform rates of remuneration in all industries to be paid as wages for work requiring comparable skill and effort (and as interest on capital), not only because such uniform remuneration is, on grounds of " fairness ", an aim in itself but also because a more or less equal remuneration of productive factors in all industries is the counterpart of an efficient allocation of resources. On the other hand, taking the short view there are special considerations that must be borne in mind in deciding whether any industry should be allowed to be driven out of existence by the height of minimum wages. The disappearance of an industry, as long as it produces anything at all, is in itself an economic and social loss. If the workers and capital employed in such an industry were easily transferable to other more productive occupations and ones that would not be available unless the old industry vanished, the loss would be more than offset. If the process of transferring these resources took a Zealand the Court of Arbitration refused for some 30 years to make awards fixing the wages of farm workers (except in certain special cases). Its reasons included the consideration that it was difficult to fix a flat minimum rate when so many different types of workers were involved and, on one occasion, the likelihood, according to the evidence submitted, that some three or four thousand workers in one district alone would not bo able to earn the wage paid to the ordinary competent farm-hand and would have to be given permits to work for lower rates. Widespread regulation of wages in agriculture was undertaken in New Zealand only when a system of guaranteed prices for farm products was introduced. (E. J. RICHES : " Agricultural Planning and Farm Wages in New Zealand ", ibid., Vol. XXXV, No. 3, Mar. 1937, pp. 293-328.) PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 99 very long time, during which they lay largely idle, it would be more doubtful whether there would still be a net gain. But if the new employment and production opportunities would have arisen in any case, the disappearance of the old industry would be a definite loss. It has already been suggested above that programmes of economic development may be expected to lead eventually to greater equalisation of the capacity to pay wages in various industries, because economic development may be expected to result in a more efficient allocation of resources. It seems advisable, therefore, to let minimum wage policy lead to a gradual levelling-up, as economic development proceeds, of minimum wage rates in industries that at present show substantial differences in their capacity to pay. Minimum wage regulation may affect employment not only through its repercussions on the volume of output in the industries concerned but also because a rise in wage-costs may lead to the adoption of labour-saving techniques, in particular through the introduction of labour-saving machinery. Whether and to what extent this will happen will again depend on the circumstances of the particular case. As a rule the introduction of new equipment in a certain industry will depend on technical possibilities and on the awareness of the employers of such possibilities (such as the use of electric motors in smallscale industry), on the availability of the appropriate equip-' ment, on the financial resources of the employers, on the existence of credit facilities, and so on. For the economy as a whole the question is also rather complicated. With a given amount of domestic saving and a given amount of capital available from abroad, the introduction of machinery in one industry must, theoretically, entail a decrease or a slower increase in the amount of capital employed in other industries, particularly in those where wages are already high and do not increase as a result of the minimum wage regulation. It might therefore be argued that a substitution of capital for labour in some industries would be accompanied by a substitution of labour for capital in others. But this would not mean that the total number of jobs would be unaffected. Generally speaking the substitution of capital for labour does not seem to be economically justified so long as large reserves of unemployed and underemployed workers exist. In these circumstances what is needed is the utihsation of the 100 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES available capital in such a way as to increase employment ; and any substitution of capital for labour is, in principle, wasteful. Most of what has been said so far regarding the possible effects of wage regulation on employment concerns the repercussions of a wage increase on costs of production. Another question to be considered is whether the increase in the income of wage earners as a group resulting from minimum wage regulation would affect employment. At first sight this increase in demand might be expected to stimulate production and employment : this will not, however, necessarily be the case. It has already been observed that, if the additional demand from wage earners were directed to essential consumers' goods the production of which can be increased little or not at all, the result would be a rise in the price of these commodities without any appreciable increase in employment in the industries producing them. The key to this problem would therefore be to expand output in certain industries. Should this not prove possible, there would be a real danger that the shift in demand would lead to a fall in employment, since it would not be matched by a corresponding shift in the pattern of production and employment. Moreover, any increase in the real income of wage earners, or of particular groups of wage earners, which is not accompanied by an increase in national production must be at the expense of the real incomes of other sections of the community, who will have to cut down either their consumption or their saving or both. If they curtail their consumption, this will tend to offset the effects on production and employment of the increased demand coming from the wage earners who have benefited from minimum wage regulation ; if they curtail their savings the rate of capital formation, and with it the rate of expansion of employment opportunities in the future, may suffer. Wage Regulation and the Balance of Payments. The possible effects of minimum wage regulation on the balance of payments need to be carefully considered. First, in so far as an increase in wages leads to increased demand for essential consumers' goods, such as food and clothing, there may be an increase in imports and a fall in exports of such commodities. This might be termed the " income " effect of PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 101 wage regulation. Secondly, there will also be a " price " effect in response to any rise in domestic costs of production as a result of minimum wage regulation. The rise in costs of production may have several effects : it may encourage a greater inflow of imports in substitution for domestically produced goods that have risen in price ; it may lead to a rise in prices obtained for exports ; and it may lead to a reduction in the volume of goods that can be sold for export. I t is likely, therefore, that the terms of trade will tend to improve, since export prices will tend to rise to some extent in relation to import prices. But it is impossible to say in general what will be the final effect on the balance of payments. The relative rise in export prices will strengthen it ; the fall in volume of exports and the rise in the volume of imports will weaken it. In view of the importance of exports of primary products in the economies of some Asian countries, it is useful to consider the rather special position of some of these products in world markets, and ask whether increased costs of production might be offset by higher export prices. The main export products of underdeveloped countries, including those in Asia, have always been staple commodities, such as rubber, cotton, sugar, tea and tin, for which a world market exists. Competition in the markets for such homogeneous or nearly homogeneous commodities is almost perfect and no individual producer can raise his price out of line with the prices of his competitors without virtually losing his entire share in the market. As a rule the price is given, the individual producer has no effective control over it, and if his costs of production are rising while the market price for the product remains constant or falls he will sooner or later have to stop production. In such circumstances plantations in Asian countries have sometimes been abandoned. But experience shows that total demand for most raw materials depends only to a very small extent on the market price. The main factor affecting the level and fluctuations of demand for such commodities appears to be the volume of production in industrialised countries, itself not dependent to any large extent on the costs of raw materials. 1 Thus it is possible that, if all producers of a given raw material were working at higher costs, the price of this material would 1 As distinct from sharp and frequent fluctuations in these costs, which are a difíerent matter altogether. 102 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES permanently remain at a higher level. To what extent the volume of demand for the material in question would be affected would depend mainly on the availability and price of substitutes. I t is at least conceivable that demand would be little affected. In such cases the question might be raised whether the purposes of minimum wage regulation in the industry producing the raw material in question might not be facilitated by simultaneous action in the various countries concerned. If, for example, it were found that within certain limits a rise in the price of tin had little effect on the volume of demand and if all countries producing tin were to raise wages in the industry simultaneously and in the same proportion, the burden of the higher labour costs might be almost fully shifted to the more prosperous, industrialised countries. Indeed, the Secretariat of the Economic Commission for Latin America has advanced the interesting thesis that one of the main reasons why underdeveloped countries did not share to a greater extent in the fruits of the vast world-wide increase in productivity during the last century or so was precisely because the level of wages remained persistently low in these countries while it continually rose in the industrialised countries. In the latter, where labour was better organised and succeeded in obtaining ever higher and higher wages, the higher costs of production could be borne by keeping prices constant in spite of increasing productivity or by raising prices. In the underdeveloped countries, on the other hand, wages rose very slowly, if at all, and prices remained below the level they could have reached if wage costs had been rising faster. 1 A thorough discussion of this thesis would be beyond the scope of this report. The first reaction of importers in industrialised countries to rising costs and prices of the exports of some underdeveloped countries might be to cut their purchases, to switch their trade to other countries and to seek substitutes. Production, employment and exports might fall to rather low levels in the countries which had raised their wages costs. After an interval, which might be fairly short especially if other underdeveloped countries adopted similar wage policies, production, employment and exports would tend to be restored at better prices. But even a temporary drop in export proceeds 1 See United Nations : The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems (New York, 1950), and Economic Survey of Latin America, 1949 (New York, 1951), Part I, passim. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 103 might prove insupportable for countries which, like most Asian countries, are continually in difficulties with their balance of payments. It would, nevertheless, seem that the possibility of raising living standards in these countries along the lines indicated above deserves to be considered. The total value of export proceeds may rise or fall as a result of an increase in wages. Imports, on the other hand, will almost certainly tend to increase. If there is an offsetting increase in the value of export proceeds, no difficulty arises. It is possible, however, that some countries will find themselves in a position where they will have to take some action with regard to restoring international balance if they are to go ahead with minimum wage regulation. One possibility is to reduce imports of capital equipment in order to make way for imports of consumer goods, thus slackening the rate of economic development in order to promote the immediate welfare of lower-income groups. Another- possibility is to introduce or extend measures designed to expand exports or reduce imports, or both—for instance, export subsidies, quantitative restrictions on imports, import duties or exchange devaluation. Which of these methods is chosen in order to offset the effects of minimum wage regulation on the balance of payments will depend on the views of the governments concerned on sections of expenditure that should be reduced in order to make way for increased consumption by wage earners. One aspect of the relation between minimum wage regulation and the balance of payments remains to be considered. This concerns the short-term problem arising from the fact that fluctuating industrial activity in countries that are the main purchasers of raw materials exported by underdeveloped countries leads to sharp fluctuations in the prices of these commodities. Temporary slumps in demand may make it very difficult for the industries producing such materials to continue operations if costs are rigid. Thus the question arises whether minimum wage regulations should not be made sufficiently flexible to meet this difficulty, which must be expected to occur from time to time, especially so long as no effective measures have been taken to stabilise the markets for raw materials. 1 1 For example, in 1949 when rubber prices were very low, minimum wage regulation was temporarily suspended in the Ceylon rubber-growing industry. 104 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES In view of the importance of these industries in the region, probably none of the Asian countries could afford to endanger the existence of industries producing raw materials for the sake of maintaining their minimum wage regulations. On the other hand, the industries themselves might be required to make provision for some stabilisation of wages (and employment). If profits in these industries are low or disappear in times of depression, they often rise to very high levels in years of prosperity. It should be possible, therefore, to set aside some reserves in prosperous years for use in times of adversity. Measures of this kind are commonly taken to ensure stability of dividends and it would seem reasonable enough to suggest that some provision be made also for stabilising the income of the industry's workers. If this could be done the ordinary principles of minimum wage regulation could be applied, subject perhaps to some measure of flexibility, to industries that are more than usually liable to cyclical fluctuations. Wage Regulation and Profits. A rise in wages through minimum wage regulation does not necessarily entail a fall in profits. The employer may raise his selling prices or increase the efficiency of production and thus maintain, perhaps even increase, his profits. Yet it must be expected that, in at least some industries, profits that were abnormally high before the minimum wage regulation was introduced will be reduced. It is also quite possible that wage regulation will cause aggregate profits to fall. The current and prospective level of profits has often played an important part in the assessment of a firm's or industry's capacity to pay wages. Eeference has already been made above to the concepts of " a fair return on capital and remuneration to management ". Other criteria sometimes suggested are that a firm or industry should be enabled to make " a fair allocation to reserves and depreciation so as to keep the industry in a healthy condition " or, at least, " to maintain production with efficiency ". 1 It would seem that from the point of view of the economic feasibility of a wage increase, the two main considerations in judging the appropriateness of the level of profits are related to savings and to the function of profits as an incentive to private enterprise. 1 Report of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., p. 15. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 105 Profits and the supply of savings. If higher wages are paid out of profits, savings will probably fall. The additional wage income must be expected to be fully consumed ; indeed, it is generally the very objective of minimum wage regulation to raise the wage earners' consumption by the full amount of the wage increase. The reduction in profits, on the other hand, is more likely to result in lower savings by the higher-income groups than in a compensating reduction in consumption. I t is generally agreed that the first need in underdeveloped countries is for increasing savings. This may not, however, be sufficient ground for rejecting minimum wage regulations, which would result in the shift from savings to consumption mentioned above. In the first place, the incomes of large groups of the population are so low that the savings made by the rich are partly consumed by the poor. This happens, for example, when the latter sell their land or other property, or when they assume heavy debts, sometimes involving the loss of part of their personal freedom, for the bare maintenance of life. Such transactions, although involving saving and investment from the private point of view, are nothing but an increase in the concentration of wealth from the national point of view. Socially, they do not represent any net saving or investment at all. There is also the point that available savings might, to some extent, be invested in more productive ways. Various observers agree that in some underdeveloped countries an appreciable part of savings is wasted in, for example, investments in over-expensive public works or luxurious buildings or is transferred abroad, while there is a general reluctance on the part of the owners of capital to engage in more productive long-term investments involving risks of a nature different from those they are accustomed to. 1 Where misallocation of capital is widespread, the first need may be to divert savings into more productive channels ; if this can be accomplished, even some reduction in total savings may be found compatible with an acceleration of economic progress. It should be added that even when the need for saving and investment is explicitly recognised as a factor to be taken 1 See, for example, United Nations : Measures for the Economic Development of Underdeveloped Countries (New York, 1951), pp. 54 ff., and Paul A. BARAN : " Economic Progress : General Considerations—Discussion ", in American Economic Beview, Vol. XLI, No. 2, May 1951, pp. 356 ff. 106 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES into account when wages are fixed, this does not mean that every firm or industry must be able to finance its investment out of its own means. Funds for investment may also be borrowed. Provided, therefore, that the aggregate amount of savings does not fall short of the amount required for necessary investment, the wage fixed for a particular firm or industry may be put at a level at which profits in that particular firm or industry will not meet the needs for investment in it. This question of the relation between wage increases and savings is considered further in the next chapter. Profits as an incentive. It is generally recognised that private enterprise has an important part to play in the industrial development of Asia. 1 Profits being an essential incentive for private enterprise, the question may be raised whether there is a " critical level " below which " normal " profits cannot be permitted to fall if this incentive is to be preserved. To attempt a full analysis of this question would be beyond the scope of the present report. Two points may, however, be mentioned. First, it would appear that, generally speaking, because of the scarcity of capital and of industrial enterprise and the existence of special risks such as social and political instability and the absence of a developed economic system to support industrial ventures, rather high returns are at present required to attract capital into long-term investment in Asian countries. The provision of credit facilities and increased supplies of capital, the improvement of communications and the establishment of auxiliary industries on a wide scale are essential features of economic development. If that development is successful and is accompanied by greater social and political stability, it may be expected that the rate of profit required to attract industrial enterprise will progressively fall and that the capacity to pay wages will accordingly rise. Secondly, many of the new types of enterprise required to maintain economic development involve exceptionally large and long-term risks and very large investments of capital. They are likely by their nature to prove unattractive 1 See, for example, the resolution adopted by the preparatory Asian Regional Conference (1947) concerning the economic policies necessary for the attainment in Asia of the social objectives of the I.L.O., in Official Bulletin, Vol. X X X , No. 3, 15 Nov. 1947, p . 168 ; and Measures for the Economie Development of Underdeveloped Countries, op. cit., pp. 20-26. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 107 to private enterprise and must be undertaken by governments, which will not be subject to the special considerations regarding the necessary rate of profit mentioned above and will therefore be able to disburse larger wage-payments. MACHINERY FOR MINIMUM WAGE EEGITLATION The Fixing of Minimum Wages In the Philippines the minimum wage has been fixed by law. In most countries, however, the law provides for minimum wage fixing machinery and stipulates some general principles of wage fixing, leaving to boards or tribunals the actual fixing of minimum wage rates. 1 As was noted in Chapter I I I , several Asian countries have adopted the principle of joint and equal participation of employers and workers in the operation of minimum wage regulation. This principle is in conformity with the Minimum Wage-Fixing Machinery Convention, 1928, and with resolutions adopted by the Asian Eegional Conferences. It is also of particular importance in view of the need to develop a wider system of collective bargaining for which minimum wage regulation could serve as a useful preparatory device by encouraging the development of effective organisations. An important question is whether the fixing of minimum wages should be entrusted to trade boards or to more general boards. Mr. Gadgil 2 , writing of India in 1939-40, preferred trade boards on the ground that " there exists in this country a very large element of diversity in every aspect of the industrial situation, with marked differences in conditions from province to province and from industry to industry ". This factor, he considered, was more important than the advantages claimed for a general board, namely " that it enables the application of a uniform set of principles to wage determination in all industries and enables the attainment of a comparatively uniform wage level in the entire economic system ". 1 The Philippines Minimum Wage Law also provides for further minimum wage fixing by industrial wage boards. As in certain other countries, the minimum rates fixed by the law are in effect a minimum minimorum. 2 Regulation of Wages and Other Problems of Industrial Labour in India, op. cit., p. 52. 8 108 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES The United Provinces Labour Enquiry Committee, 1946-48 1, attaching great importance to the principle of a uniform minimum standard of living, proposed a provincial general wage board which might appoint ad hoc industrial divisions and would therefore show features of both types of wage fixing machinery. As has already been noted, the Indian Planning Commission recommended in 1948 that a set of principles to be followed in questions of wage policy should be established by tripartite machinery. Indeed the Commission regarded the problem of wage regulation as part of the general question of economic development. In the present report the relationship between wage policy and problems of general economic policy has also been repeatedly stressed and if this relationship is accepted it would seem necessary to provide for the formulation by some central agency of certain general principles of wage regulation. What would appear to be needed is a type of minimum wage machinery that would include bodies competent to take account both of this need and of the diversity of conditions in different industries and regions. Decisions in the field of minimum wage policy as a whole might be taken by a central body, which would be in a position to relate this part of economic and social policy to other general problems. The principles emerging from the findings of this body might be applied to particular industries, groups of industries or regions by special trade or regional boards responsible for fixing minimum rates of wages in the light of the special circumstances prevailing in the industries or regions concerned. These special boards might be given varying degrees of autonomy. For example, they might be empowered to fix minimum wage rates in the light of such general directives as the central body saw fit to issue, or they might merely be asked to propose minimum rates, the final decisions being left to the central body. They might also be given some guidance on what allowance they should make for the possible repercussions of wage regulation on employment and the chances of re-employment of redundant workers. An infinite variety of possible distributions of competence between general and more specialised bodies would be possible and the selection of. the most appropriate line of demarcation would obviously depend 1 First Eeport, op. cit.. Vol. I, Part I, pp. 306 tf. PROBLEMS OF MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 109 on the particular circumstances in each country : the existence or not of a well-defined programme of economic development, the precise objectives of minimum wage policy, the scope of the bodies concerned, and so on. It might be found desirable, during the initial phases of the minimum wage programme, to reserve comparatively large powers to the central body and to assign to the representatives of the government on that body a major degree of responsibility and power. During these initial phases the programme of minimum wage regulation would be largely experimental, particularly if it covered such industries as agriculture, smallscale manufacturing and village industries, and the government might wish to keep this experiment under rather close control. Moreover, it might prove difficult in the beginning to find a sufficiently large number of competent labour and other members to sit on trade boards. Finally, it is usually easier to delegate further authority after a lapse of time than to withdraw delegated powers which experience indicates ought to have been reserved to a central body. Machinery for Inspection and Enforcement Difficulties of inspection and enforcement are perhaps the greatest impediment to an extension of effective minimum wage regulation in most underdeveloped countries. Considering the tremendous size of some of these countries, the extremely large number of small enterprises in which only one or a few wage earners are employed, the complicated systems of payment in use in large areas where a money economy is only just beginning to develop, and the limited number of qualified persons available for inspection and enforcement, the difficulties may well seem almost insuperable. Problems of the enforcement of labour measures have been discussed comprehensively in an earlier report of the International Labour Office 1 , to which readers may be referred. In what follows a few brief remarks only will be added to this earlier analysis. The most effective approach to the problem of enforcing minimum wage regulations in Asian countries may well be through the education of the general public. The stronger the conviction in a society that the Avorker deserves a reason1 Labour Policy in General Including the Enforcement of Labour Measures, op. cit., Chapter VII. 110 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES able wage, the less a programme of minimum wage regulation will depend on machinery for inspection and control. If farreaching social measures are taken against the will of a large part of the population or if, as is more likely, people are ignorant or feel indifferent about these measures, the amount of inspection work required to make them effective will almost certainly be beyond the capacity of the administrations of Asian countries. Moreover, if the work of the inspector is to be really effective, he should be looked upon not as a special sort of policeman but rather as an instructor and advisor in matters within his competence. 1 This requires not only skill, tact and understanding on the part of the inspector but also the recognition by the employers, the workers, and the general public of the significance of his duties. If he is considered as an intruder, or if social barriers hamper normal human contact between him and the employers or workers, the inspector is likely to find his work extremely difficult and may become totally ineffective. These difficulties will be enhanced if his official rank is too low to give him the necessary authority and social standing, if his salary is so low as to expose him to the temptation to accept bribes, or if he is not consistently supported by his superiors. Indifference or hostility towards social legislation and the problems involved in recruiting and training an adequate number of competent inspectors cannot be fully overcome in a few months or, for that matter, years. In the initial phases of a comprehensive programme of minimum wage regulation it may therefore be found essential to take measures designed to reduce the amount of necessary inspection work to the barest minimum. One principle that suggests itself in this connection is that such minimum wage regulations as are promulgated should be made as simple as possible. The smaller the number of permissible exceptions to a few general rules, and the simpler the procedures for reporting and dealing with infringements, the larger will be the number of cases that a given staff of inspectors can handle. Of course, such simple regulations may prove imperfect, or even inappropriate or unfair in particular cases. To what extent such simplification should be sought is again a question that can be answered only in the light of the circumstances of each particular case. 1 See Labour Policy in General Including Measures, op. cit., pp. 285 ff. the Enforcement of Labour PROBLEMS OP MINIMUM WAGE POLICY 111 Another question which might be considered in this connection concerns the extent to which the work of inspection might be entrusted, at least during the initial phases of the programme, to persons who, though not belonging to the inspection staff proper, have to maintain contact in some official capacity with industries in which minimum wage regulation is applied and whose normal duties are such that they could, without much additional effort, check on the implementation of wage regulations. 1 While this procedure would not be ideal, it might be worth adopting until such time as the regular inspection staff can be built up to an adequate strength. Eecourse might also be had to the assistance of the trade unions in policing the application of wage decisions —a method that has been followed with success in certain industrially developed countries. Pinally, an adequate system of sanctions in cases of deliberate infringement of minimum wage regulations may, to some extent, reduce the amount of inspection required. If such sanctions are mild—for example, if only moderate fines can be imposed—non-observance of the regulations involves only a minor risk : the more severe the sanctions the less will employers be disposed to run the risk of detection, even when inspection is infrequent. 1 Groups of officials who might he found appropriate for this purpose would perhaps include persons in charge of the assessment of tax liabilities and officials who are engaged in programmes for the development of certain industries, such as cottage industries. CHAPTER V WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Two main relationships between wage policy and economic development were noted in Chapter I I above. One of the principal aims of wage policy in Asian countries is to ensure that the incomes of the workers will rise in step with the increasing output of wealth as economic development proceeds. Then, there is the problem of whether wage policy can help to speed up economic development and in what way. These two questions, together with the special problem of the adjustment of wages to changes in the cost of living, are briefly discussed below. T H E ADJUSTMENT OF THE LEVEL OF WAGES TO THE PROGRESS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT As already mentioned the Asian Advisory Committee agreed in December 1950 that the immediate need in Asia was for a minimum wage structure which would ensure a reasonable living standard, from which should emerge, as the economy developed, proper living standards, including a fair share for labour through rising productivity. Similarly, as regards agriculture the Asian Eegional Conference of 1950 had considered that " wage fixing machinery should be established in order . . . to ensure that increases in productivity will be reflected in the wage earnings ". 1 Adjustment of wages to progress in economic development may take different forms. The level of wage rates may rise in step with increases in national output while the volume of employment remains more or less constant ; or the total sum of wages paid may increase because the volume of employment expands even though the level of wage rates remains more or 1 Industry and Labour, Vol. I l l , No. 7, 1 Apr. 1950, p . 251. AVAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 113 less constant. Various combinations of these two extreme cases are, of course, also possible ; if a planned attempt is to be made to influence the wage level, a choice has to be made among these various possibilities. One important consideration affecting this choice would normally be its effect on general economic development. I n Asian countries economic development is essentially a matter of finding ways and means of increasing productive employment, and it is generally believed that at present an increase in employment opportunities is limited by lack of capital. This is probably correct, but in an analysis of employment and capital shortage in Asian countries the role of the wage level and changes therein should not be overlooked : the extent of the shortage of capital itself may be determined in part by the wage level. UNEMPLOYMENT, CAPITAL SHORTAGE AND THE WAGE LEVEL The statement often made that a shortage of capital is one of the main causes of unemployment in underdeveloped countries needs to be interpreted with some care. What this statement usually means is that, production and production methods being what they are, there is not enough capital to provide employment for all those seeking work at the prevailing level of wages (including social charges and other elements of labour cost). Broadly speaking, the volume of capital required for providing employment to a country's working population depends on the types of commodities produced and on the technical processes by which they are produced. In many cases the nature of the goods to be produced is such as to leave little scope for variation in the amount of capital used per unit of value added or per worker employed. Thus capital requirements are relatively low, for example, in the production of soap and candles and of ready-made clothing ; they are higher for rubber goods and tyres, and very high in steel works and rolling mills, synthetic textiles and the generation of electricity. In many cases, however, the ratio of capital technically required to value added or labour employed is not rigidly fixed but can be varied within fairly wide limits : road building, dam construction and textiles production are cases 114 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES in point ; more generally it may be said that in small-scale units of production the ratio of capital (and energy) per unit of labour and output is often smaller than in large-scale manufacturing. 1 In countries with relatively abundant labour and meagre capital resources it would seem clearly desirable to concentrate on the production of commodities that have a high labour content and, when there are possibilities of producing the same or similar goods through more labour-intensive or less labourintensive processes, to concentrate on the former. Such a policy will enable the amount of capital available to provide employment for a larger proportion of the labour force than could find employment if production were concentrated on goods with a high capital content and if capital-intensive production methods were applied. Normally it might be expected that the market mechanism would more or less automatically take care of the process of selecting the commodities and production processes that would ensure the highest possible degree of employment of the labour force. If labour is abundant and capital is in short supply labour might be expected to be so cheap and capital so expensive that entrepreneurs would find it profitable to produce commodities with a high labour content and, in doing so, to apply labour-intensive production processes. However, in actual practice this often does not happen. On the contrary, it has frequently been noticed that producers using a high proportion of labour (such as small-scale producers) find it extremely difficult to compete with the larger mills, which apply more capital-intensive production methods, or that countries with an abundant supply of labour import commodities with a high labour content and produce for themselves goods with a high capital content. To some extent such economic anomalies are the result of deliberate government policies designed to provide the country with a minimum of heavy industry. But in addition it is likely that, in Asian countries, the market mechanism does not always operate to bring about the selection of the goods and production processes that, from a general economic point of view, would seem to 1 See, for example, Joseph STEINDL : Small and Big Business : Economic Problems of the Size of Firms (Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1945), pp. 16 and 22 ff. WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 115 conform to the normal pattern of production for countries with large unemployed labour resources. One reason is probably that the prevailing level of industrial wages does not fully reflect the abundance of labour in relation to the volume of capital available but is determined to a much greater extent by the level of income in agriculture. As was noted in Chapter I, the occupational structure of the working population in most Asian countries is such that (a) the great majority of workers are engaged in agriculture, and (b) the great majority of these workers are self-employed. Selfemployed agricultural workers being the major source of wageearning industrial labour, there is bound to be a close relationship between the average incomes of farmers and the level of wages in non-agricultural employment. Workers will not normally move from the country to take up employment in the town for any prolonged period if the wage is worth less than the income they would earn in their villages as small independent or semi-independent farmers or simply as members of a farming family (although some may be forced to take up short-term employment for a very low wage if they are in urgent need of money). In order to attract people to settle as industrial workers in an urban environment, wages may in practice have to be somewhat higher than average incomes in agriculture so as to offset the higher cost of living and the absence of traditional forms of social security often provided by the rural communities and to overcome workers' resistance to the more disciplined methods of work in industrial employment. 1 Generally a wage earner is hired only if his employment yields an addition to the value of the firm's product that is at least equal to the amount of his wage. This principle does not apply in family farming. When there are no alternative employment opportunities members of the family will stay on the farm and share in the family's income even when the same output could have been produced without their services, which, when underemployment is as serious as it is in most Asian countries, is the normal case. In such circumstances it is possible that workers can remain " employed " in agriculture while it would not pay an industrial employer to hire them at 1 These and similar factors may also explain the rather substantial differences between wages in agriculture and industry noted in Chapter I. 116 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES a wage equal to—let alone higher than—the income which they receive in family farming. This may be so even though the value of their services in manufacturing would be greater than the value of the decrease, if any, in agricultural output that would result if they were transferred from agriculture to manufacturing. Wherever the latter is the case it would clearly have been advantageous to the economy if the workers were indeed transferred from agriculture to manufacturing, but this will not happen as long as the money value of their work in manufacturing is lower than the money wage as determined by average incomes in agriculture and by the other factors mentioned above. However low this wage may be, it is often higher than might be expected in view of the abundance of labour—particularly unskilled labour. One result is that in Asian countries it is difficult, because of high labour costs, to establish competitive manufacturing industries even though there is an abundant supply of labour. A second result is that in such industries as do exist producers find it profitable to invest in labour-saving equipment and to produce capital-intensive goods, even though there is widespread unemployment. In other words more capital tends to be invested per worker than would have been the case if wages had reflected more accurately the very low scarcity value of labour. The total employment-creating capacity of the capital available is therefore relatively small and the capital shortage more acute. If economic development gets under way and more capital becomes available, more labour could be employed at the prevailing wage rate and labour would become somewhat less abundant. However, if wage rates go up at the same rate as capital formation, employers will find it profitable to introduce more labour-saving equipment and to concentrate further on the production of goods with a high capital content. Although the total stock of capital is increasing, employment will rise less quickly ; in extreme cases it may not rise at all and the shortage of capital may remain as acute as it was before. As regards the relationship between wage policy and economic development, this appears to mean that a choice has to be made between a more rapid rise in the level of wages on the one hand and a more rapid increase in the volume of employment on the other. As a very broad generalisation it WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 117 might be said that the more rapidly the wage rates paid to those already employed are rising, the smaller are the opportunities for providing employment for additional workers. 1 WAGES, ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND INFLATION If wage policy is not to have inflationary effects, it will be important to bear in mind that, in the course of economic development, employment is likely to increase. Workers who were either wholly or partly unemployed will find jobs, and consequently their incomes will increase. This means that even at stable wage rates the total wage bill of the developing country and the demand for wage-goods will increase. If the newly employed workers are producing consumption goods this additional demand can probably be satisfied without much difficulty ; it will be clear, however, that if the supply of wage-goods is increased by a given percentage this will not, in itself, make possible a proportional increase in average earnings, since the larger volume of goods will have to be distributed among a larger number of workers. In practice, the situation will probably be more complicated. Even if the emphasis in development planning is on a rapid increase in the supply of essential consumers' goods, some preliminary investment will usually be required. Such investment will give rise to additional employment and income, but there will be no immediate increase in the supply of consumption goods on which the wages earned by the workers employed on the investment projects can be spent. Such commodities will become available in a future that will be more or less remote according to whether the investment goods produced are of the " slow " or " quick " type ; and at that future date wages should be sufficiently high to enable the workers to take the increased supply off the market. But in the initial phases of economic development some caution should be observed with regard to the wage level so as to 1 It is indeed doubtful whether the general level of wage rates could easily be made to increase much faster than, for example, average agricultural incomes. If the difference between agricultural incomes and industrial wages became very large, more workers would be attracted to industry and competition for jobs would become keener. As a result wage rates would tend to fall to a level where there is a rough equilibrium between the number of workers prepared to settle in towns for industrial employment and the number of jobs available outside the agricultural sector. 118 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES maintain equilibrium between the supply of wage goods immediately available and the total wage income that is being increased by the employment of additional workers in investment industries and related activities. The first general problem involved in adjusting the wage level to the progress of economic development is thus seen to consist in adapting the flow of wage income over a period of time to the expanding flow of consumers' goods in such a way that neither shortages nor excesses of purchasing power disturb the smooth process of economic development. Again, the need for close co-ordination between wage policy and the planning of economic development becomes apparent. More particularly, there may be a need for co-ordination between wage policy and other government policies designed to combat inflationary pressures. As has already been pointed out above, programmes of economic development are likely to generate such pressures. Since the essence of economic development is to make as intensive a use as possible of the limited resources available in Asian countries, it is only natural that this should be the case ; it follows, however, that most Asian governments will find it necessary to take measures to keep inflationary pressures within as narrow bounds as possible. They may find it necessary to use such means as fiscal and monetary policy, direct control of investment, the allocation of raw materials, rationing and price control. In some cases there may also be a need for some control on wages as an antiinflationary measure. Some groups of Asian wage earners have already passed the stage of depending on government intervention for the improvement of their living standards ; effective trade unions have been formed, for example, in the transport industry. Moreover, it must be expected that the number and strength of trade unions will increase in the not-too-distant future. Where strong unions have come into existence it may be necessary for the government to call on them and on employers' organisations to shape their wage policies in accordance with the economic needs of the country and to co-operate with the government in carrying through programmes of economic policy, especially when increased demand for certain groups of workers with special skills strengthens the bargaining position of the unions concerned. WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 119 Wage policy in this sense is an extremely delicate matter, as experience in industrialised countries has shown. 1 Few general rules with respect to the shaping of such policy can be given. I t would seem, however, to have but slight chance of success unless at least the following conditions are satisfied : (1) A government that appeals to organised labour for collaboration in questions of economic policy should clearly state what that policy is, why it is thought to be necessary, and why the co-operation of the trade union movement is essential if the policy is to be carried out. (2) Whenever moderation in wage demands is asked of the trade union movement, it should be made clear that other groups of the population will also assume their fair share of the burdens that have to be imposed ; it would also seem indispensable to consult representatives of organised labour on proposed government wage policy and to inform them of the government's intentions in respect of related measures of economic policy, such as taxation, control of prices and profits, and the rationing and subsidising of essential consumers' goods. (3) The leaders of the trade union movement should be able and willing to evaluate the economic and social needs of their country, the impact of their actions on the economic and social position, and the necessity, in the long-run interests of their own membership, of taking into account the requirements of rapid economic development when shaping their own wage policy. PROFIT-SHARING Profit-sharing or the award of bonuses based on profits are sometimes advocated as a means of raising workers' incomes in step with economic progress. For example in a number of Latin American countries the workers have legal rights to a share in profits, and proposals for the introduction by legislation of a general scheme of profit-sharing applicable 1 Cf. Report of the Director-General, Keport I, International Labour Conference, 34th Session, Geneva, 1951 (Geneva, I.L.O., 1951), Chapter I I . 120 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES over a wide range of industry have been considered by the Government of India since 1947.1 Systems of profit-sharing raise a number of general problems concerning, for example, the nature of profit-sharing (whether it is an ex gratia payment or recognition of some sort of right) ; the question whether the principle of profit-sharing implies that the workers should also share in losses ; the possibility that solidarity among the workers will be weakened and the growth of trade unions hampered ; the danger that workers will lose part of their independence and mobility ; fluctuations in the wage earners' total income ; and so on. These problems need not be discussed in this report ; two points may, however, be briefly noted. First, as a device for enabling workers to share in the benefits of economic progress profit-sharing is likely to function in a somewhat arbitrary way. Increasing efficiency and output, if they do not lead to lower prices, will to some extent be reflected in higher profits, especially when wages rise only slowly : to that extent profitsharing has indeed the advantage of providing a rather rapid and automatic adjustment of the workers' income to rises in national income. But economic progress does not result in equal increases in profits in all industries. In some, such as public utilities, and in government services in general, profits may not rise at all, since such industries or services may not attempt to make profits. In industries where competition is keen, profits will rise less than in those where competition is imperfect or absent. Moreover, to a large extent profits are the result of fortuitous factors, such as fluctuations in foreign demand, by which some industries benefit while others do not. Thus, if a large part of the benefits of economic development were distributed among wage earners through schemes for profit-sharing, the part accruing to any particular group might be largely the result of sheer chance. If profit-sharing is to be accepted as one method of distributing the fruits of economic development, it should at least be supplemented by measures designed to ensure a more general and more equal rise in wage earners' income through a rise in wages proper. In India two other objections have been raised against profit-sharing. First, during 1949 the possible inflationary effects of the distribution among the wage earners of substantial 1 P. S. NARASIMHAN : " Profit-Sharing : A Eeview ", in Labour Review, Vol. L X I I , No. 6, Dec. 1950, p. 496. International WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 121 amounts in cash as a profit bonus caused some concern. Secondly, it has been reported that some of the Indian Ministries, when studying the implications of a proposed scheme for large-scale profit-sharing, felt strongly that under the prevailing economic conditions the sharing of profits with labour might result in an irrational distribution of capital, so hindering the Government's industrial programme, and would discourage the investment of fresh indigenous and foreign capital in Indian industries. 1 These two objections, unlike those mentioned above, would seem to apply not only to profit-sharing but to any effort to raise the workers' income through a reduction in profits. The possible inflationary effects of such redistribution of income have already been mentioned in Chapter IV. Essentially, the difficulty is not that wage earners' incomes are rising but that, on the average, wage earners save less (if they save at all) than higher income groups. The problem would be solved if workers could be brought to save more ; indeed, such a solution would seem to be of considerable social importance. If wages are for a time kept low in order to maintain or raise the community's rate of private saving, the existing inequality in the distribution of income will not be diminished ; on the contrary, it may be made worse. If private saving and capital formation are limited to the well-to-do, the concentration of property in the hands of a relatively small proportion of the population will be increased. Private capital being one of the main sources of private income, there will also be a tendency towards further concentration of income. 2 Such a development may perhaps be necessary in the interest of economic progress, but it can scarcely be regarded as satisfactory from the point of view of social betterment. The Indian Committee on Profit-Sharing, in its proposals for a large-scale scheme of profit-sharing 3, proposed that part of the share going to labour should not be given in cash but should be held on the worker's account, either in his provident fund or otherwise. In June 1949 the Indian Government issued an ordinance empowering industrial tribunals, when making 1 2 NAKASIMHAN, op. cit., pp. 496 and 498. Cf. A. VEBMEULEN : "Collective Profit-Sharing", in International Labour Review, Vol. LXVII, No. 6, June 1953, p. 495. 3 Government of India, Ministry of Industry and Supply : Report of the Committee on Profit-Sharing (New Delhi, 1948). 122 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES an award in an industrial dispute concerning a profit bonus, to direct that part of the bonus should, under certain conditions, be paid in the form of Post Office National Savings Certificates.1 These examples show that, at least in principle, it is not impossible to raise the workers' savings while at the same time keeping the inflationary impact of a shift from profits to wages within reasonable bounds. In fact, wage earners would, under the above proposals, receive some future claim to the productive wealth they have been producing instead of to consumers' goods that are not yet being produced in sufficient amounts. Workers might, for example, be permitted after some years to sell their savings certificates for the purpose of buying an appropriate dwelling built under a programme for construction of workers' housing. Thus, although consumption out of the workers' incomes might, to some extent, be regulated and adjusted to the available amount of consumers' goods, it would not be necessary to limit these incomes to the current supply of such goods. The fact that such regulation would probably be easier to operate if applied to an annual profit bonus than through the " freezing " of part of the regular wage might be regarded as an argument in favour of profitsharing. T H E W A G E STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT The term " wage structure " covers, on the one hand, the pattern of wage differentials among occupations, types of wage earner, firms, industries and regions and, on the other hand, the various components of wage earnings. The wage structure, as well as the general level of wages, may be the object of measures of wage policy. Generally speaking, wage differentials may be of importance from the point of view of allocating labour and other economic resources ; or of social justice, in so far as they are or are not in accordance with accepted standards, for example of equal pay for equal work or of equitable wage differentials for different types of work. The various components of wage earnings, on the other hand, may be important as incentives to the individual worker as regards the way in which he performs his normal duties. 1 Industrial Awards in India, op. cit., p . 75. WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 123 As a general rule it might be argued that large wage differentials between regions and industries may have the effect of distorting the pattern of production in a country since low-wage areas and industries tend to attract more capital and enterprise than would be justified by basic economic conditions. For example, the rather substantial wage differentials between industry and agriculture in Asian countries noted in Chapter I might be said to have the effect of hampering industrialisation and perpetuating the heavy emphasis in these countries on agricultural production. 1 More generally, it has been argued that industries that have to rely on exceptionally low wages in order to survive have no right to exist ; while there is an element of truth in this reasoning, it has been suggested in Chapter IV that it should be applied very cautiously. Differentials based on skill may serve the purpose, on the one hand, of inducing able workers to improve their vocational skills and, on the other hand, of allocating skilled labour among the firms and industries which, because of higher general productivity, are able to make the best use of its services. In many cases it may be presumed that market forces will adequately determine differentials based on skill and that there is no immediate need for special measures of wage policy in this field. Wherever such differentials are fixed or implied, for example under arbitration awards or minimum wage regulations, due regard should be had to the need for determining wage differentials that conform with the relative scarcity of the particular skills concerned. Systems of Payment by Results Incentive wage systems may play an important part in improving productivity, particularly in industry. There undoubtedly is considerable scope in Asian countries for improvement in the utilisation of plant, equipment and materials. Such improved utilisation of scarce resources has economic effects similar to those of new capital formation obtained without restrictions on consumption. Among systems of remuneration that may help to improve the utilisation of scarce resources, the most important are the following : 1 Cf. C. M. PALVIA : An Econometric Model for Development Planning (with Special Reference to India) (The Hague, Institute of Social Studies, 1953), Chapter VIII. 124 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN OOUNTEIES (1) Those which lead to direct savings in the use of capital, such as bonuses for exercising care in the use of tools and other equipment, premiums for the saving of raw materials, etc. Techniques for the establishment of such systems of payment have been developed in most of the industrialised countries, and the provision of technical assistance in these matters should prove useful. (2) Those which lead to a more intensive utilisation of the available capital. The obvious way of attaining this objective would be the introduction of systems of payment by results ; in this field again, technical assistance based on the experience of industrialised countries should prove useful. While the introduction and dissemination of incentive wage systems falls somewhat outside the normal scope of wage policy, it is important that, when fixing wages under arbitration awards or statutory regulations, the government or other authorities should pay due regard to the functioning of existing systems of remuneration. For example, it has been found in some cases that the award of substantial flat-rate cost-of-living allowances has considerably blurred the incentive effects of systems of payment by results. In a number of cases, systems of payment by results have already been successfully applied in Asian countries. In Ceylon, for example, piece-work has been extensively applied for many years on the tea and rubber plantations and in certain dock works. In India systems of payment by results are operated in the textile industry, in some mines and in the metal trades and, on a smaller scale, also in the building and clothing industries. In Pakistan piece-work is found in certain railway workshops and in the entire mining industry (except for underground chrome miners). From these three countries favourable effects on productivity and production have been reported. 1 A recent I.L.O. technical assistance mission operating in India at the request of the Indian Government in the textile and engineering industries had as its object to show how productivity and earnings could be raised by the application of modern techniques of work study and plant organisation and, when appropriate, by the introduction of suitable systems of payment by results. 1 See I.L.O. : Payment by BesuUs, Studies and Reports,New Series, No. 27, (Geneva, 1951). WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 125 However, it has also been observed in some cases that workers have shown little disposition to respond to higher pecuniary remuneration by increasing their effort or output ; the indifference of the workers concerned seemed to be due to their limited wants. In such cases the introduction of incentive systems of remuneration can serve no useful purpose. If higher payment as a reward for harder work leads to a higher degree of labour turnover, it may even be disadvantageous. Considerable numbers of wage earners in Asian countries are only parttime workers, who accept employment for wages to bridge the gap between the minimum needs of their families and the income they earn from their own small plots of land ; for them employment for wages loses its interest, and they return to their villages, as soon as this gap has been filled. Where this is the case, the various advantages and disadvantages of any proposed change in the system of remuneration deserve critical and thorough examination before any decision is taken upon it. As a basis for the promulgation of policy regarding systems of remuneration it would therefore seem desirable to obtain as much information as possible on— (1) The results in practice of the application of systems of incentive payments ; methods of measuring the degree of success obtained and the costs involved ; and causes of success or failure. (2) The relative urgency of increases in production in various regions and industries and the likelihood that the application of new or amended systems of remuneration in those regions and industries would help to secure the desired increases in output. (3) The possibility of adapting systems of payment by results to the special preferences and needs of Asian workers. It may be found, for example, that, while some groups of wage earners are relatively indifferent to an increase in money earnings, the prospect that by working harder or more accurately they might more rapidly acquire, say, " points " for the acquisition of a small plot of land or a dwelling would be an effective incentive. On the basis of information on these matters a programme might be drawn up indicating the scope for changes in existing 126 "WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES methods of remuneration. Once a well considered list of urgent tasks in respect of methods of remuneration has been drawn up, the government concerned could work out a programme of action to stimulate the introduction of new systems of payment. Such a programme might cover the questions of disseminating technical information on the subject and, where necessary and appropriate, enlisting foreign technical assistance and providing aid to industries in which a revision of existing systems of remuneration seems particularly urgent. T H E ADJUSTMENT OF WAGES TO CHANGES IN THE COST OP LIVING The adjustment of wages to changes in the cost of living has been one of the most debated issues of wage negotiations and wage policy in recent years. It is not possible to say whether, in general, wages should or should not be adjusted : in some cases full adjustment may be found to be justified, in others partial adjustment only, in still others, no adjustment at all. In fact the problem is similar to that of assessing the appropriate level of the minimum wage. When prices are rising it will generally be considered desirable to protect wage earners against a fall in their standards of living, but the question immediately arises whether it is economically feasible to do so. For instance, if prices rise as a result of a crop failure it will be virtually impossible to avoid some reduction in workers' living standards and, unless some system of food rationing is introduced, it will also be impossible to avoid a rise in prices. Conversely a period of falling prices may appear to offer a good opportunity to allow real wages to rise -, but if, for instance, prices are falling because of a slump in export prices, there will have been a fall in the capacity to pay wages and it may even be difficult to avoid some reduction in the living standards of the workers. As noted in Chapter I I I , a number of regulations in Asian countries provide that mimmum wages may be adjusted to changes in the cost of living, although there is usually no formal obligation involved. In some Latin American minimum wage regulations changes in the cost of living are explicitly mentioned as one of the factors to be taken into account when the minimum wage is being revised. Beyond the realm of WAGE POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 127 minimum wage regulation some Indian tribunals have awarded dearness allowances, but there is no uniformity with respect to the degree of compensation for rising prices ; one of the main considerations on which the decisions were frequently based was capacity to pay. 1 Although it is impossible to frame a general rule concerning the adjustment of wages to fluctuations in the cost of living, consideration might be given to the question whether, in the case of the very lowest paid workers, at least partial protection against rises in the price level could not be guaranteed by fixing a minimum wage for these workers partly or wholly in kind. They would then be saved serious losses of real income during the periods which necessarily elapse between an increase in the cost of living, its statistical measurement, and the final revision of the minimum wage or the dearness allowance. The fixing of minimum wages entirely in kind has, indeed, been recommended in some cases, although not on the grounds just mentioned. 2 Needless to say, under any regulation of minimum wages in kind precautions would have to be taken to prevent and counteract abusive practices. 1 Industrial Awards in India, op. cit. pp. 32 ff. ; cf. also Report of the Committee on Fair Wages, op. cit., pp. 24-25. 2 See, for example, the resolution adopted by the Asian Eegional Conference of 1950 concerning agricultural wages and incomes of primary producers, in Industry and Labour, Vol. I l l , No. 7, 1 Apr. 1950, pp. 250-253. 9 CHAPTEE VI CONCLUSIONS The average living standards of the working population in Asia, of which wage earners constitute only a small proportion, are very low in comparison with those in economically developed countries. Wage policy is but one of a number of measures needed to improve these living standards. Of the other measures the most important will be economic development to increase national income. The main objectives of wage policy in Asia appear to be (a) to abolish malpractices and abuses in wage payment ; (b) to set minimum wages for workers whose bargaining position is weak because they are either unorganised or inefficiently organised, accompanied by separate measures to promote the growth of trade unions and collective bargaining ; (c) to obtain for workers a just share in the fruits of economic development, supplemented by appropriate measures to keep workers' expenditure on consumption goods in step with available supplies, so as to minimise inflationary pressures ; and (d) to bring about a more efficient allocation and utilisation of manpower through the operation of wage incentives— particularly through wage differentials and, where appropriate, systems of payment by results. Before the Second World War there was little state intervention in wage determination in Asian countries. Since the war the State has played an increasingly active role, particularly through the enactment in an appreciable number of countries of minimum wage legislation, and through legislation for the settlement of industrial disputes. The scope, application and degree of enforcement of wage legislation vary greatly and the wages of large groups of workers in Asia are still unregulated. This is particularly the case in agriculture, in cottage and small-scale industries and in personal service. The formulation and execution of a comprehensive wage policy capable of achieving the objectives referred to above CONCLUSIONS 129 and suited to the needs and conditions of Asian countries raises a number of problems which call for special consideration and investigation. T H E CONTENT OF MINIMUM WAGE REGULATION Eapid economic development is the most important objective of economic policy in Asian countries and there are few questions of social policy which can be considered independently of this objective. If minimum wage regulation is to result in something more than the mere legal confirmation of the existing level and structure of wages, programmes of wage policy must be planned and executed in close co-ordination with policies for economic development. The purpose of such co-ordination is to ensure that the aims of wage regulation are compatible with the targets set for production, employment, the balance of payments and other strategic factors affecting the expansion of the economy. The larger the difference, in any country, between the prevailing pattern of wages and the pattern that it is the purpose of the minimum wage policy to attain, the more effective must such co-ordination be. The need for co-ordination is likely to have a decisive influence on the type of machinery chosen to determine, for example the level of wage costs in major industries or the economic feasibility of a rise in workers' living standards. This choice will also be affected by a number of other circumstances which may differ from country to country : the nature and the method of administration of the programme for economic development, the existing economic structure and the changes which it is intended to bring about in the pattern of production and employment, the opinion prevailing on the necessary extent of government intervention in economic and social matters, the ratio between prevailing wage rates and the targets of wage policy, and the availability of competent and responsible representatives of various interests. If wage policy is to prepare the way for the development of collective bargaining, it will be important that workers and employers should be adequately represented. It follows from what has been said above about co-ordination that arrangements should also be made to associate with the process of minimum wage determination the authorities responsible for the government's policy in related fields. 130 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES In deciding on the level of the minimum wage the vital criteria are workers' needs and economic feasibility. Neither provides an absolute standard. There is a very wide gap between the present living standards of workers in Asian countries and even a fairly low estimate of their needs. This gap cannot be bridged quickly. The important thing is to make steady and sure progress towards reducing it. Similarly, as regards economic feasibility, the needs of rapid economic development, considered alone, might suggest that relatively few resources should be allocated to raising hving standards in the near future, so that as much as possible can be allocated to investment designed to raise productive capacity. But when workers' needs are considered it becomes apparent that the rate of economic development has to be adjusted to provide for the satisfaction of at least the most urgent needs for improved living standards. The average minimum wage for each country will thus be determined in the light of the decisions of the responsible authorities as to the best balance to strike between workers' needs and the rate of economic development. This balance will depend upon what assessment is made of the probable economic consequences of different wage levels—their immediate effect on prices, employment, output, the balance of payments, savings, investment and other relevant factors, and the final effect they are likely to have on the basic objectives of the programme for economic development. This does not mean, however, that a uniform wage should immediately be fixed for all workers in all industries, even though there are strong arguments in support of such uniformity. In view of the wide differences in the capacity to pay wages in various sectors of the economy, such a uniform minimum wage would either have to be fixed at a very low level or, if fixed at a higher level, would involve such a large disruption in the economy as to make it unenforceable. I t is likely therefore that different minimum wage rates will have to be fixed at least at the beginning for a number of broad groups of wage earners (for example, those engaged in agriculture, village industries, plantations, manufacturing, transport and government undertakings). Within each group, individual sections might be awarded different wage rates related to the minimum established for the group as a whole. As economic development succeeds in achieving a more CONCLUSIONS 131 efficient allocation of resources, the capacity of different industries to pay wages should tend to become more nearly equal and the minimum wages fixed for different industries can be more uniform. Indeed, the periodic review of minimum wages in the light of changing conditions, such as fluctuations in the cost of living, improvements in workers' productivity, and the general progress of economic development, should be an esssential element of minimum wage policy. The need to find the desirable level for the average minimum wage and the need to fix different minimum wages for various industries or regions lead to the conclusion that provision should be made for co-ordination not only of the decisions of wage fixing and other authorities but also of the decisions taken by the agencies responsible for fixing wages in various industries or regions. As regards wage differentials, it seems doubtful whether minimum wage regulation should provide for differentials based on skill, since the additional technical work required for their establishment would at least seriously delay the implementation of minimum wage regulations. As for differentials according to sex, it would hardly be possible for minimum wage regulation to abolish them immediately, but their gradual elimination might be accepted as an ultimate aim. Special problems exist in industries producing raw materials for world markets. Since competition in these markets is almost perfect, it is difficult for any single country to raise its wage costs without prejudice to its position in the world market ; this problem might be lessened if countries exporting the same primary commodity were to proceed simultaneously with minimum wage regulation in the industry concerned. The frequent and violent fluctuations in the prices of primary products raise a further difficulty : in this regard consideration might be given to the desirability of fixing minimum wages in the industries concerned on the basis of a reasonable average selling price and on the understanding that, while the minimum wage would not be raised in the case of a short-term rise in the price of the product, it would not be reduced during periods of falling prices. INSPECTION AND ENFORCEMENT The most difficult aspect of minimum wage regulation in Asian countries is enforcement, which is fundamentally a 132 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES question of the attitude of the general public. The immediate problem, however, is the shortage of adequately trained inspection staff. When minimum wage regulation is extended to agriculture, cottage and small-scale industries, the difficulties of enforcement will be further increased by the large number of small producing units in those economic sectors. Asian governments will therefore have to take all possible steps to lighten the task of enforcement and to strengthen labour inspection. Such steps might include the following : (a) the setting up of a separate wage administration service charged with special responsibility for the enforcement of wage regulation ; (b) simplification of minimum wage regulations ; (e) raising the pay and social status of labour inspectors ; (d) entrusting part of the inspection work to persons who, though not on a regular inspection staff, maintain contact in some official capacity with industries where a minimum wage regulation is applied ; (e) securing full co-operation of employers' and workers' organisations ; (f) legal protection, particularly from discharge, of individual workers who report infringements ; (g) making the penalty for infringements severe. W A G E POLICY AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT : THE PROBLEM OF CO-ORDINATION As national income rises with the progress of economic development, the national wage bill will also tend to increase. This rise in the total sum of wage payments may take two extreme forms : the level of real wages may be kept more or less constant and the volume of employment increase, or the level of wages may rise while employment increases less, if at all. Where there is much unemployment the former alternative may be considered preferable on social and economic grounds. In this case it may be necessary to avoid measures of wage policy that would bring about or encourage substantial increases in wages in the short run. The existing wage structure in most Asian countries appears to be not altogether satisfactory. Large wage differentials among firms and industries for comparable occupations have been reported to be a cause of industrial disputes and unnecessary labour turnover and to hamper the efficient allocation of manpower. In certain cases statutory wage CONCLUSIONS 133 regulation or wage fixing by arbitration awards or conciliation procedures may be instrumental in overcoming such problems by introducing a more rational pattern of wage differentials ; but in other cases the structure of wage differentials based on skill and occupation may better be left to the operation of market forces. With a view to increasing both the efficiency and the earnings of workers, improvements in existing systems of remuneration may be desirable, including in certain cases the introduction of appropriately designed systems of payment by results. In order to formulate a policy in this matter information is needed on (a) the results of the application of different systems of remuneration and the causes of success or failure ; (b) the relative urgency of increases in production in various industries and the likelihood that the application of systems of payment by results would help to secure the desired increases in output ; (c) the possibility of adapting systems of payment by results to the special attitudes and needs of Asian workers. On the basis of an investigation of these matters a programme of action could be drawn up for the promotion of improved systems of payment including the dissemination of technical information on the subject and the provision of technical assistance and other aid to industries in which a revision of existing systems of remuneration seems particularly urgent. T H E PBOBLEM OF THE SUPPLY OF ESSENTIAL CONSUMÉES' GOODS Wage policy, by itself, can make only a minor contribution to expanding the supply of essential consumers' goods, which is the basic factor determining workers' standards of living. Because of the need to increase employment and divert resources to capital formation, the supply of essential consumers' goods and hence the level of workers' real income may not rise appreciably in the early phases of economic development. On the other hand, the awakened social consciousness of Asian countries demands that their living standards should improve as rapidly as possible in the course of development. To resolve this dilemma the countries of Asia will have to ensure that total output rises as fast as possible and that the 134 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES demand for capital conflicts as little as possible with the demand for consumers' goods. In particular, measures should be taken to ensure (a) the effective utilisation of surplus labour ; (b) the rapid spreading of improved techniques requiring little additional capital ; (c) the careful selection of appropriate capital investment projects, with special emphasis on essential consumers' goods industries and on breaking bottlenecks in the production of basic materials ; (d) the most economic use of resources available for purchasing imports ; (e) the restriction of non-essential consumption and investment. If all these lines of action can be pursued simultaneously with vigour and determination, it seems reasonable to suggest that the supply of essential consumers' goods, the level of workers' real wages and the level of living standards in Asian countries can rise at a satisfactory rate, even in the early stages of accelerated economic development. APPENDIX RESOLUTION CONCERNING WAGES Adopted by the Asian Regional Conference of the International Labour Organisation (Tokyo, September 1953) 1 Whereas the International Labour Organisation has a solemn obligation to further among the nations of the world programmes which will achieve policies in regard to conditions of employment, particularly wages and earnings, calculated to ensure a just share of the fruits of progress to all, and a minimum wage to all employed and in need of such protection ; Whereas the Asian Begional Conference in 1947 recommended action by the governments of Asian countries designed to assist the conclusion of collective agreements and, when the necessary conditions of collective bargaining are not satisfied, to provide for the fixing and enforcement of fair wages 2 ; The Asian Begional Conference of the International Labour Organisation, having met at Tokyo, adopts this twenty-fourth day of September 1953 the following resolution : Having regard to the need to improve the standard of living of the people of the Asian countries and to the essential interrelation between the regulation of wages and the requirements of economic development of these countries, the Conference considers that— (a) it should be the common objective of governments, employers and workers to establish wages at the highest possible level which the economic condition of each country permits, and in future such wages should aim to provide the worker with a fair share of the increased prosperity of the country as a whole resulting from economic development ; (b) to this end collective agreements between employers and workers are normally the best means for the determination and adjustment of wages, and the development as soon as possible of free associations of employers and workers and- systems of collective negotiation based on such associations, if possible on an industrywide or regional basis, or both, should be actively promoted and encouraged by all concerned ; (e) pending the general development of effective systems of collective negotiation in each country, there is a pressing need for the immediate introduction of statutory measures to regulate wages in occupations in each country in which collective bargaining is not effective or is non-existent and as a preliminary step towards the development of systems of collective negotiation ; 1 2 This resolution was adopted unanimously. See Official Bulletin, Vol. X X X , No. 3, 15 Nov. 1947, pp. 178-180. 136 WAGE POLICY IN ASIAN COUNTRIES (d) the determination and adjustment of wages by statutory means, with the object of prescribing a minimum wage or wages, should be arranged through tripartite machinery, such wage or wages to be subject to review when necessary or at regular intervals ; (e) such machinery should afford equal representation of workers and employers, where possible nominated by their respective organisations or otherwise appointed after consultation with such organisations ; an independent chairman and any independent members should be appointed either by agreement between the members constituting such a tripartite body or by the government, so far as possible in conformity with the views of the organisations concerned ; (f) the wages resulting from this machinery should be statutorily enforced with the sanction of penalties sufficiently severe to deter non-observance ; (g) in order to make statutory wage regulation effective, there should be an authority in each country fully empowered by law, and adequately staffed and equipped, to carry the responsibility for the enforcement of statutory wage provisions ; (h) the work of this authority should be facilitated by such means as the framing of wage provisions in a simple form easily understood by all concerned, the provision of inspectorate staff suitably qualified, trained in their work and adequately remunerated so as to ensure that they inspire the confidence of employers and workers alike, and the laying down of procedures for bringing complaints of infringement of wage provisions to the notice of the enforcing authority without risk or detriment to the worker's livelihood ; (i) in order to ensure that, in the general operation of statutory wage fixing systems as described above, as well as in the operation of systems of collective negotiation as and when they develop, consideration is given to the utmost extent possible to maintaining a relationship between the wage regulation and the requirements of economic development, there should be arrangements for continuing consultation between governments, employers and workers so that policies in the field of wage regulation and economic development may be co-ordinated, framed, implemented and enforced with the widest possible measure of agreement between the parties concerned ; And requests the Governing Body to transmit this resolution to the governments concerned. INDEX A Agrarian reform, 27, 93 Agriculture, 34, 76, 93, 115, 123, 132 Incomes in, 115-116, 117 n. Minimum wages in, 44, 49, 52, 58, 61 ff., 71-72, 79, 97 n., 98 n., 103, 109, 112, 128 Allocation of materials, 37, 118 Andrus, J . Russell, 4 n., 19 Arbitration, 39-40, 52 ft., 69 fi., 74, 82, 97, 123-124, 127, 133 Australia, 82-83, 97 B Bakuls, 23 Balance of payments, 75,90,92-93,100 ff., 130 Bank Indonesia, 18 n. Baran, Paul A., 105 n. Bottlenecks, 34, 134 Bribes, 110 Burma : Arbitration, 53-54, 70 Conciliation, 54 Minimum wage regulation, 49-50, 57 ff., 64 Collective bargaining, 26, 39, 44-45, 72-73, 78, 82, 107, 128-129 Commerce, 7, 72 Communications, 29 Community projects, 33 Competition, 91-92,95-96,101,116,117 n., 120, 131 International, 39 Concüiation, 39-40, 52-57, 69 ff., 74, 133 Construction, 37 Consumers' goods, 37-38, 39, 47, 90, 92 ff., 100, 103, 117, 122, 128, 133-134 Consumption, 28 ff., 37, 84, 87, 93, 105 Conspicuous, 11 of Fibres, 10 of Food, 9, 31 n., 93 Per head, 30 Consumption goods industries, 31 n., 34, 134 Consumption unit, 86 Co-ordination of policies, 46-47, 72, 74-75, 87-88, 102, 108, 118, 129, 131, 132-133 Copland, D. B . and Foenander, O. de R., 97 n. Cost of living, 20, 76, 85, 115, 131 Allowance 46, 49, 59, 64, 72, 124, 127 Changes in, 39, 4 1 , 46, 59, 72, 88, 112, 126-127 Credit facilities, 99, 106 C Capacity to pay, 15, 46, 51, 59, 77 ff., 81, 84-85, 87 ff., 90, 92, 96 ff., 104, 106, 126-127, 130-131 Capital : Equipment, 28, 34, 36-37, 91, 95, 99, 103, 123-124 Formation (see Investment) Imports, 37, 121 Output ratio, 29-30, 35, 113 Scarcity, 29, 31, 106, 113 ff. Utilisation, 124 Capital intensive processes, 114 ff. Ceylon : Arbitration, 53-54 Conciliation, 54 Distribution of income, 13, 15 Minimum wage regulation, 50, 58 ff., 63, 65, 103 n. Payment by results, 124 Chandrasekhar, S., 13 n. Chaturvedi, S. C , 20 n. China : Distribution of income, 12 Minimum wage regulation, 50, 59 Clark, Colin, 2, 8 n., 30 n. Cole, G. D. H., 32 n. D Da Costa, E., 91 n. Daya, E., 52 n. Dearness allowance (see Cost-of-living allowance) Debt (see Indebtedness) Demand : Effective, 93, 100 Foreign, 101 ff., 120 for Labour, 81 for Raw materials, 101 ff. for Skills, 83 Depreciation allowances, 34 Depressed areas, 89 Devaluation, 103 Diets, 91 Dividends, 104 Dobb, Maurice, 33 n. E Earnings, 32 Deductions from, 40 ff., 49, 63 Increases in, 117 Economic Commission for Latin America, 102 138 INDEX Economic development, 10, 26, 28 ff., 35, 39, 44, 79, 81-82, 85, 87-88, 94, 98-99, 103, 106, 108-109, 112 ff., 117 ft., 129130, 132-133 and Living standards, 32,44, 46-47,112 and Wage policy, 47 Education, 109, 132 Efficiency (see Productivity) Employment, 40, 78, 88, 90 ff., 93, 95-96, 98-100, 102, 104, 112 ff., 117-118, 130, 132 Opportunities for, 32, 35, 43, 81, 91, 99, 115 ff., 117 n. 1, 132 Wage Regulation and, 94 ft. Employment services, 41 Enforcement of minimum wage regulations (see Minimum wage regulation : Enforcement) Enterprise, 31 n., 104, 106-107, 123 Equal pay for equal work, 58, 80-81, 122 Equal Remuneration Convention, 1951, 80 Equipment (see Capital equipment) Expanded Programme of Technical Assistance, 35 Exports, 36, 93, 101-103, 126 F Factories, 16 Seasonal, 20 Fair wages (see Wages, Fair) Family, Size of, 80, 85 ff. Family allowances, 86-87 Family farming, 115-116 Finance, 106 Fiscal policy, 118 Foenander, 0 . de R. and Copland, D. B., 97 n. Foreign trade, 31 n. Freedom of association, 45 G Gadgil, D. R., 91 ff., 107 H Handicrafts, 5, 8, 16, 22 ff., 35, 41 ff., 72, 76, 78, 93 Handweaving, 6, 8, 23, 26, 35, 98 Heavy work, 83 Homeworkers, 23 Hong Kong : Arbitration, 53 Minimum wage regulation, 50-51, 60 Household budgets, 85 ff. I Illiteracy, 43 Imports, 35-36, 93-94, 103, 114, 134 Restriction of, 94, 103 Incentives, 11, 39, 46, 90-91, 106-107, 122, 123 ff., 128 Income : Average, 8 ff., 10-11, 16, 26, 47 Distribution of, 10 ff., 32, 85, 94, 121 Redistribution of, 11,15,26-27,121-122 Indebtedness, 27, 40, 42, 105 India : All India Cottage Industries Board, 6 Arbitration, 53 ff., 70-71, 80, 127 Committee on Fair Wages, 77 n., 80, 82, 97, 104 Committee on Profit Sharing, 121 Conciliation, 54, 70-71 Distribution of income, 13, 15 Fact-Finding Committee (Handloom and Mills), 7 n., 23 n. Fair wages, 66 Fair Wages Bui, 5 1 , 58 First five-year plan, 62, 67, 82, 88-89, 108 Indian Labour Conference, 62, 66-67 Minimum wage regulations, 57 ff., 61 ff., 65 ff. Minimum Wages Act, 1948, 51, 62 Payment b y results, 124 Profit-sharing, 120 ff. Indonesia : Arbitration, 53, 55, 70 Conciliation, 55 Emergency Law concerning labour disputes, 1951, 55 Industrial Revolution, 31 Industries : Cottage, 5-6, 8, 22 ff., 35, 72, 76, 78-79, 109, 128, 132 Expanding, 78 Large-scale, 35, 78-79, 114 Small-scale, 114, 128, 132 Stagnant, 78 Inflation, 75, 117 ff. Inspection (see Minimum wage regulation : Enforcement) International Labour Organisation : Asian Advisory Committee, I I I , 43, 112 Asian Regional Conferences, I I I - I V , 43-45, 106-107, 109-110, 112, 135 Equal Remuneration Convention, 1951, 80 Minimum Wage-Fixing Machinery Convention, 1928, 107 Protection of Wages Convention, 1949, 43 n. Technical Assistance Programme, 34 n., 64, 124 Investment, 11, 28 ff., 34 ff., 37, 40, 44, 87, 97, 99-100, 106, 116-117, 121, 123, 130, 134 Per worker, 35 Investment goods : Industries, 31 n., 118 Quick and slow, 117 Irrigation, 33 139 INDEX J Japan, 2 Arbitration, 53, 55-56 Conciliation, 55 Distribution of income, 13, 32 Minimum wage regulation, 51-52, 5960, 67 J o b evaluation, 26, 83 K Karkhanadar, 7, 23 K h a m b a t t a , K. J . and Shah, K. T., 13 n. Korea, Arbitration in, 53 Kuznets, Simon, 14-15 Kyiwin, 49-50 L Labour, Abundance of, 116 Labour force, Allocation of, 39 Labour intensive processes, 114 ff. Labour surplus, 33, 35, 134 Labour turnover, 78, 125, 132 Landlords, 12, 93-94 M Màhajan, 7 Maintenance of equipment, 29 Malaya, Federation of: Arbitration, 53, 56 Minimum wage regulation, 52, 60 Malpractices in wage payment, 39, 40 ff., 127, 128 Management, 91 Market forces (see also Supply and Demand), 123, 133 Middlemen, 6, 23, 27, 40-41 Migrant labour, 41 Minimum wage : Adjustments in, 46 in Agriculture (see Agriculture) Criteria for determining, 75, 84 ff. Economic feasibility of raising, 76, 8485, 87-88, 104, 126, 129-130, 132 Level of, 44, 46, 58 ff., 84 ff., 126, 130131 Minimum Wage-Kxing Machinery Convention, 1928, 107 Minimum wage regulation, 15, 32, 40, 43 ff., 48 ff., 57 ff., 74 ff., 103 n., 123, 129 ff. Enforcement, 44, 61, 74, 76, 78, 109 ff., 128, 130, 131-132 Machinery for, 49 ff., 107 ff., 129 Scope, 46, 57-58, 77 Simplicity of, 110, 132 Uniformity in, 44, 75 ff., 85, 88, 96, 99, 107-108, 127, 130-131 Misallocation of productive factors, 97-98, 105 Mobility of productive factors, 31 n., 79, 87, 95, 97 ff., 100, 115-116, 133 Moneylenders, 12, 42 Mukerjee, Radhakamal, 3 n., 20, 91 n. Mukerji, K. P., 18 n., 21 n. N Narasimhan, P . S., 120 n., 121 n. New Zealand, Minimum wages in agriculture in, 98 n. Non-wage benefits, 46 Non-wage earners, 93, 100, 107, 115 Nurkse, Ragnar, 33 n. 0 Occupation structure, 1 ff. Ou, Pao-san, 5 n. Output (see Production) P Pakistan, 30 n. Arbitration, 53, 56 Fair wages, 69 Payment by results, 124 Palvia, C. M., 123 n. Payment by results, 46, 83, 123 ff., 128, 133 Penalties, 42, 49, 132 Personal services, 7, 72, 76, 128 Philippines : Arbitration, 53, 56-57 Conciliation, 56 Distribution of income, 13 Minimum Wage Law, 1951, 52, 60, 63, 67, 107 n. Minimum wage regulation, 52, 57 ff., 63-64, 67-68, 76, 107 Piece rates, 6, 76, 83, 124 Pillai, P . P., 19, 21 Planning, 29-30, 37-38, 40, 117-118, 121, 129, 134 Plantations, 16, 21-22, 41, 101 Population : Growth of, 30 Pressure of, 12, 43, 116 Post Office National Savings Certificates, 122 Prices, 92 ff., 130 Changes in, 84, 87-88, 92 ff., 96, 100 ff., 104, 120, 126 of Food, 11 of Primary products, 22, 36, 101, 103, 131 Regulation of, 94, 118-119 Private enterprise, 31 n. Production, 40, 92-93, 95, 96, 98 ff., 102, 114, 120, 130, 133 P a t t e r n of, 11 Primary, 2 ff. Secondary, 5 ft. Tertiary, 7 ff. 140 INDEX Productivity, 12, 31, 33-34, 36, 39, 43, 47, 78, 87, 89 ff., 94 ff., 102, 104-105, 120, 123-124, 131, 133-134 Distribution of benefits of, 44, 112 Marginal, 80 n. Profits, 90, 94, 96, 104 ff., 119 fi. Control of, 119 Fair, 84, 87, 104 and Wages, 15 Profit-sharing, 119 fi. Collective, 121 n. Protection of wages, 49 Public works, 69, 105 Puerto Rico, Distribution of income in, 14 R R a w materials, 101 fi., 104, 131 Recruiting agents, 41 Rent, 12 Riches, E . J., 98 n. Risks, investment, 105-106 S Sanctions, 111 Savings, 31 n., 32-33, 87, 93, 99-100, 104, 105-106, 120-121, 130 Mobilisation of, 36 Self-employed persons, 86, 93-94, 115 Shah, K. T. and K h a m b a t t a , K. J., 13 n. Shih, Kuo-heng, 21 n. Singapore, Arbitration in, 53 Singer, H . W., 32 n. Sirki Khas-hi-Tatti, 6 Social policy, 39, 45-46, 48-49, 122 Social unrest, 40 Soviet Russia, First five-year plan in, 32 Standard family, 85-86 Standards of living, 10, 30 fi., 34, 40, 43 ff., 46-48, 59, 75-77, 79 ff., 85, 88 ff., 91 ff., 94, 103, 108, 118, 126-127, 130, 133 Steindl, J., 114 n. Subsistence farming, 41 Substitutes for raw materials, 102 Substitution : of Capital for labour, 91, 99, 113, 116 of Imports for domestic output, 101 of Labour for capital, 99, 113 Supply : of Labour, 81, 92 of Skills, 83, 123 T Taxation, 15, 37, 78, 94, 119 Technical assistance (see also Expanded Programme of Technical Assistance), 34 n., 64, 124, 126, 133 Technical training, 35 Technology, 35 Terms of trade, 36, 93, 101 Thompson, Virginia, 19, 23 n. Trade unions, 40, 43, 45, 63, 70, 102, 111, 118-120, 128, 132 U Underemployment, 23, 99 Undertakings, Size of, 44 Unemployment, 44, 87, 91-92, 94 ff., 99, 108, 113 ff-, 116, 132 Seasonal, 20, 27 Structural, 32 Uniformity in minimum wage determination (see Minimum wage regulation) United Kingdom, Distribution of income in, 15 United Provinces Labour Enquiry Committee, 15, 108 United States, 2 Distribution of income in, 13 Urbanisation, 115 V Vermeulen, A., 121 n. Viner, Jacob, 11 n. W Wage boards, 59, 65, 67, 68, 89, 107-109 Wage determination, Methods of, 39 Wage disputes (see also Arbitration and Conciliation), 40, 53 fi., 69 ff., 72, 74, 78, 128, 132 Wage earners, 1, 3 ff., 26, 86, 120 Agricultural, 12, 17 in Cottage industries, 6, 27 in Domestic services, 7, 11, 27 in Manufacturing, 5 ff. Savings of, 121-122 Wage-earning units, 86 Wage floor, 77 Wage goods, 117 Wage legislation, 48 ff., 128 Application of, 48 Wage policy : Aims and objectives of, 37 ff., 44, 46, 74, 77, 81, 90, 105, 109, 112, 122, 128-129 and Economic development, 47 Effects of, 40, 44, 46, 75, 8 1 , 87-88, 108, 116 ff., 130 and Redistribution of income, 11 Wage regulation : Principles of, 88-89, 108 Statutory, 39, 74 Systems of, 48 ff. Wages : Agricultural, 17 ff., 27, 45 Control of, 118-119, 122 INDEX Differences in, 16 ff., 27, 78, 89, 115 n., 117 n., 122 ff., 128, 131 ff. Geographical, 83 according to Sex, 18, 58, 76, 80-81, 131 according to Skill, 82-83, 98,123,131 Fair, 39-40, 51, 66, 69, 77, 98, 122 Handicraft and factory, 22 ff. Increases in, 44 Effects of, 90 ff. Industrial, 17 ff., 27 in Kind, 40 ff., 49, 59, 127 Level of, 39-40, 47, 74 fí., 102, 112, 113 ff., 117 ff. Living, 43, 89 Low, 39, 43-44, 59, 77, 79, 83, 90, 94 ff., 123, 127 141 Money, 16, 26 Payment of, 40, 42, 49, 109 Plantation and farm, 21-22 and Profits, 15 Real, 16, 20-21, 47, 74, 126-127, 132 Structure of, 16, 27, 39 ff., 47, 74 ff., 82, 112, 122 ff., 132 Wage standardisation, 83, 89 Wang, Foh-shen, 5 n. Workers : Agricultural, 12, 17 ff., 43, 58 Female, 18, 58, 80-81 Purchasing power of, 38, 93 Skilled, 18, 24 ff., 35, 82-83, 91, 118 unskilled, 18, 24 ff., 36, 43, 91, 93, 116 Workers' needs, 75, 83 ff., 130 Work study, 124 PUBLICATIONS OF THE INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE Mig/her Productivity in Manufacturing ¡industries Studies and Reports, New Series, No. 38 This study is based on a draft submitted to a meeting of experts in December 1952. The draft has been revised and expanded in the light of the discussion which took place at the meeting, and the volume includes the conclusions adopted by the experts. The first part deals with the effects of higher productivity on the worker and the share of the benefits which the worker may expect to receive whether it be in increased money wages, the lowering of prices for consumers' goods, social security, better working conditions or the reduction of normal hours of work. The possibility that greater productivity may result in some unemployment is taken into account and it is suggested that the problem should be tackled by governments, with the aid where necessary of employers and workers, by such means as minimum wage legislation, price control, selecting the industries in which productivity increase is to be encouraged so as to minimise the displacement of workers and assisting in the re-employment of the displaced workers by improving vocational training and retraining facilities, by the payment of removal grants and by energetic action to overcome housing shortages. The many factors which affect productivity are reviewed : the size and stability of markets, the utilisation of resources, the degree of competition, the quality and flow of materials, the availability of capital and credit, particularly in underdeveloped countries, taxation, and the development of industrial and production engineering and the exchange of information. Part I I turns from the general problems of increasing productivity to the steps which may be taken to raise productivity in individual establishments, such as the modernisation of plant and equipment, mechanisation in the handling of materials, careful maintenance of machinery, the organisation and control of production with a view to lowering costs and using available resources as efficiently as possible, and the development of good relations between the personne! service and other departments in the undertaking. Part I I I reproduces the conclusions of the meeting of experts, which were adopted unanimously. 195 pages, including index Price : $1.25 ; 7s. 6d.