INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE STUDIES AND REPORTS Series D (Wages and Hours of Work) No. 18 WAGES AND HOUES OF WOEK IN THE COAL-MINING INDUSTEY / PREFACE On 28 April 1925, the Committee of the International Miners' Federation, at a meeting held in Brussels to consider the economic difficulties with which certain coal-producing countries were already faced, adopted a resolution in which it declared t h a t the causes of these difficulties arose to a great extent from the competition and commercial rivalry prevalent in the coal markets. It placed on record that the differences in the working conditions existing in the various coal-producing countries served to sharpen and to embitter this state of competition and rivalry. Consequently, in its opinion it was necessary to pursue energetically the standardisation of working conditions of miners on an international basis. But, as it was not in possession of complete information, it realised that it was necessary to undertake an enquiry in the principal coal-producing countries dealing with hours of work, annual holidays, and wages paid by the employers to different categories of miners 1. The resolution added : 1 The full t e x t of this resolution is as follows : "Whereas in certain coal-producing countries economic difficulties are such as to lead to continually increasing unemployment among miners and the lowering of their standard of living ; "Whereas these economic difficulties arise very largely from competition and commercial rivalry in t h e international coal m a r k e t ; "Whereas this competition and commercial rivalry is more acute a n d embittered by reason of the differences in the working conditions existing in the principal coal-producing countries ; "The Committee decides t h a t efforts should be made to secure t h e standardisation of working conditions of miners on an international basis. "Since t h e Committee desires to be fully informed before i t formulates definite and concrete proposals, it decides to organise, in agreement with the National Miners' Federations, an international investigation in the principal coal-producing countries. This investigation shall deal with hours of work, annual holidays, and wages paid by employers t o the various categories of mining workers. " I n order t h a t the proposed investigation should be as thorough a s possible and t h a t the enquiry may be completed with t h e least possible delay, the Committee also decides to appeal to t h e International L a b o u r Office for assistance and the co-operation of the means of investigation a t its disposal." VI — In order that the proposed investigation should be as thorough as possible and that the enquiry may be completed with the least possible delay, the Committee also decides to appeal to the International Labour Office for assistance and the co-operation of the means of investigation at its disposal. On 2 June 1925, this resolution was submitted to the Seventh Session of the International Labour Conference by Mr. Mertens, the Belgian workers' delegate, and the Conference adopted the following resolution : . . Whereas it is one of the functions of the International Labour Office as defined by Part XIII of the Treaty of Peace to collect all information upon hours of work, wages, and annual holidays ; And whereas there would be a special value in an international comparative investigation of all the documents already collected by the great public mines administrations, which documents could be still further supplemented by those of the employers' and workers' organisations : The Conference requests the Governing Body to consider the conditions under which this investigation could be initiated and carried out by the International Labour Office. In the following October, the Governing Body of the International Labour Office, in its turn, asked the Office to proceed with this enquiry with a view to publishing all the comparable statistics which it might be able to collect relating to hours of work, paid holidays, and wages of miners in most of the coalproducing countries of the world. To emphasise the importance which it attached to this enquiry, the Governing Body appointed from among its members a Committee whose task was to follow closely the work of the Office and, if need be, to give its opinion on the execution and the result of this work, leaving to the Office, however, full responsibility for its undertaking. This Committee, composed of six members, was formed by MR. WOLFE and MR. SOKAL, representing the government members of the Governing Body, MR. LAMBERT-RIBOT and SIR JAMES LITHGOW, representing the employers' group, MR. JOUHAUX and MR. POULTON, representing the workers' group. It was understood that during the Sessions of the Committee, these members could be assisted by experts. Thus it was not in this case one of those Committees of outside experts called in by the International Labour Office to assist it in those technical studies which need such assistance. The International Labour Office retained full control over its enquiry and full responsibility for it. Through the medium of the Committee of the Governing Body, it kept the latter informed of the progress of work as opportunity offered. It received, in conditions fully safeguarding its independence, VII criticisms from the members of the Committee assisted by the experts chosen by them, which would be of use in the continuation of its work. But this Committee was, as it were, an internal committee of the International Labour Office ; the latter had recourse to no external authority to alienate any part of its responsibility, which was completely and entirely preserved. At this point it is desirable to mention briefly the underlying causes of the enquiry which the Office was requested to undertake, and whose results are here published, to indicate the different stages through which it passed, and to describe shortly its essential character and the scope of the results which may be expected of it.i The underlying cause of the resolutions of the Committee of the International Miners' Federation and of the International Labour Conference is only too obviously the coal crisis from which the world has been suffering for several years ; but it is necessary to point out how the examination of the causes of the crisis led in the minds of certain people concerned, and especially in the minds of the workers, to the conclusion that the conditions of work in the coal-mines lay at the root of the crisis. From an examination of pre-war and post-war statistics, it appears that the coal production of the present time is approximately equal to that of 1913, the last normal year of the pre-war period. It is even the case, in favour of the present period, that the distribution of this production is slightly less unequal; in 1913 the three great coal-producing countries of the world— the United States, Great Britain, and Germany—represented 82 per cent, of the world production ; to-day they only represent 77 per cent. However, the French production, thanks to the intelligent reconstruction of the mines of the Northern Departments, is continually increasing ; the production of the Netherlands, formerly almost non-existent, is also continually developing, and above all, overseas, the mines of Australia, South Africa, India, and indeed China are beginning to take a more important place in the statistics. Hence the monopoly of the former producers is losing its rigidity and its power ; the pits are becoming more scattered. It follows that the former holders of a quasi-monopoly suffer restrictions in their exports and, in particular, as they are obliged to reduce their exports of coal to the overseas mining countries, — VIII they are led to seek markets to which they have better access nearer home. Such is more especially the case with Great Britain and Germany, whose endeavours to gain or retain the European buyers are becoming more bitter. In this restricted field of competition the two exporting countries come into collision, but they also come into conflict with the producing countries of the Continent. This fierce competition, moreover, coincides with a certain number of phenomena which tend to diminish, at least temporarily, the consumption of coal. In the first place, the results of the industrial crisis, which does not exist in all countries to the same extent but is everywhere active or latent, are that the industries of the whole world, which are producing less taking all in all, require less fuel. Further, whereas before the war one could say that coal was the only source of energy which the great industries used to a considerable extent, to-day such is no longer the case. Oil is in demand as fuel for tractive motors ; more than a third of the world's shipping is now propelled by oil. Electricity plays a rôle of first importance as the source of power in textile spinning and weaving mills and in the electrometallurgic industries. Finally, economical methods necessitated by more than four years of war have been continued and even perfected during the peace ; industries have sought and found processes which will give the same output with a diminished consumption of fuel. Hence an overproduction of coal, which is not in fact the result of an increase of production but of a reduction of consumption, due in part to incidental causes, but also. in part to causes which appear to be really permanent. Hence the keenness of the competition for the capture or the keeping of markets, and the combative measures—certain of which, "dumping" for example, are deplorable—which the States concerned have been obliged to adopt. From this ruinous competition was bound to arise the idea of an agreement between the producing countries for the purpose of sharing markets equitably and rationally, and also no doubt to eliminate the overproduction of a commodity for which the consumer was not so eager as formerly. To increase production in a restricted market would be to risk strengthening the rivalry. Is it wise in present conditions, when 50 or 100 million tons of coal are taken from the soil each year without being able to find a purchaser, to increase still more this unsaleable stock by an intensified production ? To some the remedy appears — IX — in a reasonable restriction of production, perhaps in the closing down of old mines which are carried on at a loss, but especially in some kind of standardisation of working conditions in the coal-mines, that is to say, in equalisation of hours of work—as far as possible an equalisation downwards so that the miners bring less coal to the pithead than they do at present, and also so that this diminution may be everywhere equal. It is this idea which is found in the proceedings of the Royal Commission on the Coal Industry in Great Britain, whose report (1926) says : "If a common level of working hours, through the intervention of the International Labour Office or otherwise, could be agreed upon, it might be advisable to accept it, even if it meant some small increase here to meet part-way a decrease elsewhere." 1 The same considerations apply to wages. It is well known that the remuneration of human labour is a very considerable factor in the cost of coal production. Estimates vary according to the source ; but it may be said without fear of grave error that wages represent, according to- the country, from 45 to 76 per cent, of the cost price of coal. The share of wages in the cost price is here far greater than in any manufacturing industry. It is thus quite evident that in these conditions competition can be benefited in certain countries by very low wages, which means that it is at the expense of the standard of living of the workers that the economic triumph of the nation to which they belong can be achieved. Hence the importance of endeavouring to determine the possibilities of a standardisation of wages, considered from the following two points of view. In the first place, the point of view of the worker, that is to say, the worker's standard of living. It is here a question of determining an average wage which would enable the miners of all countries to have the same purchasing power and consequently to live everywhere in the same conditions. Secondly, the point of view of the employers. It is here a question of seeking to establish a wage per ton which, taking into account differences in the natural conditions in the various mines, in their economic position and their technical conditions, would enable an average wage to be found which would not be disadvantageous to any mining country as far as international competition is concerned. 1 Page 178. X Some have considered these ideas to be Utopian. Others, on the contrary, firmly maintain that they are sound and capableof realisation. But, above all, it is necessary to know if the differences existing in the various mining countries in the hours of work, or in conditions of remuneration, are so wide that they create, as it were, irreconcilable antagonisms, or are already somoderate that the means of reducing them to a common measure may reasonably be considered. Hence the idea, which the International Miners' Federation wisely suggested, of an international comparative enquiry. Hence, also, the factors of the enquiry which, at the request of the Federation, the International Labour Office has endeavoured to collect, and to elaborate in a manner capable of rendering them comparable,. or at least as comparable as possible. In order to conduct the enquiry in all security, it was necessary, in the first place, to decide on the methods to be adopted, that is to say, to assign a clear and precise definition to each of the data and then to draw up the rules which would render the statistics to be furnished by the Governments comparable,, if, as had to be anticipated, they were not comparable in the first place. In effect, the difficulty of agreeing on a definition of hours of work and of wages is great where miners working underground are concerned. What was t h e duration which was to be determined and compared ? The legal hours of attendance in the mine or the hours of attendance underground or the actual period of work, that is to say, the time spent by the worker at the coalface, after deducting rest periods ? With regard to wages, which were those which had to be compared to give satisfaction tothe suggested enquiry of the International Miners' Federation ? Wages per hour, wages per day, or wages per year ? Or, further,, nominal wages in the currency of the country, or gold wages,. or real wages, or wages per ton ? A.nd, in the second place, once the choice had fallen on one or other of these factors, it was necessary to decide on the method which would ensure that in all districts each of them would be understood in the same way. The differences in the methods; applied in thejvarious mining countries for the calculation of the hours of work of the underground worker were soon noticed and it is only after a long series of investigations that it has been possible to establish a common measure for the various. — XI — terms used for indicating the length of a shift. Similarly, in the case of wages, it was soon perceived that under the various terms enumerated above, different conceptions existed in different countries. For one region, for example, money wages were supplied in which allowances in kind, such as free housing, free coal, or coal at reduced prices, were not included ; elsewhere, on the other hand, these elements were included in the estimates of the workers' earnings. The same considerations apply to insurance contributions. The figures furnished by the Governments only took into account the contributions paid by the workers, but certain experts affirmed that the employers' contributions should be taken into consideration. All these questions (and only the most important have been indicated) had to be studied and settled by the Office for the purpose of determining the methods to be employed. The explanation of the methods will be found in Part One of this survey, in the form in which it was established, first provisionally, and then, after consultation with Governments, the organisations concerned, and the Committee of the Governing Body, definitively. Having thus fixed upon a method, which being approved by all should be understood by all, having a sure foundation for carrying out the enquiry, the Office passed to the second stage of the work, which was the collection of information. It proceeded with meticulous prudence. For this purpose, the Office addressed itself, as it constitutionally should, to the Governments of the countries concerned. But, whenever it appeared that the information communicated by the Governments might be challenged by the workers' organisations, because it seemed to be furnished exclusively by the employers, or vice versa, the attention of the Governments concerned was drawn to the matter, and if they maintained their original figures, the reservations made by those concerned have been expressly indicated in our survey whenever this precaution seemed legitimate. Once the data were assembled, they were co-ordinated, that is to say, in cases where the Governments had not taken the trouble to do so themselves, they were whenever possible made to conform to the definitions which had been adopted and are defined in the methodological study. Naturally, great difficulties in the work of examining and — XII co-ordinating this documentary information have often been encountered. However, the Office may claim to have attained the maximum of co-ordination and comparability possible with the statistics supplied, of which some are incomplete and others insufficiently exact. After the figures had been rendered comparable, the results were communicated to the Governments, to the organisations concerned, and to the Committee of the Governing Body, as was done after the collection of the original information, and it is only after having carried out all these consultations, whose results were taken into account in so far as was judged consistent with the interests of truth, that it was decided to] publish the results of the enquiry. If, even in the preface of this publication, the minute details, which some will perhaps find excessive, of the method adopted are thus emphasised, it is for the purpose of endeavouring to give to those who may consult it an idea of the extreme difficulties encountered in bringing it to a successful conclusion. Mining statistics are, among all industrial statistics, those which appear to be the most richly endowed with trustworthy material, which appear to be the most uniform and the simplest, and which appear to lend themselves most readily to an international comparison. And yet it is at the cost of long and minute labour that the Office has succeeded in extracting a certain number of data which are relatively comparable. This experience enables the difficulty of the work in connection with the international enquiry to be appreciated. What are the essential characteristics of this enquiry ? In the first place, it claims to furnish -statistics which, if not entirely comparable, are at least as comparable as the uncertainty and lack of precision of present statistics allow. It is necesssary to emphasise the relative comparability. In the second part of this report the essential results of the enquiry are given in tabular form. They are even summarised in a concluding chapter, at least in so far as they are really comparable. E u t the reader must be warned against the danger of hasty perusal and unjustified generalisation. The figures which appear in the tables must not be read and cannot be utilised except in the light of the abundant notes and comments added to the tables, otherwise the figures might be given an absolute — XIII — authority which, in many ways, they do not deserve. The same observation applies to the summary, however prudent and however carefully expressed it may be, which is given in the concluding chapter. The simple perusal of the tables and conclusions may produce a general effect on a hurried reader who wishes to acquire an approximate idea of the work. But, in truth, it is impossible to make any profound study in the matter, and especially to draw any practical conclusions without a thorough scrutiny of the report, which, in spite of a desire to be brief, simple and clear, could not be simplified or abbreviated to any great extent without failing to render justice to the matter which was entrusted to the Office and to the intentions of those who had so entrusted it. It will be noticed, moreover, that having had in the first place the intention of undertaking an investigation universal in space and very extensive in time, the Office was forced to restrict itself to considering, at least as far as the comparative study was concerned, only the principal coal-producing countries of Europe, and those only for the year 1925. Statistics which could be reduced to a common basis have not, in fact, been received from certain oversea countries. Certain of these countries have not even replied. However, for those which have replied, and for those which, like the United States, have already published certain of the information desired, the statistics have been summarised in a copious appendix (Appendix V) ; but it must be emphasised that these figures are not in any way comparable with those which have been utilised in the body of the report concerning the principal coal-producing countries of Europe, because in the form in which they were submitted it was impossible to utilise them and to reduce them to terms of the basic data adopted for the enquiry. It is therefore only in respect of the principal coal-producing countries of Europe (with the exception of Russia) dealt with in the body of the report that these figures may be used for any approximately accurate comparison. With regard to the limitation of our enquiry to the year 1925, it was imposed upon us by the three following facts. In the first place, whatever interest a comparison between the pre-war and post-war situations might have presented, it has not been possible to take the figures previous to 1914 into account, because they were not at all comparable, in the extent to which they could be supplied, with those which obtained for 1925. Secondly, — XIV — our enquiry dealt principally with the year 1925 because at the time at which the method had been determined, that is to say, towards the middle of 1926, the figures for 1925 were the most recent. Finally, the year 1926 was an exceptional one in consequence of the great coal stoppage in Great Britain ; and as for 1927, complete and trustworthy documents are not yet available. Consequently, the report only gives comparable statistics for a year which is already relatively remote, although in certain of the countries taken into consideration, the conditions of labour have been substantially modified since. In this respect, too, the Office has endeavoured to remedy the defect by giving in another appendix (Appendix IV) the statistics which it has been possible to compile for the year 1926, and even for 1927, for the countries considered in the main enquiry. But here again, it must be emphasised that these figures, furnished, as it were, in the crude state, and without being made comparable as were those for 1925, must not be compared with the latter. What is to be expected of the survey which is now being published ? In the first place, no doubt, that the International Miners' Federation and all those who are interested in the mining question will find, if not all the information desired, at least as much as can be assembled and presented in a comparable form in the present state of knowledge. To what extent the Federation will be able to use it for its purpose, it is impossible to say. But the International Labour Office may claim that by the thoroughness of its methods and the soundness of its results this survey is a sure starting point for more extensively developed and more fruitful researches. But such a study exceeds, if one may say so, the scope which was assigned to it by its promoters themselves. The difficulties— which will no doubt be even better understood after the perusal of the following pages—of an enquiry of this kind have been already mentioned. Unless one proceeds with the greatest prudence and with the assistance of a method arrived at after mature consideration, there is a risk of arriving at false conclusions and hasty generalisations. The method laid down may be used, with the necessary modifications, for the study of hours of work and wages in other industries. With regard to the coalmining industry itself, it is possible (and it is the earnest hope of the International Labour Office that this will be the case) XV t h a t it will incite the Governments concerned to use it as a basis in the future for the compilation of their statistics on an international and comparable foundation. It might be asked whether the method which we have laid down in this way might not form the subject of a discussion at a future Conference of labour statisticians specialising in mining statistics. This investigation might be considered as a beginning. It would be eminently desirable, now that the methods have been tested and already applied to the statistics of one year, that in the future, if not every year, at least periodically, an enquiry on the same subject might be repeated ; in this manner, the evolution of the essential conditions of labour in the coal-mines of various countries would be outlined in a series of periodic monographs. Doubtless if investigations and publications along these lines were continued, they might, at the same time, be extended to countries which, for reasons mentioned, remain outside the scope of the present report. In brief, the Office would proceed in this respect as it has already proceeded with success in the case of migration statistics. To show by means of permanent enquiries, periodically published, the changes and differences in the working conditions of different classes of workers is surely one of the most important duties laid upon the International Labour Office. Finally, this study is, only a part of a vaster study. The mining crisis mentioned at the beginning of this preface is a profound crisis, and one which concerns, directly or indirectly, all the countries of the world. This enquiry, if one may say so, is only an element in a more extensive enquiry which perhaps will one day be undertaken, which would not only relate to hours of work and wages of miners, but to all other working and living conditions, extending to questions of safety in the mines and insurance. And even an enquiry into working conditions completed in this way would be merely one of the fundamental factors of an exhaustive enquiry into the social and economic conditions attending the production and marketing of coal. Be that as it may, the International Labour Office emerges from this difficult task with the conviction which it has always had, but which this new experience has still further strengthened, that any international agreement, any Convention, must rest on a scientific knowledge of the problem which it aims at solving, that this scientific knowledge is difficult to obtain, but that it may be done by dint of patience and objec- — XVI • — tive methods. Above all, the close investigations of the working conditions of the miners in the various coal-producing countries. still further fortifies the conviction that if one day in the mining realm international agreements are instituted between merchants or between producers, they cannot be realised without taking into consideration the situation of the miners. CONTENTS PAGE PREFACE v P A R T ONE Methods of Compiling Statistics of Hours of Labour and Wages in the Coal Industry INPRODUCTION 1 CHAPTER I : Classification of Mine-Workers 5 CHAPTER II : Methods of Calculating the Hours of Labour . . . . 13 CHAPTER I I I : Methods of Statistics of Wages 34 PART TWO Results of the Enquiry into Hours of Labour and Wages in the European Coal Industry in 1925 INTRODUCTION 59 CHAPTER I : Hours of Work in the Europena Coal Industry A. D a t a B. Conclusions in 1925 64 64 71 CHAPTER II : Wages in the European Coal Industry in 1925 . . . A. Composition of the Total Wages Bill. B. Distribution of Total Wages Bill among Different Classes of Workers C. Manshifts (Days) Worked D. Manshifts (Days) Lost E. Number of Workers Employed F. Comparison of Average Earnings Expressed in Terms of Gold G. Comparison of the Average Purchasing Power of Average Earnings H. Total and Average Output of Coal I. Comparison of the Average Labour Cost per Ton of Coal 74 75 120 130 137 CONCLUSION : Summary 143 of the Results 85 88 93 97 103 XVIII APPENDIXES PAQE A P P E N D I X I : Methods of Calculation, and Limitation, of Hours of W o r k in 1925 in European Countries Belgium Czechoslovakia France Germany Great B r i t a i n Netherlands Poland Saar 157 157 158 159 161 162 163 165 166 A P P E N D I X II : Methods of Compiling Statistics of Wages in the Coal-Mining Industry in E u r o p e a n Countries . . . . Belgium . Czechoslovakia F r a n c e and t h e Saar Germany Great B r i t a i n Netherlands Poland 167 167 169 171 172 175 176 178 A P P E N D I X I I I : Method Employed for Calculating Purchasing Power of Average Earnings 181 Relative A P P E N D I X IV : Changes in Hours of Labour a n d Wages in t h e Coal I n d u s t r y of European Countries from 1925 to 1927 . . Introductory N o t e . p 31 185 185 A. Hours of Work Germany Great B r i t a i n Poland 186 186 188 189 B. Wages Belgium Czechoslovakia France Germany Great B r i t a i n Netherlands Poland Saar Territory 189 189 194 198 201 209 213 217 222 XIX PAGE A P P E N D I X V : Hours of Labour and Wages in the Coal Industry of Non-European Countries Preliminary Note 228 228 A. Hours of Labour Canada India Japan Union of South Africa United States 229 229 231 232 235 235 B. Statistics of Wages Canada India Japan Union of South Africa United States of America 242 242 249 250 257 261 PAKT OM METHODS OF COMPILING STATISTICS OF HOURS OF LABOUR AND WAGES IN THE COAL INDUSTRY INTRODUCTION § 1. In undertaking an international enquiry into the conditions of labour in the coal-mining industry, attention is chiefly concentrated on two connected problems, viz. the problem of hours of labour and the problem of wages. There are no other problems which concern both the welfare of the workers and the interests of the employers as closely as these. The question of the reduction of hours has long been one of the principal labour problems discussed in the coal industry ; and although it has been settled, to a greater or less extent, in many countries by legislation, it has remained in others, as recent events have amply shown, a matter of primary importance. The wages problem, although of more recent origin, has gradually become as momentous, and even dominant ; being more sensible to industrial fluctuations, more directly connected with economic competition, and more likely to provoke social strife, wages, without doubt, form the crucial point in the satisfactory regulation of labour conditions existing in the coal industry at the present time. A third problem, that of holidays with pay, is apparently of minor importance and may conveniently be dealt with as a part of the problem of wages. Since the hours of labour and wages determine, to a great extent, both the standard of living of the workers and also the production costs and the competitive capacity of the industry, i — 2 — international comparisons on these subjects have always been recognised as useful. They are of outstanding interest in the case of the coal-mining industry. Not only is this trade one of the basic factors of modern industry, but the coal industry of the different countries is eminently interdependent. Consequently, the differences in the labour conditions prevailing in the various coal-producing countries have accentuated the economic competition in the international coal market, and, inversely,. the international rivalry has created-, in certain coal-producing countries, economic difficulties which, in turn, have affected adversely the conditions of labour. The recent years of the "coal crisis" have thus rendered an international enquiry into the working conditions of the coal industry particularly desirable. The establishment of international comparisons on the subject of hours of labour and wages has proved a particularly difficult task. To the ordinary problems of these statistics, the special conditions of the coal industry add others, which are peculiar to this trade. In order, therefore, to avoid superficial and misleading conclusions, and to construct a rational and uniform basis for comparisons, it will be necessary to analyse carefully the methods of compiling statistics of hours of labour and wages. The purpose of the following chapters is to study these problems on general and theoretical lines 1 . At the outset, it will be convenient to determine the character and object of the statistics concerned. § 2. The particular and rather complicated character of the labour conditions in coal-mining is ultimately due to the fact that the industry is dependent, much more than manufacturing industries, on natural conditions. These natural conditions vary enormously from coal-field to coal-field, and even from mine t o mine. The coal-seams vary from place to place in respect of thickness, jointing, inclination, and frequency of faults ; t h e pits vary in depth ; the roofs and floors of the roadways vary in firmness and dryness ; the work-places vary in their size, lay-out, distance from the shaft to the face ; and the coal itself varies in quality. Nor are these geological factors the only causes of variety. The use of machinery and explosives, the methods of ownership, the scope of mining. legislation, the concentration of the mines in large undertakings, 1 The methods employed in the statistics of various countries aresummarised in Appendixes I (hours) and II (wages). — 3 — the combination of coal-mining with other industries, and, finally, the distance from the market, all these circumstances influence, in a varying degree, the' technical and economic conditions under which the mines are working. As a consequence, the number of units of labour required to produce a given quantity of coal is bound to vary almost indefinitely from coalfield to coal-field and from country to country. It would seem, therefore, that in fixing the conditions of labour, particularly wages, allowance is to be made for the natural and economic difficulties with which coal-mining is confronted. The price of coal competing in the same market is not in direct relation to the relative labour cost of production, to labour conditions prevailing in any particular district or country, and to other similar factors. "Competitive equality" of the coal industry then requires that hours of labour and wages are regulated in such a manner that the cost of production and transport of coal of a similar quality would be approximately equal. Natural and economic conditions vary, price is uniform ; hence, other things being equal, different wages are paid for similar work in the various coal-fields and countries. Although it would be impossible in practice to adapt labour conditions to the natural and economic conditions, it has undoubtedly tended to influence the mine-owners' point of view in the regulation of the conditions of labour in the coal trade. On the other hand, however, these factors are to some extent counterbalanced by other tendencies. The regulation of labour conditions is also influenced by the standard of living which the workers have reached. Work in the coal-mines, requiring more than usually hard effort, engendering a very high degree of occupational risk, performed by workers and teams independent of each other, has created among the miners a particular "natural craft" which has developed powerful industrial organisations. Their influence has made itself felt both in collective bargaining with the employers and in the activities of the State, which has intervened effectively in the regulation of the conditions of work of mining by means of limiting hours of work, enforcing safety regulations, fixing minimum wages, instituting conciliation boards, etc. These developments have tended to bring about a standardisation of labour conditions in coal-mining, and to modify the "competitive equality" in the direction of fixing in each country a more or less equal standard of labour for the different employers. _ 4 — § 3. The above general considerations may be sufficient to indicate the principal causes which underlie the complex questions relating to the hours of work and wages in the coal industry, and which render the international comparisons of these labour conditions extremely difficult. The statistics of hours and wages are, however, not directly concerned with these questions. The study of the circumstances which have determined the hours of work and wages, as they are in actual practice, is beyond the scope of the statistics. The various economic and social factors upon which the actual state of things depend are taken for granted : the statistics record, but do not explain, the existing variations and differences. Nor do they explain the consequences which might emerge from the existing conditions ; it is for the institutions and organisations concerned with the trade to draw the practical conclusions. The real object of the statistical study is confined to the devising of correct and uniform methods with a view to the determination of the average hours and the average wages ; and also to establishing inter-regional and international comparisons of the data obtained on the basis of these methods. In order to comply with this object, three main statistical problems are t o be examined and solved. There is first the question, important in view of the varying natural conditions, of an adequate classification of mine-workers, a preliminary question which is common to both of the other matters. Secondly, the methods of determining, on a uniform basis, the hours of labour are to be analysed. The third problem is that of statistics of wages, considered, on the one hand, as an element in the standard of living of the workers, and on the other, as a factor in the labour cost of production. CHAPTER I CLASSIFICATION OF MINE-WORKERS § 1. The general object of the classification of workers evidently is to show the structure of the "human factor" engaged in the productive process ; in statistics relating to conditions of labour the task of the classification is to provide an adequate basis for the comparison of wages. In the coal industry such a classification is all the more necessary as the operations involved are extremely numerous and varied. The working of the mine requires, in fact, the employment of many crafts other than mining properly so called ; the nature of the work varies from simple manual processes to the utilisation of highly developed machines. Average hours or average wages of all mine-workers in any district or country would have little real significance ; hours of Work and wages are determined by different factors, and are established by different methods, for the different groups of workers. The principal criterion of the classification of mine-workers is the personal occupation. By personal occupation is meant "speciality of work", or work connected with one of the numerous tasks involved in coal-mining. Apart from this classification, and subsidiary to it, there are classifications according to other criteria, especially sex and age, which are of importance mainly from a social point of view. § 2. Prior to any detailed classification of occupations, however, there is one general distinction based on the place of work, which is observed in all statistics relating to labour in coal-mines. This distinction is that between underground and surface work. The particular characteristics of labour conditions in coal-mines which have been indicated above, apply mainly to underground workers ; the tasks involved in surface work are — 6 — to a great extent comparable with those in other industries rather than with the work underground in the mine. The nature of the work of these two groups is indeed so different that any statistics concerning mine-workers must start from this distinction. It is, for the reason of its obvious simplicity, the only classification which is similar in the statistics of the several countries. International comparison of the conditions of underground and surface work is feasible in the sense that these two terms mean the same thing everywhere ; and for some statistical purposes it may be considered sufficient. As regards hours of work, more detailed classification, although desirable, is not indispensable : hours of labour are fixed by legislation or by collective agreement with a view to the equalisation of the daily and weekly period of work for all underground and surface workers, whatever their occupation. However, this general equality is confined to the ordinary length of the shift or to the "hours of attendance" ; owing to the different natural conditions, the "hours of actual work", or the period which the worker is at his place of work, are bound to vary to some extent for the different categories of underground workers. The case is more obvious as regards wages. As has been pointed out, wages present much greater variations than hours, and these variations are due not only to different natural conditions, but also to different kinds of work done in the mine, and arc particularly conspicuous as between occupations. It seems, therefore, necessary to carry the classification beyond the primary distinction between underground and surface workers. § 3. The basis for the occupational classification of underground workers may be obtained from a broad view of the different operations involved in coal-mining. The first general group of tasks — and the most important — is "work at the face". Different methods are used for mining coal, and a particular difference is due to the use of explosives and machines. However, while these save labour and increase efficiency, they cannot be employed everywhere, since natural conditions still render the hand-pick method more practicable, or inevitable in numerous places ; it may be also that aversion to new methods sometimes restricts the introduction of machines in coal-mining. The extent of the use of explosives or machinery thus varies considerably from coal-field to coal-field, and the aggregate amount of coal obtained by hand-cutting and by — 7 — machine-cutting varies in the different countries *. After the coal has been broken up, it is loaded or filled into "trucks" or "tubs". The loading, again, may be effected either by hand or l>y mechanical "conveyers". Finally, work at the face requires ""timbering", that is to say, putting in props of timber to support the roof when necessary, and "stone driving", i.e. cutting away the stone and earth—operations which are necessary for ensuring safety and possibility of further cutting of coal. Connected with this latter kind of operation, but independent of the work at the face properly so called, is the work of planning and repairing roads in order to open new coal-seams. This "work requires the setting up of new timber to support roofs, "ripping" the roof, floor, and sides of roads, taking down parts of roofs, "digging" up floors, etc. Another class of operations underground is that connected writh the transport of coal to the surface. The tubs loaded and filled at the face are pushed by hand or drawn by ponies to sidings, where they are coupled and drawn either by horses or mechanical means to the shaft bottom. From there the tubs are hauled to the surface. Beside the above three main kinds of work, there are in the mine several "auxiliary tasks", viz. : the general supervision of the work ; the supervision required by the safety regulations of the different arrangements, such as timbering, tram lines, machinery, cages ; the work connected with ventilation, lighting, pumping of water, etc. It will be seen that coal-mining involves numerous operations other than coal-getting properly so called, and it is extremely difficult to arrange them into a clear system of grades. The difficulty lies in the fact that the division of labour has been developed to a different degree and depends on different geological conditions and local customs in the various coal-fields and countries. The methods of payment of wages are dependent on these diverse systems of work, and the level of wages is largely influenced by these methods. The most obvious and necessary distinction would be that between hewers (abatieurs, Hauer) or coal-getters properly so called and other underground workers. Hewers form in all coal-fields the basic occupation, both from the point of view of the skill required, and that of the number engaged, which, 1 In the United States, two-thirds of the total amount of coal produced is cut by machines ; in Great Britain, only one-seventh. — 8 — however, varies enormously, according to the natural conditions and according as the assistants of hewers are included or not. Moreover, from the point of view of the method of remuneration, hewers also form a separate group, for they are mostly employed upon piece-work basis, while other workers are largely employed upon time-work basis ; exceptions are, however, to be found in both groups. If then the class called "hewers" really represented workers doing everywhere the same kind of work, it should be taken as the basis for the comparative study of labour conditions in coal-mining. In fact, however, this is not possible. How far the work of hewers actually extends, and where the work of other occupations begins, is difficult, if not impossible, to establish as a general rule. In certain districts hewers perform not only the operations connected with actual coal-getting, but also those of loading, filling, timbering, and stone driving, not only at the face but on roads cut in order to promote access to a new coalseam or to a different part of the same seam ; in this case they have other semi-skilled or unskilled labourers under their control. In other cases, again, especially where the employment of machines has pushed the division of labour farther, a hewer's task is confined to actual coal-getting only, and other work is performed by skilled and semi-skilled craftsmen. Hence a "hewer" does not mean the same thing in different countries and districts. The various other occupations connected with the work at the face form a very heterogeneous group. They perform, as a rule, loading, timbering, stone driving, etc. The most important of these occupations, found in the terminology of the various statistics, are as follows : putters, fillers, trammers, drawers, pushers, reddsrnen, drillers, trunkmen, timbermen, stonemen, -rippers, brushers. All these are skilled or semi-skilled occupations, but are assisted by unskilled labourers. A discussion of the differences existing in the various districts as regards the number of operations done by special craftsmen would lead too far. A small special group may, however, be distinguished from others, namely, the group of "deputies", "firemen", "examiners", etc., who are responsible for the safety of mines. But even this group is not perfectly uniform ; for instance, timbering at the face, usually done by the coal-getter, or by a special timberman, is sometimes done by the "fireman" or "deputy" 1. As a rule, 1 In the Northumberland and Durham districts of England. — 9 — these are regarded as under-foremen or officials, and they are not directly connected with the work at the face. The remaining occupations consist of semi-skilled or unskilled workers, mainly concerned with transport, haulage, and various machines. The number of these occupations is large, and includes, for instance, pony putters, hauliers, men engaged in mechanical haulage, engine-men, onsetters, rollingwaymen, blacksmiths, pumpmen, motormen, masons, etc. To attempt a comprehensive classification of all these numerous occupations would be a very difficult task. The remarks made above in respect of hewers apply here too : a given occupational term does not actually cover the same kind of work in different districts. As a matter of fact, there hardly exists any detailed occupational classification of underground workers which would be applicable to more than one or a few connected coal-fields. To try to reduce the various occupations into a few distinct groups would be equally difficult. Some such attempts at grouping have, in point of fact, been made. The following classification made in the statistics of wages published in Great Britain may serve as an example * : I, II. Coal-getters (distinguished according to the method of wage payment). III. Putters, fillers, hauliers, and trammers. IV. Timbermen, stonemen, brushers, and rippers. V. Deputies, firemen, and examiners. VI. Other underground workers. All these groups, however, are composed differently for different coal-fields, especially classes III, IV, and VI, which are extremely heterogeneous and hardly afford any reliable comparison ; this classification has, therefore, not been generally accepted in Great Britain. The same remarks apply, also, to other similar attempts at grouping. § 4. The group of surface workers is, as pointed out above, of less importance than that of underground workers. Their case is, from the point of view of statistical classification, somewhat simpler ; but here, too, the number of crafts is considerable. 1 F I N L A Y A. GIBSON : A Compilation of Statistics of the Industry of the United Kingdom, p. 140. Cardiff, 1922. Coal-Mining — 10 — The operations performed on the surface of a mine are largely analogous to work in a factory. There are cages by which coal is hoisted from the shaft to the surface, weighing machines, unloading machines, machines for sorting and washing coal, boiler rooms, power plants, blacksmiths' shops, machine shops for the maintenance and repair of locomotives, cars, tools and machines, railroads, etc. These different plants and shops require, of course, a number of different crafts on the surface. It is needless to enter into a detailed description of these various occupations. The British classification mentioned in the preceding section groups these above-ground workers as followsx : I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. Winding enginemen. Enginemen other than winding enginemen. Stokers and boilermen. Pitheadmen. Persons on or about screens. Tradesmen (i.e. mechanics, joiners, blacksmiths, and other skilled workers). Other surface labour. This list shows the principal classes of surface workers in coal-mines. But the above brief classification is obtained by sacrificing to some extent the clearness of the terms. Classes VI and VII especially are extremely composite and do not provide a basis for any trustworthy comparison so far as wages are concerned. Moreover, even this classification has not been taken into general use in Great Britain. The observations made above in the case of underground workers thus arjDly also to surface workers. § 5. The above brief review of occupations of coal-mining shows that at present statistics relating to labour conditions in this industry are greatly handicapped by lack of adequate occupational classification. Such classification, while particularly important in view of the great variety of occupations, is extremely difficult to obtain, owing to different natural conditions and different local customs and usages which cause variations in the division of labour, in the terminology employed, and in the real meaning of the several occupations, even when these are designated by the same term. The fact is, as has been pointed 1 FINLAY A. GIBSON, loc. cit. — 11 — out above, that no existing classification fulfils the requirements of a standard classification. In these conditions, it would be desirable to select a few basic occupations which, while not characterised by the same "speciality of work", may nevertheless be taken as representative of important and distinct groups of mine-workers.. For the purposes of international labour statistics, the principal point of interest is related to the labour conditions (hours and wages) of workers of a given "industrial position", rather than the conditions of "Workers engaged in a specified job. A classification of mineworkers in some typical industrial groups would in any case render better results- than comparisons relating to the whole of underground and surface workers, to which the present mine statistics are mainly confined. § 6. Statistics concerning labour conditions require, apart from the occupational classification, a further distinction of workers according to sex and age. Coal-mining being known as one of the heaviest and most hazardous industries, the extent to which female and juvenile labour is employed in it presents great interest. As a matter of fact, the employment of women in coal-mining was one of the most conspicuous social evils in early industrialism ; at present, however, the use of female labour underground is legally prohibited in most countries. Similarly, children were previously generally employed to the detriment of their health, but modern legislation has gradually fixed a minimum age of admission to employment in coal-mines. Juvenile labour is, however, still very general ; boys are often employed underground as assistants to skilled workers. Above ground both juvenile and female labour is employed in various occupations. In order to elucidate the extent of this part of coal-mine labour, it would be desirable that the statistics distinguish between male and female as well as between adult and juvenile workers. It is to be noted in this connection that the term "juvenile worker' ' is defined in a different way in the different countries. The age limit varies, in fact, from 16 to 21 years. In view of the definition of the juvenile worker given in the Washington Draft Convention concerning the night work of young persons employed in industry, it would be desirable that all countries indicated separately the number of workers under 18 years of age. So long as this is not done, an adequate international — 12 — comparison would require the classification of juveniles into two or three age groups, e.g. workers under 16, those between 16 and 18, and those between 18 and 21 years of age. In the case of wage statistics, however, such standard classification would in some cases be misleading. Wages are not paid in direct function of the age, but in relation to the task performed by the worker. In certain cases adults whose efficiency is below the normal level are employed as "juveniles" ; in other cases, workers below the general age limit may receive adult wages. Thus the real problem of comparison is the difference, not between wages received by workers under and above a fixed age limit, but between "juvenile rates of pay." and "adult rates of pay' ', the age limit being different in different periods, different occupations, and different countries. CHAPTER II METHODS OF CALCULATING T H E OF LABOUR HOURS § 1. For certain categories of workers employed in coalmines the hours of work problem has certain special features of its own. The hours of surface workers may in most cases be considered similar to any other workers employed in industry, but the position is different for underground workers, who work under special conditions. The exact determination of their working hours is difficult, and when international comparisons are to be made, the obstacles to be overcome, if not insuperable, are at least very serious, and for the following reasons. In the first place, as has been shown, there is great variety in underground work, and to each form of work there is a corresponding special class of worker. Secondly, the working day of ' the miner is divided into several stages. On reaching the pit-head each worker checks in and is then at the disposal of the undertaking. He puts on his working clothes, goes to the opening of the shaft, and, after more or less of a wait, enters the cage which takes him down to his work (in some mines the level is reached by a gallery). He finally arrives at his working place either by foot or by some form of mechanical transport. At the working face he makes the necessary preparations and begins to work. His work may be interrupted for meals or breaks, or because the conditions of working require it, e.g. blasting, waiting for tubs, materials or tools. At a given time he stops work and returns to the surface in the same manner as he left. He takes possibly a bath, dresses, checks out, and ceases to be at the disposal of the undertaking. — 14 — The miner's working day therefore comprises : (a) a period at the surface at the beginning and end of the day; (b) a period underground made up of (i) the time needed to go from the surface to the working face and back, in which time a distinction may be made between the descent, the journey from the shaft bottom to the working face, the return journey to the shaft, and the ascent, and (ii) a period of work at the working face interrupted by breaks. Finally, work in mines is carried out by shifts of workers, and its duration may be calculated for the whole shift or for each worker taken individually. It follows that the difficulties of determining and comparing the hours of underground workers are due to : (a) the many categories of workers, (b) the several stages in the working day, and (c) the need of calculating the hours of work for a shift and not for one worker. An examination of these various factors gives results which differ widely not only from country to country but from coalfield to coal-field and from mine to mine, owing to differences in the equipment of the undertakings, the number of workers in each shift, the distance of the working face from the shaft, etc. § 2. If the object of the statistics is to be fulfilled and hours of work in coal-mines are to be compared internationally, factors that can give data offering the maximum of accuracy must be defined, in spite of differences of regulation, terminology, custom and method of working. This involves, first, considering the groups of workers in the mines, then on this basis making distinctions according to the categories of workers, and finally defining hours of work and the units of measurement to be used. § 3. With respect to the groups of workers, it should be observed t h a t when the employment of women and young persons is allowed in mines, their hours are usually subject to special regulations. These particular cases will not be considered here, and we shall examine only the hours of work — 15 — of adult male workers. Even for the latter, however, the term "miner" has been seen to be very wide if it is taken to cover all workers employed in a coal-mine. In spite of the distinctions established in the previous chapter, only two special groups will be distinguished here — surface workers and underground workers. Owing to the many different kinds of work carried out aboveground there are many categories of surface workers. From the point of view of determination of hours of work, however, there is much similarity between these different forms of work, despite their diversity and particular nature. For this reason the enquiry will cover surface workers in general. For underground workers, on the other hand, the question is whether the different categories should be distinguished, or only a typical category examined : the workers engaged in hewing for instance, or all employed at the working face ? The last group has been chosen for the present enquiry, as it makes it possible to extend the investigation to the largest number of workers employed in almost identical conditions. The distinction between the different categories of underground workers would take us too far. The results obtained would no doubt give interesting information, but would have little practical importance. There are, no doubt, several exceptions in the case of hewers. As a rule, instead of keeping to fixed hours, they sometimes work more, sometimes less than other underground workers. They may be the first to descend and the last to ascend, etc. But it is impossible to take these special cases into account in an international comparison, which cannot lead to practical results unless it is pursued on more or less systematic lines. In view of the particular conditions of work inside the mine, it is also necessary to define for underground workers the particular place at which their hours of work are to be determined. Two distinctions are called for : (a) the interior of the mine itself where the worker spends the greater part of the day, so that it is of most interest from his point of view ; (b) the place of work where activity in the mine is concentrated, and which from the point of view of output is of most interest to the undertaking. — 16 — The inside of the mine comprises all that part of the undertaking which is situated underground. The working-place is the place where the worker engages in his particular occupation. This may be near the shaft if he is a eager, or a t the working face or stall of he is a hewer or loader, or it may be the roads between these two points if he is a haulier or labourer. The place of greatest interest, and the only one to be considered here as it covers the largest numbers of workers and is directly connected with the problem of output, is the working face, the furthest point within the mine, •whose distance from the shaft varies with the state of the undertaking. § 4. The idea of hours of work in coal-mines is complex and may be considered from different points of view. The tendencies of the present economic system favour the standardisation of hours of work not only for all workers in an undertaking, but also for all workers employed in one branch or even in competing branches of an industry. The conception of hours of work is thus governed by factors applying to all workers in respect of their occupation (for instance, the time from when the worker enters the undertaking to when he leaves it). All the work performed in an undertaking is not alike. Even if, as is proper, individual exceptions due to special circumstances are left out of account, the present system of division of labour in industry still means that the so-called "work" period includes periods during which the worker is not directly engaged in production. Undoubtedly it is the object of economic management to reduce such periods to a minimum, and in the large majority of industries they have become very small and even insignificant. In certain industries, however, the technical processes themselves make such periods unavoidable. The coal-mining industry is one in which this problem arises. At the present day a coal-mine covers a wide area and employs many workers. For this reason a distinction may be made hetween the definition of hours of work for the two groups of workers already specified, surface workers and underground workers at the face. For surface workers, the reasons already put forward suggest that it will be sufficient to determine the working day, or period during which they are at the disposal of the undertaking, and the hours of actual work less breaks. — 17 — For underground workers, the brief description of the workingday already given enables a distinction to be made between "various aspects of the idea of hours of work. These will now be •examined and only those chosen which are of real importance to the worker or the undertaking, while at the same time lending themselves to international comparison, that is to say, those capable of evaluation with the least degree of uncertainty. (a) There is first the total period spent in the mine, which begins when the worker checks in on entering and ends when he checks out on leaving. It is, in fact, the period during which he is at the disposal of the undertaking. This period is very important from the social point of view, and is of particular interest to the worker as largely determining the amount of his spare time. On the other hand, it is difficult to estimate, and it varies very much from place to place. It may include the time spent by the worker on operations before the descent or after the ascent 1 , or it may not. On the other hand, it will include the varying time spent by the worker in going from the timekeeper's office to the pithead. There are, in fact, many kinds of special cases, and it may be added that this period is very seldom fixed by regulations, for these as a rule determine only the length of the shift. (b) The length of the shift (in French : durée du poste ; in German : Schichtzeit) is the usual measure of the hours of work of underground workers in coal-mines. It is a part of the total period spent in the undertaking, calculated sometimes for each worker individually, sometimes for the whole shift collectively. In the first case (individual calculation) it represents approximately the period spent by the worker underground and therefore -corresponds to the period from when he leaves the surface to descend until he returns after the ascent (from bank to bank). In the second case, that of collective calculation, the length of the shift is determined in various ways according to the method of allowing for the descent and ascent. It will be shown later that it is possible to relate the collective length of shift to the individual shift, and therefore to determine the length of time spent by the worker in the mine. This measure of the miner's hours of work is very important to him, for it corresponds exactly to his working day as fixed 1 The time spent in changing clothes and bathing varies considerably, imd may make an appreciable addition to the length of the shift. 2 — 18 — by regulations. This is, in fact, the reason why it may be determined very accurately, as its elements are given by the regulations. (c) The length of the shift, or time spent in the mine, is not necessarily equal to the hours of actual work at the place of work, i.e. the period during which the hewer, for instance, is working a t the face (in French : chantier d'abatage ; in German : vor Ort). As a rule, the hours of work at the face correspond to the length of the shift less (i) the time needed for the worker to go from the surface to his place of work and back, and (ii) all breaks' and. stops. This period is of great interest to the undertaking, as being an important factor in production, and it should therefore be given consideration. The question is whether it can be determined with precision. To do so, all the factors of which it i& made up should be exactly estimated. These factors, as already explained, are the period spent in the mine, travelling time,. breaks and stops. Three of these, the time spent in the mine,. travelling time and breaks, may be determined exactly, but the loss of time inherent in the very conditions of the undertaking,. such as that due to preparatory work, blasting, waiting for trucks,. material, etc., varies from place to place, nor can it be strictly determined. This is an essentially variable factor which cannot. be determined in practice and does not satisfy the demands of statistics. Hence it becomes necessary to abandon the idea of calculating the actual hours of work at the face and to retain only those factors which can be exactly estimated, namely, the time spent in the mine, travelling time underground, and breaks. The time spent in the mine less travelling a time will be described. here as the time spent at the face. If the breaks are deducted, the basis of estimation will then be what will be called the time spent at face less breaks. Obviously this period does not represent the hours of actual work at the face. If the time spent in the mine is denoted by X, the time spent at the face less breaks by Y, the travelling time by a, and the breaks by b, the following formula is obtained : Y = X — (a + b) 1 In certain mines the travelling time, particularly the time spent on returning to the shaft may be. prolonged by the practice of delaying the ascent until all the workers have been collected at the bottom of the shaft. These are exceptional cases, however, limited to mines^ where the ascent is not organised on rational lines and the system is merely traditional. — 19 — To obtain exactly the hours of actual work at face, which may be called A, Y would have to be reduced by a period Z, representing the various losses of time which, as already explained, vary with the undertaking. The formula would then be : A = Y —Z or A = X — (a + b + Z) As Z is very variable and difficult to calculate, it will be left out of account here, and only the relatively fixed and comparable figure Y (time spent at face less breaks) will be retained, no attempt being made to define A (hours of actual work at face). To sum up, three calculations may be admitted in theory : that of the total time spent in the mine, that of the length of the shift, and that of the actual hours of work at face. In practice, however, these three calculations are not of equal importance for purposes of international comparison, nor is it equally easy to determine them with exactitude. The present study will therefore relate only to two factors : the time spent in the mine, and the time spent at face less breaks. The latter gives an approximation to the "actual hours of work at face", which cannot be determined exactly. § 5. It is finally necessary to determine the units of time best suited for measuring hours of work. The usual measure of the hours of underground workers is admittedly the shift. As a rule, in industry, the measure of a worker's hours is his working day, and the regulations of the various countries on this point are fairly uniform. In mines, calculations based on the shift serve the same purpose as those based on the working day in other industries. But in mining too, the working day also constitutes a measure of hours of work, sometimes combined with the shift. For instance, according to the German Ordinance of 21 December 1923, "the length of the shift shall be deemed to be the statutory working day in coal-mines". It might be pointed out that the length of the shift and the working day are not identical. The worker may, for instance, work overtime in excess of the shift and in countries in which several shifts are worked, he may even work more than one — 20 — shift a day (in French : poste supplémentaire ; in German : Nebenschicht). In both cases the working day will be longer than the shift. If extra shifts are worked, the statistics add them to the normal shifts worked in the period under consideration. If overtime is worked, the statistics show the amount of overtime reduced to the equivalent number of normal shifts. In neither case is the amount of overtime per day shown. It should be added that in the coal-mines of certain countries (for instance, France, Belgium) such extra shifts are the exception, affecting as a rule only a relatively small proportion of the total number of workers, so that nominally the workers work only for the normal length of the shift. There are other countries, on the contrary, where overtime is regularly worked and may be equivalent to several shifts a month. These will be taken into account and added to the manshift. It is equally unjustifiable to distinguish between the working day and the shift in cases of short time, for in coal-mines the introduction of short-time does not usually mean a reduction of the shift in such a way that the working day becomes shorter than the normal shift, but shifts are withdrawn instead. Since for the purpose of this comparative study it is necessary t o know in the first place the average hours of work, and since this period is equally well expressed by the working day and the length of the shift, the identity of the two ideas may be accepted. Thus the terms "working day" and "length of the shift" (in French : journée de travail ; in German : Schichtzeit) will be taken to mean the same thing. The working day or shift thus taken as a measure of the miner's hours of work is not the only one acceptable. The working week may also be used. This measure has the advantage of throwing light on cases in which the working week is regularly reduced because by custom or regulation all the working days of the week are not worked, or on certain days (as a rule, Saturday) the shift is generally shortened. Obviously such cases should not be left out of account, for the situation is altogether different if the miners work 48 hours a week or 44 hours or less. The normal working week should therefore be calculated in terms of the working day, that is to say, the average working day should be multiplied by the number of working days in a week, account being taken of any regular reduction in the length of the shift on a given day. — 21 — On the other hand, it is considered unnecessary here to use the working week for calculating an average working day. No doubt it would be possible in cases of an eight-hour working day with a six-hour day on Saturdays, to calculate the working day as j - = 7 hours and 40 minutes, which would be a relatively exact average. But in doing so the nominal length of the other days of the week would be placed in the background and the enquiry would be based on a figure less representative of the facts. From an international point of view such cases are exceptions, and it seems more expedient to keep to the working day or the shift as recorded for the different countries, with a reference to the length of the working week calculated as indicated above. § 6. Most countries have now compulsory regulations for all wage-earners in the matter of hours of work. It follows t h a t a distinction must be made between the period during which the worker should work, or statutory hours of work, and the period during which he actually works, or actual hours of work. The statutory hours cannot be left out of account altogether here, as their determination and the comparisons to which they lead are interesting in themselves, and in particular they indirectly facilitate the study of actual hours. Hours of work may be fixed either by official regulations or by collective agreements. In the first case, the official regulations may be in the form of an Act, Order or Decree, and according to the end in view will be general or apply specially to mining undertakings and coal-mines, or solely to one class of workers, for instance, underground workers. When hours of work are governed by an Act, the regulation usually applies to the whole country, that is to say, to all employers and all workers. When they are governed by a collective agreement, the regulation as a rule applies to a more limited area, most often the mining district, and covers only the contracting parties. The provisions of laws, like those of collective agreements, may apply to all the principal forms of hours of work. They may cover surface workers and underground workers, fix the working day and the working week, the length of the shift and the manner in which it is calculated, the last a very important point in practice. The actual hours of work may be determined from statistics, but if the latter are insufficient, or compiled in different ways, — 22 — making comparison impossible, the statutory hours should serve as the basis for determining actual hours of work. The regulation of hours of work is, in fact, of capital importance. Obviously there may be a difference between the statutory and actual hours of work. The statutory hours may either not be worked in full or be exceeded (in certain cases illegally). It will be remembered, however, that in modern industrial States regulations are adopted not by one party alone, but after negotiations and mutual concession between the interested bodies, whether it is a case of concluding collective agreements or enacting legislation. Thus in practice it may be admitted, especially in countries where inspection is effective, that statutory and actual hours of work are the same. Both legislation and collective agreements, where these exist, are therefore used in determining actual hours of work. Moreover, the texts of laws and collective agreements define the expressions "length of the shift" and "working day". The precise significance of the expressions used in order to estimate the hours of work, can therefore be determined for each country or district so that only figures based on the same interpretations may be compared. The determination of the working day of surface workers does not as a rule raise any difficulties. Undoubtedly the fact that the hours of work include breaks in some countries and not in others may lead to confusion. It is not necessary to repeat that the comparison must be solely of hours of work excluding breaks, which should therefore be deducted where possible. § 7. For underground workers it has been assumed so far that their working day or length of shift corresponds approximately to the period spent underground., This may vary from country to country and from district to district, according to the method adopted for measuring it. The length of the shift may be calculated for each worker taken individually or for a group of workers (shift, or part of a shift) taken as a whole. In the first case (individual calculation) the shift begins as a rule when the worker enters the cage to descend and ends when. he leaves it at the completion of his work (from bank to bank). If the shift does not exclude the descent or ascent of the worker, the time spent on this operation may be considered negligible, as will be shown below. — 23 — In the second case (collective calculation) there are two alternatives. Either the group in question comprises only workers descending and ascending in the same cage, or else it comprises workers using several different cages. The first of these alternatives may be taken as equivalent to the case when the hours of work are calculated for the individual worker. For if a certain number of workers regularly travel together in the same cage it is in practice almost indifferent whether the length of the shift is calculated for each individual worker or for all of them together. Even if the cage has several decks, the time spent in loading and unloading and in the descent and ascent is so short that it may be neglected. For purposes of theoretical accuracy, however, this factor should also be taken into account, as will be discussed under § 13. The most frequent case is the calculation of the length of the shift for a group of workers representing several cage-loads. This case corresponds as a rule to the collective calculation of length of the shift for the whole shift. In this case the length of the shift may be determined in three ways : (a) It may be counted from the time the first worker of the shift enters the cage to descend until the time the last worker leaves it on ascending. (b) It may be counted from the time the first worker of the shift enters the cage to descend until the time the first worker ascends, or, which comes to the same thing for the present purpose, from the time the last worker of the shift descends to the time the last worker leaves the cage on ascending. (c) Finally, it may be taken from the time the last worker descends to the time the first worker ascends. In the first of these cases the total length of the shift includes jboth the descent and ascent of the whole.group of workers; in the second it includes only one winding time, the descent •or ascent ; in the third, it excludes both descent and ascent. Clearly, if the length of the shift is nominally eight hours, the term "eight hours" will mean something different in each, of the three cases, in spite of the apparent uniformity. § 8. The length of the shift calculated individually (which, as explained, corresponds to the length of the shift calculated for a single cage load) may now be compared with that — 24 — calculated collectively for the whole shift, representing several cageloads. If the time needed for the loading and unloading, descent and ascent of a single cage is considered negligible asin the previous case, the following results will be obtained for each of the three cases mentioned above. (a) If the length of the shift is calculated for the whole shift from when the first worker enters the cage to descend until the last worker leaves it on ascending, the period from the time a particular "worker enters the cage to descend until he leaves it on ascending; on the completion of his work, represents only a part of the total length of the shift. There are two possibilities : either the •workers enter and leave in the same order, or they do not. In the first case it is obvious that the time from when any workerenters the cage to descend until he leaves it on ascending, is less than that from when the first worker in the shift entera until the last worker leaves. In the second case, it may be supposed that the first worker entering the cage is not necessarily the first worker to leave it, and may even be the last, and conversely that the last worker to enter may be the first toleave. This gives the notion of an individual minimum period,. measured from the time the last worker enters the cage to> descend until he leaves it on ascending, being the first to do so,. as also of an individual maximum period, measured from when the first worker of the shift enters the cage to descend until he leaves it on ascending, being the last to do so. Only this. individual maximum is equal to the length of the shift calculated. for the whole body of workers. It may be added that these theoretical possibilities can have no practical influence on this enquiry, the object of which is to compare the average length of the shifts. For if the workers come up in the same order asthey go down this average is a part of the actual length of the shift for the whole shift. If the order is not fixed, the averagelength is represented by the arithmetical mean of the minimum and maximum periods mentioned above, and this mean corresponds also to the actual length of the shift when a fixed order is observed. It follows from the above that a length of shift which, calculated for the whole shift, is eight hours including the two winding times, will not mean the same thing as a shift of eight hours. calculated individually for each worker from bank to bank. If the length of shift for the whole shift taken collectively is. — 25 — to be eight hours, the length for each worker in the shift individually will be less than eight hours, and the difference between the two will be equal to the time spent in winding by the other workers of the shift. This may be made clear by an illustration. Suppose t h a t the shift calculated collectively, including the descent and ascent of the whole shift, begins at 6 a.m. and ends at 2 p.m.,. the first worker will enter the cage to descend at 6 a.m. but on ascending he must leave it early enough for the last worker of the shift to be able to leave exactly at 2 p.m., i.e. the first worker must leave sufficiently before 2 p.m. to allow time for the whole shift to leave. Similarly, the last worker to enter the cage would enter it at such a time after 6 a.m. as to have allowed all the other workers to descend. Finally, if we consider the case of a worker in the middle of a shift, he will enter the cage sufficiently after 6 a.m. to allow the workers preceding him toenter before him, and leave sufficiently before 2 p.m. to allow the workers following him to leave. These two periods added together correspond to the time spent by the shift either on descending or ascending, which, as already explained, comes t a the same thing. It may thus be said that the length of shift calculated for the individual worker from bank to bank, is equal to the length of shift of the whole shift taken collectively from the beginning of the descent until the end of the ascent, less one windingtime. (b) The next case is that when the length of shift is calculated for the whole shift, either from when the descent begins until the ascent begins, or from when the descent ends until the ascent ends. In other words, in this case the length of the shift is measured from the time when the first worker enters the cage to descend, until the first worker enters the cage on ascending or (which comes to the same thing), from when the last worker descends until the last worker ascends. The discussion of the previous case will show that here the length of the shift for the whole shift taken collectively corresponds to the average length of the shift for each worker taken individually. It does not matter whether the period is measured by the time the worker enters the cage on descending and ascending or by the time he leaves it, in view of the fact that the actual time of descent and ascent of the cage is considered negligible. — 26 — Thus the length of the shift for the whole shift calculated from when the first cage descends until the first cage ascends or conversely, i.e. the collective length of the shift comprising one winding-time is equal to the average length of the shift {of each worker taken individually) from bank to bank. (c) The third case is that in which the length of the shift begins when the last worker enters the cage to descend, and ends when the first worker leaves it on ascending. Thus it includes neither descent nor ascent. The previous argument shows that in this case the average length of manshift, i.e. for each worker taken individually, is greater than the length of the shift calculated collectively, the difference being equal to one windingtime. The only exception would be the extreme case when the last worker to enter the cage on descending is the first to leave it on ascending. To return to the illustration already used in the first case, it may be assumed that the collective shift begins at 6 a.m. and ends at 2 p.m., the last worker descending at 6 a.m., and the first ascending a t 2 p.m. Then the first worker to enter the cage must do so sufficiently before 6 a.m. to enable the last worker to enter at 6 a.m., that is to say, to allow for the time needed for winding the whole shift ; and on leaving the last worker to ascend will leave the cage sufficiently long after 2 p.m. to have enabled the whole shift to be wound up before him. If it is assumed that the first worker to enter the cage to descend is also the first to leave it on ascending—the average case—it will be clear that the length of the man-shift from bank to bank will be equal to that of the shift calculated collectively, plus one winding-time. Without discussing in further detail the theoretical relation between the length of the shift calculated for an individual worker, and that calculated collectively for a certain group of workers which is smaller than the total shift of workers, it may be stated that the above considerations concerning the relation between the lengths of the shift calculated individually and collectively for the whole shift, apply here also, subject only to the remark that the time to be added to, or deducted from, the collective period will be shorter than for the whole shift in proportion as the group is smaller than the shift. § 9. The different methods of calculating the hours of work for underground miners, have been discussed in detail. In the — 27- — light of these definitions, it will be comparatively easy to relate these methods of calculation to each other. But if these data for the working day are to be compared, a common unit for the terms "length of the shift" or "working day" is needed, to which the various interpretations of the terms in use in different countries and different mining districts must be reduced by the methods indicated above. Now, the purpose of this enquiry is to compare the average hours of work of miners, and this average should therefore be adopted as a common unit. It should be understood that the data to be supplied relate to the average length of a shift, i.e. of a shift calculated for a worker individually from the time he enters the cage to descend until the time he leaves it on ascending, his actual time spent on descending and ascending being considered negligible. In cases where the hours of work of underground miners are calculated on different bases, the preceding considerations will give the means of relating the period to the unit adopted here, provided that in each particular case the winding-time is known. It will then be sufficient to subtract or add this time according as the total length of the shift for the country or district in question includes or excludes both descent and ascent. The figure adopted for the time of descent or ascent will be only an average, and therefore approximate. The regulations often provide for a maximum winding-time but this varies from one mine to another, depending as it does, among other factors, on the number of workers, and also on the degree of technical advancement of the mine. For if in certain mines the workers can use simultaneously several shafts and several cages with many decks, the time spent on descending and ascending will be much shorter than in other mines without such conveniences, even if the number of workers employed is much smaller. These methods will make it possible to obtain comparable data on the length of the shift or the working day of underground miners. § 10. The time spent at the face, less breaks, corresponds, as already explained, to the period spent in the mine, or the length of the shift, reduced to a common unit, less travelling time and breaks. The method to be used for determining the principal factor has just been explained. The interpretation of the terms "travelling time" and "breaks" remains. — .28 — The time needed by an underground miner to enter the mine, go to his stall, and then return from his stall to the shaft and ascend to the surface \ constitutes the time spent on the underground journey, or travelling time, and must be deducted from the length of the shift as defined, if it is proposed to obtain the time spent at the face. Now this time is variable. Sometimes the vein worked by the miner is only a few minutes away from the shaft, sometimes it is several miles away, and both cases may occur in one and the same mine. In one case, there may be mechanical means of transport for all or part of the journey from the shaft to the stall (electric railways, paddy mail, etc.), in another, the journey must be made on foot. All these factors influence the time spent on the journey, to be deducted from the length of manshift, in order to determine the time spent at the face ; and it therefore becomes necessary to calculate an average period corresponding to the category of workers considered. § 11. The time spent at the face includes breaks, and here, too, there are wide differences. Certain regulations provide for fixed breaks, during which work is suspended for the whole mine or for certain categories of workers. It is easy to deduct such periods. In others no provision is made for fixed breaks, but the worker does in fact interrupt his work to rest, for meals, etc. Sometimes an arrangement is made to have these interruptions at the times when the worker would in any case be bound to stop working. This holds, for instance, in undertakings where blasting is used, and where the workers are compelled to stop after each explosion until the fumes have been dissipated. As a rule, the inspectors' regulations prescribe that explosions must be followed by a stop in the work. But in this case, in accordance with the distinction made between breaks properly so called, and the stops inherent in the conditions of the undertaking, such losses of time can be taken into account only in so far as they correspond to the normal period of the breaks. properly so called. § 12. Thus the time spent in descending and ascending, which is considered negligible here, the time needed for going from the shaft to the working place and back, and breaks, all of 1 As already stated, the time spent on the actual descent and ascent is considered negligible for the purpose of this enquiry. — 29 — which periods are calculated individually, must be deducted from the length of the shift calculated individually, in order to obtain the time spent at the face less breaks. For these three periods, an average estimate must be obtained, applying either to the -whole country under consideration or at least to each important mining district. Only in exceptional cases is it possible, owing to the smallness of the mining district concerned, to estimate them exactly by definite investigation and calculation. Generally, it is necessary to approximate. In districts where a fixed break is prescribed, only this should be taken into consideration, otherwise an approximation must be used and an average break per worker be indicated. It is necessary to ascertain, however, whether the length of the shift or working day as fixed includes breaks or not. If not, there is obviously no occasion to make any further deduction. As a result of all these inevitable approximations, the data concerning the time spent at the face less breaks are less valuable than those on the length of the shift or the working day. It may be assumed, however, that the errors due to such approximations will be similar and of a similar order of magnitude for all the countries covered by the enquiry. There will thus be a certain equality between the degree of error. As an international comparison can be only relatively exact, comparisons of the data concerning the time spent at the face less breaks may be permitted, provided that to obtain these data does not meet with insurmountable difficulty in certain districts. § 13. It may be interesting from the theoretical point of view to carry this method of calculation somewhat further, and to deduce mathematically exact rules and establish formulae. In the first place it should be noted that, save in altogether exceptional circumstances, the worker never goes about alone. He enters the cage, or one of the decks of the cage, with other workers. Hence the time spent on loading and unloading the cage, which has so far been considered negligible, is not entirely so. The actual winding of the cage also takes some time. So far the time spent on these operations has been considered negligible because it seemed of an order of magnitude which, in practice, did not involve appreciable error *. 1 In point of fact, these operations take from four to six minutes, according to t h e size and number of decks of t h e cage. In exceptional cases, the figure m a y be higher. — 30 — It would, nevertheless, be interesting to know the effect of the relation between the lengths of the shift taken collectively and individually already indicated, if a value, however small, is attached to the time spent on a descent or ascent, and on loading and unloading. For this purpose, we may take the average worker in the middle of the descending or ascending group, and in the middle of the group entering one and the same cage. If it is remembered that the length of the shift or of the shift taken as a whole (reduced to a common unit) is the time from when the worker enters the cage to descend to when he leaves after the ascent, it will be clear that when he enters the cage, half of the group which enters with him have still to do so before the descent can begin, and when he has arrived at the bottom, he will similarly have to wait until half of the group have left the cage before he himself can leave. The same applies to the ascent ; in other words, the time from when the worker enters the cage to descend until he leaves it after the descent, comprises the time needed for half a loading, the time of the descent properly speaking, and the time for half an unloading. If the times of loading and unloading are considered equal, the total period comprises one loading (or unloading) operation and the actual descent. The same applies to the time from when the worker enters the cage to ascend until he leaves it after the ascent. To simplify the explanations below, the terms "descent" and "ascent" will be taken in a wide sense so as to include, with the actual descent and ascent of the cage, also the time needed for a loading (or an unloading). As regards the collective descent or ascent, it may be recalled that this includes the time from when the first worker of the group enters the cage to descend or ascend to when the last worker of the group leaves after the descent or ascent has been completed. Once the time spent on loading and unloading is taken into account, there is no longer occasion to consider separately the case of a group of workers who descend together in one journey of the cage, and that of a group of workers whose transport involves several j ourneys for the cage. In both cases, the calculation is collective. In the first, the waiting time before the average worker enters or leaves the cage will comprise only the time for half a loading or unloading. In the second, it will also include the time needed for the journeys of the cage effected before that in which the average worker takes part. — 31 — § 14. It remains to examine the relation between the length of the shift calculated for a group of workers and that calculated individually according as the collective shift includes both winding-times, or only one of these, or excludes them both. (a) In the case when the collective shift includes both windingtimes, the average worker will in theory be in the middle of the shaft half-way through the descent. He will therefore have left the surface a certain time after the beginning of the collective shift equal to half the time of the collective descent plus half the individual descent, that is to say the time from when he entered the cage to when he passes the middle of the shaft. On the return, half-way through the collective ascent this same worker will in theory be in the middle of the shaft. He will, therefore, arrive at the surface a certain time before the end of the shift, equal to half the time of the collective ascent plus half the individual ascent, that is to say the time from when he passes the middle of the shaft to when he leaves the cage. Thus the time spent in the mine is equal to the length of the shift less half the time of the collective descent plus half the individual descent on the one hand, and less half the time of the collective ascent plus half the individual ascent on the other hand ; that is to say it is equal to the length of the shift less the time of a collective journey (winding-time) plus the time of an individual journey. If the length of a shift comprising both descent and ascent which begins at A o'clock and ends a t B o'clock is denoted by P x ; the period of the collective descent (or ascent), that is to say, the winding-time for the collective journey, T ; the time spent on the individual descent (or ascent), that is to say, on an individual journey, t; and the length of the individual shift or the whole shift reduced to a common unit X, the following results are obtained : T (1) At the middle of the collective descent, i.e. at A -f- -» o'clock, the average worker will be at the middle of the shaft, and he will therefore have entered the cage a t T t A + -K — -O o'clock ; T (2) At the middle of the collective ascent, i.e. at B — -^ o'clock, this same worker will be at the middle of the T t shaft and will leave the cage at B — "5 + "2 • — 32 — His individual shift X is measured by the time from when he •enters the cage, i.e. A + -» — -» o'clock, until he leaves it, T / T í i.e. B — "2 + "2 • fr *s therefore equal to B — -» + -s ~~ {A + ^ — 1). Therefore X = B — | + -| - A - -^ +{ = B — A — T + f, and as B — A = P l s therefore : X = P x — T + t. (b) If the length of the collective shift includes only one winding-time, a similar line of reasoning will show that the length of the shift of the average worker is equal to that of the collective shift plus the time of an individual journey. If in this •case the length of the collective shift is called P 2 , we have the following result : X = P 2 + t. (c) Finally, if the length of the collective shift includes neither of the winding-times, the length of the shift of the average worker is equal to that of the collective shift plus one winding-time plus an individual journey. If in this case P 3 represents the length of the collective shift, t h e n X = P 3 + T.+ t. To sum up, if the length of the collective shift includes both winding-times, X = P x — T -f- t. If the length of the collective shift includes only one windingtime, X = P 2 + t. If the length of the collective shift excludes both windingtimes, X = P 3 + T -f t. § 15. These formulae may be combined with that given for the calculation of the time spent at the face, less breaks. The value of Y (the time spent at face less breaks) is given by the following formulae, in which a, representing the time from hank to bank, consists of t, the individual descent, s the time from the bottom of the shaft to the working face and also the time from the working face back again to the shaft, t the individual ascent (therefore a = It -\- 2s), and in which b represents t h e breaks. If the length of the shift includes both descent and ascent, Y = P X — T + / — 2t — 2s — b =P1 — T — t — 2s — b. If the length of the shift includes only the descent (or ascent), T == P 2 + t — 21 — 2s — b = P 2 — t — 2s — b. — 33 — If the length of the shift includes neither descent nor ascent, •Y = p 3 + T + í — 2i — 2s — b = P 2 + T — f — 2s — fc. These formulae have many advantages. They are mathematically exact and take into account all the factors which are -clearly defined and separated. The only risk of error lies in their -determination. In every case, whether the calculation is individual or collective, they enable the length of the shift reduced to a common unit, or the time spent in the mine, and the time spent at the face less breaks to be exactly determined. The results obtained are perfectly comparable. As there is no difficulty in using the formulae, the various administrative bodies concerned may easily employ them in preparing their statistics. CHAPTER III METHODS OF STATISTICS OF WAGES § 1. The statistics of wages involve, in the first place, the calculation of average wages. The method employed for this calculation consists, in its broad lines, in a simple operation of division. The dividend is the total wages bill of workers employed in a given district or country during a given period. The divisor may be chosen differently according to the various objects in view : it may be the total number of hours or days worked during the period under review ; or the total number of workers employed ; or also the quantity of output in the period. In the statistics relating to coal-mining, the determination of these different elements gives rise to a series of rather complicated problems. The composition of wages, the number of days worked and workers employed, and even the total output of coal produced, all may be conceived and calculated differently. In order to obtain uniformity and thus to render comparisons possible, it will be necessary to examine in detail each of these different elements of the wage statistics. § 2. The first problem to be analysed is the composition of the wages bill of coal-mining undertakings. As a consequence of the particular conditions of work and the variety of occupations found in coal-mining, the methods of wage payment are also different from those commonly prevailing in most other industries. The usual system of employment on the time-work basis is not practicable in the case of most underground workers,. since the workplaces are scattered over a large area and an efficient supervision of the work is difficult. Hence the dominant method of payment underground is the payment of piece-rates,. although time-rates also are to be found. Hewers and allied occupations are, as a rule, employed directly by the mine-owners on the piece-work basis. It may be noted — 35 — that hewers do not always work alone and independently of each other. In some districts and countries they themselves employ an assistant to whom they give a share of their own earnings ora day-wage ; the wages of these assistants are included in the hewer's gross earnings and are deducted from these either by the mine-owner or, especially in the case of boys, by the coal-getters who themselves pay their assistants. In other districts and countries, again, hewers are working in teams, the total wages of which are paid by the employer and then shared among the miners themselves according to the function of each member of the team. Apart from hewers, loaders, and their assistants, other occupations, e.g. men engaged in making and repairing roads, are generally—though not invariably— employed on the piece-work basis. The wages of these groups of workers are fixed by schedules of rates (called "price-lists" in England). These piece-rates are extremely complicated. In their determination allowance is made for, or, in mining terminology, "consideration" is given to, the numerous different operations with which the underground workers are charged, and also to the different natural conditions which have been indicated above 1. For this reason, the pay-sheets of underground workers employed on piece-work contain a very large number of different entries which are far from being similar in the various districts and countries. Time-wages are sometimes paid to hewers, either to certain specific classes of them, or for certain kinds of work performed by them beside actual coal-getting ; a considerable part of their labourers are also in receipt of time-wages. The importance of this circumstance is shown by the fact that it is customary to divide coal-getters, and also their assistants, into two groups, according as they are employed on a piece-or time-rate basis. Employment on the time-rate basis is the ordinary system for the certain superior and auxiliary crafts underground, such as foremen, engineers, men charged with the supervision of the safety and lighting arrangements, workers engaged in transport and haulage of coal, etc. ; and the same applies to the majority of surface workers. In general, it may be said that the employees receiving time-wages comprise, on the one hand, certain superior classes and, on the other hand, the bulk of unskilled labour 1 Cf. Chapter I, § 3, pp. 14-16. — 36 — employed in and about the mine. The proportional number of these workers in any mine depends largely on the favourable •or unfavourable conditions of mining. The larger their number, the heavier is the wages bill to be borne by the output, and the less favourable are, consequently, the conditions of the workers •concerned. The very condition of the payment of time-wages is that the work is more or less standardised and can be supervised. Timerates do not vary when the kind of work or the natural conditions •change. They often show an approach to the principle that workers doing similar work are to receive a similar rate of pay. This does not, however, apply to all districts nor to all groups : the varying natural conditions may exercise a certain influence •on the variety of the wages of workers on time-wages. On the other hand, however, the composition of time-wages is rather simple as compared with the piece-rates. § 3. However, although there is a marked difference in the •establishment of piece-rates and in that of time-rates, there are some common features in their composition. Differences are to l e found in details ; but the broad groups of items are approximately similar. It is therefore unnecessary to examine the composition of piece- and time-rates separately on the basis of pay-sheets. A clear survey will be obtained by passing under review the general features of the total wages bill which, as experience from statistics published in the various countries shows, are similar for practically all the groups of workers and all districts. The term "wages" is here preliminarily taken in the largest sense, including income of any nature which workers draw from their employment in the mine, whether in cash or in kind. In calculating the wages bill of mine workers in this sense, four different groups of items are to be taken into account, namely : (i) Money wages paid on account of work done ; (ii) Deductions from these money wages ; (in) Allowances of various kinds, including payments for holidays, and (iv) Advantages drawn from schemes of social insurance. § 4. The first and most important group of items is formed hy wages in money. By "wages in money' ' are here understood wages paid in direct function of the amount of work done. They — 37 — are usually based on standard rates of wages. When, as is the case in several districts, the "basis rates" have been fixed years, or even decades, ago, and a given percentage increase, determined according to various methods, is added to them, then standard rates mean current rates, that is to say, the basis rates plus any increases. These standard rates comprise a number of items, especially in the case of hewers and other skilled workers who are paid piece-rates. Two different aspects are here to be distinguished, viz. work directly productive of coal and work incidental thereto. The largest single item involved in the cost of coal is the wage paid for the actual getting of coal (including loading) ; the rates of these wages are fixed per ton of coal cut, loaded, and weighed at the pithead ; but it is to be observed that they are sometimes also fixed per tram, tub, or mine-car. The variety of these rates will appear from the fact that the amount of "yardage" or the capacity of the tram, etc., is different as between mines or even in the same mine. As has been pointed out above, the standard rates per ton of coal produced reflect to a more or less extent the variations in the natural conditions and the methods of work in the different districts. Further to rates fixed for the getting of coal, the standard rates of wages include other items paid for work not directly productive of coal, the so-called "dead work". In order to meet unequalities arising out of adverse natural conditions, special rates are commonly paid for work connected with unremunerative or "abnormal" places which involve some extra work due to difficult conditions, handling of hard substances, etc. These rates are fixed per square or cubic yard or- metre, or also per mine-car, tram, or tub. These complications arising in the case of underground workers do not, of course, apply to workers employed on the time-work basis. Finally, it should be noted that the standard rates include both rates paid for work done during the normal hours of work and for that performed during overtime or supplementary shifts. This distinction, important in the calculation of average earnings per time unit, will be considered later. § 5. Before proceeding to an examination of further component parts of mine-workers' wages, it is necessary to consider a peculiar group of items called deductions. In all coal-mining districts the employers are entitled to deduct certain sums from — 38 — the workers' money wages as defined above. There are different kinds of deductions which, from the point of view of statistics of wages, are to be clearly distinguished. The three principal groups are workmen's contributions to social insurance, "occupational charges", and various penalties. (a) In most coal-producing countries, \ and especially in all European coal-mining districts, workers defray contributions to voluntary or compulsory schemes of social insurance. When they are compelled to contribute, the system of "prior deduction" (précompte) is often employed, that is, the employer deducts from the gross wages of each worker the contributions due by the worker and effects the payment on his behalf to the insurance institution. The actual amount of these deductions naturally varies with the structure of compulsory social insurance, which presents great differences as between the different countries. The principal fact to be noted in this connection is that these payments are made with a view to meeting, by a method which is financially the most advantageous to the miners as a group, the cost of certain risks to which they are exposed on account of their work. Although, then, the benefit which the individual worker will draw of this amount will depend on the occurrence of certain definite events (sickness, invalidity, unemployment, etc.), it is clear that it forms a part of their money wages. (b) Practically everywhere the employers are further entitled to make deductions for so-called occupational charges, that is to say, charges for powder and other explosives, checkweighing lighting materials, tools, sharpening of tools, etc. The reason for this is to be found in historic conditions : the miner has since olden times been supposed to furnish his own tools and working equipment, and when at the present time the employer has taken over the duty of furnishing them, he deducts their cost from the miner's wages. The practice of deductions, however, varies. In some districts explosives and tools are now supplied by the mine-owner free of charge and workers only have to pay for the deterioration or loss of tools. In some countries, again, the law forbids the employer to make deductions for tools, while those for explosives are authorised. Whether the deductions for occupational charges actually cover the cost of these materials or not is an open question which need not be discussed in this connection. As a matter of course, this item should be excluded from the money wages of the mine-workers. — 39 — (c) A third class of deduction are penalties for various types of misconduct and inefficiency, e.g. for loading dirty coal or for violating the labour contract in some way. The definition of "dirty" coal is subject to different interpretations, and so are also the other reasons for penalties. In principle, it is difficult to state whether this item should be included in the money wages to be taken into account in the statistics of wages, or excluded from the same. Some penalties no doubt are based on the fault of the mine-worker and are comparable with fines that any person may be compelled to pay from his income in virtue of existing orders or rules of contract ; other penalties may not be of this kind but are simply based on occasional inefficiency which, in the nature of the case, diminish wages. In practice the question is of small importance, and it seems, therefore, most convenient to put the penalties on the same standing as deductions for occupational charges, that is to say, to exclude them from the money wages of the mine-workers. What may here be called mine-workers' "gross money wages" is the sum of wages paid for work done plus an amount corresponding to contributions to social insurance. The "net money wages" include the wages based on standard rates less any deductions "whether made for social insurance or for occupational charges •and penalties. It is the amount paid on account of work done and placed at the disposal of the workers for their consumption during the period following the pay-day. § 6. Apart from money wages paid on the basis of work itself, additional payments are made in most districts and countries. These items are independent of the work done in the sense that they are not fixed, and do not vary, in direct relation with the efficiency or hours of labour of the worker. On the other hand, however, the period during which the worker has been in the service of the mine, the grade of the worker, and similar considerations generally are taken into account in determining the amount of the allowances in each individual case. Three different groups of allowances must be distinguished, viz. -allowances in cash, allowances in kind, and payments for holidays. (a) Allowances in cash were, before the war, of minor importance, but have since attained a considerable degree of development. The principal form of these payments is the family allowance, which plays an important part in the system — 40 — of wages of certain countries. Bonuses for the high cost of living, which are usually included in current rates of wages,, may sometimes appear as a separate item, especially when they are variable and when in their determination regard is had to considerations other than work done, e.g. family responsibilities. More exceptional are allowances paid for clothing,. good attendance, etc. (6) Allowances in kind form a regular feature in the composition of coal-miners' wages. The most general and important of these are housing accommodation and the provision of household coal. The housing accommodation, with or without land, may be given free of charge or at a reduced rate,. and the coal may similarly be granted gratuitously or at a reduced price. If the lodging and the coal are granted free of charge, then they generally do not appear in the miner's paysheet, but as they are really payments in kind they are to be added to the other supplementary payments. If, on the other hand, the lodgipg is let by the employer at a reduced rate and the coal sold at a reduced price, then the price actually paid by the worker may be deducted by the employer from the mineworker's wages and may thus appear in the pay-sheet like the deductions of insurance premiums. The supplementary payment to be taken into account in the calculation of workers' wages is in this case formed by the difference between the commercial and the reduced price. In practice it may often be difficult to ascertain the exact money value of these items. (c) A special payment, which in principle is not an "allowance", is the payment for holidays. The payments for holidays are fixed by law or by collective agreement in most, although not in all, coal-producing countries in Europe. This item naturally includes both payments for legal or contractual holidays as well as compensation for such holidays from which the workers have not actually benefited. § 7. Finally, workers draw in numerous cases a material advantage from various schemes of workmen's compensation for industrial accidents and of social insurance against industrial accidents, sickness, invalidity, old age, death, and unemployment. The question whether these advantages should in principle be counted in the aggregate wages of mine-workers is somewhat controversial. It is sometimes held that in common practice this item is not a part of wages properly so called — 41 — • but is comprised, in the accounts of the mining undertakings, as "cost of production other than wages". On the other hand, however, the essential purpose of the social services concerned is, according to the modern conception, to secure to the workersthe means of maintenance in cases of loss or reduction of their earning capacity or earning possibility, cases which [are inherent in industrial work and must be provided for in any adequate wage system : in the absence of collective methods of meeting these risks, wages of individual workers would have to be increased by an amount which would enable them to maintain themselves when unable to earn full wages. Hence the advantages. which the workers draw from these schemes form really a supplement to their wages. And if this is so, it is correct t o allow for this item in the statistics. The question presents, however, further difficulties, both theoretical and practical. It would seem natural, at first sight, to represent the "advantages" concerned, by the benefits actually accruing to the workers from workmen's compensation and social insurance. If this would be done, of course, workers* contributions, mentioned above should be deducted from. money wages in order to avoid double counting. This method, however, is not easily applicable in practice, since detailed statistics showing the benefits paid to the Workers employed in the coal industry are lacking in some important countries, and since such statistics as exist have a different scope from those relating to wages. Moreover, the method concerned is open t a criticism from the point of view of principle. It may be questioned, indeed, whether the total of advantages drawn from social insurance schemes are to be counted as an element in wages. The financial resources of the schemes of workmen's compensation and social insurance are secured by varied systems : the charges of industrial accident compensation and insurance are in most countries borne by the employers alone, those of other schemes are shared between employers and workers, and those of still others are apportioned between employers, workers, and the public finances (the State and communes). If now by wages are understood payments made by the industry to labour, it is clear that subsidies to social insurance from public funds should be altogether disregarded 1 . It would then be incorrect to take into 1 It is true that any industrial undertaking pays, by way of taxes, a part of the subsidies granted by the State or communes to social insurance. These subsidies thus represent a charge to industry, due to the employment of labour. In practice, howewer, it is impossible to value their amount. — 42 — account the total of benefits actually paid to workers, since some benefits include such subsidies. Therefore, the only method left is to estimate the sum of contributions paid out of the funds of the industry. This sum is bound to be considerably higher than the corresponding part of benefits, since it includes payments for the cost of administration, the reserve funds, and sometimes •even the prevention of risks. But as these expenses are incidental to any scheme of social insurance, the sum of contributions may be taken as representative of the advantage furnished hy the industry to the workers by medium of social insurance. In practice, the sum of contributions concerned is divided between those paid by the workmen and those paid by the employers. The former are to be allowed for, as pointed out above, in the calculation of the gross and net money wages of the "workers. The latter item of contributions, therefore, is to be added to the total wages bill. Its total amount can, as a rule, he ascertained from the undertakings which supply the statistical material ; but, owing to certain financial systems of social insurance, this information is sometimes only approximate or «ven defective. This reservation should always be borne in mind when comparing advantages which workers draw from social insurance. The above considerations are naturally subject to the acceptance of the general idea of social insurance as a complement to workers' wages ; and it may be well to repeat that this question is still an open one. § 8. The preceding paragraphs embody an attempt to analyse the composition of the aggregate wages of coal-mine workers. It is realised that this survey includes not only what the word "wages" suggests prima facie, but every possible source of wages and advantages which the workers receive by reason of their participation in the productive activity of the mine. As a matter of fact, three different conceptions of wages may be construed, for the purposes of the statistics of wages, from the above data. In the first place, the term "wages" may be taken in the somewhat loose sense in which it is commonly used With reference to manufacturing industries, as meaning the amount of money received by the worker on account of his services. In this sense the term wages only covers earnings in money (gains en espèces; Bar verdienst), i.e. what has been — 43 — called above "net money wages" plus allowances in cash. This method would, however, lead to unsatisfactory results, especially from an international point of view. The remuneration of workers in the coal industry diners in many respects from the system common in most manufacturing industries. Although the money wages form the principal item, their composition is more than usually complicated ; and although the remarks made above in respect of advantages provided by schemes of social insurance would be applicable to any industry, it is to be remembered that social insurance has developed in coalmining earlier than in most other industries and along special lines. Above all, the various deductions, supplementary payments, and allowances constitute in all coal-mining districts and countries quite a peculiar feature which influences the general level of wages to a considerable extent, and in a very varying degree in the different countries. A second conception of wages is represented by the term wages for normal work done (salaire à raison du travail normal; Leistungslohn). This notion represents the total amount paid to the workers in virtue of the standard rates fixed in collective agreements, and the wages based thereon render possible the control of the working of such agreements in practice. It includes wages in cash or in kind, on the basis of time-or piece-rates, paid for work done during the normal shift, as well as workers' insurance premiums. On the other hand, it excludes not only amounts deducted for occupational charges and penalties and all payments independent of the work done, but also all extra payments for supplementary work which may either be done in overtime hours or supplementary shifts. Wages for normal work done are less useful for international comparisons than for national purposes, since the object of international comparison of wages is to compare all elements in the standard of living of the mine-workers and in the labour cost of production of coal in various countries. Moreover, the wages for normal work done cannot, in practice, be ascertained for most countries. For these reasons it is proposed to adopt as a standard a third conception of wages which may be called the calculated actual earnings (gains effectifs; Gesamlverdienst) of the mineworkers. By this is meant here the whole amount of wages and other advantages received by the workers by reason of their employment in and about the mines. It includes the items as _ 44 — defined in the preceding paragraphs, viz. : net money wages, i.e. money wages excluding deductions for occupational charges and penalties ; workers' contributions towards expenses of social insurance ; various allowances in cash and in kind ; and payments for holidays. As regards, finally, employers' contributions towards schemes of workers' compensation and social insurance, it seems convenient, in order to do justice to the different conceptions which prevail, to calculate the sum total of "actual earnings", both including and excluding this element. This notion of the total wages bill will be used in the determination of workers' standard of living, and the same conception will be also taken as basis in determining, from the employers' point of view, the total labour cost of production of coal. § 9. A comparison of the total wages bills of the different districts and countries would, of course, be meaningless ; comparisons can only be made as between average wages of the coal-mine workers. The first important category of averages is that calculated for a given period of time. There are three principal measures of time in terms of which the average earnings may be expressed, viz. (i) the hour, (ii) the day or manshift, and (iii) a longer calendar period, e.g. a year. It should be noted, however, that these different averages have not the same bearing in the statistics of earnings. While the hourly and daily averages indicate what are the payments made for a given unit of work done, the yearly averages bring the earnings into relation with consumption. The objects of the statistics of earnings will evidently not be fully served unless all these different averages are calculated. The calculation of the daily and hourly averages, on the one hand, and of the yearly averages, on the other, give rise to several statistical problems. These problems have been solved in the national statistics in an extremely variable manner, but it is needless to enter into details in this connection 1. "What is necessary here is to arrive at some sort of standard definition of each average to which the national statistics may be adjusted with a view to international comparisons. 1 The methods employed in the statistics of various countries are discussed in Appendix II. — 45 — § 10. It will be convenient to examine at the outset the daily averages, for the statistics of earnings usually take the day or the shift as the principal time measure. Since the term "day" may lead to some confusion, it is preferable to take as basis the shift. The work done by one worker during a shift is called the "manshift" {poste; Einzelarbeiislag). The average earnings of a worker are expressed as per manshift (durée de l'équipe; Schicht). These averages are computed simply by dividing the aggregate amount of wages constituting the workers' actual earnings during a period by the total number of manshifts accomplished by all workers employed during the same period. It is now necessary to consider the calculation of the aggregate number of manshifts for a given calendar period, e.g. one year. There are two alternative methods of computing this number. The simpler method consists in recording the number of manshifts without taking into account their length ; in this case the number of manshifts is equal to the total of the days of attendance of the workers. The fact that the length of the shift is disregarded obviously is of no consequence, provided this length is invariable during the period under review. When, on the other hand, the shift is not of uniform length, considerable variations are apt to arise from the fact that during certain days or periods some crafts work only part of the day or, per contra, work overtime. It is, therefore, necessary to take as basis the ordinary or normal manshift, comprising the regular hours of labour only, and to record separately the hours worked, short-time, or overtime. The number of manshifts will then be constituted as follows : (a) the number of normal manshifts, i.e. those comprising the ordinary number of hours, plus (b) the number of supplementary manshifts, i.e. those accomplished, in addition to normal manshifts, by the workers who are working more than one shift per day, plus (c) the number of overtime manshifts, which is obtained by adding the number of hours worked overtime during the period under review and dividing this by the number of hours comprised in a normal manshift, so as to express overtime in terms of "normal manshifts" ; plus, finally, (d) the number of short-time (week-end) manshifts, which is ascertained by adding together the number of hours comprised — 46 — in the short shift and dividing this by the number of hours of the normal manshift ; this item is of importance, especially as regards manshifts worked on Saturdays, when these are considerably shorter than ordinary man-days 1. The difference between results as to average earnings arrived at on the basis of these two methods is obvious. It is to be remembered that, in the calculation of the average earnings, the dividend (amount of actual earnings) includes, according to the definition given above, also payments for overtime. If the divisor (number of manshifts) does not allow for overtime, as is the case when a manshift is taken as equal to a day of attendance, the result (average earning per manshift) will not be statistically correct. Full accuracy is only obtained if the divisor allows, further to normal manshifts, for overtime manshifts. As, moreover, overtime is usually paid at a higher rate than work during the ordinary shift, the latter method is to be considered as more satisfactory. The same applies, mutatis mutandis, to short-time. How far an appreciable error is introduced in the calculation of average earnings by neglecting the definition of the length of manshift, depends on the actual occurrence of work overtime and short-time. If no overtime or short-time is worked, then, of course, the employment of the simpler method would give satisfactory results ; but, if the length of the shift is irregular, the more overtime and the less short-time is worked the higher will be average earnings calculated according to that method as compared with the average arrived at by the more detailed process. § 11. As a measure of time in terms of which the average earnings are expressed, the shift is not altogether satisfactory. Owing to the fact that the number of hours worked during a shift varies as between different occupations, districts, and countries, the shift does not constitute a uniform basis for comparisons. Therefore, it seems clear that the only correct measure of time is the hour. However, as indicated in Chapter II, even to determine the hours of work meets with certain difficulties. In the case of underground workers, whether employed on piece-work or timework, the total time spent in the mine differs in a considerable 1 Short-time manshifts may also be counted as normal manshifts ; in this case the number of hours lost on account of short-time (expressed in terms of manshifts of ordinary length) should be deducted from the total. — 47 — and varying extent from the time actually spent in work : the time taken in descending and ascending, the time needed for going from the shaft to the stall and back, and breaks, vary widely according to the natural conditions and the habits of the mine-workers. Therefore, it appears necessary to take into account three different conceptions of hours of work, viz. : (i) hours of attendance, including travelling time and breaks ; (ii) hours of attendance, including travelling time, but excluding breaks ; and (iii) hours at face. If exact information is obtained as to these three factors, the calculation of the average earnings per hour can be made on the basis of average earnings per day or per manshift. The latter averages are simply divided by the average number of hours comprised in the day or in the shift. The average earnings per hour thus complement the daily averages, and their accuracy depends for the most part on the kind of information available for the calculation of average earnings per day or manshift» and for the hours of work. § 12. When the earnings are to be studied in their relation to consumption, the question is what amount is placed by the mine industry at the disposal of the workers during a given period. From this point of view, the day and the hour evidently do not form adequate periods. It is necessary to take as a further time unit a longer calendar period, e.g. a year. The basic measure of time in terms of which mine-workers' earnings are expressed evidently is the "year of consumption", which represents the period during which the workers consume the earnings at their disposal. This period naturally comprises Sundays, holidays, etc., as well as working days. The calculation of average earnings, however, only covers days of productive activity which exclude not only Sundays and holidays, but also such weekdays on which the mines have been idle. The difference may be considerable, for mines not infrequently are closed on some days of the week, or during some weeks of the year. These different conceptions of the year are introduced in the statistics of wages through the calculation of average yearly earnings. These averages are, of course, ascertained by relating the aggregate sum of earnings to the total number of workers employed during the year. An additional unit of calculation, namely, the number of workers, must therefore be determined. — 48 — The simplest method of calculating this number is obviously t o record the number of workers registered at a given date, say, 31 December of the year under review. In view of the fact that the number of workers employed varies more or less regularly according to the season and the state of the market, this method must be considered as wholly inadequate. There (i) (ii) These are left two other methods, namely : the calculation of the average number of workers, and the calculation of the number of full-time workers. will be considered in turn. § 13. The average number of workers employed may be obtained by recording the actual number of workers once or twice a month or on each pay-day, and by calculating an arithmetic average of the figures so obtained. If these selected days are really representative of the whole period, this method will lead to correct results ; but as a matter of fact the intensity of production in coal-mining is rather variable. This fact is taken into account in the methods which consist in recording the number of manshifts during the year and dividing the sum by the number of working days. It is, however, to be noted that in this calculation both the dividend (the number of manshifts) and the divisor (the number of working days) may be ascertained according to different methods. The methods of recording the number of manshifts worked have already been examined 1 . If the length of the shift is regular and invariable during the period under review, the number of manshifts is equal to that of days of attendance, and does not raise any difficulties ; if, on the other hand, overtime or short-time is worked, the correct way to calculate the total number of manshifts is that based on the ordinary or normal manshift, of definite length, so as to add to the normal manshifts, the hours worked in supplementary shifts, overtime, and short-time, expressed in terms of manshifts of normal length. In calculating the average number of workers, however, the problem has another aspect. In the first place, it is indifferent, from this point of view, whether the statistics take into account the length of the shift or not ; the number of days of attendance "will be sufficient. In the second place, if the total number of 1 Part One, Chapter II. — 49 — manshifts is calculated on the basis of the normal manshift as explained above, it is essential to eliminate the overtime and supplementary manshifts, because they are worked by the same workers as the ordinary or normal manshifts ; only normal manshifts are to be counted. It follows that, if the statistics calculate separately the number of normal and overtime manshifts, but the latter cannot be distinguished and deducted Jrom the total, an error is introduced in the calculation of the average number of workers. If no time were lost for any reason, and the mines were -winding coal every day on which work can ordinarily be done, the number of normal manshifts worked would provide an adequate basis for the calculation of the average number of workers. As was already pointed out, however, this is not the case. In a long calendar period the number of manshifts worked may not cover the whole possible working time. Now, when mineTvorkers lose some manshifts, their earnings are necessarily reduced ; on the other hand, the object which the calculation of average yearly earnings has in view is precisely to ascertain the amount of wages placed by the mines at the disposal of the workers for the whole year. Consequently, it is necessary to allow for the time lost ; and owing to the importance of this factor in coal-mines, special attention is to be given to the methods of calculating the time lost. In the first place, the dividend — the number of manshifts — may be modified by taking into account the number of manshifts lost. By this is meant manshifts occurring on ordinary working days (weekdays) during which workers regularly employed have not actually worked. The most important basis of classification of these manshifts seems to be the operation or otherwise of the mine. Starting from this criteria the following classification is arrived at : (i) Manshifts lost when the mines were idle owing to technical obstacles, industrial disputes, transport difficulties, or want of trade ; (ii) Manshifts lost when the mines were operating ; this time lost, again, may arise from two kinds of circumstances : (a) from mine-workers' voluntary absence, including absence on account of holidays with pay ; (b) from mine-workers' involuntary absence on account of accidents, sickness, etc. 4 — 50 — Incidentally, it may be noted that the lost-time is sometimes classified according to fault. Lost-time in group (i) in the above classification is generally caused by the establishment,. with one important exception, viz. strikes ; group (ii) could be referred to as including cases where the fault of lost-time falls. upon individual workers, except so far as industrial accidents and diseases are imputable to defective measures of prevention. Since it is, as a rule, difficult to establish the responsibilityfor disputes, accidents, etc., and this, moreover, is of no. significance in this connection, these distinctions have not been adopted in the above classification. If the number of manshifts worked and that of manshifts lost (as defined above) are added together, the sum covers the whole working time of the year. Consequently, in the calculation of the average number of workers, the divisor should be the total number of possible working days of the year, i.e.. excluding Sundays and public holidays. While this method is very clear in theory, it is less so in practice. In fact, how can the number of manshifts lost when the mines are idle be determined ? For that purpose, an average number of workers employed on the mine should already be given, while this number is precisely the unknown quantity searched ; and, furthermore, the assumption is to be made that the average number would have remained unchanged during the period. Therefore, it may be advisable to take into account in the dividend (the number of manshifts) only time lost when the mine was operating, and to allow for the other part of lost-time in the divisor (the number of working days).. This latter number may be determined as the number of days of productive activity, thus excluding days on which mines have been idle. The number of "days of productive activity",. or of days on which the mines have been actually operating, may also be ascertained according to different methods It may include either days on which mines wound coal ("coal winding days" ; jours d'extraction) or those days plus days on which mines were open but no coal Was raised. In practice,. however, this difference will not be very considerable. Another problem arises from the fact that days on which mines were operating only part of the normal hours (e.g. Saturdays) may be calculated, for the sake of simplicity, as full days. But if parts of days are taken as full working days, the time lost on account of the reduction of the day's work is neglected in the-. — 51 — calculation, since this fraction of time lost is taken into account neither in the number of manshifts lost (the dividend) nor in the number of working days (the divisor) ; this method is, therefore, likely to introduce an error in the calculation. Finally, it should be noted that since in a given country the number of days worked by the different mines varies, which again raises some divergencies in the statistics, it is necessary to calculate an average of days when mines were operating for a district or a country. The most adequate method of calculating this average is to weight the number of days worked in each mine by the number of manshifts worked in the same. It may now be well to summarise the three principal methods of calculating the average number of workers. (i) The simplest method consists of dividing the number of normal manshifts by the number of actual days worked. In this case there is a discrepancy between the logical basis of the dividend and the divisor ; the former includes only such manshifts as have been actually worked, whereas the manshifts lost when the mine was operating are left out of account ; the divisor, however, includes all days on which the mine was operating ; and thus implies that all manshifts which could be accomplished on the days during which the mine was operating are really worked. Therefore, the average number of workers calculated according to this method tends to be too low. (ii) A more exact method devised for this calculation consists of adding to the number of normal manshifts, in the dividend, the number of all manshifts lost ; and adding to the number of actual days worked, in the divisor, the number of days when the mines were idle ; the average number of workers is thus obtained by dividing the number of normal plus lost manshifts by the number of possible working days. This calculation is, however, open to criticism. The number of manshifts lost when the mines were idle is necessary for the calculation ; but it can only be obtained by assuming an average number of Workers for the coal-winding days ; and the number of manshifts lost when the miners were idle is simply the product of this average number and the number of idle days. (iii) Therefore, the best method of calculating the average number of workers is to divide the sum of normal manshifts — 52 — and manshifts lost when the mines were operating, by the number of days on which the mines were operating. The three figures required for this calculation can be, and actually are, in many countries, ascertained. § 14. The number of full-time workers (unités ouvrières; Vollarbeiter) is the second main consideration which may be used to calculate annual earnings. This number serves to show what the actual number of workers would have been if each worker had been regularly and constantly employed on the maximum number of working days, lost time being left out of consideration. It is a fiction to which the actual state of things approaches in a greater or less degree. The calculation of the number of full-time workers is therefore based on a stable element, namely, the time necessary to perform the normal amount of work. This element may be expressed in three different forms, viz. the number of wage periods per annum, the number of working days, and the number of manshifts which could have been worked, (i.e. shifts worked plus shifts lost). It follows therefore that there are three different methods available for calculating the number of full-time workers. (i) The first and most simple method of establishing this figure is, like the corresponding calculation of the average number of workers, based on the number of workers on the colliery books on pay-days. The number of full-time workers may then be ascertained by adding together the numbers of registered workers and by dividing the total obtained by the number of wage periods included in a regular year. (ii) A second method is to divide the number of manshifts worked by the annual number of working days. This latter figure is, of course, not strictly invariable, as the total number of holidays officially sanctioned or agreed upon does not exactly tally for the various districts, although such differences are .generally very small. (iii) The third system presupposes the calculation of the average number of workers, this figure being multiplied by the number of manshifts (days) worked and the result divided by the total number of manshifts worked plus manshifts lost. — 53 — The number of manshifts actually included in the last two methods may theoretically include either the number of regular manshifts only, or the total number of regular supplementary and overtime manshifts such as they have been already defined. In compiling wage statistics, the object of which is to establish the average wage of the individual worker, it is, however, advisable not to include supplementary and overtime manshifts as these are performed by the workers employed on regular manshifts, often with a view to making up for time lost by workers temporarily absent. It is manifest that the result obtained by employing the first of the methods mentioned (i) is only approximate. This method presupposes, in fact, that the number of workers has remained unchanged during the different wage periods, and that, consequently, all the possible manshifts between two pay-days have been worked, while, on the other hand, it is the number of manshifts actually worked which forms the basis of the other two methods. Further, the two latter methods give analogous results when the number of manshifts does not include supplementary and overtime manshifts as already defined. These two methods of calculation may be aptly illustrated by the following formulae. Suppose that Average number of workpeople employed . = a Number of manshifts worked = m Number of manshifts lost = n Number of possible working days = d Then, according to method (ii) the number of full-time workers is — > while according to method (iii) it is , which d m+ n m+n is equivalent to m -. a But, as may be considered as equivalent to the number a of possible working days, that is to say, d, the result is the same as that obtained by the other method. This, however, no longer holds if the number of supplementary and overtime manshifts is added to the number of normal shifts, as the extra manshifts increase m and m + n and consequently the result of the calculation in both cases, but in different proportions, as may easily be seen by means of the formulae given above. — 54 — On considering the relative merits of the three methods for calculating the number of full-time workers, the most satisfactory would appear to be method (ii) which consists in dividing the number of normal manshifts by the number of possible working days, as it is superior to method (i) from the point of view of accuracy and to method (iii) on account of its simplicity. § 15. It is obvious that the average number of workers and the number of full-time workers, obtained by the methods described above, must agree, provided that no manshifts or days have been lost for any reasons whatsoever. The differences observed in the results obtained when manshifts are lost may be brought out by giving an example taken from existing statistics. The figures available for Great Britain for 1925 show the following : BRITISH GOAL-MINING Number of days Days on which wound coal Days on which were idle . pits . . pits . . 252.8 STATISTICS FOR Number of manshifts Regular Overtime and reduced Lost 245,388,000 15,587,000 21,141,000 46,919,000 46.8 T o t a l possible working days . . . 299.6 1925 245,388,000 15,587,000 68,060,000 The average number of workers, which is based on the average of the weekly figures on the colliery books, is given as 1,040,500. When the average number of workers is calculated according to the first method, consisting in the division of the total of normal, overtime and week-end manshifts by the number of coal-winding days (§ 13, (i)), the result is as follows : (245,388,000 + 15,587,000) 4- 252.8 = 1,032,338 (1) In using the third method (§ 13, (iii)), which is given before the more complicated second method, the number of overtime and week-end manshifts is ignored, but the number of manshifts lost on working days is added to the dividend, the calculation then giving the following result : (245,388,000 + 21,141,000) ~ 252.8 = 1,054, 308 (2) — 55 — Finally, if the second method (§ 13, (ii)) be employed, it is «essential, first of all, to fix the number of manshifts lost when t h e mines were not operating, and then divide the sum of manshifts worked and lost by the total possible working days. The average number of workers obtained by this method then "works out as follows : (245,388,000 + 68,060,000) -j- 299.6 = 1,046,222 (3) It should be pointed out that, as result No. (2) is based on figures relating to days on which pits wound coal, it may be used to calculate the number of manshifts lost when the mines were idle. Logically it may indeed be admitted that the proportion between manshifts worked and lost would be the same in the period when the mines were idle as when they were working. The number of manshifts lost as a result of the non-working of the mines will then be 1,054,308 x 46.8 = 49,341,614 (instead of 46,919,000). Now, it is obvious that if this figure be utilised to calculate the average number of workers in accordance with method (ii), the result will be exactly the same as that obtained by using method (iii). As regards the calculation of full-time workers, two different methods, based on the statistics included in the foregoing table, may be used. If the method (§ 14, (ii)) of dividing the number of normal manshifts by the number of working days is used, the following result is obtained : 245,388,000 ~ 299.6 = 819,052 (4) With the other method (§ 14, (iii)), which is based on the total number of manshifts worked and lost, the result is : (245,388,000 + 15,587,000) x 1,040,500 ~ (245,388,000 + 15,587,000 + 68,060,000) = 825,275 (5) It will thus be seen that the number of full-time workers is considerably less than the average number of workers calculated according to all the methods set forth above. §16. The average earnings per year may be obtained by •dividing the aggregate amount of the workers' earnings by the average number of workers calculated according to one of the above-mentioned methods. The average earnings calculated on the basis of methods in which account is taken of lost manshifts, are intended to show the "actual earnings" of an average worker. It is clear from the foregoing discussion — 56 — that even if the hourly or daily earnings in two districts or countries are the same, the yearly averages computed on these bases may differ widely among themselves according to the. regularity of the employment. The averages computed on the basis of the number of full-time workers, again, aim at showing, what the earnings of a normal worker regularly employed on normal time would be, i.e. the "potential earnings" While averages computed on this basis are comparable as between different districts and countries, they are, in all cases of irregularemployment, higher than the average actual earnings. The calculation of the average yearly earnings per full-time worker adds, in fact, little to the information obtained by calculating. average earnings per hour or manshift. §17. When the average earnings of mine-workers havebeen calculated, according to as uniform methods as possible,. the question of their comparison arises. The inter-regional comparisons within a country can be made; directly, as the currency in which the earnings are expressed is the same, and, although there might be variations in the price level and the habits of expenditure as between different coalfields, these differences are relatively small. The international comparisons are much more complicated.. The method to be employed depends on the object in view. If the problem is to find out the comparative cost of a unit of work,. then it is necessary to convert the averages, by the ruling rates of exchange, into terms of a common monetary unit. The comparison of earnings so obtained is of interest mainly from the point of view of the international commerce. But this method is wholly inadequate for a study of the standard of living of the workers. What is important from this point of view is to compare the earnings in terms of goods and services purchasable by the money, or "nominal" earningsAs a matter of fact, a given amount of money received as earnings has its real significance only in relation to the prices of the commodities upon which workers' wages are usually spent ;, and the differences in these prices are actually very marked as between different countries. The comparison then consists in finding the relation of the average earnings of mine-workers to the internal prices of commodities in each country during the period under review. This relation gives what is called t h e real earnings of the mine-Workers. — 57 — The compilation of the statistics of real earnings, i.e. of the relative purchasing power of average earnings, involves several problems which are not particular to the statistics of wages in the coal industry and Which therefore are omitted from the present discussion x. § 18. The principal question of wages, from the point of view of the mine-owners, is the "labour cost" as part of the total costs of production of coal. It should be observed at the outset that the question concerning the proportion of total cost of production of coal represented by the labour cost would involve the examination of payments for supplies, for overhead costs, etc. It therefore is beyond the scope of the statistics of wages. The main problem to be discussed in this connection is that concerning the average labour cost per ton of coal. The calculation of this average requires two series of data, viz. the aggregate amount of labour cost, and the aggregate tonnage of coal produced. The amount of "labour cost" may be taken as being equal to what was called above the amount of "actual earnings", since the total payments made to the workers will represent the cost of labour in the balance sheet of the employer. On the other hand, the quantities of coal produced may be ascertained according to different methods. In the first place» it may be noted that the simple term "ton of coal" does not always mean the same measure. The metric ton (1,000 kg.) and the British ton (2,240 lbs.) are different, as are also the gross or "long ton", equal to the British ton, and the net or "short ton" of 2,000 lbs. used in American and Canadian statistics. Moreover, the ton of coal represents in reality very different things. It is affected by the quality of coal raised, its freedom from impurities and other similar factors ; and it is practically impossible to make allowance for these factors in the statistics. Finally, it is to be observed that the quantity of coal is, in many countries, to a large extent only estimated. In the second place, in calculating the quantity of output of coal, the different uses of coal must be taken into consideration.. Two different notions are to be noted. When coal has been raised, it is washed, and what is left is called (a) the tonnage of The method is explained in Appendix III. — 58 — saleable coal (tonnage du charbon produit) ; this quantity of coal is distributed in different directions, one part being coal not actually for sale, as it is consumed either by the mine itself or by workers who receive coal free or at reduced rates, while the remaining part, finally, represents the quantity of (b) commercially disposable coal (tonnage du charbon vendable), i.e. coal actually sold plus stocks. Both of these notions should be taken as bases in computing the average cost of labour. If the statistics are confined to the calculation of the average cost of labour per ton of coal, the method of computing the average will be simple. Given the total earnings during the period considered and the total amount of coal produced during the same period, the average is obtained by dividing the former figure by the latter. § 19. The "labour cost" of production of coal is not only a question of wages paid per ton of coal, but also of wages in relation to efficiency. The efficiency, again, is best measured by calculating the output of coal per unit of labour. Two different units of labour may be here taken into account, viz. the day or manshift, and the average or full-time worker employed per year. Given the tonnage of coal produced, the total number of days or manshifts worked, and the average number of workers or the number of full-time workers, it will be easy to calculate, for each district or country (a) the average output per day or manshift, and (b) the average output per year per worker or full-time worker. The comparability of these averages will, of course, depend on the uniformity of the methods employed in calculating the basic figures which have been examined above. The comparison between the average wages per ton of coal and the average output of coal per day or per worker will be of great interest, especially in order to study in which direction the level of wages is influenced by the efficiency. The statistics, of course, throw no light upon the question whether the efficiency itself is determined by favourable or unfavourable natural conditions, or by efficient or inefficient methods of management and work, or by other circumstances. PAßT TWO RESULTS OF THE ENQUIRY INTO HOURS OF LABOUR AND WAGES IN THE EUROPEAN COAL INDUSTRY IN 1925 INTRODUCTION § 1. In order to arrive at a comprehensive and comparative survey of the conditions of labour in the world's coal industry, it would be necessary to cover all the chief coal-producing countries in the world and a considerable period of time. The plan of the present enquiry was, as a matter of fact, drawn on these extensive lines. The International Labour Office prepared, with the assistance of experts and after close examination of all material published hereto, a series of tables and documents, on the basis of which information was asked on the hours of labour and wages in the coal industry before the war, as well as from the year 1919 to 1925. These tables and documents were despatched, in the beginning of 1926, to the competent government offices of the principal coal-producing countries of the world, viz. 1 : European Germany Belgium France Great Britain Netherlands Poland Russia Saar Territory Czechoslovakia Non-European South Africa Canada United States India Japan 1 The countries are arranged in alphabetical order as determined by their French names. — 60 — The work which the Governments were asked to undertake was both long and difficult. In many cases the statistics were not immediately available and special enquiries had to be made. Further delays were caused by the consultation of the employers' and workers' organisations as well as by the outbreak of the long coal stoppage in Great Britain in May 1926. Not until the end of 1927 were replies received from all countries mentioned in the above list, except Russia, Canada, and the United States. § 2. The replies received, however, are in some respects defective and differ from the standard scheme devised by the International Labour Office. Owing to these flaws, the scope of the present report is limited in two directions. In the first place, certain material data are lacking for several countries, or are of such a character that comparisons with other countries are impossible. For this reason the main part of the report refers to the European coal industry alone, and furthermore, only to those European countries from which comparable information has been secured. The significance of this limitation will be illustrated by the following tables where the total output of coal has been taken as the criterion of the importance of the different coalfields 1. The first table shows the place of Europe as a whole in the world production of coal. WORLD PRODUCTION OF COAL, 1 9 0 9 - 1 9 1 3 AND 1925 (Metric Tons — 000's Omitted) Continents North America Central and South America The World Average, 1909-1913 1925 6,878 476,208 1,433 49,502 551,543 12,070 1,097,634 12,492 539,405 1,850 80,500 538,688 14,868 1,187,803 It will be seen from the above figures that Europe produced, before the war, not more than 50 per cent, of the world's total output of coal, and that this proportion has declined after the war, being only 45 per cent, in 1925. 1 The figures are drawn from statistics contained in : LEAGUE O F NATIONS : International Economic Conference. Documentation. Memorandum on Coal. Vol. I, Annex IV, p. 43, Geneva, 1927. — 61 — The following table refers to the distribution of the European coal production among the different countries, with percentages showing the relative part of each country in the total output in 1925. EUROPEAN PRODUCTION OF COAL, 1909-1913 AND 1925 (Metric Tons — 000's Omitted) Absolute figures Countries A v e r a g e , 1909-1913 Saar Territory (a). . . . Czechoslovakia (a). . . . Other countries (a) . . . Total 121,118 23,260 3,861 41,848 (c) 273,905 1,498 35,922 23,765 (c) 11,500 (c) 13,085 1,781 551,543 1925 132,729 23,133 5,925 47,046 248,067 6,849 29,081 17,637 12,990 12,754 2,477 538,688 Percentage to total European production, 1925 24.6 4.3 1.1 8.7 46.0 1.3 5.4 3.3 2.4 2.4 0.5 100.0 (a) Post-war territory. (6) U.S.S.R., including Asiatic Russia, (c) Estimate. The countries covered by the present enquiry, viz. Germany, Belgium, France, Great Britain, Netherlands, Poland, the Saar Territory, and Czechoslovakia, thus are the most important coal-producing countries of Europe, and represented, in 1925, about 95 per cent, of the total European output. It should, however, be noted that the relative importance of the different countries, from the point of view of the international coal market, is very unequal. Compared with Great Britain, Germany, and (to a less extent) France, other countries appear to have only secondary importance ; the Saar, Czechoslovakia, and the Netherlands, taken together, furnish not more than 6 per cent. of the European coal supply. As regards extra-European countries, official information has been received from India, Japan, and South Africa, but as this material is comparable neither with that supplied for European countries nor among these non-European countries, it is dealt with separately in an appendix. On the other hand, in view of the importance of the United States as the greatest — 62 — producer of coal, it has appeared convenient to give, in the same connection, such information as has been found in the various official publications of this country ; and similar information is given for Canada 1 . A second, and still more important flaw is the limited period for which material has been received. Information as to conditions of work in coal-mines before the war, and the first years following the war, has been supplied from two countries only (Germany and Czechoslovakia) and even in these cases the pre-war statistics are not comparable with those given for the post-war period. The only year for which approximately comparable information has been obtained from all European countries, is 1925 ; and the following chapters are therefore confined to the situation in this single year. As a matter of course, this limited scope necessarily reduces the value of the present enquiry for several reasons. In the first place, it is now impossible to draw any conclusions as to the development which has taken place since the pre-war period, a question which is of outstanding interest for many quarters. Secondly, even an adequate survey of post-war conditions of labour is extremely difficult to obtain on the basis of figures relating to one year only, since this year (and, in fact, any of the post-war years) cannot be considered as wholly representative of this period in all countries. And, finally, it is to be noted that the labour conditions have undergone important changes in several countries since 1925. In the nature of the case, it has not been possible to remedy the lack of material for the period prior to 1925. Nor has it been found practicable to extend the international enquiry beyond that year. For, apart from the fact that the year 1926 was abnormal on account of the great British coal stoppage and the violent oscillations in the exchange rates and purchasing power of money in several European countries, the collection for this year of supplementary information on the same extensive lines as that secured for 1925 had certainly led to further delays, and even met with insurmountable difficulties ; and this applies, of course, with increased force to the year 1927, for which statistics will not be available until a considerable period after the publication of the present report. An attempt has been made to indicate simply the general trend of development of 1 See Appendix V. — 63 — the rregulation of hours of labour and wages in individual countries since 1925 on the basis of the available official statistics which are not comparable among themselves 1. Finally, it is to be pointed out that the present enquiry refers to conditions of labour in the coal industry (bituminous and anthracite), and thus excludes lignite mines, which, as a matter of fact, are much less important than coal-mines 2. On the other hand, the supervising staff and salaried employees of the coal mines are left outside the scope of the enquiry. § 3. The material which has been at the disposal of the International Labour Office is thus limited in scope ; but it may be considered as fairly representative of the conditions of labour prevailing in the European coal industry in 1925. The next task of the International Labour Office has been to analyse in detail the comparability of the data obtained from the different countries, and then to effect such comparisons as the material permits. The results arrived at in the analysis of the methods in Part One are taken as basis, and the material available is adjusted to the theoretical scheme in order to render it, as far as practicable, internationally comparable. This task is carried out in the following chapters concerning respectively hours of labour and wages. It should be noted that the question of holidays with pay which is mentioned in the original Resolution of the International Labour Conference, is dealt with in connection with the statistics of wages. A final chapter will summarise the results arrived at in the enquiry. 1 See Appendix IV. The lignite industry is almost entirely confined to Europe and particularly t o Germany. The t o t a l European o u t p u t in 1925 was 177,861 thousands of metric tons (of which 139,790 thousand tons in Germany) ; but, in order to compare the economic importance of this o u t p u t with t h a t of coal, lignite should be converted into terms of coal at the r a t e 2 of 2 : 9. Cf. L E A G U E O F N A T I O N S , op. cit., pp. 44-45. CHAPTER I » O U R S OF W O R K IN T H E EUROPEAN COAL INDUSTRY IN 1925 A. — DATA § 1. Statistics concerning underground and surface workers received from various Governments, together with their notes •on the subject, are given below in tabular form. The Governments were requested to compile these statistics by the method laid down in Chapter II of Part One of this study. § 2. Table I, page 66, showing the hours of work of underground workers, comprises four series of columns corresponding to : (1) countries and districts ; (2) statutory hours of work ; (3) hours of work reduced to a common unit ; (4) length of time spent at the face, less breaks. A careful examination of the table shows the various operations that affect the calculation of the above factors. (1) Column 1 gives the country, or the districts in a country, in which the enquiry was made. (2) The statutory length of the shift, which depends upon legislation or upon collective agreements, is set forth in columns 2 to 5. — 65 — (3) With regard to the determination of the hours of work reduced to a common unit, it may be necessary, according to the manner in which the length of the shift is calculated, to know the collective winding time (descent or ascent) (columns 6 and 7). In such a case the winding time (descent or ascent) must be added to or deducted from, as the case may be, the figure given in column 2 or 3, as is explained for each country in Appendix I. When the length of the shift is calculated per individual, or if the length of the shift only includes one winding time (descent or ascent), the figures in column 6 do not affect these calculations. (4) Column 8 shows the weekly hours of work obtained by multiplying the hours indicated in column 7 by six, and by taking into account, where necessary, the shorter Saturday working hours. This calculation is based upon the supposition that each working day corresponds to a shift, whereas in reality the number of shifts worked in a week may be higher or lower than the number of working days. This also applies to the figures in column 14. (5) The length of the shift, reduced to a common unit (column 7) forms the basis for the calculation of the time spent a t the face, less breaks. The following factors must then be taken into account : (o) Travelling time underground (to the face, column 9, and from the face, column 10) ; (b) The length of the breaks (column 11). In order to simplify these calculations, column 12 gives the total of columns 9, 10 and 11, from which it is sufficient to deduct the total in column 7 in order to obtain the length of time spent at the face, less breaks (column 13). Column 14 indicates the time spent at the face, per week. § 3. Table 11, page 69, concerning the working hours of surface workers, includes three series of columns, corresponding to : (1) the countries or districts ; (2) the statutory hours of work ; (3) the actual hours of work. 5 TABLE I. HOURS OF W O R K FOR U N D E R G R O U N D Statutory hours of work Average collective Week Day or shift winding time Collective (descent Collective Legis- agreements Legis- agreements or ascent) lation lation or arbitral or arbitral awards awards 6 4 | 5 2 3 Country and district 1 Germany : Whole country1 8 Ruhr 8 8 Upper Silesia.. 8 Lower Silesia . 8 Free State of Saxony 8 4 5 7+1 7 + 1.30' 7.30' + 1 7 +1 Hours of work Average trav time underg to a common unit Day or shift 7 ' Week To the face 8 9 3 2 — — 7+1 th 1 2 8 8.30' 8.30' 8 48 51 51 48 8 48 7 10 Great Britain .. 8 — 48 — 8 __ — — 7 — — 6' to 10' 7.50'to 7.65'' 47 to 47.30'' 20' to 30'' 20' 7.50'' 47' 16' 30' — 7.44' 46.24' 27' 11 7.30' 40.45'to 45 — 8.10' 47 45' 35'13 8.30' 8 46 10' Upper Silesia.. 8 Dombrowa and! Cracow coal- > 8 fields ) Czechoslovakia.. 8.30' 8 — 25' 8 48 32' 25' 8 46 32' 8 48 46+2 35' 7.25' 44.30' 30' Saar19 7.30' — — — 7.30' 45 '— 8 is 4613 15 — 46 17 * For the meth od of calculation of hours of work, reduced tp a common unit, coun — 67 — Notes to Table I The importance of the various coalfields is shown in the following table, which gives the number of full-time underground workers (Vollarbeiter) employed in 1925 : Ruhr 284,391 Aachen 12,500 (approximately) Upper Silesia 28,477 Lower Silesia 19,700 Free State of Saxony . . 15,909 2 The German Government states in its memorandum that no official statistics are available concerning the average winding time (ascent or descent), the underground travelling time and breaks, and consequently the average time spent at the face, less breaks, is not given. Saxony is the only district for which the length of the breaks and the average length of time spent at the face less breaks are given. With regard to this, the Prussian Government states in a letter accompanying the memorandum that it has only used the officially compiled figures, whereas the Government of Saxony has used approximate average figures for the length of the breaks and the length of time spent at the face, less breaks. The letter adds that, in view of the different conditions under which the mining undertakings are run, it is very difficult, with regard to the Prussian coalfields, to supply even approximately average figures. Also the employers' and workers' organisations concerned have been consulted. The difficulties in connection with a single coalfield, such as in Saxony, are less. 3 The figures in this column have been taken from the statistics published in the Zeitschrift für Berg- Hütten- u. Salinenwesen, 1925, Second Statistical Returns. 4 In conformity with the National Agreement, this period is calculated for each worker individually from the time when he enters the cage to descend until the time when he leaves it after ascending. In Saxony this period is calculated from the time when the descent begins until the time when the ascent begins. 5 In conformity with the arbitral awards pronounced and made compulsory by the public authority upon the expiration of the overtime agreement of the Ruhr (Mehrarbeitsabkommen) of 29 November 1923, this period is calculated for each worker individually, from the time when he begins the descent to the time when he begins the ascent. 6 This figure corresponds to the difference between the figures in column 7 and in column 13. 7 The Belgian Government gives the range for these various periods, and adds the following explanation : "In order to indicate the various hours of work shown in the table by means of an average figure for each instead of by the limits within which they vary, it would be necessary to calculate a weighted average, taking into account the data concerning each place and the number of workers employed at each. In order to compute this average, average calculations of time would be required that have not been made for 1924 and 1925. Without these figures it would be unwise to rely upon an arithmetic mean between the figures which are a result of estimates that have been used to compile the figures mentioned in the table. For this reason only extreme limits have been given, within which the working hours in question vary. It would appear, however, that the weighted average for the travelling time underground, plus breaks, as a whole, is about 1 hour 30 minutes, and that the average actual hours of work are 6 hours 20 minutes." 8 The average travelling time underground, from the face, is given as 31 minutes — somewhat longer than the travelling time to the face, 27 minutes. This is due to the fact that, when going to the face, the 1 — 68 — workers set out as soon as they leave the cage, whereas when returning it is impossible that each worker should arrive at the cage from the face at the exact moment of his ascent. In order that the collective ascent of a shift shall finish at the statutory hour, it is necessary that the workers leave the face a little sooner than would be necessary for the actual journey. A difference between the travelling time to and from the face corresponds in fact to what actually happens. 9 The 29 minutes for the average length of the break, calculated collectively, constitutes an average of 20 minutes in the Lorraine coalfields and 30 minutes in the others. 10 The figures in columns 2, 6, 7, 8. and 13 are those of the Royal Commission on the Coal Industry (1925) (Vol. I, pp. 166-171). 11 "The lower figure represents 11 days a fortnight, with Saturday one hour less than an ordinary weekday. This is the general practice in Northumberland. The higher figure represents six full days a week, as is worked in South Wales. The hours in Scotland, Yorkshire, and Lancashire for the most part lie between these two extremes." (Royal Commission on the Coal Industry, p. 170.) 12 The British Government gives an approximate total figure for the average travelling time underground, plus breaks. This figure includes an average waiting time at the bottom of the pit in order to allow the workers of a shift to collect before the ascent begins. However, the British Government states that the length of this average wait is not known and is not easy to determine. It considers, however, that the figure of 1 hour 45 minutes is the most accurate that can be given, although only approximate. 13 These figures have been compiled by the method used for the "collective calculation", including the collective winding time (ascent or descent). (See Appendix I, Netherlands.) The Government of the Netherlands has supplied further data that is given in the table, concerning which the following is to be observed : It has been shown in the theoretical analysis that it was not absolutely accurate, when calculating per cage, to disregard the time taken in loading and unloading the cage to descend or ascend. This period has been disregarded in view of the approximate nature of certain figures in the enquiry. However, the Government of the Netherlands thinks it is necessary to show this loss of time in the statistics, and fixes this period at ten minutes for all operations connected with the descent and at ten minutes for all operations connected with the ascent. The Government therefore adds to the statutory length of a shift calculated per cage or per worker the time required for all the operations connected with the ascent of the cage—that is to say, ten minutes. The hours of work reduced to a common unit are thus fixed at 8 hours 10 minutes. This calculation is undoubtedly accurate. However, it has not been thought possible to mention these figures in the international comparison without drawing attention to the fact that the other countries that have also calculated the length of the shift by cage, and have disregarded this factor, can no longer be compared under the same conditions. It should be noted that the figure of 45 minutes, given by the Dutch Government for each of the underground travelling times, to the face and from the face, includes ten minutes corresponding respectively to operations connected with the descent and those connected with the ascent. 14 These figures were compiled by the Ministry of Industry and Commerce (Mines Department) and theMinstry of Labour and Social "Welfare. 15 This calculation is based on the figures supplied by the Ministry of Industry and Commerce (Mines Department) and the Ministry of Labour and Social Welfare. 16 The calculation of customary breaks has been checked by the Ministry of Industry and Commerce (Mines Department) and the Ministry of Labour and Social Welfare. — 69 — 17 The total working time for a week is 46 hours, with a permanent undertaking on the part of the workers to work two hours longer on Saturday in consideration of special overtime pay (that is to say, 48 hours total working time). 18 The second figure is obtained exclusively from the data taken into account in the enquiry. The first figure supplied by the Government of Czechoslovakia takes into account an average period of waiting of 17 minutes at the bottom of the pit. That is deducted from the length of time spent at the face. In the Czechoslovak coalfields the ascent does not begin until all the workers have collected at the bottom of the pit. They are therefore obliged to leave the face on an average 17 minutes earlier than if they left the face in time to arrive at the bottom of the pit at the approximate time of their ascent. (See Theoretical Analysis, Part I, Chapter II, note 1, p. 18). 19 These figures are supplied by the Director-General of the French State Mines of the Saar (Mines domaniales françaises). TABLE II. HOURS OF W O R K OF SURFACE WORKERS Statutory hours of work Actual hours of work D a y or shift Week Country and district Legislation Collective agreements or arbitral awards Legislation Collective agreements or arbitral awards Day Week 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Germany : 1 Whole country. Ruhr Aachen . . . . Upper Silesia . Lower Silesia . Free State of Saxony . . . 8 8 8 8 8 8 22 10 3s 8 2 10 4 8 10 5 82 9 8 82 58-59 58-59 60-58 55.30'-53 54-48 8 2a 10 33 8 10 8 a2 10 45 8 9 9.30' 6 2 8 9 58-59 58-59 60-58 55.30'-53 54-48 Belgium 8 — 48 — — 8 8 — — — 7.59' 9 47.54' Great Britain — — —- 46.30' 7.45' 1 0 46.30' Netherlands . . . — 8 — — 8 48 8 8 — 8 48 8 46 . . . . Poland : l l Upper Silesia . Dombrowa and Cracow coal-fields . . — 9" 8 7 46 Czechoslovakia. . 8 — 48 — 7.45' 46.30' Saar12 — 8 — — 7.45' 46.30' — 70 — Notes to Table II 1 In completion of the figures shown in this table, t h e German Governm e n t sent the following information concerning t h e various working hours and the percentage of surface workers (with the exclusion of women and children) employed during these hours, for each of the districts under consideration. The Zeitschrift für Berg- Hütten- u. Salinenwesen, 1925, Second Statistical Return, is given as the source of this information : ( 10 hours for 7 3 . 2 % full time workers {Vollarbeiter). Ruhr . . . 9 „ 8.5% ( 8 J> „ 18.1% Aachen . . . 1 1 0 „ 99.0% i 8 5? „ 1-0% ( io „ 65.2% Upper Silesia J? 9 / „ 4.4% 8i 2» „ 1-6% ( 8 „ 29.2% ( io ) 9i,'?,< » 36.1% Lower Silesia 9 „ 9.1% I 8 3> „ 23.0% 10 ? ? „ 31.8% 9 Free State of „ 1.4% Saxony . 8 JÎ „ 80.1% „ 18.5% I t should be added t h a t in 1925 the number of full-time workers corresponding to surface workers (adults, both sexes), with the exclusion of those occupied in subsidiary establishments, was as follows : Ruhr 67,434 Aachen 3,100 (approximately) Upper Silesia 10,415 Lower Silesia 8,300 ,, Free S t a t e of Saxony . . . . 5,639 2 In conformity with t h e National Agreement. 3 In conformity with t h e arbitral awards pronounced and made compulsory by t h e public authorities upon t h e expiration of t h e overtime agreement ; however, t h e working week comprises 58 hours in coalfields where there are two shifts engaged in production and 59 hours where only one shift is engaged in production. 4 In conformity with the arbitral awards pronounced and made compulsory by t h e public authorities upon t h e expiration of the overtime agreement ; however, the S a t u r d a y working day comprises eight hours in undertakings where production is not continuous. 5 In conformity with t h e arbitral awards pronounced and made compulsory by t h e public authorities upon the expiration of the overtime agreement ; however, the working day comprises 9 hours 30 minutes for five days of t h e week and 8 hours for one day in undertakings with continued production, and 9 hours for five days and 8 hours for one day in undertakings where there is not continued production. 1 6 In conformity" with t h e arbitral awards pronounced and made compulsory by the public authorities upon the expiration of the overtime agreement ; however, t h e working day comprises 8 hours for firemen. 7 Figures established upon a basis of t h e d a t a in notes 3, 4, 5 and 6. 8 Since Belgium does not give the actual length of the working day, no figure for Belgium appears in this column. 9 The average working hours are indicated as 7 hours 59 minutes instead of 8 hours, in view of t h e fact t h a t in certain coalfields and for certain local reasons t h e actual working hours are somewhat less t h a n 8 hours. — 71 — 10 This figure is taken from the report of the Royal Commission on the Coal Industry (1925) (Vol. I, p. 171). 11 These figures were compiled by the Ministry of Labour and Social Welfare and the Ministry of Industry and Commerce (Mines Department). 12 This figure was supplied by the Director-General of the French State Mines of the Sarr (Mines domaniales françaises). B . — CONCLUSIONS § 4. The statistics enable a more accurate international comparison of the hours of work in coal mines to be made than has hitherto been possible. The various conclusions that may be drawn from these statistics are given below. § 5. With the exception of the surface workers in Great Britain and in the Netherlands, the working hours of adult workers employed in mines are fixed by legislation in all the countries from which information has been received. Hours of work are also regulated in Germany, Great Britain, the Netherlands, Poland (Upper Silesia), in Czechoslovakia, and in the Saar, by collective agreements that give a more accurate idea of the facts, since they are the result of direct agreement between the persons concerned. The statutory shift for underground workers is in general 8 hours, with the exception of Great Britain x where it is 7 hours. In the Netherlands and in Poland (Dombrowa and Cracow) the working day is reduced to 6 hours on Saturday, thus limiting the working week to 46 hours. Judging by these figures, the hours of work seem to be more or less uniform. § 6. Greater differences appear when these figures are reduced to the basis for international comparison. With regard to the three countries under consideration, Belgium, France, and Czechoslovakia, it is necessary to deduct the collective winding time (ascent or descent). In Great Britain, however, this winding time must be added. In Germany, the Netherlands, Poland and the Saar, the statutory unit of measure is the same as the international basis. The international comparison of these figures shows that the shift as defined above is less than 8 hours in Belgium, 1 Changes that have been made since 1925 in the working hours of underground and surface workers are indicated in Appendix IV. — 72 — Czechoslovakia, France, Great Britain, and the Saar; is 8 hours in the German coalfields of the Ruhr, Lower Silesia, Saxony, in the Netherlands, and in Poland; and it is more than 8 hours in Aachen and in the Upper Silesian districts in Germany. The length of the working week, established on the basis of the definition used for the shift, is less than 48 hours everywhere except in Polish Upper Silesia and in Germany, where it reaches 48 hours, and even exceeds this period (51 hours) in Aachen and in German Upper Silesia. The average winding time (ascent or descent) for the whole shift is different in each country, and varies between five minutes (some Belgian coalfields) and 35 minutes (Czechoslovakia). ' The figures for Poland have a purely documentary interest in view of the fact that they are not used for the calculation of the shift reduced to a common unit. Generally speaking, the average winding time (ascent or descent) in the various countries under consideration is less as the number of workers ascending or descending collectively is lower, particularly in Belgium where the staff is subdivided by categories or in cage loads. The winding time is reduced to a minimum. § 7. The travelling time underground works out at about 60 minutes. No figures are available in this connection for Germany and Great Britain (90 minutes in the Netherlands according to the basis for calculation used by the Dutch Government). With the exception of this country, the various figures shown in the table are more or less similar. In all the countries, the statutory breaks are included in the working hours. The average length of the breaks varies between 30 and 40 minutes. In Belgium the workers have longer breaks than those in other European countries ; the Belgium Government, however, states that it "has taken the definition of breaks as given by the International Labour Office into consideration". It will be seen from a study of the figures for travelling underground and breaks, that the total time lost in the various countries is generally the same. The time lost is on an average about 40 minutes, although it reaches two hours in the Netherlands. The second important factor to be determined, the length of time spent at the face less breaks, corresponds on the whole to the actual period during which the worker works for the undertaking. This period is approximately 6 hours 10 minutes — 73 — to 6 hours 20 minutes. The shortest periods occur in Great Britain and in Czechoslovakia. § 8. The statutory working hours for surface workers consist of 8 hours in every country except Germany, where they are higher on account of the overtime worked in accordance with arbitral awards made compulsory by the public authorities, and in Great Britain where they are less (7 hours 45 minutes). In Poland (Dombrowa and Cracow) and in Great Britain, the working week is less than 48 hours on account of shorter hours on Saturday. Finally, in Germany and Great Britain, the Netherlands and Poland, the actual working hours correspond to the statutory working hours. In France they are very slightly less (7 hours 59 minutes instead of 8 hours), and also in Czechoslovakia and in the Saar (7 hours 45 minutes instead of 8 hours). CHAPTER II WAGES IN T H E EUROPEAN COAL INDUSTRY IN 1925 § 1. In the following sections, the information received from the various Governments concerning wages in the coal industry is analysed and compared. Following the order of presentation adopted in the study ói the principles and methods of wage statistics, the first sections (A - E) are designed to present the basic data of the statistics. Their main object is to state to what extent the wage data actually are furnished in conformity with the standard method outlined ; in other words, how far the information relating to the total earnings, their distribution among the various groups of workers, the number of manshifts (days) worked and lost, and that of workers employed is comparable. Each group of data available for the various countries is summarised in one table, and percentages are calculated showing the relation which the different items bear to the total in each country : the differences in these percentages will throw light upon the differences prevailing in the industry in the various countries concerned. The next sections (F and G) give the average earnings per time unit (day, hour, and year) calculated from the basic data. The comparison is effected on two different lines. On the one hand, the average wages given in the original data in the national currencies, are first converted to a common basis, the gold franc (approximately equal to the Swiss franc) being chosen as the most convenient basis ; the results are then expressed in terms of "relative numbers", which illustrate the comparative level of "gold earnings" in the various countries. On the other hand, the relative purchasing power of average earnings are calculated in terms of retail prices. The resulting index numbers of comparative "real earnings", although affording only approximate conclusions, are of particular interest in the study of the miner's standard of living. — 75 — The labour cost of production of coal is dealt with in the concluding sections. To the basic data mentioned above is here added the total output of coal, completed by a calculation of the average output. The labour cost of coal is then computed on the basis of the total wages bill and the total output, and converted to the gold franc basis for the purpose of international comparison. Information on these lines is available only for the country as a whole in the case of France, Great Britain, and the Netherlands ; and for the principal coal-fields, as well as for the whole country, in respect of Belgium, Poland, and Czechoslovakia. In the case of Germany, information not being available for the whole country, data are given separately for the two principal coal districts, viz., the Ruhr (Niederrheinisch-Westfälischer Steinkohlenbezirk) and Upper Silesia (Oberschlesischer Steinkohlen^bezirk), which supplied, in 1925, about 79 and 11 per cent. respectively of the total German output of coal, as well as for a third district, the Free State of Saxony, representing 3 per cent, of the total output of the Reich 1. The Saar territory is dealt with as an independent coal district. It should be observed, finally, that the figures refer, as a rule, to coalmining undertakings proper, and exclude ancillary establishments. In the case of Germany, however, it has been impossible to carry out this principle consistently : whereas figures which exclude ancillary establishments have been obtained for the Ruhr district and for the Upper Silesian district (except as regards the different items included in the total wages bill), all figures for Saxony include the ancillary establishments 2. A. — COMPOSITION OF THE TOTAL WAGES BILL § 2. The basis adopted for the international comparisons of mine-workers' wages is the total wages bill. This is composed of the aggregate actual earnings, i.e. "money wages", plus other advantages which the workers receive by reason of their employment in and about the mine. The fact that this conception 1 Saxony is the fourth coal district of Germany from the point of view •of output. The third is Lower Silesia (4.2 per cent, of total output •of Germany in 1925). 2 It should be noted that the "ancillary establishments" are on the surface ; hence the figures relating to underground workers are comparable with those given for other districts. — 76 — of wages covers several different elements of income to the workers which are not always considered as wages in the ordinary sense of the term may call for some criticism. Account may be taken of the objections by setting forth separately money wages in the restricted sense of the word, and the aggregate actual earnings as defined in the present enquiry. The main concern of the statistics is, however, with the latter element, for it would not be correct, from an international point of view, to limit the statistics to the bare money wages, and omit the allowances and benefits which constitute in all countries a particular feature in the miner's earnings, and which influence to a considerable and varying extent the level of wages. In general, the statistics of the various countries contain data which lend themselves to international comparisons on these lines. There are, however, certain flaws and divergencies which will be considered below. § 3. The money wages taken into account in the statistics do not consist of "gross money wages" as they appear.in the pay books, since allowance must be made for the various deductions. The position of the different groups of deductions, however, is not identical. Amounts corresponding to various kinds of occupational charges, which are usually deducted from the gross wages, cannot be considered as a part of wages ; while contributions of workers towards social insurance, which also are usually deducted from the gross wages, really form a part of wages. The actual money wages of the workers thus include the sum left when all deductions are made, i.e. "net money wages", plus the sum of workmen's contributions. It is to be noted t h a t money wages in this sense do not include allowances in cash granted for reasons other than work done ; these are considered later as a separate item in total actual earnings. The degree in which the figures relating to net money wages are comparable will appear after considering, first, the gross money wages and the deductions made therefrom in the statistics of the different countries. The amount of gross money wages is apparently recorded according to similar principles in the different countries 1. 1 The British statistics include in the money wages allowances to make up "subsistence wages" for low-paid workers. This item, provided for in the National Wage Agreement of June 1924, clauses 6 and 7, in force during 1925, forms an integral part of the miners' wages, and cannot be separated from the total of money wages. — 77 — Deductions for so-called occupational charges include amounts deducted, on the one hand, for explosives, lighting materials, tools, sharpening of tools, etc., and, on the other, for penalties. The practice adopted in the different statistics in respect to this item varies to some extent. In Germany, this item does not appear in pay-sheets at all, as tools are supplied by the establishments free of charge, and the price of explosives does not enter into the wage cost of production ; in Poland, tools and carbide are supplied, as in Germany, free of charge \ while charges for explosives are deducted from the total money wages ; in Czechoslovakia, the law authorises the employer to deduct expenditure for explosives, but not that for lighting materials and tools ; expenditure for explosives is deducted .from the total money wages ; the deductions for penalties (which are, in fact, very small) are paid into the Social Insurance Fund. In all countries except Germany occupational charges thus form a special item in the pay-sheets. Information was asked on this point in order to make sure that all statistics of wages will allow for it and deduct it according to similar principles. As a matter of fact, two different methods are employed. A total corresponding to gross wages may first be established, and an amount corresponding to deductions for occupational charges may then be given separately and be deducted from the total of aggregate earnings ; the British statistics have followed this method. The statistics of most countries, however, give the amount of net wages, i.e., they deduct the amount corresponding to occupational charges already from the money wages. For the purpose of international comparisons, it will therefore be necessary to apply the latter method throughout the statistics. Deductions for occupational charges are thus left outside the statistics relating to money wages. The total amount of deductions for occupational charges and the percentage they bear to the total earnings for the two countries which have supplied the information is as follows : Great Britain.. €1,096,000, or 0.7 per cent, of the total earnings. Poland... 32,117 zloty, or 0.02 „ The amounts representing workers' contributions to social insurance are given separately in the statistics of all countries. This item varies considerably from country to country owing 1 In Germany and Poland the worker is, however, obliged to pay for deterioration and loss of tools. — 80 — same accuracy as the items expressed in money. Thus the statistics available for Great Britain indicate that the amount concerned is calculated from a special return obtained by the Mining Association for March 1926, adjustment being made for the variations in 1925 in the number of workers employed, quantity of coal supplied, and in the price of coal. Allowances in kind other than coal include principally housing accommodation free of charge or at reduced rate. As regards Poland, the data furnished give, on the one hand, the difference between the normal rent of a flat, including lighting and water, and the rent paid by the workers ; and, on the other hand, payments effected in view of the maintenance of schools, child welfare institutions, and medical relief. In short, the data relating to allowances in cash and in kind are compiled according to similar statistical principles ; but the original data are necessarily only approximate and usually based on information furnished by employers' organisations with which trade unions have not agreed in all countries 1. The different degree of accuracy of the estimate in the various countries constitutes a source of error, which should be taken into account in the international comparisons. § 5. A special place has been reserved to payments for holidays, including compensation for such holidays to which workers have been entitled but by which they have not actually benefited. The inclusion of the latter item in the total of actual earnings has been objected to by the German miners' organisations on account of the fact that the compensation for holidays not actually taken is not compulsory under the national agreement ; but in view of the fact that such compensation, when actually granted, should logically be placed on the same footing as payment for holidays, it is correct to include this item in the account concerned, as is actually done in the official German statistics. It goes without saying that this item does not appear in the, statistics relating to countries where no holidays with pay are granted, i.e. in the statistics of Belgium, France, and Great Britain. The data which are available may, in general, be considered as comparable with one another. 1 The Miners' Federation of Great Britain, particularly, has advanced doubts as to the basis on which the amount of allowances in kind have been estimated. — 81 — § 6. The difficulties which arise from the contributions towards expenses of workmen's compensation and social insurance from others than workmen themselves, have been discussed in detail above 1 . It was pointed out that the question whether this item should properly be considered as an element of wages is open. It was further observed that, even if this question is answered in the affirmative, other difficulties subsist. Thus the method which consists in computing the benefits paid instead of contributions has proved defective. Similarly, it is impracticable—and perhaps incorrect in principle—to take into account subsidies paid from public funds. If then the advantage drawn from social insurance schemes (apart from workers' own contributions which are on a different footing) is to be counted, it seems convenient to limit it to the payments made by the industry to the workers it employs, i.e. to employers' contributions. But even this method has met with difficulties. Employers' contributions are not usually included in the wage statistics, and therefore the figures are in part only estimations. In view of these difficulties, the aggregate amounts of actual earnings are calculated in two ways, viz. by adding up (a) all items considered above, except employers' contributions, and (b) the same items plus employers' contributions. Therefore, in each case in which the total wages bill enters, two series of calculations must be established. The actual data relating to the contributions employers defray in the different countries have, of course, a very different meaning in practice : the remarks made above on the divergency of the schemes of social insurance and their financial organisation apply also in this case. The scope of the schemes to which employers are obliged, by the law, to contribute, may be indicated as follows : (i) All schemes to which workmen contribute, mentioned above (§3). (ii) 1 Workmen's compensation for industrial accidents in Belgium, France, and Great Britain, as well as compulsory accident insurance in Germany, the Netherlands, Poland, the Saar Territory, Czechoslovakia ; some of these schemes cover also, to a varying extent, Cf. Part One, Chapter III, § 7. 6 — 82 — (iii) occupational diseases ; and employers are responsible for their entire cost 1 . Compulsory insurance against invalidity and old age in the Netherlands ; employers being responsible for a part of the cost (the other part being on the charge of public funds) %. Information is lacking as to the amount of the contributions that employers pay in German Upper Silesia, the Saar Territory, and the individual coal districts in Czechoslovakia. § 7. After having defined the comparability of the existing wage data, a first general survey of figures relating to the composition of the aggregate actual earnings may be given. Table I shows the composition of total earnings as defined in the preceding paragraphs, and expressed in national currency. It should be noted that the German statistics do not give any totals for the whole Empire ; the figures refer to the principal districts, which account for about 93 per cent, of the total production. The British figures relate to about 97 per cent, of the coal-mining industry of this country. IMPORTANCE OF " N E T MONEY W A G E S " AND OTHER ELEMENTS OF EARNINGS (In Percentages of Total Actual Earnings) Country and district Great Britain Germany—Ruhr. . . . ,, —Saxony . . . „ —Upper Silesia France Poland 1 Total earnings excluding employers' contributions = 100 Total earnings, including employers' contributions = 100 Net money Net money Other items 90.1 88.0 78.6 73.9 73.1 12.0 21.4 26.1 26.9 93.9 91.7. 86.7 82.6 82.6 80.7 78.7 77.3 77.0 70.0 Other items 6.1 8.3 13.3 17.4 17.4 19.3 21.3 22.7 23.0 30.0 — 73.8 67.9 — 62.5 9.9 — 26.2 32.1 —. 37.5 From the point of view of the financial charges, "workmen's compensation" which is usually accompanied by voluntary insurance, and compulsory insurance, are on the same footing. Therefore, the general term, "employers' contributions to social insurance" will be taken to cover also workmen's compensation. 2 In certain cases, however, also the insured persons themselves pay contributions. — 83 — T A B L E I . — COMPOSITION OF T H E TOTAL W A G E S BILL I N T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , (National Currency I925 — 000's Omitted) lilowaocts Country, district aid n i t of currency «e none; wages Workmen'! insurance contributions Payment! In kind in cask for holidays Frei coal Olttar Total actual Employers' earnings contributions excluding to social employers' insurance> contributions Germany (R.M.) : 655,806 77,316 30,917 Ruhr Upper Silesia (a) 55,732 7,562 2,228 Saxony (a) . . 769 37,055 4,175 Belgium (Fr.) : Charleroi . . . 391,621 9,006 3,365 Liège 301,857 6,206 4,440 Couchant de Mons 270,476 5,894 2,468 Whole country. 1,266,041 29,691 14,095 France ( F r . ) . . 1,828,043 106,699 87,534 Great Britain (£) 133,177 2,855 38,168 2,606 1,984 Netherlands(Gulden) Poland (Zloty): 91,038 12,389 8,821 Silesia 27,749 1,845 3,683 Dombrowa. . . 126,271 14,776 13,338 Whole country. 427,764 40,148 54,733 Saar (Fr). . . . Czechoslovakia (Kc) 347,197 35,036 14,977 Ostrava-Karvina 93,960 7,096 4,602 Kladno- Rakovnik 519,022 49,152 24,485 Whole country. 11,500 2,112 1,669 18,307 1,428 1,188 793,846 94,136 69,061 — 44,856 5,801 12,445 4,668 13,971 4,346 11,255 3,664 50.869 20,594 63,317 237,613 4,286 1,546 328 313 — 330,820 15,147 — 293,757 13,049 — 1,381,290 58,055 — 2,323,206 154,934 — 141,864 5,935 421,105 17,578 8,431 2,820 11,720 22,210 6,440 2,339 9,072 490 3,587 130,706 16,631 1,323 39,759 3,818 5,297 180,474 21,477 10,065 555,400 — 39,139 8,510 53,937 10,938 193 11,237 7,339 454,626 3,354 116,715 — 13,640 671,473 92,489 637 44,036 4,498 (a) Including ancillary establishments ; in Upper Silesia, the total actual earnings excluding these establishments are R.M. 67,562,000 and this figure has been used in the calculation of averages. For Saxony, the corresponding total is not available. — 84 — Table I serves to indicate the differences prevailing in the relative importance of the different items in the total amount of actual earnings. The principal result in this respect is • illustrated by the table on page 82, where countries are arranged in the descending order of the percentage of net money wages. These considerable differences show, first, that the conception of "total actual earnings" taken as basis of the present enquiry is justified : the different kinds of allowances paid in addition t o net money wages represent an extremely variable and, in many cases, an important part of the total earnings received by the mine-workers on account of their employment. This will be seen more clearly in the following table where the heading "other items" has been analysed in detail. The total actual earnings are taken as equal to 100, as in the previous table (page 82), and the percentages represented by the different elements other than "net money wages" have been calculated. The totals correspond to the column "other items" in the preceding table (page 82). IMPORTANCE OF THE DIFFERENT ELEMENTS OF EARNINGS OTHER THAN M O N E Y W A G E S (In Percentages of Total Actual M r « and district ' Great Britain Belgium Netherlands Germany—Euhr. . . . „ —Saxony. . . „ —Upper Silesia France Czechoslovakia Saar Poland Workmen's w insurance anes _ . - • • • contributions Allowances in in money A. Total Earnings, 2.0 — 2.1 1.0 6.0 4.5 9.7 9.3 10.9 Free or cheap or cheap coali Earnings) Other allowances allowances • i • É in kind excluding 3.0 3.7 0.7 Ewuiuiare Employers' ,..'.. nsi R i m h ti Ti n n o contributions Total «rainas other than wages employers' contributions = 100 — jÍ — 1.1 — 6.1 1.5 — — 8.3 1.4 — ' 13.3 0.7 1.4 — 1.5 3.7 3.1 4.0 1.7 3.2 Payments -'— tor tor . .- . holidays 2.2 2.7 2.1 — — 17.4 17.4 19.3 Germany—Ruhr . . . . „ —Saxony . . . 21.3 3.8 10.2 2.7 — 22.7 3.6 1.7 2.0 8.1 23.0 9.9 0.1 4.0 1.8 — 30.0 7.4 5.0 6.5 2.9 — B. Total Earnings, including employers' contributions = 100 2.9 1.9 1.1 4.0 9.9 2.1 1.0 3.5 1.4 4.0 12.0 5.4 4.1 0.6 9.3 1.3 0.7 21.4 26.1 8.7 3.5 1.3 10.6 2.0 8.2 26.9 1.5 3.3 2.4 11.5 France Czechoslovakia Poland 4.3 6.4 7.3 . . . . Great Britain Belgium Netherlands 4.6 7.3 7.7 8.2 3.5 3.2 6.6 2.6 7.1 5.8 9.6 1.5 4.5 1.8 2.6 6.2 12.1 10.7 26.2 32.1 37.5 — 85 — Certain percentages shown in the above table no doubt represent real differences in the composition of earnings. Thus the high proportion of workmen's contributions in Germany* Poland, the Saar, and Czechoslovakia is due to the fact that compulsory and contributory social insurance in these countries has a particularly Wide scope and is, to a very great extent, in the charge of workers themselves. Similarly, the conspicuously high percentage of allowances in kind other than coal in France is explained by the building activity especially in the mining regions of Northern France. On the other hand, it is obvious that a low percentage of any item does not necessarily mean that the absolute amount of this item is low as compared with that paid in another case. This remark applies particularly to allowances in kind (coal) : in countries where total actual earnings are comparatively low, these allowances are bound to represent a higher proportion in the total, since their absolute value is to some extent determined by the international market and therefore tends to be approximately equal in the different countries. Finally, employers' contributions to social insurance deserve particular attention. It is seen from the latter table that the percentage representing this item is, on the one hand, rather considerable, as a rule higher than any other single item (except in France, where allowances in kind are exceptionally important); and, on the other hand, very variable as between the different countries and districts, ranging from 4 per cent, in Great Britain and Belgium to 12 per cent, in Czechoslovakia 1. It is therefore clear, as both of the above tables indicate, that the exclusion or inclusion of employers' contributions is bound to make a real difference in the results of the comparative wage statistics. B. — DISTRIBUTION OF TOTAL WAGES BILL AMONG DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF WORKERS § 8. In order to obtain comprehensive statistics of mineworkers' wages, it is necessary to distribute the total amount of actual earnings according to different categories of the workers, as distinguished (Ö) by sex and age, and (b) by the nature of the Work under and above ground. 1 These variations are in part due to, and to some extent counterbalanced by, the subsidies from public funds which are left outside the scope of the present statistics. — 86 — As regards Belgium, no information as to the distribution of total earnings according to any of these criteria has been secured. In regard to the other countries, more or less different methods have been employed. It should be first mentioned that all countries have taken as basis of distribution the amount of total earnings as given in Table I, except Dutch statistics, which give only the total of net money wages, workmen's contributions, and allowances in cash. The method employed in the British figures is based on the results shown by the special Return of the Mining Association relating to March 1926. The distribution of total earnings by different sex and age groups is not made in the French statistics, and is given in the statistics of other countries only in an incomplete manner. The statistics of Great Britain, Germany (Prussia), the Saar, and Czechoslovakia give the distribution by adults and juveniles for men, but not for women ; they cannot therefore give the totals for adults and juveniles. In the Netherlands, no women are employed in mines, and therefore the totals for adult and juvenile men also represent the respective totals. The Polish statistics, again, distinguish, on the one hand, the earnings of male and female workers—omitting the age distribution of male workers which is given for the other countries mentioned— and, on the other hand, the earnings of adults and juveniles of both sexes taken together. Apart from these differences, it must be remembered that the age-limit of juvenile workers varies from country to country, being 16 years in Germany and in Czechoslovakia, similarly 16 years in Polish Silesia, but 18 years in the Dombrowa-Cracow district of Poland, and 21 years in Great Britain. The figures obtained thus hardly permit of any comparison. And even if these statistics were more complete, they would not show the difference between "juvenile wages" and "adult wages' ' which, as pointed out above 1, are independent of any fixed age-limit. A somewhat better result has been obtained in regard to the distribution of total earnings among hewers, underground workers and above-ground workers. All countries (except Belgium) have supplied these figures. A few divergencies of minor importance are to be noted. Thus the British statistics make it clear t h a t hewers comprise piece-work and day-Wage 1 Cf. Part One, Chapter I, § 6. — 87 — coal-getters and contractors and their helpers, except those under 21 years of age, who are included with other workers employed below ground. The German (Prussian) statistics exclude from the group of hewers the supervisory timbermen {Reparaturhauer) who are old experienced hewers, but are counted among other underground workers. However, attention should be drawn to the fact that the figures obtained are not intrinsically comparable. This applies particularly to those relating to hewers. As has been pointed out above in the theoretical part 1 , and as will be seen later on, the category of hewers does not include workers having the same functions, or doing the same kind of work, in the different countries and districts. On the other hand, the groups of "underground workers" and "surface workers" are very heterogeneous, and their composition varies considerably from country to country. § 9. It follows from the above that the summary table concerning the distribution of total earnings among different categories of workers can be given only in a restricted form. The distribution of total earnings among male and female workers and among adults and juveniles is omitted, as it cannot be usefully employed for the calculation of average earnings ; only the distribution by categories of hewers and other underground workers, as well as by those of all underground and all surface workers is given. DISTRIBUTION OF THE TOTAL EARNINGS AMONG DIFFERENT CATEGORIES O F W O R K E R S (In Percentages of the Total Actual Earnings) Underground workers Countries and districts Hewers 1 Other | Germany — R u h r . . . Great Britain Czechoslovakia G e r m a n y — U p p e r Silesia „ — Saxony . . 1 Cf Part One, Chapter I, § 3. 52 46 40 34 26 23 35 40 23 32 38 38 43 51 54 40 35 46 All 84 84 78 77 77 77 75 75 69 Surface workers Underground and surface workers 16 16 22 23 23 23 25 25 31 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 . — 88 — In order to show more clearly the results of Table II, the percentages of the total amount of actual earnings accruing to these main categories of workers are given in the table on page 87. The countries (and districts) are given in the descending order as determined by the percentage of all underground workers' earnings. The percentages are not likely to vary much according as account is or is not taken of employers' contributions to social insurance. An outstanding feature of these figures is that the portion of aggregate actual earnings accruing to hewers varies considerably (from over one-half to less than one-fourth), while the portion accruing to all underground workers taken together is sensibly more equal, being about 70-80 per cent, of the total wages bill. This seems to prove the remark made above that the category of "hewers" does not mean exactly the same thing in the different countries and districts. C. — MANSHIFTS (DAYS) WORKED § 10. The number of manshifts worked forms the necessary basis of the calculation of average earnings per manshift and per hour, and, in so far as it is utilised for ascertaining the average number of workers, of the calculation of average annual earnings. It is, therefore, very desirable that this basic measure should be computed according to uniform principles for the different countries. The result of the theoretical examination of the different methods was that the most satisfactory procedure would be to ascertain (a) the number of "normal manshifts", i.e. those comprising the legal or statutory number of hours, plus (b) the number of "overtime" shifts and (c) that of "supplementary manshifts", i.e. the hours worked overtime and in addition to the normal shift, converted to manshifts of ordinary length, plus (d) the number of "short-time manshifts", i.e. the hours comprised in short shifts (especially on week-ends) converted to manshifts of ordinary length. In practice, short-time shifts may be* for the sake of convenience, counted as normal manshifts, and item (d) may be neglected ; the possible number of hours lost from normal manshifts on account of short time, expressed in terms of manshifts of ordinary length, should then be deducted from the total 1. 1 Hours of work underground are reported to be generally reduced at week-ends only in certain districts of Great Britain, the Netherlands, and Poland (Dombrowa). — 89 — TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF TOTAL WAGES BILL AMONG DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF W O R K E R S I N T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , 1925 (National Currency— 000's Omitted) Total actual earnings, wcloding employer!' contributions to social insurance Countrj. district and unit of currencf Underground workers Hsvreri Olners Total Surface workers Total Total actual earnings, including taiployere' contributions to social insurance Underground workers . Hewers | Otters Total Surface workers Total Germany ( R.M.) : Ruhr 418,612 245,515 664,127 129,719 465,901 277,416 743,317 144,665 61,721 (a)17,340 36,122 Upper Silesia . . 15,599 33,667 (a)ll,289 17,832 15,736 Belgium (Fr.) . . France ( F r . ) . . . 602,158 1,181,320 1,783,478 539,728 642,126 1,261,018 1,903,144 574,996 Great Britain (£). 65,811 52,901 118,712 23,152 68,564 55,114 123,678 24,121 Netherlands (¿>) (Gulden) . 14,591 18,497 33,088 9,671 Poland (Zloty) : 93,572 37,134 34,536 62,935 70,943 103,479 41,858 30,637 Dombrowa . . . 18,289 24,607 15,152 26,970 16,607 16,687 8,681 7,920 Whole country . 41,635 93,343 139,954 61,997 83,350 124,985 55,489 46,611 Saar(Fr.) . . . . 222,267 194,351 416,618 138,782 Czechoslov.(Kc): Ostrava-Karvina 191,439 173,225 364,664 89,962 Kladno-Rakovnik 40,886 43,740 84,626 32,089 Whole country 270,168 253,319 523,477 147,996 307,154 288,464 595,618 168,344 (a) Including ancillary establishments. Total actual earnings of surface workers, excluding these establishments, were R.M. 15,841,000 in Upper Silesia, and this figure has been used in the calculation of averages. Corresponding figure is not available for Saxony. (b) Excluding allowances in kind, payments for holidays, as well as employers' contributions. — 90 — Information on these lines is available for Germany (Prussia) and Great Britain only. The British figures relating to normal manshifts are based on an estimate, arrived at by deducting from the total number of manshifts, as given in the regular mining statistics, the number of overtime manshifts, as estimated by the Mining Association of Great Britain. Also the Polish statistics received make a distinction between normal manshifts, on the one hand, and overtime and supplementary manshifts,. on the other, but do not allow for short-time, a fact which, however, is of minor importance and hardly affects the general comparability of the figures with those given for Germany and Great Britain. The data obtained for other countries and districts are less complete. Thus, Germany (Saxony), the Saar district, and Czechoslovakia only give the aggregate number of normal, overtime, and supplementary manshifts, but do not give separately the number of normal manshifts. On the other hand, the statistics of Belgium, France, and Netherlands do not calculate the number of manshifts at all, but give simply the number of days of attendance (journées de presence) or days worked. The difference between these methods of calculating the number of manshifts and days, and its implications as to average wages, have been sufficiently discussed above 1. Provided that overtime is not worked in any appreciable degree (short-time may be neglected in this connection), the total number of manshifts and the days of attendance mean the same thing. Now, it is understood that in Belgium, France, and the Netherlands, practically no overtime or supplementary shifts were worked in 1925, and were worked to a rather small extent in the Saar Territory and Czechoslovakia. Consequently, the data available for these countries, although ascertained according to different methods, may be considered as roughly comparable among themselves and with those given for the other countries. In the case of Saxony, however, the number of manshifts cannot be taken as representing at the same time the number of days worked. § 11. For the sake of clearness, it seems advisable to divide Table III relating t o manshifts and days worked in two parts. The first part gives the total number of manshifts (i.e. normal 1 Cf. Part One, Chapter III, § 11. — 91 TABLE I I I . NUMBER O F MANSHIFTS AND DAYS W O R K E D I N T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , 1 9 2 5 (000's Omitted) Total number of dajs normal manshifts worked Total number of manshifts worked faii.'rj and district By underground Wirkers Hewers 1 Others Germany : 49.574 38,725 Ruhr Upper Silesia. . . 1J994 7,039 2,207 2,868 Belgium (a): Couchant de Mons Whole country . France (6) Great Britain. . . . Netherlands (b). . . Poland : Dombrowa. . . . Whole countiy . . Czechoslovakia (c) : Ostrava-Karvina . Kladno-Rakovnik. Whole country . Total surface workers underground and surface workers Bj underground workers Hewers 88,299 21,783 110,082 4 8 , 5 3 1 9,033 3,344 12,377 1,913 5,075 (a)2,004 (a) 7,079 Otters Total 3,321 855 5.074 14,373 4,095 19,743 13,868 7,083 21,456 3,431 923 3,333 7,428 11,252 30,995 4,772 5,435 19,303 4,321 7,642 2,244 1,128 1,983 935 6,505 11,579 4,052 Bjundarground and surface workers 37,614 86,145 20,426 106,571 6,573 8,486 3,104 11,690 (o)8,662 1,983 7,813 9,796 1,436 6,788 8,224 1,635 5,586 7,221 6,497 26,597 33,094 18,040 40,734 58,774 206,076 54,899 260,975 87,897 105,211 193,108 2,349 3,771 6,120 3,459 10,914 938 3,157 4,819 14,924 6,589 7,279 surface workers 5,325 15,121 3,504 11.728 3,082 10,303 15,824 48,918 24,507 83,281 52,280 245,388 2,381 8,501 10,484 13,915 6,579 20,494 3.034 3,957 3,006 6,963 14,359 19,131 10,369 29,500 9,886 2,918 15,631 (a) Including ancillary establishments. (ft) The number of days worked is practically equal to that of manshifts worked. (c) The number of manshifts worked is nearly equal to that of days worked. — 92 — plus overtime, supplementary, and, if available, short-time manshifts) ; and the second, the number of days of attendance which corresponds to that of the total number of manshifts, less overtime, supplementary and short-time manshifts, i.e. the number of normal manshifts. It follows from the above review that Belgium, France, and the Netherlands do not figure in the first part, as Germany (Saxony), the Saar Territory, and Czechoslovakia do not appear in the second. Finally, it should be noted that the number of manshifts (days) is given separately for hewers, other underground workers and surface workers, as the data concerning the wages bill. In the case of Great Britain, however, separate figures relating to the manshifts worked by hewers and other underground workers are not given because this classification is established on a different basis in the statistics of manshifts and in those of days. An examination of the. table shows, in the first place, that there is a difference between the number of all manshifts and that of days worked in Germany, Great Britain, and Poland, which give both figures. This difference is highest in Upper Silesia where the former number (for all workers) exceeds the latter by €.9 per cent., and in Great Britain, where the corresponding percentage is 6.4. The relative importance of work performed by the different categories of mine-workers will be seen from the table on page 93. For the sake of simplicity, the percentages relating to manshifts and days are given together : these percentages are in fact likely to be much the same whether calculated on the basis of manshifts or days. The order of countries and districts is as determined by the percentage of manshifts (days) Worked by all underground workers. In general, the differences in the percentages of manshifts (days) worked b y the different categories of workers are similar to those shown in regard to the distribution of total earnings. It should, however, be noted that the portion of the aggregate earnings accruing to hewers is somewhat higher than the proportion of manshifts (days) worked by them. This simply indicates that hewers are paid more per manshift (day) than other workers ; and this question will be examined in detail in a subsequent section. — 93 — IMPORTANCE OF T H E MANSHIFTS (DAYS) W O R K E D BY D I F F E R E N T CATEGORIES OF W O R K E R S (In Percentages of Total Manshifts (Days) Worked) Surface workers Underground and surface workers Underground workers Country and districts Germany—Ruhr . . Great Britain . . . Czechoslovakia . . Germany—Saxony . „ —Upper Silesia. Netherlands.... Hewers Others AH 45 36 32 32 35 43 42 42 80 79 74 74 20 21 26 26 100 100 100 100 16 28 34 22 13 16 57 44 ' 38 49 54 4S 73 72 72 71 67 64 27 28 28 29 33 36 100 100 100 100 100 100 D. — MANSHIFTS (DAYS) LOST § 12. The number of manshifts and days lost is required for the calculation of average annual earnings where the average number of workers is calculated by allowing for this item. Moreover, this number is of interest as throwing light upon the conditions of labour in the coal industry in which the time lost, for various reasons, often represents a more important element than in manufacturing industries. Manshifts or days lost have been divided into two chief groups, distinguished according as (i) the mines were operating or (ii) were idle ; time lost when the mines were working is subdivided according as the absence of miners is (a) voluntary or (b) involuntary. The number of shifts lost on days when the mines were operating is recorded in colliery books. The number lost when the mines were not working is usually based upon the average number of days when the mine was not working multiplied by the average number of workers regularly employed, allowance being made for any manshifts worked on those days ; hence this number is necessarily only an estimate. The classification of time lost is different in the German statistics, which give data relating to (i) time lost owing to "personal grounds", i.e., on account of sickness, holidays, voluntary absence of workers, as well as strikes and lockouts, and (ii) time lost "due to the establishment", i.e. owing to want of trade and wagons, as well as on account of breakdowns. — 94 — The principal difference arises from the classification of time lost due to strikes and lockouts : even when they affect the •whole establishment, the time lost on account of them is counted as due to "personal causes" in the German statistics. Apart from this point, group (0) may be taken as representing time lost when mines were working, and group (b) as representing time lost when mines were idle K On the other hand, no distinction between voluntary and involuntary absenteeism of workers can be made on the basis of statistics for Germany (Prussia). Again, the Czechoslovakian statistics give a series of headings which can be conveniently arranged under the three main titles adopted above : time lost on account of paid holidays and absence without motive is classed as "voluntary absence" ; sickness and other absence is taken as "involuntary absence" ; want of trade and transport difficulties, as Well as strikes and lockouts as representing time lost when the mine was idle. The Netherlands, finally, do not furnish any information as to shifts lost when the mines were not operating. Other countries and districts—Belgium, France, Great Britain, and the Saar—have followed the standard classification mentioned above. In Great Britain, however, the division between voluntary and involuntary absence is based on an estimate, involuntary absence being taken as representing 4 1 / a per cent, of the total of manshifts which could have been worked when the mines were working 2. The information secured, therefore, is not quite complete, and is not based on entirely uniform methods : but the differences are generally of secondary importance and, with the reservations made above, rough comparisons may be attempted. The main difference arises from the fact that, manshifts lost on account of strikes and lockouts are classed differently in the German statistics than in other statistics. In fact, it would be better to establish a special group for this kind of time lost, but this is not possible on the basis of information available *. 1 2 Cf. Part One, Chapter III, § 13. This figure was adopted by the Royal Commission on the Coal Industry (1925). The Miners' Federation of Great Britain, on the other hand, maintains that thisfigureshould be higher. * This question, it may be noted, is of little direct importance for the: present enquiry. — 95 — § 13. A summary of figures secured from the different countries is presented in Table IV (page 96). There is evidently no need to make a distinction between manshifts and days of attendance in this table. The figures are given separately for underground and surface workers. The Belgian figures have been furnished by employers, the official statistics containing no information as to this point ; moreover, in these statistics, separate figures do not exist for time lost under and above ground. Since the proportion of time lost will influence both the calculated average number of workers, as well as the level of average annual earnings, it will be of interest to compare the proportion which the number of manshifts (days) lost bears to the total of manshifts (days) worked and lost in the different countries. These percentages, which refer to the total of mine workers, are as follows : IMPORTANCE OF TIME LOST, 1925 (Jn Percentages of Total of Manshifts (Days) Worked and Lost) Manshifts (days) lost Country and district „ —Upper Silesia . . . France Belgium . When When mines were mines were idle working 6.5 7.1 8.8 10.4 9.7 12.1 9.0 8.8 6.3 6.9 (a) Less than 0.1 per cent. 15.0 12.5 11.1 3.5 3.5 (a) 0.2 (b) 1.5 0.3 (b) Figure not Total 21.7 19.6 19.9 13.9 13.2 12.1 9.2 (b) 7.8 7.2 available. Total of manshifts (days) worked and lost 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 It should be noted that these figures refer to one year only, which was an exceptional year in some countries, and should not be taken as representative of general conditions in the mining industry of different countries. The differences between the various countries as to the relative importance of time lost are striking. About one-fifth of the working time was lost in 1925 in Czechoslovakia, Great Britain, and Poland. In the western coal-fields of Continental Europe, — 96 — TABLE IV. N U M B E R OF MANSHIFTS (DAYS) LOST IN T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , (000's Omitted) Distribution of manshifts lost, by causes Country and district Germany : Ruhr Upper Silesia (o) . Saxony (a). . . . Belgium : Charleroi Liège Couchant de Mous Whole Country . . France Great Britain. . . . Netherlands . . . . Poland : Silesia Dombrowa . . . "Whole Country . . Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina . Kladno-Rakovnik. 1 Whole Country . . 1925 Distribution of manshifts lost, by categories of workers When the mine was Underground working, owing to When the mine Volun- Involun- was not working Hewers Others tarytary Total absence absence 12,380 4,270 1,292 464 3 307 610 758 733 156 392 407 323 1,917 3,461 8,446 1,402 4,836 12,695 294 523 1,087 1,065 3,038 538 291 662 1,769 158 184 339 781 132 46,919 (&) 1,475 1,025 4,076 407 289 117 489 626 121 893 1,662 65 445 2,421 — — — — — — — — 14,662 1,341 705 Above ground 2,488 415 215 , .— — 2,119 — — __ — — — 952 192 1,346 4,375 — — — — — — — — — 6,494 1,935 56,305 11,755 677 140 3,744 1,001 5,226 1,446 490 2,094 — 1,253 2,205 316 508 1,802 3,148 (a) Including ancillary establishments, (b) Figure not available. 372 175 655 — 97 — t h e relative amount of time lost was less than one-tenth. The German coal fields are, in this respect-, in an intermediate position. With regard to the distribution of the time lost among the two principal classes, too; marked differences are shown. In -Great Britain, Czechoslovakia, and Poland the loss of time was mainly due to commercial or technical difficulties which necessitated the closing down of mines ; about two-thirds of total time lost were due to these causes. Conversely, the absenteeism -(voluntary and involuntary) of workers was the main source of time lost in other countries, where indeed the proportion of this loss in general was considerably smaller. The number of manshifts (days) lost owing to the non-operation of the mines was quite negligible in France, the Saar, and Saxony. Table IV affords further conclusions in respect of the relative importance of the different kinds of workers' absenteeism. "Though this question is not immediately relevant to the present enquiry, it may be worth while to observe that involuntary .absence of workers appeared generally to be more frequent than their voluntary absenteeism. The contrary was true, however, in the case of Belgium and Poland. E. — NUMBER OF WORKERS EMPLOYED § 14. The number of workers employed in and about the mines is the divisor by which the total wages bill is divided in order to get the average annual earnings. As has been pointed out, two different methods of calculation of this divisor may be employed for this purpose, giving respectively (i) the average number of workers, and (ii) the number of fulltime workers. In view of the primary object of the enquiry which is to throw light on the conditions of work of coal-mines, stress should be laid on the average number of workers, which alone can give the number of persons really in receipt of wages from the mine and can relate earnings to consumption. The number of full-time workers shows what the number of workers would have been if all workers had been regularly employed all the time. The adequate method will therefore be to take as basis the average number of workers ; but the number of full-time workers is also given for the sake of comparison. It is clear that the average number of workers and the number •of full-time workers agree when no overtime is worked, and when 7 — 98 — the mine is operating and all workers are present, every day on which work can ordinarily be done. In all other cases the latter number is bound to be lower than the former. The information furnished by the "different countries is very heterogeneous. Both figures are calculated in the existing statistics of Germany ; while the statistics of other countries only give one number of workers. Secondly, these figures have been calculated according to different methods. Thus* the average number of workers available for Great Britain is simply an arithmetic average of the number of workers a t certain pay-days on the colliery books ; the Saar and Polish statistics are based on a similar method. The statistics of Belgium, France, and the Netherlands obtain the average number of workers by dividing the total number of days of attendance actually worked by the average number of days on which mines were operating. Again, in the German statistics, the sum of normal manshifts (excluding overtime and supplementary manshifts) worked, plus manshifts lost, is divided by the number of possible working days of the year. Finally, the Czechoslovakian statistics do not give a true average number at all, but calculate a kind of number of full-time workers. It is clear that these different methods of calculation will give results which are not altogether comparable. A recalculation of these basic numbers according to uniform principles will, therefore, be necessary. The most satisfactory result is obtained by a method which allows for the lost time, as shown in the theoretical discussion 1 . If the number of days on which pits were open is unknown, then the German method, which includes the number of manshifts lost in the dividend and takes the number of possible working days as the divisor, will prove most adequate. It is largely for this purpose that the number of manshifts (days) lost has been ascertained. The relevant calculations have been effected according to these principles. As a matter of fact, the average number of coal-winding days for the whole country or district has been given only exceptionally ; on the other hand, the number of possible working days is either known or, if not known, may be 1 Cf. Part One, Chapter III, § 13. — 99 — taken as equal to 300 *. Therefore, it has seemed advisable to employ the method which consists in the division of the total of normal manshifts (days) worked and those lost, by the number of the possible working days of the year. The figures given for Germany are based on this method, and similar calculations are made for Belgium, France, the Netherlands, Poland, the Saar, and Czechoslovakia, since the necessary elements are available. The average number for Great Britain, however, is that given by the Mines Department, i.e. calculated on the basis of colliery books 2. § 15. The number of full-Lime workers, too, has been ascertained in statistics which employ this measure, according tosomewhat different methods. In Germany, this number is calculated, for each undertaking, by dividing the number of normal manshifts worked (excluding overtime and supplementary manshifts) by the number of possible working days ; the average number of possible working days, neccessary when the calculation refers to a district, is obtained by dividing the sum of normal manshifts worked in the district by the sum of full-time workers as calculated for each undertaking. In British statistics, again, the number of full-time workers has been obtained by multiplying the average number of persons employed, as recorded from the colliery books, by the number of all manshifts worked, and dividing this product by the number of manshifts which "could have been worked" (i.e. manshifts worked plus manshifts lost). The two methods will lead in practice to nearly the same results, provided that the number of "normal manshifts" worked is utilised in both ; but the results will be different in the converse case, i.e. if overtime is worked and the number of "overtime manshifts" is taken into account in the British method. 1 The number of "possible working days of the year" is given for Germany, Ruhr: 303, Upper Silesia : 298, Saxony: 302; and Czechoslovakia : 310. In France, the number of "coal-winding days" is given : 301.2 for underground, 301.6 for surface, and 301.3 for all workers; and may in this case be taken as approximately equal to the number of possible working days. This latter number is assumed in all other cases to be equal to 300. 2 If the average number is calculated for Great Britain according to the same method (in principle more adequate) as for other countries, the result does not differ much from that given in the statistics of the Mines Department. — 100 — T A B L E V. AVERAGE N U M B E R OF W O R K E R S AND N U M B E R O F FULL-TIME W O R K E R S I N T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , 1 9 2 5 Average uumber ol workers Country and district Underground Hewers Others j Total Above ground Number of full-time workers Under Under Underground Above and and ground above above Hewers Others Total ground ground Germany : 187,334 145,460 332,794 75,647 408,441 160,216 124,175 284,391 67,434 351,825 Ruhr. . . . 7,425 25,552 32,977 11,738 44.715 6,418 22,059 28,477 10,415 38,892 Upper Silesia 7,919 10,322 18,241 («)6,873 (a) 25,114 6,966 8,943 15,909 («)6,162 (a)22,071 Saxony . . . Belgium : 54,763 6,610 26,043 32,653 17,750 50,403 Charleroi . . 43,507 4,787 22,627 27,414 11,680 39,094 Liège . . . . 37,070 5,450 18,620 24,070 10,273 34,343 Couchant de Mons 176,727 21,657 88,657 110,314 52,747 163,061 Whole country 66,930 149,766 216,696 87,670 304,366 58,497 136,636 195,133 81,257 276,390 France Great Britain . . 403,200 439,400 842,600 197,900 1,040,500 308,000 353,000 661,000 163,300 824,300 22,657 8,403 Netherlands. . . , 31,060 7,827 12,570 20,397 7,937 28,334 Poland : 14,753 44,110 58,863 26,752 85,615 11,437 34,946 46,383 21,930 68,313 Silesia . . . . 3,842 12,629 16,471 11,616 28,087 3,066 10,080 13,146 9,987 23,133 Dombrowa . . 20,498 60,619 81,117 41,493 122,610 15,890 47,822 63,712 34,521 98,233 Whole country 69,333 21,963 24,263 46,226 18,117 64,343 Saar , Czechoslovakia: 13,782 17,983 31,765 8,436 40,201 10,713 13,939 24.652 7,239 31,891 Ostrava-Karvina 11,618 2,758 3,639 6397 3,016 9,413 3,376 4,658 8,034 3.584 Kladno-Rakovnik 62.693 16,368 20,984 37,352 13,071 50,423 20,711 26,797 47,508 15,185 Whole country. (a) Including ancillary establishments. — 101 — The number of full-time workers given in the Czechoslovakian statistics represents a different thing ; it is calculated simply by adding up the numbers of workers as recorded in colliery books at each pay-day (every two weeks) and by dividing the sum by the number of pay-days included in the year (26), whatever the actual working time of the mines. The figure arrived at, in cases when one or several days are not worked during a pay period, does not correspond exactly to the number of full-time workers as understood in the present report 1 . In order to render the statistics as comparable as possible, the number of full-time workers has been calculated in all cases according to a simple uniform method, that is to say, by dividing the number of normal manshifts, or days, worked, by the number of the possible working days of the year. It is to be observed that although the number of normal manshifts is lacking for Saxony, the number of full-time workers, computed according to the indicated method, has been supplied, and that in the case of the Saar and Czechoslovakia where little, if any, overtime has been worked in 1925, the number of manshifts can be taken as representing fairly the number of days worked. The number of possible working days is, in each case, the same as that used in the calculation of the average number of workers. § 16. The results of the figures obtained as to the number of workers employed in and about the mines are given in Table V. The average number of workers is given separately from the number of full-time workers ; and several of the calculations have been made by the International Labour Office on the lines explained above. Both numbers are computed for the different categories of workers (hewers, other underground workers, all underground workers and surface workers) for all countries except for Belgium and the Saar district, which give the number of days lost only for the total of workers, and for which the average number therefore can be shown only for all mine workers ; further, the average number of hewers is not available for the Netherlands. As may be expected, the number of full-time workers is lower than the average number in all countries. This difference is, however, not the same in the various countries and districts, as will be seen from the following figures : 1 Cf. Part I, Chapter III, § 14. — 102 — N U M B E R OF FULL-TIME WORKERS AS A PERCENTAGE O F T H E AVERAGE NUMBER O F W O R K E R S Saar Belgium Netherlands France Germany : Saxony Upper Silesia Ruhr Czechoslovakia Poland Great B r i t a i n 92.8 92.3 91.2 90.8 87.1 87.0 86.1 80.4 80.1 79.2 ' The number of full-time workers thus is about 10 per cent. or more below the average number in most countries ; even 20 per cent, less in Great Britain, Poland and Czechoslovakia, which is explained by the peculiar circumstances of 1925 involving a large time loss. It follows that if the calculation of wages is based on the full-time worker, the average annual earnings will be considerably higher than if the "average worker" is taken as basis. It goes without saying that the percentages of the total of mine-workers, represented by the various categories of workers under and above ground, are generally similar to those found in preceding sections, since the numbers of workers employed are calculated on the basis of the number of manshifts (days) worked and lost. These percentages, calculated on the basis of the average number of workers where possible will be seen in the following table, where countries are arranged in the descending order of the percentage of all underground workers. IMPORTANCE OF D I F F E R E N T CATEGORIES OF M I N E W O R K E R S , 1 9 2 5 (In Percentages of all Mine-Workers) Underground workers Country and district Hewers 1 Others Germany : R u h r Great Britain . Czechoslovakia Germany : Upper Silesia All UnderSurface 1 ground and surface workers workers . . . . . . 46 39 33 35 42 43 81 81 76 19 19 24 100 100 100 . . 17 32 22 28 34 13 17 57 42 50 . 44 38 55 49 74 74 72 72 72 68 66 26 26 28 28 28 32 34 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 France Netherlands (a) . . Saar (a). . . . . . Belgium (a) . . . . Poland (a) Percentages based on the number of full-time workers, because the average number is partly unknown. — 103 — It appears clearly that the "hewer" cannot represent the same category of workers in the different statistics. Apart from this, marked differences are to be noticed in the proportional numbers of underground and surface workers in the various countries. It is difficult to say, however, by what natural, economic and technical factors these differences are caused. The fact itself no doubt has some bearing upon the level of wages and the labour cost of production. F . — COMPARISON OF AVERAGE EARNINGS TERMS OF GOLD EXPRESSED IN § 17. The average earnings obtained on the basis of elements which have been passed under review above, are expressed in the national currency of each country. They are, of course, incomparable among themselves. In order to render them comparable they might be expressed in terms of gold, which is the common measure of value in the world's economy. Thus average earnings expressed in terms •of gold will show the purchasing power of these wages in the international market. The comparisons which will be made on this basis are subject to important reservations. In the first place, in countries where the national currency has not been stable in relation to gold throughout the year 1925, the total wages bill (on which the calculations of average earnings are based) is expressed in terms of a monetary unit, the value of which has changed during the period considered ; this flaw is corrected only partly by taking into account the average gold value of the national monetary unit i. Secondly—and this is a more important point—average earnings expressed in terms of gold will indicate the cost of labour per a time unit ; but they do not provide .a true index of workers' standard of living. For workers are using their earnings for buying, in their own country, commodities and services the prices of which, expressed in terms of gold, are not identical in the different countries. Therefore, it is indispensable to calculate and compare average earnings in terms of the prices of commodities, i.e. their internal purchasing power. Nevertheless, it is of interest to compute the average earnings in terms of gold as showing the discrepancy between the international and internal value of the wages. 1 This will be more obvious when wages are compared over several years. — 104 — Average earnings may be most suitably "expressed in terms. of gold" by converting them to the basis of the gold franc. The conversion of the national currencies to "gold francs"' has been effected with reference to the cost of the dollar, which. is assumed to represent gold : the cost at par of 100 dollars in francs (518.26), multiplied by 100, is divided by the product of the cost at par of the dollar in the national currency concerned, and the percentage which the cost of the dollar was, on averagein 1925, of its cost at par in the same currency 1 ; the result. gives the value of 100 units of the national currency in "gold francs". For instance, the conversion of the Reichsmark is. effected as follows : , H „„ 518.26 x 100 R . M . 1 0 0 = 4 1979 x l O O X ^ n l .no 123 ,,„ 00 -33 g°ld francs- The gold franc values of the different currencies utilised are shown in the following calculations 2 : Gold francs Germany R.M. 100 = Belgium Francs 100 = France a n d t h e Saar Territory Francs 100 = Great B r i t a i n £1 = Netherlands Guldens 100 = Poland Zloty 100 = Czechoslovakia Kc. 100 = 123.33 24.67 24.71 25.02 208.09 92.00 15.37 § 18. Average earnings are calculated for (a) hewers ; (b) other underground workers ; (c) all underground workers, i.e. the total of (a) and (b) ; (d) surface workers ; and (e) all mineworkers taken together It has been repeatedly pointed out above that a gross average for all mine-workers would have little real significance, owing to the large variety of crafts employed in mines. In theory, it would be convenient to base the international comparisons. mainly on the average earnings of a definite groups of workers,. viz. hewers ; in practice, however, this would be misleading. The natural conditions and the methods of work are so different in the various countries (and even in the various coal-fieldsof the same country), that the data relating to the number of manshifts (days) worked and lost by hewers, and the number 1 This percentage is calculated on t h e basis of t h e New York rate of exchange of each currency. See LEAGUE OF NATIONS : Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, Table X I V ("Value of Gold"). 2 These rates correspond approximately, though not exactly, to the-. rates in Swiss francs. — 105 — of hewers, are not comparable. It appears that the work done by "hewers" is different in different countries ; and what is comprised under "hewers" in one country is included under "other underground workers" in another country. The group of "all underground workers", although very general and heterogeneous, seems to provide a more suitable basis for international comparisons than the group of hewers. As regards surface workers, their work is entirely different from that of underground workers, and their average earnings evidently are of minor importance in an enquiry into the wages in the coal-mining industry. It may be very instructive to calculate separately the average earnings of an adult male underground worker for all countries. But it has been seen in the preceding analysis that this is also impossible owing to the considerable differences in the statistics of the various countries. § 19. The basic time measure to which earnings are to be related is the manshift or day. The average earnings per manshift (day) are calculated by dividing the aggregate earnings by the total number of manshifts (day). Both the dividend and the divisor may be chosen according to different principles. The total wages bill, corresponding to "total actual earnings", is taken as the dividend. For reasons set forth above \ this amount is calculated in two ways, viz. (a) excluding employers' contributions to social insurance, and (b) including the same. As has been mentioned above, the amount of employers'contributions is not known for Germany (Upper Silesia), and the Saar Territory, for the different districts of Czechoslovakia, nor for the different categories of workers in Germany (Saxony). Moreover, the distribution of the aggregate actual earnings among the different categories of workers is not available for Belgium and the Netherlands. The divisors, again, are both (i) the total number of manshifts, including supplementary and overtime manshifts, and (ii) the total number of days of attendance, corresponding to that of "normal manshifts". In principle, both these numbers should be taken into consideration in each case. This distinction is made for reasons of principle and method, as well as for the sake of actual comparison, as the figures will be influenced to a not inconsiderable degree by the different methods employed. 1 Cf. Part One, Chapter III, § 7, and also § 6 of this chapter. — 106 — As a matter of fact, however, both the number of manshifts and that of days of attendance are available for three countries only, viz. Germany (Prussia), Great Britain, and Poland ; for Germany {Saxony) and Czechoslovakia, the number of days of attendance is lacking, and for Belgium, France, and the Netherlands the number of manshifts. This would tend, other things being equal, to render the averages given for the three last-named countries too high as compared with the averages for the districts of Saxony, the Saar, and Czechoslovakia. In practice, however, this point is of little, if any, importance, owing to the fact that in all the countries concerned (except Saxony) a day is practically •equivalent to a shift 1 . The averages given for the different categories of workers in Belgium and the Netherlands are only approximate. It will be remembered that Belgium has not furnished information as to the distribution of the total wages bill among the various categories of workers ; however, these statistics give the average money wages per day (excluding allowances and similar payments) for hewers, all underground workers, and all mineworkers. On the other hand, the Netherlands show, for the different categories of workers, only the sum of net money wages, workmen's contributions and allowances in cash (excluding allowances in kind, payments for holidays, etc.), and from these data average money wages per day can be calculated for each category. It will now be easy to ascertain the ratio by which average "actual earnings" of all mine-workers (calculated on the basis of data in Tables I and III) exceed their average "'money wages" (calculated from data furnished by the Belgian and Dutch statistics). In order to render figures given for Belgium and the Netherlands comparable with the others, it has been assumed that the ratio which the unknown items of earnings, bear to the money wages is the same for each category of workers as for the total of workers ; average actual earnings are thus obtained by increasing the average money wages by a given ratio (9.5 to 11.3 per cent, for the different coal-fields of Belgium ; 13.5 per cent, in the case of the Netherlands). Table.VI (pages 108-109), where the results of the above calculations are presented, is divided into two main sections : (A) average earnings, excluding employers' contributions to social insurance, per manshift (day), and (B) average earnings, 1 Cf§ 10 of this chapter. — 107 — including employers' contributions, per manshift (day). Both tables are further subdivided into two sections, giving the averages in national currency and in gold francs respectively. The first point to which attention should be drawn is the difference between the averages computed per manshift and those calculated per day of attendance. The average per day for all mine-workers is 7 per cent, higher than the average per manshift in Great Britain and in German Upper Silesia and 5 per cent, higher in Poland. In order to facilitate the comparison of the averages obtained for the various countries and districts, the table below gives the figures showing the average earnings expressed in terms of gold francs converted to relative numbers. That is to say, the highest average earnings are taken as basis equal to 100, and the average earnings in other countries and districts are related to this basis so as to express them in terms of relative numbers. The highest average earnings, as will appear from Table VI, are as a matter of fact those received in Great Britain. RELATIVE LEVELS OF AVERAGE EARNINGS ( E X P R E S S E D IN GOLD) PER MANSHIFT AND P E R DAY (Base : Great Britain = 100) Manshift basis Underground workers Country and district Day basis Surface All workers workers Under- Surface ground workers workers All workers (A) Excluding Employers' Contributions Great Britain . . Netherlands . . Germany, R u h r . Germany, Saxony Saar Germany : Upper Silesia . Czechoslovakia . . . . . 100 — 64 57 52 100 — 70 66 60 100 : 66 58 52 100 75 62 — — 100 79 71 — — 100 74 63 57 — . . 49 48 — — 40 56 53 — — 43 50 49 — — 39 49 — 50 49 39 57 — 49 49 45 50 — 48 48 39 100 80 66 100 83 75 100 79 68 62 50 50 42 50 49 48 49 48 42 (B) Including Employers' Contributions Great Britain . . Netherlands . . Germany, R u h r . Germany, Saxony Czechoslovakia . France Belgium . . . . Poland 100 — 69 100 — 75 52 — — 43 58 — — 46 100 — 70 62 53 — — 42 — 108 TABLE V I . AVERAGE EARNINGS P E R MANSHIFT AND PER DAY I N THE E U R O P E A N GOAL I N D U S T R Y , 1 9 2 5 ( A ) E X C L U D I N G E M P L O Y E R S ' C O N T R I B U T I O N S TO SOCIAL Per manshift Country, district and unit of currency INSURANCE Per day Underground Underground Under Under Wor- Above Above and and Workers ground He- Others kers ground above underabove underwers ground Hewers Others ground ground ground (i) Average Earnings in National Currency Germany ( E . M.) : 8 44 Euhr Upper Silesia . 7.82 7 13 Belgium (Fr.) : Charleroi . . . Liège . . . . Couchant de Mons. . . . Whole country France (Fr.) . . Great Britain . . Netherlands (Gulden) . . . . Poland (Zloty) : Silesia . . . . 8.8 Dombrowa . . 8.4 Whole country 8.6 Saar ( F r . ) . . . . 33.7 Czechoslovakia (Kc): Os trava- Karvina 57.64 KladnoEakovnik. . 47.82 Wliole country 53.24 6.34 5.13 6.22 7.52 5.73 6.66 5.96 4.74 5.63 7.21 5.46 6.34 8.63 8.16 6.53 5.50 34.25 34.97 lls.6d. 8s. 5d. lOs.lOd. 5.77 5.29 5.58 26.70 6.51 6.01 6.33 30.04 5.24 4.55 4.93 25.53 6.09 5.35 5.82 28.77 40.09 47.72 40.09 45.99 38.78 38.94 42.68 45.21 34.32 36.52 40.00 42.96 7.71 6.09 6.35 5.10 7.45 5.83 6.73 31.25 31.04 21.59 21.68 27.85 28.21 31.14 22.38 28.51 31.18 22.09 28.24 30.34 22.02 27.90 12s.4d. 8s.l0d. lls.7d. 33.58 34.45 33.38 15s.Od. 29.00 10s. I d . 6.40 5.05 5.57 4.18 5.18 8.93 8.58 8.72 6.00 5.60 5.80 6.72 6.22 6.53 5.64 5.04 5.35 6.38 5.71 6.12 9.51 7.51 7.83 6.29 9.19 7.19 • 8.30 8.45 8.63 7.71 7.66 5.33 5.32 6.87 6.96 8.28 8.50 8.25 18.77 13.32 7.17 12.61 10.51 7.68 7.69 7.50 15.43 11.59 5.52 5.45 5.44 11.05 8.70 7.03 6.97 6.89 14.49 10.78 8.22 7.89 8.02 5.52 5.06 5.34 6.18 5.72 6.01 5.19 4.64 4.92 5.87 5.25 5.63 (ii) Average Earnings in Gold Francs Germany : Euhr 10.41 Upper Silesia . 9.64 Saxony . . . . 8.79 Belgium : Charleroi . . . Couchant de Mons . . . Whole country France Great Britain . . Netherlands . . . Polands : Silesia . . . . 8.15 Dombrowa . . 7.76 Whole country 7.95 8 33 Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina 8.56 KladnoEakovnik. . 7.35 Whole country. 8.18 7.82 6.33 7.67 9.27 7.07 8.21 7.35 5.85 6.94 8.89 6.73 7.82 14.39 10.53 13.55 5.31 4.87 5.13 6.60 5.99 5.33 5.82 7.42 4.82 4.19 4.54 6.31 5.60 4.92 5.35 7.11 6.16 7.33 6.16 7.07 5.96 5.99 6.56 6.95 5.27 5.61 6.15 6.60 10.64 10.06 8.05 6.78 — 109 — TABLE V I . AVERAGE EARNINGS P E R MANSHIFT AND P E R D A Y IN THE E U R O P E A N GOAL I N D U S T R Y , (B) INCLUDING EMPLOYERS' 1925 CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL Per day Per manshift Country, district and unit of currency INSURANCE Underground Underground Under Under Above and Wor- Above and Workers ground He- Others kers ground underabove above Hewers Others underwers ground ground ground ground (i) Average Earnings in National Currency Germanv (R.M.) : 8.42 6.64 Ruhr' 9 40 7.16 Upper Silesia . . Saxony Belgium"(Fr.) : Charleroi . . . Liège Couchant de Mons Whole country . France (Fr.) . . . 12s.0d. 8s.9d. Great Britain . . . Netherlands (Guld.) Poland (Zloty) : 7.34 9 98 6.50 5.91 Dombrowa . . . 9.25 5.79 6.59 4.98 Whole country . 9.67 6.25 5.51 7.09 Saar (Fr.) . . . . Czechoslovakia (Kc) Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 60.53 44.34 51.44 41.55 8.07 9.60 8.63 7.38 7.08 7.60 7.16 lls.4d. 6.87 5.87 6.52 8.33 29.01 22.49 29.50 22.56 29.78 23.37 29.42 23.02 29.75 23.46 9s.3d. 12s.ld. 5.71 4.61 35.69 36.56 35.07 35.90 35.59 15s .7d. 7.05 30.96 10s.6d. 5.56 32.55 32.45 32.51 32.49 32.38 12s.l0d. 6.14 10.07 9.41 9.77 6.77 6.03 6.50 7.58 6.82 7.32 6.36 5.52 5.98 7.19 6.26 6.85 10.64 8.73 10.27 48.87 (ii) Average Earnings in Gold Francs Germany : 11 59 Ruhr Upper Silesia . . Saxony Belgium : Charleroi . . . . Liège Couchant de Mons Whole country . 8.83 8.19 9.95 11.84 9.10 8.83 Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Poland : 918 Dombrowa . . . 8.51 Whole country . 8.90 Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 9.30 10.38 15.01 10.95 14.18 5.98 5.33 5.75 6.75 6.06 6.52 5.44 4.58 5.07 6.32 5.40 6.00 6.82 7.81 6.39 7.51 9.37 8.80 9.02 8.65 8.86 8.79 19.49 14.67 9.26 8.66 8.99 7.65 13.14 11.55 8.03 8.01 8.02 8.02 8.00 16.05 12.78 5.55 5.57 5.77 5.68 5.80 11.57 9.59 7.16 7.28 7.35 7.26 7.35 15.12 11.88 6.23 5.55 5.98 6.97 6.27 6.73 5.85 5.08 5.50 6.61 5.76 6.30 — na — The relative numbers are computed separately for earnings, (A) excluding and (B) including employers' contributions to social insurance ; further (i) on the manshift basis, and (ii) on the day (or "normal manshift") basis, and finally for the main categories of workers. As regards the last-named division, it is to be noted that the total number of manshifts worked by hewers in Great Britain is not known, and consequently relative numbers cannot be calculated for this category of workers ; this defect is, however, as shown above, of minor importance. It will be observed at the outset that the proportion of the total wages bill, represented by employers' contributions is, in Great Britain, smaller than in any other country (being equal to that in Belgium l ) and consequently the relative numbers calculated for other countries appear higher under (B) where the item concerned is included in the average earnings. This increase in the relative level of wages, due to the inclusion of employers' contributions, varies from 1 to 5 per cent. Again, owing to the fact that the total number of manshifts worked in the basic country exceeds that of days of attendance more than elsewhere (except in German Upper Silesia), the relative numbers of other countries are, in general, somewhat higher as calculated per manshift than as computed per day. The difference due to this, however, is of little importance. As regards, finally, earnings received by the main groups of workers, it will be seen that, as a rule, relative numbers for countries other than Great Britain referring to surface workersare higher than those relative to other groups of workers. This indicates that, while the earnings of underground workers exceed those of surface workers by about one-third in Great Britain, the difference is smaller in other countries ; only Belgium and France show the same proportion as the base country. It appears, however, that this fact has little bearing upon the relative level of all mine-workers' earnings, which generally is similar to that obtained for underground workers. According to these figures, the countries may be grouped, in respect of the level of average (gold franc) earnings of mineworkers, in the following rough manner. Earnings in Great Britain are considerably higher than those in. the Continental countries. Among the latter, the Netherlands and the Ruhr district of Germany form a class apart, the earnings in these 1 Cf. § 7 of this chapter. — Ill — districts attaining about three-fourths and two-thirds respectively of the British level. The Saxony district of Germany is in an intermediate position between the Ruhr and the group of Belgium, France, the Saar, German Upper Silesia, and Czechoslovakia, in which coal-fields the level of earnings is nearly equal and approximately one-half of the level in Great Britain. Finally, the level of earnings in Poland is decidedly lower than in any other country, being less than two-fifths of the British level of earnings. § 20. The average earnings per hour of work are calculated simply by dividing the amount of average earnings per manshift or per day of attendance by the number of actual hours worked. In so far as the hours worked are substantially different in different countries, this calculation will usefully complete the international comparisons based on the average per manshift or day. The average hours of labour used as basis of the calculations of average hourly earnings are those given above in the chapter concerning hours of labour 1. It is to be noted that three different concepts may be taken into consideration in respect of hours of work underground, viz. (i) hours of attendance (i.e. hours including travelling time and breaks) ; (ii) hours of attendance, excluding breaks, and (iii) hours at face. The two latter are not available for Germany, and the Saar ; the hours of attendance, excluding breaks, are not given for Great Britain. The hours of work above ground refer to the length of effective work, excluding breaks. These hours have not been obtained for the Saar territory. It is, moreover, to be noted that the average number of hours refer, in general, to the shift and not to the day. For countries in which no other basic figure than the amount of average earnings per day of attendance is available, viz. Belgium, France, and the Netherlands, the averages are calculated as per day ; as it is known that overtime and supplementary shifts •See Part Two, Chapter I, Tables I and II (with notes). It should be added that, in the case of Poland, Dombrowa, the hours as indicated in Table I are not used as such, since somewhat shorter hours are worked underground at week-ends, and a daily average based on the weekly hours must be calculated. The hours arrived at are then as follows : Hours of attendance, 7 hours 40 minutes in Dombrowa, 7 hours 54 minutes in Poland as a whole ; the same, excluding breaks, 7 hours 2 minutes and 7 hours 15 minutes respectively ; hours at face, 5 hours 58 minutes and 6 hours 10 minutes respectively. — 112 — TABLE V I I . — AVERAGE H O U R L Y E A R N I N G S COAL I N D U S T R Y , (A) EXCLUDING EMPLOYERS' IN T H E EUROPEAN 1925 CONTRIBUTIONS TO S O C I A L INSURANCE Per hour, /underground Country, district and unit of currency Hour of attendance Hour of attendance Hour at face (including travelling (excluding breaks) time and breaks) Workers | (Workers (Workers Hewers Others under- Hewers Others! under- Hewers Othersl underI 1 ground 1 ground ground (i) Average Earnings in National Currency Germany (R.M.) : Ruhr . . . . Upper Silesia . Saxony. . . . Belgium "(Fr.) : Charleroi . . Liège . . . . Couchant de Mons Whole country France (Fr.) : Great Britain . . Netherknds(Gulden) Poland (Zloty): Silesia . . . . Dambrowa . . Whole country Saar (Fr.) : Czechoslovakia (Kc.) 0 s trava- Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 1.06 0.92 0.89 0.79 0.60 0.78 4.37 4.47 4.29 4.40 4.32 0.94 0.67 0.83 0.93 0.81 0.87 1.14 1.00 3.99 3.96 3.98 3.98 3.75 3.92 — is.6y2d. 4.78 4.88 4.68 4.80 4.60 — — — 4.00 4.36 4.33 4.34 4.35 4.18 5.41 5.52 5.30 5.44 5.32 — — — — 4.94 4.90 4.92 4.93 4.62 4.83 — 2s. Od. 0.78 0.62 0.68 0.83 0.66 0.73 1.04 1.11 1.10 1.09 0.72 0.69 0.71 0.81 0.78 0.80 1.21 1.20 1.19 0.79 0.75 0.77 0.89 0.85 0.87 1.41 1.41 1.40 0.92 0.89 0.90 1.04 1.01 1.03 4.50 3.56 4.01 7.77 6.45 7.18 5.41 5.23 5.25 6.43 5.75 6.10 8.33 6.91 7.70 5.80 5.61 5.63 6.90 6.17 6.54 9.74 8.08 9.00 6.78 6.55 6.58 8.06 7.21 7.64 — — — 1.07 — — — 0.82 .90 (ii) Average Earnings in Gold Francs Germany : Ruhr . . . . Upper Silesia . Saxony. . . . Belgium : Charleroi . . . Liège Couchant de Mons Whole country . France . . . . . Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Poland : Silesia Dombrowa . . . Whole country . Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava. Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 1.31 1.13 1.10 0.97 0.74 0.96 1.08 1.10 1.06 1.09 1.07 — — — 1.1G 0.83 1.02 1.15 1.00 1.07 1.41 1.23 1.31 1.18 1.20 1.15 1.18 1.14 — — — 0.99 1.08 1.07 1.07 1.07 1.03 1.33 1.36 1.31 1.34 1.31 — 1.73 ' 1.37 — 1.62 2.16 1.22 1.21 1.21 1.22 1.14 1.19 — • 2.50 1.71 1.87 1.62 1.29 0.98 0.98 0.98 0.98 0.97 1.93 1.42 1.02 1.01 1.00 1.11 0.66 0.63 0.65 0,88 0.75 0.72 0.74 0.99 1.11 1.10 1.09 0.73 0.69 0.71 0.82 0.78 0.80 1.30 1.30 1.29 0.85 0.82 0.83 0.96 0.93 0.95 1.19 0.99 1.10 0.83 0.80 0.81 0.99 0.88 0.94 1.28 1.06 1.18 0.89 0.86 0.87 1.06 0.95 1.00 1.50 1.24 1.38 1.04 1.01 1.01 1.24 1.11 1.17 0.93 — — — — — — 113 TARLE VII. AVERAGE HOURLY EARNINGS IN T H E EUROPEAN COAL I N D U S T R Y , 1 9 2 5 (B). INCLUDING E M P L O Y E R S ' CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL I N S U R A N C E Per hour underground Country, district and unit of currency Germany (R.M.) : Ruhr Upper Silesia. . Belgium (Fr.): Charleroi . . . Couchant de Mons Whole country . France (Fr.) : Great Britain Netherlands (Gulden) . Poland (Zloty): Dombrowa . . . Whole country . Saar (Fr.) : Czechoslovakia (Kc) Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . Hour of attendance . per Hour of attendance hour Hour at face (including travelling (excluding breaks) at and breaks) Workers Workers Workers Hewers Others under- Hewers Others under- Hewers Others underground ground ground (i) Average Earnings in National Currency 1.05 1.18 0.90 4.56 4.67 4.48 4.68 4.60 4.16 4.14 4.15 4.15 4.19 4.01 l8.7i/td. 0.86 0.68 1.25 1.21 1.22 8.16 0.66 4.27 4.54 4.53 4.53 4.53 4.47 5.64 5.78 5.54 5.67 5.67 4.93 0.92 0.72 0.80 1.14 0.90 1.00 0.58 0.92 0.86 0.90 1.36 1.32 1.33 0.89 0.82 0.86 1.00. 0.94 0.98 1.59 1.55 1.57 1.04 0.97 1.01 1.17 1.10 1.15 0.74 0.67 0.70 6.94 8.75 6.41 7.44 10.23 7.49 8.69 5.36 4.98 5.10 4.89 5.01 4.91 0.75 0.81 0.76 0.79 5.98 5.14 2.81 5.13 2.82 5.14 2.92 5.13 2.88 5.16 2.94 2s.ld. H.l%d. (ii) Average Earnings ¡n Gold Francs Germany : 1.46 1.11 1.29 0.81 Upper Silesia . . Belgium : Charleroi 1.12 1.15 1.11 1.13 1.14 0.99 1.79 Dombrowa . . . Whole country . Czechoslovakia : Osfaava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . . . . Couchant de Mons Whole country . Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Poland : 1.23 1.26 1.21 1.24 1.21 1.42 1.03 1.02 1.02 1.02 1.04 2.01 1.56 1.15 1.11 1.12 0.75 0.70 0.73 1.25 0.92 1.06 1.12 1.12 1.12 1.12 1.10 1.39 1.43 1.37 1.40 1.40 1.22 1.91 1.50 1.66 2,37 0.85 0.79 0.83 1.25 1.21 1.22 0.82 0.75 0.79 0.92 0.86 0.90 1.05 1.34 0.99 . 1.13 1.67 1.27 1.27 1.27 1.27 1.28 2.61 2.08 0.69 0.70 0.72 0.71 0.73 1.41 1.21 1.46 1.43 1.44 0.96 0.89 0.93 1.08 1.01 1.06 0.68 0.62 0.64 1.57 1.15 1.32 0.82 8 — 114 — have hardly been worked in these countries in 1925, no appreciable error is introduced by this factor in the averages concerned. Table VII (pages 112-113) contains the results of the calculation of the average hourly earnings, (A) excluding and (B) including employers' contributions to social insurance. As in the case of average earnings per manshift (day), averages are further given separately in national currency and in gold francs, as well as for the different categories of workers. Figures for underground workers other than hewers are not available for Belgium. In the nature of the case, no general averages for the whole of mine workers can be given. A consequence of the considerable difference in the average number of hours is that the differences in the level of earnings as between the various countries and districts are accentuated, and show different relations to those found in the preceding comparison. RELATIVE L E V E L O F AVERAGE HOURLY EARNINGS (EXPRESSE» IN GOLD), 1 9 2 5 (Base : Great Britain = 100) Underground workers Country and district Earnings per hour of attendance 1 Earnings per hour at face Surface earnings per hour of effective work 1 A. Excluding Employers' Contributions 100 75 — 52 — 49 48 47 — 37 100 79 54 57 — 50 50 53 43 42 B. Including Employers' Contributions . . . . . . . 100 100 78 80 64 — 52 51 49 52 49 . 51 40 41 100 86 57 58 52 50 45 Belgium Germany, Upper Silesia . . . Great B r i t a i n Germany, R u h r 100 74 60 53 51 51 50 49 43 38 — 115 — This is illustrated by the table on page 114, where t h e level of hourly earnings in the different countries is related t o the average hourly earnings received in Great Britain, taken as the basic figures ; the method of presentation is similar to that employed in comparing the relative level of earnings p e r manshift (day). Owing to the fact that "hours of attendance,.. excluding breaks" are not available for Great Britain, Germany,, and the Saar, relative numbers have not been established oni this basis. As the hours of work are more or less shorter in Great Britain than in other countries, the relative levels of hourly earnings; in the latter naturally are lower than in the case of earnings' per manshift (day). In certain cases, however, the difference' in the hours is not very great, and hence the relative numbers; are practically the same in both comparisons for some countries,, viz. the Netherlands, Belgium, France, the Saar, as well as. Poland. On the other hand, the comparatively long hours indicated for Germany account for the fact that the ratio which: the hourly earnings in this country bear to the British level is lower than that found in the comparison of daily earnings. I t is seen in fact that the level of hourly earnings in Saxony is not very much above the level of Belgium and France, while the earnings in German Upper Silesia are at about the same level as those received in Poland. § 21. The average annual earnings are calculated by dividing the aggregate actual earnings by the number of workers employed. In view of the difference between the average number of workers and the number of full-time workers, both these figures have been taken as the divisor. The information available contains certain defects : first, those relating to the composition and distribution of the aggregate earnings 1 ; and secondly, the average number of the different categories of workers is unknown in the case of Belgium and the Saar, and that of hewers and other underground workers, in the case of the Netherlands. It should be further noted that the average annual earnings in the Netherlands are calculated (as in the case of daily averages) on the assumption that items other than money wages and allowances in cash bear the same ratio to money wages in the case of the different groups of workers as in the case of all mineworkers. 1 Cf. § 19 of this chapter. — 116 — TABLE VIII. AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS I N T H E COAL I N D U S T R Y , (A), EUROPEAN 1925 E X C L U D I N G E M P L O Y E R S ' C O N T R I B U T I O N S TO SOCIAL I N S U R A N C E Per worker employed Country, district and unit of currency Germany (R.M.) : Euhr : . . . . Upper Silesia . . Saxony . . . . Belgium (Fr.) : Charleroi . . . Liège Couchant de Mons "Whole country . France (Fr.) ". . Great Britain (£ s.) Netherlands (Golden) Poland (Zloty) : Silesia Dombrowa . . . "Whole country . Saar (Fr.) . ". . Czechoslovakia (Kc.) Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik "Whole country . Per full-time worker Under Underground Underground Under Above Above| and Workers ground and Workers ground | above above Hewers Others underHewers Others underground ground ground ground (i) Average Earnings in National Currency 2,235 2,101 1,969 8,997 163 4 2,077 2,061 2,031 13,891 12,111 13,044 1,688 1,414 1,728 1,996 1,568 1,865 1,715 1,350 1,613 , — •— — —^ — — — 1,590 1,494 1,541 1,388 1,304 1,337 — — 1,944 1,511 1,794 2,613 1,977 2,430 1,638 2,260 1,995 2,335 1,819 2,112 1,924 1,521 1,894 — 7,690 7,604 — — .— — 7,924 — —. — — 7,816 — — — — 7,8 8,230 6,156 7,633 10,294 8,646 9,140 6,642 120 8 14018 117 0 136 7 213 13 14917 179 12 141 16 1,504 1,185 1,418 1,920 1,516 1,671 1,255 1,427 1,321 1,375 1,527 2,679 1,416 2,583 1,472 2,620 8,011 10,120 1,801 1,655 1,743 8,010 2,017 1,693 1,872 1,517 1,962 1,607 9,013 7,660 9,633 11,480 10,664 11,309 17,870 12,427 14,792 12,427 9,390 10,533 8,953 10,046 14,825 12,020 13,229 10,640 9,453 11,019 9.746 10,710 16,505 12,072 14,015 11,322 (ii) Average Earnings in Gold Francs Germany : Ruhr . . . . Upper Silesia . Saxony Belgium : Charleroi . . . Liège Couchant de Mons Whole country . France Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Poland : Silesia . . . . . Dombrowa . . . "Whole country . Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 2,756 2,082 2,462 2,591 1,744 1,934 2,428 2,131 2,300 — — — — — — — — — 1,911 1,896 1,869 2,115 1,665 1,989 2,398 3,223 2,438 2,880 2,370 1,864 2,997 2,020 2,243 1,876 2,213 2,787 2,460 2,605 2,336 — 2,034 3,525 3,130 — .— .— 1,897 1,876 — — — — 1,955 — — — — 1,928 — — — — 1,521 1,886 2,544 2,136 2,288 1,641 2,930 3,411 5,346 3,749 4,494 3,648 2,466 2,951 3,995 3,155 3,477 2,612 1,313 1,215 1,265 1,463 1,374 1,418 1,277 1,200 1,230 2,223 1,949 4,083 3,012 .— — — — — •— — — — — — — 1,405 1,303 1,354 1,980 2,135 1,861 2,006 1,481 1,443 1,453 1,764 1,619 1,694 1,639 1,376 1,498 1,738 1,544 1,646 2,465 2,376 2,410 2,501 1,657 1,523 1,604 1,979 1,856 1,558 1,722 1,396 1,805 1,478 2,227 1,893 2,746 2,279 2,537 1,910 1,847 1,855 2,274 1,910 2,033 1,635 2,154 1,740 117 T A B L E V I I I . — AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS IN T H E COAL I N D U S T R Y , (B). EUROPEAN 1925 I N C L U D I N G E M P L O Y E R S ' CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL Per worker employed Country, district and unit of currency Germany (R.M.) : Ruhr" Upper Silesia . INSURANCE Per full-time w o r k e r Underground Underground Under Under Above and Above Workers ground and Workers ground Hewers Others underabove Hewers Others underabove ground ground ground ground (i) Average Earnings In National Currency 2,487 1,907 2,234 1,912 2,174 2,908 2,234 2,614 2,145 2,295 2,017 Belgium" !(Fr.) : Charleroi . . . Liège Couchant de Mons Whole country . France (Fr.) . . . 9,594 8,420 8,783 6,559 Great Britain (£s.d.) 170.1.0 125.8.7 146.15.8 I2I.I7.8 Netherlands (fiulden) 1,657 1,307 Poland (Zloty) : 2,341 1,608 1,792 1,565 Dombrowa . . . 2,260 1,448 1,637 1,430 Whole country . 2,274 1,540 1,725 1,494 Saar (Fr.) . . . . Czechoslovakia (Kc): Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 14,830 10,765 12,537 11,086 2,524 142.0.11 1,563 9,229 222.12.2 156.2.7 2,116 1,671 8,704 8,850 S.934 8,827 9,753 7,076 8,966 187.2.2; 147.14.2 179.6.1 1,841 1,383 1,713 1,721 1,552 1,647 3,020 2,831 2,933 2,030 1,814 1,950 2,274 2,052 2,197 12,186 18,766 13,747 8,011 7,952 8,276 8,144 8,142 10,977 1,909 1,663 1,796 2,157 1,884 2,056 15,946 12,879 15,151 (ii) Average Earnings in Gold Francs Germany : Ruhr Upper Silesia . . Saxony . . . . Belgium : Charleroi . . . 3,067 .2,352 2,755 2,358 3,586 2,755 3,224 2,645 3,113 2,488 2,830 2,712 5,570 4,403 2,280 3,906 3,477 2,410 4,681 3,831 1,748 3,696 2,878 2,147 2,183 2,204 2,178 2,215 4,486 3,565 2,371 4,255 2,081 3,138 2,170 3,673 3,448 1,621 3,050 2,720 1,976 1,962 2,042 2,009 2,012 3,554 3,252 2,154 2,079 2,092 1,479 1,332 1,417 1,649 1,506 1,587 1,440 1,316 1,374 1,583 1,428 1,515 2,778 2,605 2,698 1,868 1,669 1,794 2,092 1,888 2,021 1,756 1,530 1,652 1,984 1,733 1,892 2,279 1,655 1,927 1,704 1,873 2,884 2,113 2,451 1,980 2,329 Couchant de Mons Whole country . Great Britain . . . Netherlands Poland : Silesia Dombrowa . . . Whole country . Saar Czechoslovakia: Ostrava- Karvina. Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . 2,681 — 118 — Table VIII (pages 116-117) gives the results of the calculation of t h e average annual earnings in the different countries and districts. As before, the table is divided into two main sections, according as employers' contributions to workmen's compensation and social insurance are (A) excluded or (B) included ; and each section gives separately the average earnings (i) per worker employed (i.e. calculated on the basis of the average number of workers) and (ii) per full-time worker. In order to illustrate the differences found, relative numbers showing the level of average earnings in each country and district as compared with the level in Great Britain (where annual averages are the highest) are calculated according to the method employed in the case of daily and hourly averages. The countries and districts are arranged in a descending order as determined by the relative numbers, calculated on the average worker basis, for all mineworkers. RELATIVE LEVEL OF AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS, 1 9 2 5 ( E X P R E S S E D I N GOLD) (Base : Great Britain = 100) A v e r a g e worker basis Under- Country and district worked (A). Great Britain . . Netherlands . . Germany, R u h r . Germany, S a x o n y . . . . Belgium Germany, Upper Silesia . . Czechoslovakia . . Surface workers AU workers Full-time worker basis Underworked Surface workers All workers Excluding Employer s' Contrib utions 100 89 70 65 — — 58 100 84 72 68 — — 52 100 87 70 65 58 57 55 100 77 64 58 50 — 50 100 74 67 66 53 •— 46 100 75 65 59 50 49 48 55 48 40 57 51 42 55 48 40 50 48 40 53 49 42 50 .48 39 100 78 72 — — 47 54 45 100 79 69 63 49 49 52 42 (B). Including Employers ' Contribiitions Great B r i t a i n . . Netherlands . . Germany, R u h r . Germany, S a x o n y Czechoslovakia . . . . . . 100 94 75 — — 59 52 43 100 89 77 — — 53 56 45 100 92 75 70 57 57 63 43 100 82 69 •— — 51 52 43 — 119 — As may be expected, the relative numbers obtained when employers' contributions are included appear here, in general, as higher than those relating to average earnings when these contributions-are excluded. In this respect the above table shows almost exactly similar results to those given in preceding* comparisons. Similarly, the average earnings per full-time worker and the corresponding relative numbers do not introduce a new element in the discussion. As a matter of fact, average annual earnings per full-time worker are bound to be equal to average daily earnings multiplied by the number of ordinary working days (about 300 in most cases), and add little to information which is already obtained on the basis of daily averages. The absolute average earnings per full-time workers (as given in Table VIII) are, of course, higher than those calculated on the average worker basis ; the relative numbers, again, appear lower for most Continental countries. This is due to the fact that the number of full-time workers in Great Britain was, in 1925, considerably smaller than the average number of workers. The outstanding feature of the above figures is that the relative levels of the annual earnings, calculated on the basis of the average number of workers, approaches in the Continental countries and districts the British level considerably more than is the case in respect of daily and hourly earnings. The natural explanation of this is that the time lost (in 1925) which is allowed for in the calculation of the average number of workers, was in Great Britain larger than in other countries, except in Czechoslovakia, which showed the maximum, and Poland, where it was nearly as great as in Great Britain \ The picture of the relative wage levels in European countries is thus different from that shown in respect of daily and hourly earnings. While Great Britain still shows the highest level, the Netherlands now come very near it, especially when employers' contributions are taken into account, and the Ruhr and Saxony districts of Germany also show a relatively high wage level, which attains three-fourths of the British in the Ruhr. The Saar territory, France, Belgium and German Upper Silesia show a rather similar wage level which is more than one-half of that found for Great Britain ; the same applies to Czechoslovakia when 1 Cf. §§ 12 and 14 of this chapter. — 120 — employers' contributions are counted. Poland, where time-loss was considerable (as mentioned above) remains in the same relative position as in tables concerning daily and hourly averages. G. — COMPARISON OF THE RELATIVE PURCHASING POWER OF AVERAGE EARNINGS § 22. Comparison of earnings expressed in terms of gold does not give an adequate measure of the relative level of earnings from the point of view of the standard of living of the workers. It is therefore indispensable to complete the study of average earnings per time unit by expressing them in terms of the prices of commodities and services upon which the miner's wage is usually spent. The average earnings expressed in terms of commodity prices of the different countries will show their purchasing power in the internal market. The method adopted is identical with that which has been adopted by the International Labour Office for several years in comparing the real wages of workers in certain occupations in different capital and other cities 1 . To put it briefly, this method consists in (i) calculating the price of a given quantity of foodstuffs, a "basket of provisions", in typical mining districts of different countries ; (ii) calculating how many times the miner can purchase, with his earnings, the "basket" of his own district, on the one hand, and the foreign "baskets", on the other ; finally, (iii) calculating index numbers in each case, by relating the numbers (which show how many times the average earnings can purchase each basket) to a common basis, and taking a general average of these index numbers 2. This method, it will be seen, amounts to calculating index numbers of the relative purchasing power of earnings, or of comparative real earnings. It is by no means a fully satisfactory method, and it is indeed necessary to make in advance. all reservations against any close comparison of the results. In the first place, the fact alluded to above that in periods of fluctuations in the value of currency the purchasing power of the monetary unit is not constant, has its importance also in the calculation of real earnings. The principal defect, however, is that only certain items of food consumed by 1 See International Labour Review, "Vol. X, No. 4, Oct. 1924, and subsequent issues. 2 The method is explained in detail in Appendix III. — 121 — miners are taken into account. The real earnings calculated accordingly would be representative only provided that the relative price level of all commodities consumed by the miners would correspond to that of foodstuffs considered ; and this cannot be assumed. Moreover, it is to be noted that although the expenditure on food, as a rule, forms the largest part in the workers' budget, it bears a varying ratio to the total family budget in the different countries. The inclusion of other items of expenditure (clothing, rent, etc.) is, however, in practice impossible owing to the lack of information as to expenditure on these quantities, and the very considerable differences in the habits of consumption of the different countries. § 23. The index numbers of comparative real earnings are given in Tables IX to XI (pages 122-127). Table IX is based on the average earnings per day (in the case of the Saar and Czechoslovakia per manshift) and gives index numbers separately for (i) underground workers, and (ii) all mine-workers. Table X refers to average hourly earnings, and is divided into three sections, viz. (i) earnings per hour of attendance (including travelling time and breaks) underground, (ii) earnings per hour at face underground, and (iii) earnings per hour at the surface. Finally, Table X I shows the comparative level of real average earnings per annum (i) per underground workers and (ii) for all mine-workers. Each table is, moreover, divided into two main sections according as employers' contributions to social insurance are (A) excluded or (B) included 2. The calculations of index numbers are based on four different "baskets of provisions" representing quantities of food consumed in Germany, Belgium, Great Britain, and Poland. The purchasing power of average earnings received in Great Britain is taken as basis (equal to 100). A remark is to be made as regards France. The average earnings refer to the whole country ; the prices used in the calculation are those current in the northern region. Now, prices in the north of France are in general higher than in France as a whole, and consequently the index numbers of real earnings are somewhat under-estimated. If a separate calcalation could be made for Northern France (which is impossible 1 These three tables thus correspond to Tables VI, VII and VIII, and are based on data contained therein as to average earnings expressed in national currency. — 122 — TABLE IX. I N D E X NUMBERS OF COMPARATIVE REAL EARNINGS P E R MANSHIFT ( D A Y ) , IN T H E EUROPEAN COAL I N D U S T R Y , (Base : Great Britain (A) EXCLUDING EMPLOYERS' Country and district = 100) CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL INSURANCE Index numbers based on quantities of food consumed in : Great Britain Belgium 1925 Germany Poland General average index number (i) Average Earnings of All Underground Workers Great B r i t a i n . . . Netherlands . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. France Saar Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Ruhr Upper Silesia . . 100 81 68 100 83 69 100 89 78 100 84 75 100 84 73 64 59 60 63 65 62 69 68 66 68 68 65 66 65 63 57 59 62 64 61 57 48 44 53 45 45 69 60 55 66 57 55 61 53 50 (ii) Average Earnings of All Workers (Under and Above Ground) Great B r i t a i n . . . Netherlands . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Saar . . . . . . . Germany : Ruhr Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Upper Silesia Poland 100 80 65 100 82 67 100 88 74 100 83 72 100 83 70 65 61 58 64 63 63 70 67 67 70 66 64 67 64 63 58 55 71 68 63 57 58 62 64 60 48 44 46 45 61 55 58 55 53 50 — 123 — TABLE I X . I N D E X NUMBER OF COMPARATIVE REAL EARNINGS P E R MANSHIFT ( D A Y ) I N T H E E U R O P E A N COAL I N D U S T R Y , 1 9 2 5 (Base : Great Britain B. = 100) I N C L U D I N G E M P L O Y E R S ' CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL I N S U R A N C E Country and district Index numbers based on quantities of food consumed in : Great Britain Belgium Germany Poland General average index number (i) Average Earnings of AU Underground Workers Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Belgium Germany : Ruhr France Poland 100 85 68 100 87 69 100 94 78 100 89 75 100 89 73 61 61 48 58 66 49 74 70 59 71 67 59 66 66 54 (ii) Average Earnings of All Workers (Under and Above Ground) Great B r i t a i n . . . Netherlands . . . Belgium Germany : Ruhr France Poland 100 84 65 100 87 67 100 93 75 100 88 72 100 88 70 63 59 48 60 65 49 77 68 59 72 66 59 68 65 54 ' — 124 — TABLE X. — INDEX NUMBERS OF COMPARATIVE REAL EARNINGS PER HOUR, 1925 (Base: (A), Great Britain = 100) EXCLUDING EMPLOYERS' CONTRIBUTIONS Country and district TO SOCIAL Index numbers based on quantities o! food consumed In : Qreat Britain Belgium Germany Poland INSURANCE General average index number (i) Average Earnings of All Underground Workers per Hour of Attendance Great B r i t a i n . . . Netherlands. . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Ruhr Germany : Upper Silesia . . 100 79 69 100 81 71 100 87 79 100 82 76 100 82 74 69 64 61 68 66 67 74 71 71 73 69 68 71 68 67 62 63 67 69 65 56 43 52 44 68 54 64 54 60 49 42 40 53 50 46 (ii) Average Earnings of AU Underground Workers per Hour at Face Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Belgium Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik 100 80 66 100 82 68 100 89 76 100 84 73 100 84 71 66 60 65 63 72 67 71 64 69 64 60 43 61 44 65 53 67 53 63 48 (iii) Average Earnings of AU Surface Workers per Hour of Attendance (Excluding Breaks) Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Ruhr Poland Germany : Upper Silesia . . 100 85 100 87 100 95 100 89 100 89 79 69 77 69 85 -79 84 75 81 73 68 61 69 67 74 71 76 67 72 67 51 48 47 49 61 53 58 59 54 52 42 39 59 50 48 — 125 — TABLE X. I N D E X N U M B E R S OF COMPARATIVE R E A L EARNINGS PER HOUR, 1 9 2 5 {Base : Great Britain (B). INCLUDING EMPLOYERS' Country and district = 100) CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL Index numbers based on quantities of food consumed in : Great Britain Belgium Germany Poland INSURANCE General average index number (i) Average Earnings of AH Underground Workers per Hour of Attendance Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Germany : Ruhr 100 83 70 63 100 85 71 69 100 92 79 72 100 87 77 69 100 87 74 68 60 47 56 48 72 58 69 58 64 53 (ii) Average Earnings of All Underground Workers per Hour at Face Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . 100 85 66 60 46 100 87 67 65 47 100 94 75 69 57 100 89 73 66 57 100 89 70 65 52 (iii) Average Earnings of All Surface Workers per Hour of Attendance (Excluding Breaks) Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Germany : Ruhr 100 . 92 69 63 52 100 94 70 68 53 100 101 78 72 65 100 96 76 69 64 100 96 73 68 59 53 50 65 62 58 — 126 — TABLE X I . I N D E X N U M B E R S O F COMPARATIVE REAL EARNINGS PER YEAR, 1925 (Base : Great Britain (A), EXCLUDING = 100) EMPLOYERS' CONTRIBUTIONS Country and district TO SOCIAL INSURANCE Index numbers based on quantities of food consumed in : Great Britain Belgium Germany General average index number Poland (i) Average Earnings of All Underground Workers Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Germany : Ruhr Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Upper Silesia . . 100 95 70 100 97 77 100 105 81 100 99 78 100 99 77 64 61 78 74 69 67 66 72 72 69 62 63 67 70 54 46 61 47 68 57 64 57 ' 66 59 52 (ii) Average Earnings of All Workers (Under and Above Ground) Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Germany : Ruhr Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Upper Silesia . . 100 93 77 72 67 100 95 78 74 73 100 97 85 78 74 100 97 82 76 73 67 100 102 88 80 78 74 68 73 71 65 61 79 75 70 61 62 66 69 65 53 45 51 46 67 56 64 56 59 51 — 127 — TABLE X I . I N D E X N U M B E R S OF COMPARATIVE R E A L E A R N I N G S PER YEAR, (Base: (B). INCLUDING Great Britain EMPLOYERS' Country and district 1925 = 100) CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL INSURANCE Index numbers based on quatities of food consumed in : Great Britain Belgium Germany Poland General average index number (i) Average Earnings of All Underground Workers Great Britain . . . Netherlands . . . Germany : Ruhr 100 100 72 100 103 78 100 111 83 100 105 80 100 105 78 69 49 65 50 84 61 80 61 75 55 (ii) Average Earnings of All Workers (Under and Above Ground) Great B r i t a i n . . . Netherlands . . , Germany : Ruhr 100 98 77 69 100 100 78 75 100 108 88 80 100 102 85 76 100 102 82 75 70 49 66 50 85 60 80 60 75 55 — 128 — owing to the absence of information on earnings) the indexes might be three or four points higher than those given in the tables. Czechoslovakia, again, must be omitted from Tables (B), where employers' contributions are included, because this item is known only for the country as a whole, whereas the prices of commodities are given, and consequently index numbers of real earnings are calculated, separately for both districts. Finally, information as to the level of prices in the coal-fields of the Free State of Saxony has not been received, and therefore this country is omitted from the tables. The results of the calculations of comparative real earnings are summarised below. For the sake of simplicity, only index numbers of earnings per hour of attendance are reproduced in the case of average hourly earnings of underground workers. The countries are arranged in the descending order of the index number of average annual earnings for all mine workers. I N D E X N U M B E R S OF COMPARATIVE REAL EARNINGS, 1 9 2 5 (Base: Great Britain = 100) Average index of daily earnings Country and district Average index of earnings per hour of attendance UnderUnder- Surface All ground ground workers workers workers workers Average index of annual earnings UnderAll ground workers workers A. Excluding Employers' Contributions Great Britain Netherlands Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. . . Germany : Ruhr . . . . Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik . . Germany : Upper Silesia. 100 84 73 63 65 100 83 70 64 63 100 82 74 68 67 100 89 73 100 99 67 76 100 97 82 76 73 66 61 67 63 71 60 81 54 69 69 71 70 61 53 50 60 53 50 65 46 49 72 48 52 66 59 52 65 59 51 B. Including Employers' Contributions Great Britain Germany : Ruhr . . . . 100 89 73 66 66 "54 100 88 70 65 68 54 100 87 74 68 64 53 100 96 73 68 58 59 100 105 78 75 65 100 102 82 75 75 55 — 129 — The above index numbers show that the real earnings index number is, in general, highest in Great Britain. However, in the case of annual earnings, the level of the Netherlands is practically equal when employers' contributions are excluded, and even higher when that item is taken into account. The Netherlands take also the second place in the case of the level of daily and hourly real earnings, and show a distinct maximum level for Continental Europe. To group the other countries according to the general level •of earnings is a difficult task owing to the variety in the index numbers. As a rule, however, the indexes for annual earnings are higher than those for daily and hourly earnings, in each country, while the two latter index numbers show a similar tendency. Roughly speaking, it may be observed that Belgium •occupies an intermediary position between the Netherlands and a group formed by the coal districts of France, the Saar, the Ruhr, and Czechoslovakia, where real earnings are .approximately at the same level. Finally, German Upper Silesia and Poland show fairly uniform index numbers of real earnings which represent not more than 50 per cent, of the British level in the case of daily and hourly earnings, and less than 60 per cent, of that level in the case of annual earnings. These results are rather different from those arrived at in the comparison of average earnings expressed in terms of gold francs. When Great Britain is taken as basis, it is seen (a) that the relative numbers of "gold franc earnings" and the index numbers of "real earnings" are approximately equal in the Ruhr and Upper Silesian districts of Germany, while (6) the relative level of "real earnings" is more or less higher than that shown by the relative numbers of "gold franc earnings" in the remaining countries and districts. In general, when related to the purchasing power of money, the "standard of living" of workers employed in the different Continental coal-fields appears more uniform, although far from equal. § 24. It may be interesting to compare the above results with those arrived at in the calculations of comparative real wages of workers of different occupations in various capital -and other large cities which have appeared in the International Labour Review, calculations in which the International Labour Office has applied the same method as in the preceding 9 — 130 — paragraphs 1 . The results conform roughly in both cases ; but certain differences are also to be found. Thus the index numbers of real daily earnings in the Belgian and Czechoslovakian coal-fields (Great Britain being taken = 100) are considerably higher than the indexes of real weekly wages in Brussels and Prague (London being taken = 100) ; both series of index numbers are nearly identical for the Dutch, French, and Ruhr coal-fields on the one hand, and for Amsterdam, Paris, and Berlin on the other ; while the index numbers of miners' real earnings in the Upper Silesian and Polish coal-fields are somewhat lower than the indexes of city workers' wages in Berlin and Lodz. The order of coal-fields therefore differs from that found for the respective cities, among which Brussels, Lodz, and Prague show the lowest index numbers of real wages. H. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL § 25. The second principal object of the present enquiry into wages in the coal industry is to calculate the labour cost of production. For this purpose, it is necessary to ascertain at the outset the quantity of coal produced which forms the basis of the calculation. Two different quantities have been taken into account, viz. (i) the quantity of saleable coal obtained after the coal raised has been cleaned, and (ii) the net quantity of commercially disposable coal, i.e. saleable coal less coal consumed by the mine and coal distributed to the employees. The figures secured from the different countries have been established according to a uniform basis and require no comment. The figures relating to the total output of coal and its distribution for different uses in the several countries and districts are given in Table XII. For Czechoslovakia, official statistics of output of coal are available for the whole country, but not for the different districts to which the wage data refer. 1 The "index numbers of comparative real wages in various cities"" taken into account here refer to wage rates and prices at 1 July 1925, except as regards Paris, for which city data are not available for this date and whose situation at 1 April 1925 is considered. Cf. International Labour Review, Vol. XII, No. 1 (July 1925), p. 106, and Vol. X I I , No. 4 (Oct. 1925), p. 570. — 131 — TABLE XII. TOTAL OUTPUT OF COAL IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, 1925 (Metric Tons: 000's Omitted) Country and district Germany : Ruhr* Upper Silesia. . . . Saleable coal Coal consumed by the mine Commercially Coal distributed to disposable employers coal 104,124 14,273 3,869 6,932 513 488 1,280 198 86 95,912 13,562 3,295 7,521 5,201 4,931 23,097 47,571 238,920 6,849 732 462 669 2,491 4,081 15,148 256 133 136 121 521 1,201 5,913 57 6,656 4,603 4,141 20,085 42,289 217,869 6,536 21,660 5,729 29,081 12,597 1,981 576 2,790 929 478 189 721 347 19,201 4,964 25,570 11,321 9,140 1,826 12,559 595 458 1,313 157 56 254 8,388 1,312 10,992 Belgium : Couchant de Mons . Whole country . . . France Poland : Whole country . . . Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina . . Kladno-Rakovnik. . Whole country . . . — 132 — The following figures show the ratio which the different items bear to the total quantity of saleable coal. COAL DISTRIBUTED FOR DIFFERENT USES, 1925 (In Percentages of Total Coal Produced) Country and district Netherlands Germany : Upper Silesia . Ruhr . . . . Great Britain Saar France Poland Czechoslovakia Belgium Germany : Saxony . . . CommerCoal Coal cially Total of consumed by distributed disposable saleable coal coal the mine to employees 3.7 3.6 6.7 6.3 7.4 8.6 9.6 10.5 10.8 12.6 0.8 1.4 2.2 95.5 95.0 92.1 91.2 89.8 88.9 87.9 87.5 86.9 85.2 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 It appears from the above percentages that the distribution of saleable coal varies in a not insignificant degree. The relative quantity of commercially disposable coal is generally about 90 per cent, of the saleable quantity, but is considerably more in German Upper Silesia and the Netherlands (95-96 per cent.), and less especially in the Saxony district of Germany (85 per cent.). While coal consumed by the mine forms less than 5 per cent. of the total in a few cases (the Netherlands and German Upper Silesia), it is twice or thrice as large in others (particularly in the Saxony district, Belgium, and Czechoslovakia). The quantity of coal distributed to employees represents in most countries 2 or 2.5 per cent, of the total, but it is in some cases (the Netherlands and Prussian districts in Germany) less than this proportion. § 26. The average output, which is of interest as indicating the differences which exist in the natural conditions and the efficiency of labour in the different countries, is calculated (a) for manshift or day as well as (b) for year and worker, separately for hewers, underground workers and all workers under and above ground. It is evident that these averages, in the calculation of which the divisors are, on the one hand, the number of manshifts or days and, on the other, the number of workers employed, are comparable only with the appropriate reservations made above. — 133 — TABLE X I I I . AVERAGE O U T P U T OF SALEABLE COAL I N E U R O P E A N COUNTRIES, (Metric 1925 Tons) Average output Per day Per manshift Country and district Hewer Germany : Ruhr". . . . Upper Silesia Saxony . . . Belgium : Charleroi . . Liège . . . . Couchant de Mons Whole country . France Great Britain. . . Netherlands . . . Polands : Silesia Dombrowa. . . Whole country Saar Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country Underground Average annua! output Under and above ground Newer Under- Per worker Under and above ground Hewer Underground Per full-time worker Under and above ground Hewer Underground Under and abate ground 2.100 1.179 0.946 2.146 1.209 0.977 557 313 255 650 366 296 7.156 1.5 1.153 7.462 1.682 1.231 2,039 433 319 2,224 501 367 0.595 484 215 156 555 243 180 1.753 0.762 0.561 137 1,074 228 150 3.79: 0.768 0.497 118 1,040 186 133 3.622 0.632 0.444 133 986 205 145 3.017 0.683 0.479 130 1,049 208 142 3.555 0.698 0.472 2.637 0.809 0.571 711 220 156 813 244 172 1.159 0.915 2.718 1.237 0.974 593 284 230 776 361 290 342 245 298 221 2.920 1.120 0.800 6.262 1.507 1.010 6.313 1.557 1.057 1,468 368 253 1,894 467 6.108 1.399 0.771 6.207 1.448 0.823 1,491 348 204 1,869 436 6.035 1.473 0.938 6.094 1.520 0.986 1,419 359 237 1,830 456 182 574 273 1.912 0.908 0.653 2.752 1.196 0.925 2.136 0.921 0.626 2.475 1.085 0.803 642 278 220 523 220 152 587 256 194 317 248 296 196 853 371 287 662 285 194 779 341 253 — 134 — The average output of saleable coal in various countries and districts is shown in Table X I I I (page 133). The basis of the calculation of the average output for manshift (day) is the total number of manshifts (days). Averages are computed both for manshift and for day of attendance (normal manshift) for all countries and districts which furnish these basic figures 1. The differences in the average output in the various countries and districts will be illustrated by the following relative numbers. The maximum output is reached, as is seen in Table XIII, in German Upper Silesia ; this output is taken as equal to 100 and the output of other districts is related to this figure. The countries are arranged in descending order as determined by the relative number of output (per manshift) underground. RELATIVE L E V E L OF AVERAGE OUTPUT OF SALEABLE COAL FOR MANSHIFT AND FOR DAY, 1 9 2 5 (Base : German Upper Silesia — 100) Manshift basis Country and district Underground Germany : Upper Silesia . . . Day basis Under and above Underground ground 100.0 96.4 88.6 74.6 73.4 68.7 100.0 87.6 66.9 82.0 79.4 69.6 64.0 48.2 53.0 48.7 Netherlands Belgium Under and above ground 100.0 92.6 86.1 71.9 73.5 100.0 85.9 66.9 79.4 79.1 66.6 65.0 46.1 41.5 48.3 46.4 38.3 The order of countries and districts is thus slightly different according as the average output for manshift or that for day (or "normal" manshift) is taken as measure; the relative numbers calculated on the manshift basis are generally higher, as compared with the basic district, than those established on the day basis, except in respect of underground work in Great Britain. The main feature of the table is the considerable difference in the average output between the various coal-fields of Europe. Taking first into account the output for manshift (day) 1 Cf. § 11 and Table III of this chapter. — 135 — underground, it is seen that the most productive coal-fields are in Silesia, both German and Polish, followed rather near by the Dombrowa district of Poland. Again, the average output in Great Britain and the Ruhr district of Germany is practically similar, being nearly three-quarters of the Upper Silesian quantity. In Czechoslovakia and the Netherlands, the output is, on the average, much below that reached in their neighbouring coal-fields mentioned above ; finally, the daily output of a miner in the Saar is little over half, and in Saxony, France, and Belgium less than half of the maximum quantity reached in Europe. These conclusions are apt to be changed but little if the average output is computed for underground and surface workers taken together. The principal point about these latter figures is that the Dombrowa district of Poland descends to the level of Czechoslovakia and the Netherlands. The output in the Ruhr district of Germany and in Great Britain appears higher, compared with the Upper Silesia level, than when underground workers alone are considered ; which fact is largely explained by the percentage of manshifts (days) worked by surface workers, which is relatively lowest in these regions K § 27. Turning now to the average annual output, it is to be observed that both the average number of workers and the number of full-time workers have been utilised as bases for the calculations, as far as available 2 (see table on next page). In order to compare the level of the averages obtained for the different countries and districts, relative numbers have been •calculated according to the same method as in the preceding case. The order of the countries and districts is determined by the average annual output per worker underground. It is evident, in view of the method adopted for the calculation of the average number of workers, that the averages relating to annual output per worker actually employed, and the corresponding relative numbers, are bound to be influenced by the quantity of time lost. It is equally obvious that the averages computed per full-time worker (which eliminates the element of time lost) will be approximately equal to the daily 1 2 Cf. § 11 of this chapter. Cf. § 16 and Table V of this chapter. — 136 — RELATIVE L E V E L O F AVERAGE ANNUAL OUTPUT OF SALEABLE COAL P E R W O R K E R , 1 9 2 5 (Base: German Upper Silesia Average worker basis Country and district Per worker underground = 100) Full-time worker basis Per worker Per worker Per worker under and underground under and above ground above ground Germany : 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 85.0 80.4 79.3 63.9 93.2 87.0 86.4 67.6 72.3 68.8 65.6 61.0 79.9 69.3 72.1 62.7 57.1 48.9 73.1 68.3 '72.1 68.1 54.5 48.7 80.7 66.8 79.0 68.9 53.4 46.9 48.9 40.8 48.5 41.5 49.0 38.7 Poland : Germany : — 50.8 Germany : 49.7 — averages multiplied by a figure near to 300, and that the corresponding relative numbers will be nearly similar. Attention should, therefore, be given to the figures relating to the averages established on the basis of the average number of workers. It will be remembered that the time lost was, in 1925, relatively larger in Great Britain, Czechoslovakia^ and Poland, than in France, the Netherlands, Belgium, and the Saar, the German coal districts taking an intermediate position l . It is then natural that the mutual position of the countries and districts is somewhat different in the above comparison than in that made in regard of average daily output. The differencesare not, however, very marked. The Polish districts, while showing lower relative numbers for annual than for daily output, still appear as the most productive coal-fields after German Upper Silesia. The Ruhr district of Germany, and Great Britain, which are joined by the Netherlands, form the following group, the average annual output per worker of which is 65 to 80 per cent, of the basic figure. After Czechoslovakia follow France, the Saxony district of Germany, and Belgium, with an average annual output of less than half the maximum quantity reached in Europe. 1 Cf. § 13 and Table IV of this chapter. — 137 — I. — COMPARISON OF THE AVERAGE LABOUR COST PER TON OF COAL § 28. The total "cost of labour" is taken as equivalent t o the total wages bill as defined above, i.e. the aggregate amount of actual earnings received by the mine-workers. On the other hand, the most suitable basis for measuring the labour cost is the ton of coal, saleable and commercially disposable. The average labour cost of production is calculated from these elements simply by dividing the total wages bill, (A) excluding employers' contributions, and (B) including the same, by the total (metric) tonnage of (i) saleable coal and (ii) commercially disposable coal. In the nature of the case, no distinction is made between the different categories of workers. For the sake of comparison, the averages have been converted to gold francs by the method employed in respect of average earnings \ RELATIVE LEVEL OF AVERAGE LABOUR COST P E R TON OF COAL, 1 9 2 5 (Base : Great Britain = 100) Per ton of saleable coal Country and district Per ton of commercially disposable coal (A). Excluding Employers Contributions 100 99 96 90 81 73 63 55 38 39 Belgium 100 104 103 86 84 75 63 58 40 38 (B). Including Employers Contributions Germany : Saxony. . . i Cf. § 17 of t h i s c h a p t e r . r . . . . 100 105 100 96 83 68 61 41 100 112 104 91 85 67 63 43 — 138 — T A B L E X I V . — AVERAGE W A G E S P E R METRIC TON OF COAL IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, (A), E X C L U D I N G 1925 E M P L O Y E R S ' CONTRIBUTIONS TO SOCIAL INSURANCE Average wages per ton Country, district and unit of currency Germany (R.M.) : Ruhr Upper Silesia . . Belgium (Fr.) : Charleroi . . . . Couchant de Mons Whole country . France (Fr.) : Great Britain Netherlands (Gulden) Poland (Zloty) : Dombrowa . . . Whole country . Saar (Fr.) : Czechoslovakia (Kc.) : Ostrava-Karvina . Kladno-Rakovnik Whole country . In national currency In gold francs Saleable coal Commercially disposable coal Saleable coal Commercially disposable coal 7.62 4.73 11.59 8.28 4.98 13.61 9.40 5.83 14.25 10.21 6.14 16.79 55.99 63.61 69.57 59.80 48.85 lls.lld. 6.45 63.27 71.87 70.94 68.77 54.94 13s.0d. 6.74 13.81 15.69 14.70 14.75 12.07 14.91 13.42 15.61 17.73 17.50 16.97 13.58 16.26 14.03 6.03 6.94 6.21 6.81 8.01 7.06 5.55 6.38 5.71 6.27 7.37 6.60 44.09 49.74 63.92 53.47 49.06 54.20 88.96 61.09 10.89 7.66 9.82 8.22 12.12 8.33 13.67 9.39 — 139 — TABLE XIV. AVERAGE WAGES P E R METRIC TON OF COAL IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, (B). INCLUDING EMPLOYERS' CONTRIBUTIONS 1925 TO SOCIAL Average wages per ton in national currency Country, district and unit Saleable coal Germany (R.M.) : Ruhr* Saxony Belgium (Fr.) : Charleroi Couchant de Mons . Whole country . . France (Fr.) . . . . Great Britain . . . . Netherlands (Gulden). Poland (Zloty): Dombrowa . . . . Whole country . , Saar (Fr.) Czechoslovakia (Kc.) : Ostrava-Karvina . . Kladno-Rakovnik . Whole country . . Commercially disposable coal INSURANCE Average 'wages in gold francs Commercially Saleable disposable coal coal 8.63 9.27 10.52 11.43 13.09 •16.37 16.14 18.96 58.32 66.51 62.21 62.31 52.09 12s.4d. 7.09 65.90 75.16 74.08 71.66 58.60 13s.7d. 7.43 14.39 16.41 15.35 15.37 12.87 15.43 14.75 16.26 18.54 18.28 17.68 14.48 16.99 15.46 6.80 7.61 6.94 7.67 8.78 7.90 6.26 7.00 6.38 7.06 8.08 7.27 60.75 69.50 9.34 10.68 — 140 — The results arrived at are presented in Table XIV (pages 138139). In order to facilitate the comparison of the average labour cost expressed in terms of gold francs, relative numbers have" been computed (see table on page 137) according to the method used in comparing the average earnings. Wages paid per ton of coal in Great Britain are taken as basis, although it will be seen at once that in three out of four series of figures they do not attain the maximum in t h a t country. The other countries and districts are arranged in descending order of the relative number showing the wages per ton of commercially disposable coal. It will be seen that the relative level of the average labour cost in the several countries and districts is influenced to some extent by the exclusion or inclusion of employers' contributions on the one hand, and of the quantity of coal consumed by the mine and the miners on the other. The average wages cost appears as the highest in Great Britain only provided that employers' contributions are excluded (representing a very low proportion of total wages in this country), and coal consumed by the mine and miners is included (this being a less important proportion of total quantity of coal in Great Britain than in many Continental districts). The British level is equalled by Belgium when employers' contributions are included and by Saxony when the cost is calculated per ton of commercially disposable coal. It is exceeded by the same countries in all other cases : the maximum cost is reached in Belgium as regards wages per ton of commercially disposable coal without employers' contributions, and by Saxony when employers' contributions are included \ In short, Great Britain, Belgium and Saxony form the three places where coal-mining becomes most costly as compared with the rest of Europe. The Dutch coal-fields show, however, a level of labour cost which approaches rather near the above maxima. Taking into account all the four relative numbers at the same time, it may be said that there is a difference of about one-tenth between Great Britain and the Netherlands ; and a similar difference, in turn, between the last-named country and France. 1 It should be noted that the wages cost in Saxony is increased, relatively to other districts, by the fact that the total wages include those paid in ancillary establishments. — 141 — The Ruhr district of Germany follows rather far behind, showing a wages cost which is hardly two-thirds of that in the high-cost countries ; and the same remark applies, with increased force, to Czechoslovakia. In Poland and German Upper Silesia—the regions with the highest productivity—wages per ton of coal are decidedly lower than elsewhere, viz. less than 40 per cent. of the maximum level of labour cost in Europe. CONCLUSION SUMMARY OF T H E RESULTS § 1. The foregoing pages embody a detailed analysis of the results of the enquiry conducted by the International Labour Office into the hours of labour and wages in the European coal industry in 1925. It will now be convenient to sum up the principal points which the study has brought into light. A few words must be said at the outset as to the general character and the limitations of the present enquiry. In order to secure material as comprehensive and comparable as possible, the International Labour Office has had recourse to a direct method of enquiry. The data contained in the existing national statistics are indeed very heterogeneous and widely divergent in scope. Therefore, after a close study of the labour conditions in the European coal mines, a framework for a uniform scheme of statistics has been elaborated on lines which are in several respects new ; this scheme was then distributed to the Governments concerned with a request to supply data on this basis; and, finally, the returns were adjusted to the standard in order to put them, as far as possible, on an internationally comparable basis. This process has met with many difficulties and has required much time ; but as a result the information secured, although still containing flaws and inaccuracies, may be considered as more comprehensive than any other statistics available on the subject up to the present time. On the other hand, however, it is necessary to emphasise the limitations of the present enquiry. In the first place, its scope is limited in that only European countries are considered, and even among these some countries (of which Russia is the most important) are excluded. In the second place, the enquiry refers to a single year which was, in several countries, an exceptional one ; and, as a matter of fact, sensible changes in the labour conditions have taken place since 1925. An attempt — 144 — has been made to remedy these in appendices. But it is not possible to remedy thus the incompleteness which arises from the unsatisfactory development of certain methods of comparison. For these reasons, reservations are to be made against drawing any sweeping conclusions from the results of the enquiry. The comparisons which will be made in the following are necessarily only approximations. § 2. The first problem considered is that of the hours of labour. The starting point of the determination of the hours of labour is the length of the shift (or the working week) fixed either by legislation or by collective agreements, or both ; and this is determined and defined according to different principles in the different countries. In order to reduce them to a comparable basis, certain adjustments are to be made. The question is particularly complicated in respect of the hours of labour of underground workers ; owing to the peculiar conditions under which miners are performing their daily task, their aggregate working time comprises not only hours of work at face, b u t also time needed for descending to the shaft bottom, or ascending to the pithead, travelling from the shaft to the place of work in the mine, breaks for meals, etc. With a view to allowing both for the aggregate working time which is the workers' primary concern, as well as for the time spent in work properly so called in which the employers are chiefly interested, two different notions of hours of labour have been determined, viz. : (i) "Hours of attendance" reduced to a uniform basis, that is to say, the length of the individual shift (day), corresponding to the period from the moment the individual worker enters the cage to descend to the moment when he leaves the cage after being raised to the surface. The calculations necessary to arrive at this uniform basis differ according to the way the length of the shift is defined, especially if it is defined as referring collectively to all the miners. (ii) "Hours at face", that is to say, the hours as determined under (i) less (a) the average length of the walking time underground from the shaft bottom to the face or the place •of work, as well as (b) the average length of breaks; no deduction is made in respect of other elements of lost time inherent in the work. This concept refers particularly to hewers -and their assistants. — 145 — As regards surface workers, their hours of labour are determined on practically an identical basis in the different countries. The "hours of real work" are based on the legal or contractual hours, excluding breaks. Information on the above lines has been secured for all countries and districts under review, except the Prussian coalfields in Germany (Ruhr, Aachen, Upper and Lower Silesia), Great Britain, and the Saar Territory, for which districts certain figures are lacking. The following table summarises the evidence in respect of the normal daily hours of labour (excluding Saturdays). These figures, if strict comparisons are made, require several precisions which have been indicated in the detailed analysis and are omitted here. AVERAGE DAILY HOURS OF LABOUR IN E U R O P E A N COALMINES, 1925 Surface workers ; hours ot real work excluding breaks Underground workers Country and district Germany : Ruhr' Aachen Upper Silesia Lower Silesia Saxonv France Great Britain Netherlands Poland : Silesia Dombrowa Czechoslovakia Hours of attendance 8h. 8 h. 8 h. 8h. 8h. 7 h. 7 h. 7 h. 8h. Hours at face 30 m. 30 m. 50 m. 44 m. 30 m. 8h. 8h. 7 h. 30 m. 7 h. 25 m. 6 6 6 5 6 li. h. h. h. h. 15 20 17 45 20 m. m. m. m. m. 10 h. 10 h. 10 h. 9 h. (9 h. 30 m.) 9 h. 8 h. 7 h. 59 m. 7 h. 45 m. 8 h. 6¡h. 16 m. 6 h. 16 m. 8 h. 8 h. 6 h. 55 m. 7 h. 46 m. The normal weekly hours of work will be obtained from the above figures by multiplying them by six and allowing, when appropriate, for the shorter hours on certain days of the Aveek, especially in various districts of Great Britain, the Netherlands, and Poland (in the Dombrowa and Cracow districts). The daily hours of attendance underground, reduced to a comparable basis, present certain divergencies. They exceeded, in 1925, 8 hours in two German districts only ; were exactly 8 hours in other German districts, the Netherlands, and 10 — 146 — Poland ; but were less in all other countries. It is further seen that the time required for breaks and walking underground to the face or the work place, while varying considerably from mine to mine, appear, on an average, to be sensibly equal in the different countries and districts (1 h. 27 m. to 1 h. 45 m.). As a consequence, "hours at face" show differences which are rather similar to those found in the comparison of the hours of attendance : 6 hours and some 15 to 20 minutes except in Great Britain and Czechoslovakia where they are less than 6 hours. This does not, however, apply to the Prussian coal-fields of Germany for which no relevant information is available. The daily hours of effective work at the surface are mostly eight, or even less ; the chief exception is provided by Germany where the hours of work are sensibly longer. The weekly hours are below 48 in five countries or districts : France, Great Britain, Poland (Dombrowa and Cracow), the Saar, and Czechoslovakia. § 3. The second problem, that of wages, has needed a more detailed analysis than the hours of labour. As a matter of fact, the task of rendering the wage data comparable among themselves is complicated by the large number of different elements on which the calculation of average wages is based. A few important points of method are therefore to be indicated in this connection. The statistics of wages have two distinct objects, viz. the determination of the standard of living of the workers, and of the labour cost of production. The former object is ultimately complied with by a calculation of the average earnings per a time u n i t : manshift (day), hour, and year; the second by a computation of average wages per a ton of coal. The starting point of the calculations is in both cases the total wages bill, which has been defined as comprising the aggregate sum of the miners' actual earnings. It should be remarked that wage statistics are usually concerned with money wages only ; but in view of the special position of miners in that they often receive, in addition to money wages, various kinds of allowances and benefits, and that in several countries a not inconsiderable portion of wages consists of these additional advantages, it has been deemed necessary to take into account the actual earnings comprising almost every possible element of income which workers receive by reason of their employment in — 147 — and about the mines ; and the results of the enquiry show t h a t it had been unjustified to employ another method. A particularly controversial point is that relating to advantages accruing; to workers from various social insurance schemes. The question whether the employers' contributions to social insurance should be considered as an element in wages has in fact been left open, and two different conceptions of the total wages bill have been applied throughout the report, the one excluding, the other including this item which constitutes about 4 to 12 per cent, of the total wages bill. With regard to the special question of payments for holidays,. the enquiry shows that they form about 1.4 to 2.9 per cent, of the total wages bill ; however, holidays with pay are not granted in the coal-mining industry of Belgium, France, and Great Britain. Another noteworthy point is that if average earnings per time unit are to be rendered internationally comparable, a clear distinction must be made between manshifts and days of attendance ; and similarly the average number of workers is to be distinguished from the number of "full-time workers". A close examination of the statistics has provided means of appreciating the practical importance of these distinctions ; and it has been seen that while the number of manshifts is in some cases practically equal to that of days of attendance, the former number exceeds in other cases the latter by a not insignificant proportion (attaining 7 per cent.). Again, the average number of workers is superior to the number of full-time workers by 8 to 21 per cent. In general, the averages as supplied by the statistics of the several countries are not comparable and have not been utilised as such ; the greater part of them, as given in the present enquiry, have been recalculated by the International Labour Office. For this purpose, the International Labour Office has applied uniform methods in the calculation of both the average number of workers and the number of full-time workers for most countries. The average number has been computed by taking account of both manshifts (days) worked and those lost, and thus is more accurate than the simplest methods usually employed. § 4. The methods employed in the comparisons of the average earnings per time unit may be briefly put as follows. In order to render them comparable, they have been converted t o — 148 — a common unit of measure, viz. the gold franc, and the averages obtained have been related to the highest average, viz. that for Great Britain, which is taken as equal to 100. On the other hand, the average earnings are expressed in terms of retail prices of foodstuffs, so as to calculate index numbers of "comparative real earnings", taking averages for Great Britain as basis and equal t o 100. Whereas the average earnings, expressed in terms of gold, show the purchasing power of the earnings in the international market, and are of interest chiefly from the point of view of commercial competition ; the average earnings expressed in terms of retail prices give their purchasing power in the internal market, and indicate the relative standard of living of mine-workers in the different districts and countries. The relative numbers of average earnings expressed in terms of gold francs, and the index numbers of average earnings expressed in terms of their purchasing power over a certain quantity of foodstuffs, are summarised in the following table. It is confined to figures relating to the earnings of underground workers only. Separate calculations have, in fact, been made for hewers, other underground, and all underground workers, as well as for surface workers ; but it has been observed that the principal and most typical category, that of hewers, has not been found anything like uniform in the different countries ; and therefore the two groups of underground and surface workers furnish a more adequate basis for comparison ; in the present general summary, however, the latter group, which on the whole is less important, may be neglected. Furthermore, average hourly earnings underground are only given as per hour of attendance ; the relative numbers relating to earnings per hour at face differ in fact but little from those found in the table. The countries are arranged in descending order as determined by the index number of real earnings. It will be seen from the table that there are marked differences in the level of earnings in the different countries and districts. Considering first the basic averages, viz. those per manshift (day), the following remarks may be made. The maximum wage level is afforded by Great Britain ; but the differences as between the Continental coal-fields appear much more marked in the calculation of earnings in terms of gold than in that of earnings expressed in terms of their purchasing power. When the average earnings are converted to gold francs and related to the maximum level, it will be seen that the earnings attain — 149 — RELATIVE LEVELS OF AVERAGE EARNINGS OF UNDERGROUND WORKERS IN EUROPEAN COAL-MINES, EXPRESSED IN TERMS OF GOLD AND OF THEIR INTERNAL PURCHASING POWER, 1 9 2 5 (Base : Great Britain = 100) Relative number of average earnings expressed in terms of gold Country and district Index number of earnings expressed in terms of their purchasing power Excluding Including Excluding Including employers' employers' employers' employers contricontricontricontributions butions butions butions (i) Average Earnings per Manshift (Day) Great Britain Netherlands Belgium Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. France Saar Germany : Ruhr Czechoslovakia : Whole country. . Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Saxony Germany : Upper Silesia Poland Great Britain Netherlands Belgium Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Saar France Czechoslovakia : Whole country . . Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Ruhr Germany : Saxony Poland Germany : Upper Silesia Great Britain Netherlands Belgium (o) .• France Saar (a) Germany : Ruhr Germany : Saxony Czechoslovakia : Ostrava-Karvina. Czechoslovakia : "Whole country . Czechoslovakia : Kladno-Rakovnik Germany : Upper Silesia Poland 100 75 50 51 49 52 64 48 46 57 49 40 100 80 50 50 69 52 43 100 84 73 66 65 63 61 100 89 73 66 66 61 53 50 54 (ii) Average Earnings per Hour of Attendance Underground 100 100 100 100 74 78 82 87 51 51 74 74 51 71 51 68 50 67 68 49 52 46 60 64 60 CA 53 38 49 53 41 43 46 (iii) Average Earnings per Year and Worker 100 100 100 100 89 94 99 105 57 57 82 82 58 59 77 78 58 76 70 69 75 75 65 50 69 48 52 46 66 55 59 40 52 55 43 (a) Information for underground workers lacking, the figures refer to all mine workers. — 150 — about three-fourths of the British standard in the Netherlands •which show the highest level on the Continent ; while they are not more, or are less, than half of that standard in every other district except in two German coal-fields (the Ruhr and Saxony). However, the average earnings, calculated in gold francs, do not give a true idea of the comparative level of mine-workers' standard of living ; owing to the differences in the purchasing power of money, the index numbers of "real earnings" show more uniformity and higher standards for most countries. Great Britain and the Netherlands still give the maximum standards for Europe as a whole and for the Continent respectively, but the difference between these two countries is smaller, little more than one-tenth if employers' contributions are taken into account. The outstanding fact is, however, that the comparative level of real earnings in Belgium, Czechoslovakia, the Saar territory, the Ruhr district, and France, while considerably below that prevailing in Great Britain, is approximately equal. The eastern region, consisting of German Upper Silesia and Poland, shows the lowest relative standard, which is somewhat more than one-half of the level of real earnings in Great Britain. Comparisons made on the basis of average hourly and annual earnings do not change substantially these conclusions. It is, however, to be observed, that the relative level of hourly earnings is in general somewhat lower than that of daily averages on account of the fact that the hours of labour were, in 1925, shorter in Great Britain than elsewhere ; per contra, the relative levels of annual averages come considerably nearer the British level—which is even exceeded by the Netherlands when employers' contributions are taken into account—than daily and hourly averages, owing to the fact that in 1925 the time loss in Great Britain (taken as basis) was exceptionally high ; in Czechoslovakia and Poland where the time lost was equally great, the average annual earnings show, in fact, approximately the same relation to the British level as do daily and hourly earnings. § 5. As the natural conditions of production vary to a large extent from coal-field to coal-field, and as wages tend, as much as possible, to equalise the production and transportation cost of coal competing in the same market, it is of interest to compare the average output of coal and the average labour cost of production in the different countries and districts. — 151 — The variety of the natural conditions is well illustrated by average output of coal per manshift (day). The best measure of the labour cost of production again is the amount of wages (expressed in terms of gold) paid per ton of saleable coal. Taking in both cases Great Britain as equal to 100 (although this country does not represent the maxima), and relating the averages obtained for other countries to this basis, the following relative numbers of average output and average labour cost are obtained. RELATIVE LEVEL OF AVERAGE OUTPUT A N D AVERAGE WAGES PER TON OF COAL IN EUROPEAN COAL-MINES, 1925 (Base : Great Britain Country and district Great Britain Belgium Germany : Saxony Netherlands France Saar Germany : R u h r Germany. Upper Silesia. . . = 100) Average output per manshift 100 48 61 82 59 71 100 88 126 101 Wages per ton oí saleable coal Excluding employers' contributions Including employers' contributions 100 99 96 90 81 73 63 55 39 38 100 100 105 96 83 68 61 41 The outstanding feature of the above table is the very great discrepancy between the relative numbers of average output and those of average wage cost per ton of coal. These numbers permit indeed an interesting comparison of the relation which exists between the "productivity" (as indicated by the average output) and the "labour cost" of production in each country or district. Compared with the relation existing between productivity and wage cost in Great Britain (and taken as equal to 100 : 100), other countries may be arranged in two main groups. The first group, formed by Belgium, the Netherlands, France, and Saxony, is in general less productive than Great Britain, yet the level of the labour cost exceeds, or is nearly equal to, the British level (in France, however, only four-fifths of it). The contrary is true for the second group, to which belong the Ruhr and Upper Silesian districts of Germany, Poland, and — 152 — (to a less extent) Czechoslovakia : whereas the productivity in these countries is superior to, or not much below, that of British coal-fields, the labour cost of coal is very much cheaper than in Great Britain. The Saar occupies an intermediate position between these groups : both the productivity and the labour cost are less than in Great Britain. § 6. The three main results of the enquiry, viz. the comparative standard of living of coal-mine workers, as determined by their average earnings (expressed in terms of purchasing power), the comparative wage cost of a ton of coal (expressed in terms of gold) and the comparative productivity, as determined by the average output per manshift (day), in the year 1925, may now be outlined as follows : (i) Great Britain and the Netherlands, where the standard of living appears to be the highest in Europe and Continental Europe respectively, show also a very high wage cost per ton of coal, and a relatively high productivity, which, however, are exceeded or equalled in a few Continental districts. (ii) Belgium, France, the Saar territory, the Ruhr and Saxony districts of Germany, as well as Czechoslovakia, where the workers' standard of living may be assumed as being roughly equal, show marked differences in respect of the wage cost of production and the productivity. The wage cost is very high in the Free State of Saxony and Belgium (where it attains indeed its maximum level), and is relatively high also in France, but the productivity is considerably less than in Great Britain ; in other districts the wage cost is considerably below the maximum level (in Czechoslovakia little more than half of the same), whereas the productivity (the Saar excepted) is equal or nearly equal to the European maximum. (iii) Finally, in German Upper Silesia and Poland, the standard of living is the lowest in Europe, and as the productivity of these regions (as determined by the average output per manshift or day) is at the same time the highest in Europe, also the wage cost of coal is cheaper than elsewhere ; it may be noted that the wage per ton is less than two-fifths, but the real earnings about one-half of the maximum level attained in Europe. — 153 — These circumstances seem to indicate that the standard of living of the mine-workers, as determined by the purchasing power of their earnings, bears direct relation neither to the productivity of the coal-fields in which they are employed, nor to the low cost of production of coal, as measured in terms of gold. They further show that the wage cost of production does not bear a direct relation to the productivity of the mines, nor to the standard of living of the workers. These three factors, the workers' standard of living, the productivity of the mines, and the labour cost of production, influence each other in a highly unequal degree in the different countries ; but they are in turn related to other factors, such as the geographical situation of the coal-fields, the overhead costs of production, the efficiency of labour, the general standard of living acquired by the workers, which escape the analysis of a statistical enquiry. APPENDIXES APPENDIX I METHODS OF CALCULATION, AND LIMITATION, OF HOURS OF WORK IN 1925 IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Belgium § 1. (a) The hours of work in coal-mines are regulated by the general Act of 14 June 1921 \ providing for an eight-hour day and 48-hour week, the application of which extends to "mines, surface mines, quarries, and other works for the extraction of minerals from the e a r t h " (section 1). So far as is known, there are no collective agreements limiting hours of work. (b) The actual working hours must not exceed eight hours in the day and 48 hours in the week (section 2). (c) As regards the underground workings of coal-mines, working hours are limited to eight either per shift or gang or per category or cage-load, both winding times to be included. Where the underground workings are accessible by adits, the working hours are held to begin with the entrance of the worker into the adit and terminate with his return to the same point (section 2). The calculation is collective on the basis of the shift or gang, category or cage-load. In order to obtain the standard manshift according to regulations, it would be necessary to deduct from the legal hours of work the time necessary for winding the whole shift (see § 8, (a), page 24). The various terms employed by the Act (shift or gang, category or cage-load) for establishing the method of calculation of the daily working hours allow the various undertakings to adopt particular methods within the general framework of the Act. In the Mons basin a shift consists of the number of workers which the cage will hold at a time. This is the system known as the "cordée" system. In the Centre, only two undertakings use the cordée system. The others divide the workers of a particular shift into two, three, four, or five groups according to occupation, according to gallery and, in one case, according to the place of residence and means of transportused by the worker for arriving at the mine (railway, motor-bus). In almost all the mines of the Charleroi basin, the shifts are arranged on the cordée system. In nine mines, however, the workers are grouped according to the kind of work. Subdivision is carried somewhat far in the latter case and each shift is made up of two or three cordées at the most. In four mines of no considerable importance in the Namur basin all the workers of one shift constitute a single gang. In four mines the cordée constitutes the shift and in two others the workers are grouped according to the nature of their work. 1 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Legislative Series, 1921, Bel. 1. — 158 — In the Liège basin the workers are grouped by occupation, by category and in some cases by gallery. The subdivision of a shift is sometimes carried somewhat far. Only three mines consider a cordée as a shift. In Limburg the workers are divided according to the working face. A system of supervision is in force in most of the districts to ensure that the ascent of the workers is carried out in the same order as the descent. Mining undertakings further require the worker to be equipped for the descent from two to fifteen minutes before taking his place in the cage 1. § 2. For surface workers the working hours are fixed at eight hours in the day and 48 hours in the week by the Act of 14 June 1921. Czechoslovakia § 1. (a) The hours of work are regulated by the general Act of 19 December 1918 respecting the eight-hour working-day 2, and by collective agreements entered into for the most important mining districts. The act applies inter alia to "mining undertakings (pits, coke works, calcining furnaces and blast furnaces), both below ground and on the surface". (b) In accordance with the Act, "in undertakings subject to. the Industrial Code . . . . the actual hours of work of workers shall not in principle exceed eight hours within 24 hours or 48 hours in the week" (section 1, subsection 1). (c) While the Act provides that " t h e entering and leaving of the mines shall be regarded as a subsidiary operation . . . . provided t h a t the shift shall not be increased thereby by more than half-an-hour reckoned from the descent of the first workman until the last workman of the same shift leaves the mine", the collective agreements include both winding times in the daily hours of work. Consequently, in order to reduce the period fixed by the collective agreements to the international standard manshift adopted in this report it is necessary to deduct the time required for one collective winding descending or returning (see § 8, (a), page 24). ((I) The Act provides for a break of at least a quarter of an hour after not more than five hours' uninterrupted work, unless a proper period of rest is otherwise ensured. In practice, breaks may be estimated at t h i r t y minutes and are regularly observed. (e) The time spent at the working face, excluding breaks, calls for a special observation. In the mines of Czechoslovakia, custom requires all the workers to be assembled at the foot of the shaft before the ascent commences. As a result, the time spent at the working face excluding breaks is reduced by half the time required for a collective ascent s . 1 Enquiry into the Organisation of Work in Coal-Mines, 1921. Legislative Series, 1919, Cz. 1, 2, and 3. 3 See note 18, p. 69. 2 — 159 — § 2. The hours of work of surface workers are fixed at eight hours per day and 48 hours per week by the Act of 19 December 1918. Breaks fixed at regular periods only exist in very rare cases. In practice, however, the worker interrupts his work for at least a quarter of an hour for the purpose of taking food. France § 1. (a) The hours of work of underground workers are regulated by a special Act of 24 June 1919 1, explained and supplemented by the Ministerial Circular of 16 February 1920 2. So far as is known, there are no collective agreements containing provisions relating to hours of work. The Act applies to all classes of mining undertakings and all persons employed in such undertakings. (b) The hours of work are fixed by section 9 of the Second Book of the Code of Labour as amended by section 1 of the Act in the following terms : " The working day of persons employed in coal (fuel) mines of all kinds. . . . shall not exceed eight hours either for underground or for surface workers." Section 11 of the Labour Code as amended by section 1 of the Act provides that the legislative provisions shall not affect agreements or customs equivalent to agreements, by which in certain undertakings a shorter period than that established by the foregoing sections has been fixed as the normal working day. (c) The Act does not prescribe any special rules except for the calculation of the hours of work of underground workers (section 10 of the Labour Code as amended by the Act) : " This period shall be calculated for each shift and for every class of workers from the time when, according to the regulations, the first descending workers enter the shaft to the time when, according to the regulations, the last ascending workers arrive at the surface. " For mines entered by means of adits the said period shall be calculated from the arrival at the entrance of the adit to the time of return to the same point." The Ministerial Circular states that "the working day is not calculated individually and that the time necessary for the descent and ascent of each class of workers is included in the eight hours". The Circular also explains the intention of the legislation with regard to the meaning to be attributed to the expressions "shift" and "class of workers": " I call your attention to the expression 'for each shift' and 'for every class of workers' . . . . This expression allows every latitude to the owners of undertakings to adjust their time-tables to the requirements of their work. 1 2 Legislative Series, 1920, Fr. 3. Bulletin du ministère du Travail, 1920, p. 38 *. — 160 — " I consider, however, in agreement with the General Council of Mines, that the expressions used by the legislation do not allow the division, for the purpose of calculating the eight hours, of a continuous and uninterrupted operation of descent or ascent according to shifts assigned to different parts of the mine, except in quite exceptional circumstances, such as, for example, the existence of two working places constituting, in fact, two distinct mines served by a single pit for the transport of the workers. "Similarly, the classes of workers contemplated by the Act can only be classes resulting either from the technical speciality of the workers, which leads the owners of the undertaking to lower and subsequently to raise to the surface the workers of a particular speciality at hours distinctly different from those applying to the rest of the staff, or from special circumstances such as t h e distance of the workers' cottages or any other similar cause necessitating the adoption of special hours of descent, and ascent for single groups of workers who thus constitute a class apart. "Finally, the distinction by class should be absolutely effective, so that no worker of one class can descend or ascend during the regulation period assigned by the time-table to another class." There are no special regulations as to time-tables of descent and ascent. In most cases there is only a notice in the lamp-shed, indicating the time at which the first cage descends. This is generally sufficient to determine the time of descent of other cages 1. In many cases the workers are given counters for the purpose of ensuring the order of their descent in the shift or category and the order of their ascent. It follows, therefore, from these provisions t h a t the windingtime of the shift or class are included in the collective calculation and that, accordingly, the standard manshift for each worker taken individually will be equal to the legal working hours of the shift or class less the winding time of the whole shift or class (see § 8, (a), page 24). (d) Breaks are provided for in the Ministerial Circular, which states that " t h e legal working hours will include the time necessary for the snack which the miner takes during the course of his work". In general, t h e rest periods are taken simultaneously by the workers of a mining undertaking. They begin and end at a given signal. § 2. The surface workers and employees are subject to the provisions of the Act of 23 April 1919 relating to the eight-hour day. The Circular of 16 February 1920 contains the following statement : " I t should be noted, however, that section 9 of the Act of 24 June 1919 fixes a maximum of eight hours for the working day and t h a t it provides no method of calculation for the week or any other period. In these circumstances subsections 1 and 2 of section 8 of Chapter II (hours of work) of Title I of Book II of the Labour and Social Welfare Code, relating to the distribution of work, are not applicable to surface workers. " 1 Communication from the Director of the Paris Office to the International Labour Office, 25 Jan. 1926. — 161 — Germany § 1. (a) For underground workers the hours of work in mines a r e regulated by the provisions of the Order of 212 December 1923 l amending those of the Order of 23 November 1918 and by collective agreements and arbitral awards in force in the principal mining •districts 3. The Order applies to all mines. (b) The regular daily working hours of workers must not exceed eight exclusive of breaks (section 1). In coal-mining the length of the shift is to be deemed to be the regular daily working hours (section 8). The collective agreements often fix regular working hours below the normal. A certain number of so called "additional" hours (Mehrarbeit) are, however, added. These are the result of arbitral awards pronounced and made binding by public authority by virtue of the provisions of the Order concerning hours of work of 21 December 1923 relating to exceptional circumstances. These measures were adopted after the denunciation of the Ruhr Agreement of 29 November 1923, relating to additional work (Mehrarbeitsabkom.men). In consequence of this, the total length of the shift varies according to district from eight hours to eight and a half hours. (c) The Order provides that the length of the shift shall be calculated "from the time of beginning winding in descending to the time of beginning winding again in ascending or from the entry of the individual worker into the adit to the time of his leaving the adit on departure" (section 8). Under the agreement relating to additional work and the arbitral awards in force in 1925, the length of the shift is calculated for each worker individually from the moment when he commences the descent to the moment when he commences the ascent. There is no difference, for the purpose of this enquiry, between these two methods of calculation since, as has been shown, a collective •calculation by cage may be assimilated to an individual calculation (see page 23). The data so furnished are therefore considered as corresponding to the international basis adopted in this report. It has been seen that in order to be perfectly exact it would be necessary to add the time required for an individual ascent (or ascent of the cage), a time which has been estimated to be practically negligible. § 2. For surface workers the hours of work are fixed by legislation at eight per day. In pursuance of collective agreements and binding arbitral awards relating to additional work, however, the daily working hours are increased by from one to two hours according to district. It should be noted that an Order of 20 J a n u a r y 1925 reduced to eight per day the hours of work in coke oven undertakings and blast furnaces from 1 May 1925. 1 Legislative Series, 1923, Ger. 7. Bulletin of the International Labour Office (Basle), Vol. XIII, 1918, p. 8. * The modifications introduced in hours of work since 1925 for underground and surface workers are indicated in Appendix II. 2 il — 162 — Great Britain § 1. (a) Prior to 1908, no statutory provision regulated the hours of adult male workers at coal-mines, either above or below ground,. although those of women and children had been governed by special and general Acts since 1872. The working hours of miners below ground have been regulated by law since 1909, when the Coal MinesRegulation Act, 1908, came into force. Modifications have been introduced, notably by the Coal Mines Act of 1919 ; and the various. Acts are cited together as the Coal Mines Acts, 1887-1919 \ The legal provisions are supplemented by regional or district collective agreements. The Acts apply to coal-mines and to mines at which certain other minerals are worked along with coal. They distinguish between persons defined as "workmen" and others (Coal Mines. Regulation Act, 1908, section 1, subsection 7): "The expression 'workman' means any person employed in a mine below ground, who is not an official of the mine (other than a fireman, examiner, or deputy) or a mechanic or horsekeeper, or a person engaged solely in surveying or measuring."' The same section stipulates special conditions relative to hours of work for "firemen, examiners, deputies, onsetters a , pump-minders,. fanmen, or furnace-men". Certain categories, viz. mechanics, horse-keepers, surveyors, etc.,. are expressly excluded, and do not come within the scope of t h e Acts. (b) As regards hours of work, the Act of 1908 (section 1) laid down that " a workman shall not be below ground in a mine for the purpose of his work, and of going to and from his work, for more than eight hours during any consecutive twenty-four hours" and for more than 9 y2 hours in the case of the specified classes referred to above. The Act of 1919 reduced the hours of work by the substitution of 7 and 8 for 8 and 9 % respectively. These Acts, however, legalised the extension of the working time below ground by not more than one hour a day for a limited number of days in the year. The relevant section is as follows : " The time fixed by this Act as the time during which the workmen in a mine may be below ground for the purpose of their work and of going to and from their work may be extended as respects any mine by the owner, agent, or manager of the mine on not more than sixty days in any calendar year by not more than one hour a day, and on any day on which an extension of time is made in accordance with this section as respectsany mine the time as so extended shall be substituted for the purposes of this Act as respects that mine for the time as fixed by this A c t " 3 . 1 Bulletin of the International Labour Office (Basle), Vol. IV, 1909,, p. 94, and INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Legislative Series, 1919,. G.B. 4. The modifications made in hours of work since 1925 as regards underground and surface workers are shown in Appendix IV. 2 Under the Act of 1919, however, "onsetters" were specifically excluded from these special classes, and thus placed in the same position. as ordinary "workmen". 3 Coal Mines Regulation Act, 1908, section 3. — 163 — (c) While it would be possible to reconcile the maxima with the limitations imposed by statute in the case of single workmen, it would be impossible, without some statutory relaxation, to do so in the case of shifts of workmen the lowering and raising of which occupy a period of time. The expression "shift" is defined as follows : "Any number of workmen whose hours for beginning and terminating work in the mine are approximately the same". 1 Such relaxation is provided by the Act of 1908, which declares " t h a t no contravention of the foregoing provisions (i.e. those laid down in section 1 as repeated above) shall be deemed to take place in the case of shifts of workmen if the period between the times at which the last workman in the shift leaves the surface and the first workman in the shift returns to the surface does not exceed 8 hours" or, subsequent to the operation of the 1919 Act, 7 hours. The owner, agent or manager of every mine is required to fix and to specify for each shift of workmen the time at which the lowering and raising of the men is to commence and to be completed, subject to the approval of the inspector that the interval between the times fixed is reasonable for the purpose 2. The average time occupied in lowering and raising shifts of workmen in Great Britain may for practical purposes be estimated to be 30 minutes, and in the case of the average workmen (i.e. the middle man down to the middle man up) this period must be added to the prescribed hours of work in order to determine the time spent below ground. § 2. Except in the case of winding enginemen, whose hours of work were limited to 8 per day under the Coal-Mines Act, 1911, and of females and boys under 16 years of age, the hours of surface workers have never been regulated by law, but have been subject to agreements made between employers and workers. Prior to 1919 district agreements were in operation, under which the weekly hours of work were fixed, according to the basin, at 48 to 50 exclusive of mealtimes. Towards the end of 1918, however, a national agreement was concluded between the owners and the workmen providing for a uniform maximum of 49 hours per week, exclusive of meal times. This arrangement came into operation early in 1919, but was superseded a few months later by a similar agreement, which was made consequential upon the reduction of working hours below ground, under which the weekly maximum on the surface was reduced to 4 6 % hours. Netherlands § 1. (a) The regulation of hours of work in coal-mines is based on the Royal Decree of 22 September 1906 3, issued in pursuance of section 9, paragraph 1, of the Act of 27 April 1904, amending the Act of 21 August 1810 relating to mines. 1 Ibid., section 1, (7). 2 Ibid., section 1, (3) and (4). 3 Bulletin of the International Labour Office (Basle), 1906, Vol. I, p. 505. — 164 — These regulations have, however, been amended in several points by the collective agreement of 17 October 1921 x. The legislation and the collective agreement apply to all workings underground and above ground of all mines. (Z>) For underground workers the Royal Decree fixes the time spent within the mine at 8% hours in every 24 hours (section 242) and the agreement reduces this period to 8 hours in 24 hours for the first five days of the week and 6 hours on Saturday, Christmas Eve and the Friday preceding a Saturday which is a public holiday. Under the agreement, the weekly hours of work are therefore 46. Section 246 of the Royal Decree provides special regulations for persons employed in mechanical traction and drivers, who are not to remain underground more than one hour daily beyond the time prescribed by section 242. (c) As regards the calculation of the time spent underground, the Royal Decree (section 243) and the collective agreement by reference thereto provide as follows : (1) The time spent in underground workings shall be reckoned for the men of a shift from the time when the shift begins to descend till the time the same shift begins to return to the surface. (2) The time taken in the return of a shift shall not exceed the time taken in the descent by more than 15 minutes. (3) Workmen shall return as nearly as possible in the same order as they descended. The result of these provisions is that the time spent by the group in the mine is calculated collectively and includes one collective winding time descending and returning. This method of calculation therefore corresponds to the international manshift standard adopted in this r e p o r t 2 (see § 8 (b), page 25). § 2. The normal working hours of surface workers are fixed by the collective agreement already mentioned at 8 hours in 24 hours, subject to certain exceptions necessary in the interest of the undertaking. As a matter of fact, the regulations of 1906 only contain provisions relating to children under 16 years of age and persons engaged in the operation of winding machinery or signals. The first paragraph of section 231 stipulates that such persons must not work more than 8 hours daily at the surface, exclusive of the time necessary for changing a shift. The working period may, however, be extended by not more than one hour for the purpose of ensuring the raising or lowering of a shift. 1 This agreement is signed by the four miners' unions : the General Union of Christian Miners of Holland, the General Union of Miners of Holland, the General Protestant Union of Miners, and the Neutral Union of Miners. 2 See also on this subject note 13 accompanying the table relating to hours of work of underground workers (p. 68). — 165 — Poland A distinction must be made between the basins of Dombrowa and Cracow, and that of Polish Upper Silesia. (a) Basins of Dombrowa and Cracow 1 § 1. (a) The hours of work in coal-mines are regulated by the Act of 18 December 1919 relating to hours of work in industry and commerce 2. The collective agreements contain no provisions as to hours of work. (b) The hours of work must not exceed 8 hours per day, exclusive of rest periods, and on Saturday 6 hours, so that the total working week does not exceed 46 hours (section 1 of the Act). Section 2 provides that " t h e hours of work shall mean the number of hours during which a worker is bound under his contract to be at the orders of the manager, either in the establishment or outside it". (c) As regards underground workers it is provided that " t h e time spent in descending and ascending the shaft shall be included in the hours of work in the mining industry. The order of descent and ascent of the workers employed in the establishment shall be fixed in detail by a register". The legal hours of work including winding times being calculated individually, as is confirmed by the statement of the Polish Government, correspond exactly to the standard manshift according to regulations as previously defined (see § 7, page 22). (d) There are no uniform regulation breaks. The worker is, however, allowed to interrupt his work for forty minutes on the first five days of the week and thirty minutes on Saturday for rest and food. § 2. As regards surface workers, the Act already quoted fixes the hours of work at 8 hours per day. This period is reduced to 6 hours on Saturdays. Surface workers have regulation breaks varying from one to two hours. These breaks are not reckoned in the hours of work. (b) Polish Upper Silesia § 1. (a) Under the provisions of the German-Polish agreement of 15 May 1922 (section 1, subsection 1), the regulations in force in Polish Upper Silesia at the date of the cession of the territory are to remain in operation so far as they apply to the working of mines, industry, commerce, or to the rights of workers. By virtue of subsection (2), however, Poland has the right to replace these provisions by its own regulations, provided that such regulations extend to the whole territory of the State and that their contents are of such a character that they can be substituted for the provisions in force. 1 The changes introduced in hours of work since 1925 as regards breaks are indicated in Appendix IV. 2 Legislative Series, 1920, Pol. 1. , — 166 — In these circumstances, the Act of 18 December 1919 relating to hours of work does not apply to Polish Upper Silesia, in which the provisions of t h e German Order as to the work of industrial workers of 23 November 1918 are still in force. These provisions apply to workers in all industries, including mining 1. The daily hours of work must ordinarily not exceed 8 hours. (b) The ordinary hours of work are fixed at 8 hours per day. Collective agreements have, since 1923, provided, in accordance with German legal provisions, that the hours of work of underground workers must be calculated by shifts, from the commencement of the descent to the commencement of the return to the surface or from the conclusion of the descent to thé conclusion of the return to the surface. The hours of work stipulated by the agreement therefore include one winding time descending or returning, and correspond to the standard manshift according to the regulations as previously defined (see § 8, (b), page 25). (c) The system of breaks is the same as in the basins of Dombrowa and Cracow. § 2. The hours of work of surface workers are legally fixed at 8 per day. The system of breaks is in this case also identical with that in the basins of Dombrowa and Cracow. Saar 2 The hours of work in force in the Saar mines were introduced in the middle of 1919 by the German administration of the Saar mines in agreement with the French supervisory authorities. This measure has been made definitive by the labour regulations issued on 3 September 1921 by the Director-General of Mines of the Saar, in agreement with the representatives of the workers. For underground workers, the shift is calculated for each worker individually from the time when he enters the cage to the time when he leaves it. The workers of a shift return in the same order as that in which they descended. The result is that the manshift calculated individually is measured by the period elapsing between the time when the first workman descends and that when he returns to the surface, or between the moment when the last workman descends and that when he returns to the surface. This period therefore corresponds exactly to the international basis adopted in this study (Cf. § 7, page 22). The manshift thus calculated is 7% hours. The hours of work of surface workers, including a break of a quarter of an hour about the middle of the shift, are 8 hours per day. 1 See the particulars as to Germany, p. 161. Information supplied by the Director-General of Mines of the Saar on 13 July 1926. 2 A P P E N D I X II METHODS OF COMPILING STATISTICS OF WAGES IN T H E COAL-MINING INDUSTRY IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES The survey published in the first part of the present report on the methods of compiling statistics of wages in coal-mining is of a purely theoretical and international character. The following notes complete the survey by furnishing a short statement of the methods employed in the official statistics published in various countries, methods which, in fact, have served as the starting point of the international analysis. The countries taken into consideration are those in respect of which statistical data have been received—that is to say, the principal coal-producing countries of Europe : Belgium, Czechoslovakia, France, Germany, Great Britain, the Netherlands, Poland, and the Saar Basin. The Saar Basin mines (mines domaniales) are controlled by the French Government, and the relevant statistics, therefore, are included in the French mining statistics. For each country information is furnished under the following seven heads : •collection of information ; classification of workers ; composition of wages and earnings ; calculation of the number of shifts ; calculation of the average number of workers ; calculation of average wages ; statistics of production. Belgium § 1. Collection of Information. — The statistical data collected each year by the mining engineers in the various concessions are assembled by the Department of Mines for the purpose of publication in the form of a special chapter of the Mining Annals of Belgium (Annales des Mines de Belgique). The results obtained are furnished for each coal-field, for groups of coal-fields, and for the entire Kingdom. They are compiled separately for coal-mines, related industries (coke and compressed1 fuel), and the other extractive and metal industries of the country . § 2. Classification of Workers. — The mining statistics include four main groups of workers : (1) workers at the coal-face ; these are the miners proper, that is, hewers and stonemen occupied in hewing coal ; (2) all underground workers, that is, workers at the face and the other workers below ground ; (3) all the surface workers ; (4) The aggregate of the underground and surface workers, constituting the sum total of the workers employed in the collieries. 1 MINISTÈRE DE L'INDUSTRIE, DU TRAVAIL ET DE LA PRÉVOYANCE SOCIALE, ADMINISTRATION DES MINES : Statistique des industries extrac- tives et métallurgiques et des appareils à vapeur en Belgique. — 168 — This personnel is classified according to age and sex in the following way : Underground : men and boys: (a) over 16 years of age, (b) from 14 to 16 years ; Surface workers : men and boys: (a) over 16 years of age, (b) 14 to 16 years; women and girls : (a) over 21 years, (b) from 16 to< 21 years, (c) from 14 to 16 years. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The Belgian statisticsdistinguish between : (1) net wages, corresponding to money wages for normal work done ; (2) gross wages which represent the preceding amounts plus the amount of workmen's social insurance contributions ; (3) wages costs, t h a t is, the amount of the allowances in cash and in kind, employers' social insurance contributions, and compensation for accidents to workmen. The apportionment of the first two factors is furnished in respect of each of the workers' groups enumerated above. Only the total amount is indicated for the third group. § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — To determine the number of days of attendance, the number of workmen appearing on each pay-sheet is taken and these figures are totalled up. No distinction between normal work and overtime is made in the total thus obtained. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — Mining statistics are based on the concept of the "estimated number of workers" obtained in each concession by dividing the number of days of attendance on coal-winding days by the average number of such days. The sum of the numbers thus calculated for each concession represents the coal-mining personnel of the whole country. The average number of coal-winding days is calculated on the basis of the total number of days in each mine on which at least one pit was being worked. The apportionment of the personnel according to age and sex is based on four normal working periods of a fortnight, one period for each quarter ; the classification by categories is drawn up in respect of each period, averages are taken and applied to the estimated number of workers. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — The wage averages calculated from the factors indicated above are the following : (1) average wages per day of attendance : (a) net, (b) gross ; (2) average annual wages : (a) net, (b) gross. These averages are furnished in respect of each of the four main groups of workers. § 7. Statistics of Production. — Production is taken as the sum of the quantities sold, distributed and consumed ; stocks existing at the end of the year are taken into account and stocks carried over from the previous year are deducted. (Production is subdivided intocoal of various qualities : charbon flenu, gras, mi-gras, maigre.) — 169 — The data relating to tonnage, to the total value of the coal and t o its price per ton are furnished separately in respect of the quantities sold outside the mine, and to coke ovens, compressed fuel works» etc., of the concession holders, of quantities distributed gratuitously to the workers, quantities consumed in the mines and quantities in stock at the begining and at the end of the year. On the basis of the total tonnage produced, the following are calculated : (1) average output : (a) per day of attendance, (b) per annum : separately for face workers, underground workers and the total number of workers ; (2) average wages, and wages costs per ton produced. These two latter averages are factors in the calculation of working expenses. Czechoslovakia § 1. Collection of Information. — The data are collected, analysed and published each year by the Statistical Office of the Czechoslovak Republic. The methods explained below were introduced in 1925 ; up till 1924 the data were collected in conformity with the methods of the former Austrian mining statistics. The new methods have effected considerable alterations in all domains, with a result that from 1925 onwards it is not possible t o compare the data with those of previous years. The classification of the coal-fields is no longer the same, but the figures continue to be furnished for each of them and for the entire country 1. § 2. Classification of Workers. — The mining statistics divide the workers into eight groups : Underground workers : (ö) pikemen engaged in hewing ; (6) hauliers (adult workers engaged in transporting the mineral) ; this group also includes pikemen-apprentices ; (c) other adult workers of more than 16 years of age employed in timbering, repairs, etc. ; (d) juveniles ; this group includes all boys up to the age of 16 years working underground. Surface workers : (a) specialists ; skilled artisans, enginemen, firemen ; (b) other adult workers (of more than 16 years of age) ; (c) juveniles : boys up to the age of 16 working at the surface ; (d) women : all women without distinction of age. 1 STATISTICAL OFFICE OF THE CZECHOSLOVAK REPUBLIC : (a) Statistika hornickych mezd za rok 1925 (Report on the statistics of wages in collieries for 1925, with an explanation of the new methods) ; (&) Vyrobni statistika hornicka, hutnicka, koksoven a briketaren (Report on the mining production statistics). The reports of the statistical office are published in Czech, French, and German. MINISTKY OF PUBLIC WORKS : Zpravy Verejné sluzby technické (Report of the technical department, which furnishes detailed information on production and output in the mines). — 170 — The supervisors, including gangers, foremen, etc., form a separate group intermediate between the workers and the technical and administrative personnel. They are not taken into account in the statistics of wages of the workers proper. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The grand total of income arrived a t in the statistics of wages includes the following factors : (a) wages for work done ; (6) surcharges for overtime ; (c) family allowances granted on the basis of work done ; (d) payment of part of the wages in cases of illness and accident ; (e) the payment of wages lost through absence owing to various reasons (fulfilment of civic duties, interruption of the transport service, important family reasons). The payments referred to under (d) and (e) are made in virtue of section 1154 (6) and 1155 of the Civil Code ; (/) holiday payments. The sum total of these factors represents the cash earnings of the "workers, to which is added the assessed value of allowances in kind, represented by : (a) free coal ; (6) free wood ; (c) free lodging, including lighting ; (d) the difference in price of lodgings let at reduced rental; (e) allowance for transport of free coal ; (/) housing allowances. The total income represents the sum of cash earnings and allowances in kind and includes compulsory contributions to social insurance funds and to the district councils (Revierrat). No deductions are made on account of occupational charges (explosives, etc.). § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — The number of shifts corresponds t o the sum of the shifts actually worked, whether they are normal or overtime. A distinction is drawn, however, to indicate the number of ordinary shifts and the number of Saturday shifts, whose duration is six hours. Lost shifts are apportioned according to the causes of time lost : illness, want of trade, lack of transport, unforeseen breakdowns in working, strikes and lock-outs, paid holidays, absence with reason (shifts paid, shifts not paid), absence without reason. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. ~ The method adopted by the Czechoslovak statistics for the calculation of the number of workers employed differs from that used in other countries. First of all, the numbers of workmen taken at the end of each period of payment (that is, every two weeks) are totalled, and the sum thus obtained is then divided by the number of periods of payment included in a normal year (that is, 26). In theory, the result is not a n average number of workers, but an average number of full-time workers (working units). In practice, the — 171 — figure obtained by the Czechoslovak method corresponds to the average number of workers in the case in which the mines are in continuous working throughout the whole year. If this is not the case, the figure obtained indicates the supposed number of workers, assuming that they have regularly worked the whole year. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — The factors enumerated in the preceding paragraph permit the. determination of three averages of wages : (a) average earnings per shift worked ; this includes the total payment for normal and overtime work as well as family allowances ; (b) average gross income per shift worked ; (c) average gross income per workman. § 7. Statistics of Production. — These are completely separated from the statistics of wages. The figures published relate to net utilisable tonnage, apportioned as follows : (a) used in the mine ; (b) distributed to workers ; (c) outside sales and sales to establishments attached to the mines; (d) stock at the end of the year. The following deductions are made from the sum of these quantities : (a) stock at the beginning of the year ; (b) outside receipts and receipts from establishments attached to the mines. From the net tonnage on the one hand, and the total number of shifts worked and the average number of workers on the other hand, the average output per shift and per worker is calculated. These latter averages are furnished by the Public Works Statistical Department. France and the Saar § 1. Collection of Information. — Statistical material furnished by each mining concession is collected and totalled by the Department of Mines (Direction des Mines) subordinate to the Ministry of Public Works and is published each year by Departments and for the entire country. The French Government mines in the Saar territory form the subject of a special chapter in the report on the mining industry. The relevant figures are compiled in an analogous manner to those in respect of other French coal-fields 1. 1 MINISTÈRE DES TRAVAUX PUBLICS, DIRECTION DES MINES : Statistique de l'industrie minérale et des appareils à vapeur en France et en Algérie. In addition to the annual reports of the Department of Mines, statistical summaries are found from time to time in the following official publications : MINISTÈRE DU TRAVAIL, DE L'HYGIÈNE, DE L'ASSISTANCE ET DE LA PRÉVOYANCE PUBLIQUE : (a) Bulletin de la Statistique générale de la France ; (b) Bulletin du Ministère du Travail et de l'Hygiène. The wages statistics which are published in the first mentioned of these publications are compiled from information furnished by the Central Committee of French Collieries (Comité central des Houillères de France). — 172 — § 2. Classification of Workers. — The mining statistics classify ' workers in the following way : (1) Underground workers : (a) men ; (b) juveniles of 16 to 18 years ; (c) children under 16 years. (2) Surface workers : (a) men ; (b) women above 18 years ; (c) boys and girls of 16'to 18 years ; (d) boys and girls below 16 years. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. —The figures published correspond to the amount of money wages earned by the workers. This amount is the wage for normal work done together with the cash bonuses and allowances and workmen's social insurance contribu. tions. The apportionment of these amounts is furnished in respect of the total underground personnel on the one hand and the total surface personnel on the other. § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — The total number of shifts is calculated by adding the numbers of workmen appearing on the attendance rolls, without making a distinction between normal work and overtime. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — The average number of workers either at the surface or underground is obtained by dividing the total number of shifts worked at the surface or underground by the number of coal winding days. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — The only wage averages compiled in the mining statistics are the average daily wages underground and at the surface, obtained by dividing the total amount of wages by the number of shifts worked by the underground workers on the one hand and the surface workers on the other. The average annual wages per underground worker and per surface worker are also calculated from the material supplied. § 7. Statistics of Production. — The information collected corresponds to the tonnage wound or net tonnage, represented by the weight of the total production of fuel at the pitheads of the mines after deducting the dirt resulting from washing and screening. These data enable calculations to be made of : (1) Average production per shift of the underground workers and also per shift of the total of all workers (underground and above ground). (2) Wages costs per ton wound, obtained by dividing the total amount of wages by the number of tons wound. The mining statistics also give the value of the fuel extracted, based on the evaluation at the pithead of the net tonnage. From this figure is calculated the average price per ton. Germany § 1. Collection of Information. — The statistics of wages and of production in the Prussian mines are published by the Prussian Ministry of Trade and Industry. For the statistics of the other German States a similar procedure has been adopted ; they are — 173 — assembled by the Ministry of the Interior, which publishes them conjointly with the Ministry of Labour 1. All the basic figures are collected by the mining authorities (Bergbehörden) by means of a form (provided for in the Order of the Prussian Ministry of Trade and Industry of 12 February 1921), whose application has been extended to t h e mining statistics of the Reich. These statistics relate to all the workmen employed in t h e mines or establishments placed under the supervision of the mining authorities, as well as to those employed by sub-contractors (Unternehmerarbeiter) in so far as they are insured with the miners' mutual insurance association (Knappschaftsberufsgenossenschaft). Information respecting the technical, managing and commercial personnel should be excluded from the mining statistics. The data published relate to quarterly and annual periods. They are compiled separately for each coal-field, and no averages are calculated by States or for the whole Reich. § 2. Classification of Workers. — The German mining statistics comprise five groups of workers : (1) Miners proper, employed in hewing and removing coal. They are subdivided into : (a) hewers or pikemen ; (b) hauliers or loaders. (2) Workmen employed in cutting galleries and on minor works. They are subdivided into : (a) shifters, timbermen, etc. ; hookers, brakesmen, trammers, coggers, and pumpmen. These two groups only include adult men (of a t least 16 years of age) working underground. (3) Surface workers (adult men), among whom are distinguished : (a) skilled workers ; (b) other surface workers. (4) Juvenile workers of less than 16 years of age, at the surface and underground. (5) Women workers who are employed a t the surface. In the last three groups are included, apart from t h e workers in the mines themselves, those who are employed in ancillary establishments, or establishments attached to the mines, such as coke ovens, briquette manufactories, etc. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The statistics of salaries are compiled from basic factors : (1) Money wages in respect of the normal work done (Leistungslohn). They are composed of the basic salary — either on a 1 REICHSMINISTERIUM DES INNEBN : Deutscher Reichsanzeiger und preussischer Staatsanzeiger. Nachweisung über die Arbeitsverhältnisse und Löhne in den Hauptbergbaubezirken. REICHSARBEITSMINISTERIUM : Reichsarbeitsblatt. (Which also publishes the above statistics.) STATISTISCHES REICHSAMT : Vierteljahrshefte zur Statistik des deutschen Reiches. Produktion der bergbaulichen Betriebe. PREUSSISCHES MINISTERIUM FÜR HANDEL UND INDUSTRIE : Zeitschrift für das Berg-, Hütten und Salinenwesen im Preussischen Staate; (a) Statistische Mitteilungen über die beim Bergbau Preussens gezahlten Arbeitslöhne; (b) Haupt Übersicht über die Bergwerkserzeugnisse Preussens an Mineralkohlen.... nach den Oberbergamtsbezirken. — 174 — time or piece-work basis — bonuses granted for the accomplishment of normal shifts (bonuses for underground workers, for example) and workmen's social insurance contributions. (2) Money earnings, known as Barverdienst. These include, in addition to the Leistungslohn, all payments made on account of overtime, as well as family allowances in cash. In addition to these two factors, the mining statistics show : (a) the amount of payments and allowances for holidays ; and (b) the total value of allowances in kind. The sum total of all these factors enables the aggregate income of the workers (errechnetes Gesamteinkommen) to be calculated. The latter does not include employers' social insurance contributions, and no account is taken of deductions in respect of occupational charges, as these are refunded to the workmen. § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — The German statistics show : the number of normal shifts worked during a given period, and (b) the total number of shifts worked (verfahrene Arbeitsschichten), including overtime, expressed in terms of normal shifts. Shifts lost (entgangene Arbeitsschichten) are classified according to the causes of time lost : want of trade, lack of means of transport, technical causes, labour disputes, illness, official and paid holidays. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — Two concepts of the number of workers will be found in the mining statistics : (1) The average number of workers (durchschnittlich angelegte Arbeiter), obtained by dividing the number of normal shifts, together with the number of shifts lost, by the number of working days during a given period. This average corresponds, in fact, to the actual number of workers employed in the mines. (2) The number of full-time workers (Vollarbeiter), obtained by dividing the number of normal shifts by the number of the working days in a given period. This average represents the number of workers taken as uninterruptedly emploj^ed in the accomplishment of normal work. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — On the basis of the factors enumerated and defined above, the mining statistics furnish the following averages of wages : (1) Money wages per shift for the total number of workmen? and for each of the groups mentioned above. (2) Money earnings per shift also in respect of the total number of workers and of each of the groups. (3) Money earnings per full-time worker. (4) Average aggregate income per workman employed. The first and the second figures are obtained by dividing the grand total of wages in the first case, and of earnings in the second case, by the total number of shifts worked in a given period. The third figure is t h e result of dividing the grand total of money earnings by the number of full-time workmen calculated for a given period, and the fourth is the quotient of the division of the aggregate income of the total number of workmen by the average number of workmen calculated for a given period. — 175 — § 7. Statistics of Production. — For Prussia, in whose territory, as a matter of fact, the majority of coal-mines is situated, t h e statistics of production are combined with t h e wages statistics in such a way as to show : (1) Total utilisable tonnage (verwertbare Förderung). (2) Average output : (a) per shift, and (b) per full-time worker on a yearly basis, calculated separately for the hewers, for the underground workers, and for the aggregate of all workers. For the Reich there are special statistics compiled for insurance purposes, which give, in respect of each State and each coal-field, the following information relating to production : total utilisable tonnage, quantity consumed by the mines, quantity consumed by the ancillary establishments, quantity distributed to workmen and employees, tonnage sold. Great Britain § 1. Collection of Information. — Data pertaining to the mining statistics are collected and published by the Mines Department in its annual report. Some are taken from the weekly and annual reports furnished directly by the mining companies in virtue of the Mining Industry Act of 1920 ; others, established by the National Wages Board (composed of an equal number of employers and workers) are summarised in the form of a quarterly bulletin on output, costs of production, proceeds and profits of the coal-mining industry. The information covers practically all the mining establishments (about 96 per cent.) 1. § 2. Classification of Workers. — The mining statistics classify the workers in the following groups : (1) underground : men. (2) surface : men and women. (3) underground and surface : men and women. Each of these groups is subdivided into : workers of less than 16 years of age, from 16 to 18 years, from 18 to 20 years, more than 20 years. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The official figures of wages consist of the "percentage additions to basis rates". Statistics of money wages are also published, however, in the annual report, compiled quarterly by the National Wages Board. They furnish the total amount of money wages earned by the mining workers in respect of work done. This amount of the total money earnings includes the workers' insurance contributions, but not those of the employers. No official statistics of the allowances in kind exist. 1 BOARD OF TRADE, MINES DEPARTMENT : Annual Report of the Secretary for Mines and the Annual Report of H.M. Chief Inspector of Mines, with a Statistical Appendix to both Reports. Statistical Summary of Output, Cost of Production, Proceeds and Profits of the Coal-Mining Industry. — 176 — § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — To determine the number of shifts, the numbers worked on each day in each mine are totalled. This total includes the shifts of normal duration, and overtime and week-end shifts expressed in terms of normal shifts. This information is furnished under the headings : shifts worked at the coal face, elsewhere below, and shifts worked on the surface. Shifts lost are those which could have been worked, and only include those lost on account of holidays, disputes, transport difficulties, want of trade, sickness and accidents, during the days that the mine is working. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — The aggregate of the workers included in the classification described above is ascertained from the pay-books of the mines at quarterly intervals. The figures thus obtained are totalled and divided by four to obtain the average number of persons employed in the mines during the year. The statistics do not furnish any explanation of the method followed to compile the figure of the average number of workers —the figure utilised by the National Wages Board—but it appears to be based on the number of workers inscribed in the pay-books of the mines. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. (1) The average wage per shift is the quotient of the of the total amount of wages by the number of shifts (2) The average quarterly earnings are obtained by the total amount of wages by the average number of division worked. dividing workers. § 7. Statistics of Production. — The figures show : (1) Total tonnage raised, including dirt, etc. (2) Tonnage of saleable coal, i.e. excluding dirt. (3) Tonnage disposable commercially, i.e. excluding colliery consumption and coal supplied to the miners or at reduced rates. (4) Average output per shift obtained by dividing the tonnage of saleable coal by the number of manshifts worked. (5) Average output per worker, resulting from the division of the saleable tonnage by the number of workers employed. (6) Wages costs per ton, resulting from the division of the total amount of wages by the tonnage disposable commercially. Netherlands § 1. Collection of Information. — The official mining statistics form the subject of an annual report submitted to the Government by the Chief Mining Engineer. In addition, the Central Bureau of Statistics periodically summarises certain data relating to wages in the mining industry 1 . 1 Jaarverslag van den Hoofdingenieur der mijnen. : Jaarcijfers voor Nederland; Maandschrift. There is also an annual report relating to the working of the State mines, which contains information concerning wages, production and output per man : Jaarverslag van het bedrijf der Staatsmijnen in Limburg. CENTRAL BUREAU VOOR DE STATISTIEK — 177 — § 2. Classification of Workers. — The Dutch statistics distinguish between : (1) Underground workers, divided into thirteen categories which may be grouped as follows : (a) foremen-pikemen, pikemen, assistant pikemen, loaders, timbermen ; b) hauliers and other artisans (skilled workers) ; c) signallers, enginemen, pumpmen, horsekeepers and other workers. Certain categories of underground workers are further divided into two groups according to age : (a) those of more than 18 years, (£>) those of less than 18 years. (2) Surface workers divided into seven categories : (a) skilled workers, (b) semi-skilled workers, (c) unskilled workers, (d) general labourers from 21 to 22 years, (e) general labourers from 19 to 20 years, (/) general labourers from 16 to 18 years, (g) general labourers of less than 16 years. § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The total amount of wages corresponds to the wages earned by the workers, including family and social allowances, but excluding payment for overtime. § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — The report of the Chief Mining Engineer furnishes the total number of shifts worked in each year. § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — The statistics give an average number of workers employed in the coalfields during, and at the end of each year. § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — The information published relates to : (a) average wages per shift, calculated from the total amount of wages earned by the workers and the number of shifts worked ; the averages are determined for each of the categories of workers mentioned above, for the total number of surface workers, and for the total of all workers, (b) average annual wages per workman, determined from the total wages and the average number of workers underground and at the surface. § 7. Statistics of Production. tion shows : (a) tonnage wound, (ft) tonnage saleable. — The material relating to produc- The latter heading is divided as follows : (a) tonnage sold, subdivided into (i) coal sent away, (ii) coal retailed by the mines, (iii) coal distributed to the personnel, (iv) coal given away. 12 — 178 — (b) tonnage utilised by the mines for the manufacture of briquettes, for the manufacture of coke, and for other purposes. From the tonnage wound, the number of shifts and the average number of workers, the statistics determine the average output per worker : (a) per shift, (b) per annum. Each of these averages is determined separately for the total number of underground workers and the general total of workers. Poland § 1. Collection of Information. — The figures are collected by the Mining Administration, subordinate to the Ministry of Industry and Trade, by means of a standard form which is sent every month to all the mining establishments. The statistics of wages, however, are not unified, as there are considerable differences between the methods employed in Polish Silesia and those employed in the coal-fields of Dombrowa and Cracow. It is for this reason that the complete results of the analysis of the forms are not published on a uniform basis for the entire country. For the moment, the official mining statistics only relate to wages and average earnings, to the average number of workers and to production. On the other hand, certain private publications (organs of mining associations) supply more detailed information, but solely for one or other of the principal coal-fields of the country 1. § 2. Classification of Workers. — The mining statistics divide the totality of workers into the following groups : Underground workers : (a) pikemen engaged in hewing operations, (b) skilled workmen, employed as timbermen, shifters, or attending to installations, etc. ; (c) assistants employed as loaders, trammers, hookers, brakesmen, etc. ; (d) juveniles (males), up to 18 years in the Dombrowa and Cracow coal-fields, and up to 16 years in the Upper Silesian coal-fields ; (e) aggregate of underground workers. Surface workers : (a) skilled workers ; (b) assistants ; (c) women ; of more than 18 years of age at Cracow and Dombrowa, and more than 16 years in Upper Silesia ; (d) juveniles of both sexes : from 16 to 18 years and apprentices of less than 17 years at Dombrowa and Cracow ; of 14 to 16 years in Upper Silesia ; (e) aggregate of surface workers. 1 O F F I C E CENTRAL D E STATISTIQUE D E LA R É P U B L I Q U E POLONAISE : (a) Statistique du Travail (Statystyka Pracy) ; (b) Annuaire statistique de la République polonaise. The information concerning the methods adopted by the Polish Statistical Office has been gathered from a report which Dr. A. STEIN, mining engineer, has prepared for the International Labour Office. — 179 — § 3. Composition of Wages and Earnings. — The gross earnings on which the mining statistics are based include the following; factors : (a) cash wages for the total work done, including overtime payments ; (b) bonuses or small allowances granted for regular attendance or for certain special tasks ; (c) holiday payments ; (d) family allowances ; (e) value of lodging ; (J) value of other allowances in kind, particularly free coal or coal at reduced prices ; (g) possible extra payments not included in the preceding groups. Deductions made from wages are apportioned as follows : (a) sickness insurance contributions ; (b) contributions to the pension fund and in respect of life insurance (survivors' insurance) and disablement insurance ; (c) contributions to the unemployment fund ; (d) other deductions, such as income tax ; (e) fines. Deductions for expenses occasioned by the work are not included in the amounts deducted, either because the system is not in force or because they have been taken into account in fixing wages. § 4. Calculation of the Number of Shifts. — The mining statistics furnish information concerning the number of shifts worked as well as those lost. Shifts worked are subdivided into normal shifts, that is, of normal or legal duration, and overtime shifts expressed in terms of shifts of normal duration. Shifts lost are grouped according to the causes of loss : illness, paid holiday, absence with reason, absence without reason, strike, and, lastly, reasons beyond the control of the workers (technical reasons or lack of transport or want of trade). § 5. Calculation of the Average Number of Workers. — The official statistics. take the number of workers inscribed at the end of each month in the registers of the mines and calculate for t h e entire year the arithmetical mean of these monthly totals. From the figures relating to the number of shifts and working; days there are calculated, in addition : (a) "average number of workers", by dividing the number of normal shifts, plus the number of shifts lost, by the number of working days in a given period (month or year) ; (b) "actual number of workers employed", by dividing thenumber of normal shifts by the number of working days in a given period ; (c) "theoretical number of full-time workers", by dividing the total number of shifts worked by the number of working days in a given period. • — 180 — § 6. Calculation of Average Wages. — By means of the factors enumerated above, the mining statistics determine : (a) average gross earnings per shift ; (&) average net earnings per shift. The first is obtained by dividing the sum total of wages paid to workmen by the total number of shifts worked, plus the number of holiday shifts. To obtain the second, the enumerator is diminished by the deduction made from the wages, the denominator remaining unchanged. In both cases it is a calculation of average earnings per shift paid and not per shift worked. § 7. Statistics of Production. — These statistics are completely separate from the statistics of wages. The information furnished by the official publications all refers to the total production and is of no assistance in calculating either average output or wages cost in production. APPENDIX I I I M E T H O D EMPLOYED FOR CALCULATING RELATIVE PURCHASING POWER OF AVERAGE EARNINGS The method adopted for calculating the relative purchasing power of average earnings is identical with that adopted by the International Labour Office during the last few years in calculating index numbers of real wages of certain categories of workers in different capital cities 1 . The object of the method is to show how many times the wages of the worker can purchase at the prices current in his town or district a "basket of provisions" containing the foodstuffs normally consumed by a worker's family. From the ideal point of view, a group of commodities should be formed including items not only of food but also of heating and lighting, clothing, house accommodation, and various miscellaneous items of consumption (e.g. furniture), so that the group is representative of the consumption of the workers in the countries covered and would serve as a common unit of measurement of wages. If such a group were established, the wages of similar groups of workers in different countries could be expressed as ratios of the cost in each country of the group of commodities, or, in other words, there would be found for each country the purchasing power of wages over a given group of commodities at the prevailing level of prices. In practice it is impossible to construct such an ideal unit of measurement owing to differences in the items consumed in the different countries or, where similar items are found in the consumption budgets, to differences in their quantity and quality. A further difficulty is the lack of price data for many of the items. Consequently, it has been found necessary to limit the calculation to a list of those articles of food which are important items in the consumption of working-class families in the countries covered. This limitation to the principal articles of food may diminish the value of the results, but it should be remembered that the expenditure on food constitutes the greater part of family outgo, often reaching twothirds of the expenditure. In the case of miners' families where coal and housing are often supplied free or at reduced rates, food expenditure would constitute an even higher proportion. The effect of the exclusion of clothing, fuel and light, and rent from the calculations depends on the extent to which the relative prices of these items differs from those of foodstuffs. In the case of fuel and light and clothing, the effect is probably small. In the case of rent, however, owing to the operation of rent restriction legislation, the levels of rent and the proportion spent on rent in different countries differ widely. In the quarterly calculations of real wage index numbers published in the International Labour Review, a correction is made for 1 See International Labour Review, Oct. 1924, and subsequent issues. — 182 — this factor, but owing to the special and widely differing conditions of housing in the different mining districts it has not been possible to do so in the present case. In order to measure wages in terms of foodstuffs, an international budget containing the quantities of the chief items of food consumed by miners' families would be necessary. The method of the International Labour Office has been to take different "baskets of provisions" representative of the consumption of different mining regions and to use each of these as a measure of the level of real wages in each district. Four different baskets have been chosen for this purpose ; the British, the Belgian (which may also be considered as representative of France), the German (which may be considered as representative of Czechoslovakia), and the Polish. Information as to the composition of these baskets has been furnished by the Governments of the respective countries and is given in the following table. TABLE SHOWING QUANTITIES OF FOOD CONSUMED IN COUNTRIES (PER UNIT OF CONSUMPTION) Items Unit British quantities White b r e a d . . . . Rye b r e a d . . . . kilo 2.10 — 1.25 0.17 0.05 0.50 0.20 0.12 1.50 0.60 0.01 — 0.10 0.08 1.20 2.75 0.135 Butter Beet Mutton Potatoes Coffee. . Coffee s u b s t i t u t e Tea Milk Eggs litre unit kilo DIFFERENT Belgian German Polish quantities quantities quantities 4.50 — 0.25 0.24 0.08 0.50 — 0.20 3.00 0.35 0.20 — — 0.10 1.70 3.00 0.06 0.50 3.00 0.30 0.10 0.12 0.25 0.05 0.11 4.50 0.25 0.03 0.10 — 0.13 2.50 2.00 0.40 0.50 2.37 0.58 0.07 0.08 0.58 — 0.23 3.50 0.26 — 0.09 0.02 — 1.75 3.50 0.35 The British, German, and Belgian budgets are based on the general budgets used in the respective countries for the compilation of cost-of-living index numbers and are also used by the International Labour Office in its quarterly calculations of real wages in capital cities. The Polish budget was supplied by the Polish Government. The cost of each of these four baskets is then calculated for each of the ten regions : Great Britain, Netherlands, Belgium, France, Germany (two districts), Czechoslovakia (two districts), Poland and the Saar at the prices current in those districts. The prices used for Great Britain are published in the Ministry of Labour Gazette; those for Germany (the Ruhr), Germany (Upper Silesia), Belgium, France, Poland, and Czechoslovakia were supplied by the respective Governments ; those for the Saar by the Saar Mining Administration ; and those for the Netherlands are those current at Maastricht (as representing the Limburg mining district) on 1 January 1926 as published — 183 — in Pripen en Kosten van Levensonderhoud. The French prices, it should be noted, refer only to the Pas de Calais region. The number of times the earnings will purchase each of these four baskets is calculated and the results expressed in the form of index numbers on the basis Great Britain = 100. The average of these four index numbers is taken and the result gives an "international average of real earnings". It will thus be seen that each of the national earnings are not measured in terms of each of the four budgets. The final average index number thus takes account of each of the representative budgets. An example will make the method clear : The cost of the four different budgets in 1925 in three of the mining regions was as follows : Region British budget French budget German budget Polish budget Great B r i t a i n . . . . Germany (Ruhr) . . 86.5d. 7.92 R.M. 30.00 frs. 102.5d. 9.95R.M. 32.60 frs. 81.0d. 6.10 R.M. 24.30 frs. 82.0d. 6.50 R.M. 25.70 frs. The average daily earnings of mine-workers in these districts were (see Table VI, pages 108-109) : Great Britain 139d. Germany (the Ruhr) 7.45 R.M. France 27.90 1rs. The number of times that a British, German (Ruhr), and French miner can buy these "baskets of provisions" is as given below : Number of times miner's wage in different region will purchase Region Great Britain Germany (Ruhr) . . . British basket French basket German basket Polish basket 1.61 0.94 0.93 1.36 0.75 0.86 1.72 1.22 1.15 1.70 1.15 1.09 Thus a British miner by spending the whole of his wages on pur139 chasing these foodstuffs could buy the British basket Q» r or 1.61 7.46 times, the German miner ~-cñ o r 0-94 times, and the French miner 27.9 or 0.93 times. 30.0 The ratio of the purchasing power of wages in Great Britain, the Ruhr, and France using the British basket is thus 1.61,0.94, and 0.93. Great Britain is then taken as 100, and the index numbers are 100, — 184 — 58.5, and 58.0. Identical calculations are made for each mining region and for each of the other three baskets and an average of the four series of index numbers is then made, as shown in the following table : Index numbers (Great Britain = 100) Region Great Britain . . . Germany (Ruhr) France British basket French basket 100 58.5 58.0 100 55 63 German basket 100 71 67 Polish basket General average 100 68 64 100 63.1 63 APPENDIX IV CHANGES IN HOURS OF LABOUR AND WAGES IN T H E COAL INDUSTRY OF EUROPEAN COUNTRIES FROM 1925 T O 1927 INTRODUCTORY N O T E The year 1925 to which the comparative enquiry presented in Part Two of this report refers, constituted an exceptional year in several respects and for several countries. Observations to this effect have been expressly made in the course of the enquiry on the part of the Polish Government and the Miners' Federation of Great Britain. For this reason, and with a view to bringing the enquiry up to date as much as possible, it is necessary to give a general survey of the changes which have taken place in the regulation of hours of work and in the level of wages in the European coal industry in the period following 1925. It goes without saying that the method of presentation in this appendix must be different from that employed in the study concerning the situation in 1925. The data given in the following notes are secured directly from the official sources of each country, and, owing to the varying scope and methods of national legislation and national statistics, each country must be dealt with in a separate note. Comparisons between different countries cannot, as a rule, be made. The principal object of the present appendix is in fact to compare the developments which have taken place in each individual country during the period 1925, 1926, and 1927. The starting point of the comparison is the situation in 1925 ; it should, however, be noted that in general the data given in P a r t Two in respect of this year cannot be compared with the information available for later periods ; hence it is necessary to furnish for each country such information for 1925 as is to be found in the official statistics, and with which the information for 1926 and 1927 agree. Section A deals with hours of labour. This section is confined to three countries only, viz. Germany, Great Britain, and Poland, where important modifications have been made since 1925. Section B deals with statistics of wages 1 . Since the level of wages in a great industry, like coal-mining, is constantly fluctuating in a greater or lesser degree, it is necessary to cover in this section all countries for which useful information is found, viz. Belgium, Czechoslovakia, France, Germany, Great Britain, Netherlands, Poland, and the Saar. For all countries, data are available for the years 1925 and 1926 ; in the case of Poland, additional information is given for the first — 186 — quarter of 1927, in the case of Germany and the Netherlands for the first three quarters of the same year, and in the case of Belgium, France, Great Britain and the Saar for the whole year 1927. The average wages are expressed (as in Part Two of this report) both in terms of national currency and in terms of gold francs. The conversion of wages into gold francs has been deemed to be indispensable in view of the fluctuations in the value of some European currencies in 1925 and 1926 which render any comparisons for the individual countries difficult, if not impossible. Wages expressed in terms of gold francs will also show in what direction the cost of an hour's or a day's work, or of a ton of coal, i.e. the purchasing power of wages in the international market, have changed. The conversion of wages into gold francs is effected on the basis of an average rate of exchange for the whole year (or for a quarter in 1927), whereas the currencies which were not stable, varied in fact from day to day ; the figures relating to gold franc wages are therefore only approximate 1. A further and more important reservation is to be made as regards the comparisons of the workers' standard of living. If wages expressed in national currencies and converted to gold francs are shown to have increased in a given period, this does not necessarily mean that the standard of living of workers has also improved. The figures relating t o wages refer in most cases to money wages only, and it is not known how the value of allowances in kind, payments for holidays, employers' contributions, etc., have changed. Above all, accurate calculations of the relative purchasing power of the wages in terms of prices of commodities cannot be made for the periods considered. In order to remedy this flaw, the cost-of-living index numbers are given for each country, but since these index numbers are not established for the mining districts concerned, they can only indicate the changes in the internal purchasing power of the national currency in its general lines. A. HOURS OF W O R K Since 1925, the period to which the figures in this report refer, new circumstances have arisen in Germany, Great Britain and Poland, as regards hours of work in coal-mines. Germany In the Ruhr2, the arbitral award of 18 March 1927 (rendered binding on 23 March 1927 and applied since 1 April 1927) contains the following provisions : (1) The maintenance of the usual shift, i.e. 7 hours plus 1 hour overtime. 1 See remarks made in Part Two, Chapter II, § 17. An enquiry made by the Mining Employers' Federation of the Ruhr showed that on 22 Feb. 1927 the effective hours of work at the lace, excluding breaks (durée de présence au chantier : reine Arbeitszeit pot Ort), for hewers, fillers and drawers, were 6 hours 15.02 minutes. 2 — 187 — (2) A reduction of hours from 10 to 8, plus 1 hour overtime, for surface workers whose work is directly connected with coal getting. (3) As from 2 May 1927, a reduction of hours for other classes of surface workers, which will reduce hours of work, breaks excluded, to 9 a day. In undertakings working two shifts, 8 hours are worked on Saturdays, in those employing one shift, 8 and 10 hours are worked on alternate Saturdays. Daily hours of attendance are reduced from 12 to 10 for the whole of the workers, a supplement of 25 per cent, being paid for the tenth hour. (4) In surface undertakings operating continuously (coke furnaces excepted) hours of work are 10 a day. Sunday work is regulated as formerly. The personnel may be required to be present during breaks and rest periods. Since 1 April 1927, a supplement of 25 per cent, is paid for the tenth hour ; this supplement is reduced to 10 per cent, for groups of workers whose occupation consists mainly in being present. At Aachen, the arbitral award of 26 March 1927 (rendered binding on 31 March and applied since 1 April 1927) provides : (1) For underground workers a shift of 7 hours. Overtime must be carried out in such a way that the total shift shall be 8 % hours, this period to be reduced to 81/t hours on 1 June 1927. (2) For surface workers whose work is directly connected with coal-getting, hours of work equal to those of underground workers. (3) As from 1 May 1927, a reduction of hours for other classes of surface workers, which will reduce hours of work, breaks excluded, to 9 on weekdays, the duration of the shift being 10 hours. In undertakings working two shifts, 8 hours are worked on Saturdays, 9 hours being worked in those with one shift. (4) In surface undertakings operating continuously, hours of work are 10 a day. Sunday work is regulated as formerly. The personnel may be required to be present during breaks and rest periods. Since 1 April 1927, a supplement of 25 per cent, is paid for the tenth hour ; this supplement is reduced to 10 per cent, for groups of workers whose occupation consists mainly in being present. In Upper Silesia, the arbitral award of 22 February 1927 (rendered binding on 1 March 1927) contains the following provisions : (1) For underground workers, a reduction of the shift by a quarter of an hour from 1 March and by a further quarter of an hour from 1 September 1927, the duration of the shift thus being reduced to 8 hours. (2) For surface workers, the duration of hours of work, breaks excluded, is reduced to 8 hours on Saturdays. (3) In surface undertakings operating continuously, hours of work are not reduced on Saturdays. Work performed in excess of 8 hours is considered as overtime. In Lower Silesia, the arbitral award of 28 May 1927 (rendered binding on 31 May and applied since 1 June 1927) provides : (1) For underground workers a shift of 7 hours, plus 1 hour overtime. (2) For surface workers whose work is directly connected with coal-getting, a shift of 8 hours plus 1 hour overtime. — 188 — (3) For other classes of surface workers, 9 hours of work, excluding rests, on weekdays and a shift of 10 hours. In undertakings where 10 hours were worked, the tenth hour to be abolished before 1 August 1927. On Saturdays, overtime is not to become a regular habit. (4) A supplement of 15 per cent, is to be paid for the ninth hour's work, and a supplement of 25 per cent, for the tenth and following hours. These supplements are, however, not granted to workers whose work normally and mainly consists in being present. (5) In surface undertakings operating continuously (coke furnaces excepted), hours of work are reduced from 10 to 9% a day. Sunday work is regulated as formerly. The personnel may be required to be present during breaks and rest periods. In the Free State of Saxony, in virtue of the arbitral award of 18 May 1927, workers were to receive a supplement of 15 per cent., as. from 1 July 1927, for the ninth hour of work, excluding breaks (reine Arbeitszeit), and a supplement of 25 per cent, for the tenth hour. At the present time, regulations guarantee that work performed in the mines over and above that fixed by agreement and overtime shall be paid at an increased rate varying between 15 and 25 per cent. Great Britain In Great Britain the Coal Mines Act of 1926 \ which received the Royal Assent on 8 July of that year and which is to continue in force for a period of five years from that date, has amended section 3 of the Coal Mines Regulation Act of 1918, included in the Coal Mines Acts, 1887-1919 2 . Section 3, subsection (1), of the earlier Act was as follows : "The time fixed ,by this Act as the time during which the workmen in the mine may be below ground for the purpose of their work and of going to and from their work may be extended as respects any mine, by the owner, agent or manager of the mine, on not more than 60 days in any calendar year by not more than one hour a day, and on any day in which an extension of time is so made in accordance with this section as respects any mine the time as so extended shall be substituted for the purposes of this Act as respects that mine for the time as fixed by this Act." The subsection as amended by the new Act is as follows : "The time fixed by this Act as the time during which the workmen in the mine may be below ground for the purpose of their work and of going to and from their work may be extended as respects any mine by the owner, agent, or manager of the mine, by not more than one hour a day, and on any day in which an extension of time is so made in accordance with this section as respects any mine the time as so extended shall be substituted for the purposes of this Act as respects that mine for the time as fixed by this Act." 1 3 Legislative Series, 1926, G.B. 2. See pp. 162-163. — 189 — This provision therefore makes it legally possible for the owner of a mine to increase working hours to 8 per day for the personnel deemed to be "workmen" and to 9 for the personnel covered by paragraph (a) of subsection (7) of section 1 of the Act of 1908. Subsequent to the passing of this Act, collective agreements have been made between the representatives of the owners and the workers in practically all the coal-mining districts, embodying the duration of the shift, or working day, below ground. In the majority of the districts the full 8 hours is stipulated, in others 7%> whilst yet in others the hewers alone work 7 % , while other underground classes (haulage hands, etc.) are required to work 8. Most of the agreements provide for a shorter shift on Saturday, varying from 5 1 / t to 7 hours. The hours of work on the shifts have also been increased pari passu with those underground, and the weekly maximum of 4 6 % hours laid down in the National Agreement of 1919 has been superseded by separate district arrangements incorporated in the various agreements. For all practical purposes the hours of work above ground are now similar to those which existed in 1919, i.e. from 48 to 50 hours per week according to the district. Poland In the Basins of Dombrowa and Cracow the Directorate of Mines introduced on 6 April 1926, for underground workers, a break of 30 minutes, which is not included in the hours of work, and must therefore be added to the regulation hours in order to give the actual working day. This rest period is not granted on Saturdays. In consequence of these provisions the actual working day is increased to 8 % hours (6 hours on Saturdays). B. WAGES Belgium § 1. Statistics as to the employment and production in the Belgian coal-mines are available for the years 1925 and 1926 ; moreover, some provisional figures for 1927 have been obtained. Data are furnished for six different districts, but in the following notes figures are given only for the country as a whole. The differences in the level of wages between the various districts are in fact rather small. § 2. Table I shows the aggregate amount of money wages paid by the coal-mines in 1925 and 1926. The statistics distinguish between the term "net wages" which means money wages paid directly for the amount of work done, and the term "gross wages", meaning the total of net wages and workers' contributions to social insurance. As was shown in the study of wages in 1925, these "gross wages" represent about 94 per cent, of total actual earnings of workpeople, excluding employers'contributions to social insurance. — 190 — TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES BILL IN BELGIAN COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (Belgian Francs—000's Omitted) Items of wages 1925 Workmen's contributions to social Total or " gross wages " . 1926 1,266,041 1,492,343 29,691 1,295,732 35,397 1,527,740 Further to money wages, the statistics show "expenditure in respect to labour" (dépenses afjérantes à la main-d'œuvre), which includes the value of coal distributed to employees free of charge or at a reduced rate, employers' contributions to the schemes of workmen's compensation for industrial accidents, subventions to mutualaid funds, and miscellaneous. The sum total of this expenditure was, in 1925, 147,585,000 francs, and, in 1926, 182,414,000 francs. This sum is somewhat higher than the total of items other than net money wages and workers' contributions to social insurance, as is shown in Part Two of the present report. The distribution of the total of gross money wages of different categories of mine workers, viz. hewers, underground workers, and surface workers, is given in the following table. TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF GROSS MONEY WAGES AMONG DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF MINE-WORKERS, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (Belgian Francs—000's Omitted) Categories ol workers All underground workers 1925 . . . . All mine workers. . . 209,940 967,877 327,855 1,295,732 1926 245,966 1,155,213 372,527 1,527,740 The aggregate number of days' work (corresponding to manshifts) of coal-winding days (jours d'extraction), as well as the average number of mine-workers, is given in Table III. With regard to the first-named number, it is to be observed that it excludes days' work performed by certain categories of workers on days when coal was not wound. The average number of mine-workers is calculated from the number of days worked and the average number of coal-winding days. By coal-winding days are meant days on which at least one of the pits was in operation. The average number of coàl-winding days was, in 1925, 295.13 and, in 1926, 298.52which corresponds nearly to the full number of possible working days. — 191 — TABLE III. — NUMBER OF DAYS' WORK ON COAL "WINDING DAYS AND AVERAGE NUMBER OF MINE-WORKERS, BY CATEGORIES, 1925 AND 1926 Average number of mineworkers Number of days' work Categories of workers 1925 1926 1925 | 1926 6,496,000 6,512,000 22,058 21,967 Surface workers . . . 32,436,000 14,899,000 33,028,000 14,795,000 109,916 50,467 110,615 49,582 All mine-workers. . 47,334,000 47,823,000 160,383 160,197 All underground It will be seen from Table III that both the number of days' work and the average number of mine-workers have remained practically stationary in the two years considered. The proportion of days worked and of workers employed in the different categories has also remained unchanged in both years. The number of hewers was 14 per cent, of the total number of workers, that of all underground workers 69 per cent., and that of surface workers 31 per cent. ; the percentages of days' work by these different categories were the same. TABLE IV. — AVERAGE DAILY AND YEARLY WAGES OF DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF MINE-WORKERS, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 Average wage Belgian francs Categories of workers 1925 | 1926 Average wage gold francs 1925 1926 (i) Average Wages per Day's Work All underground workers. . . All mine-workers . . . . 32.32 37.77 7.97 6.61 29.25 20.72 34.29 23.85 7.22 5.11 6.00 4.17 26.49 30.99 6.54 5.42 (ii) Average Wages per Worker per Year All underground workers. . . All mine-workers . . . . 9,518 11,197 2,348 1,958 8,806 6,496 10,444 7,513 2,172 1,603 1,827 1,314 8,079 9,537 1,993 1,668 — 192 — § 3. The average "gross wage" per day and per annum for the different categories of mine-workers is calculated on the basis of data furnished above. The averages are given in each case (Table IV) both in Belgian francs and in gold francs 1 . The changes which have taken place in the level of wages from 1925 t o 1926 are shown by the "relative numbers' ' in Table V. These numbers are calculated by taking in each case the average wage paid in 1925 as equal to 100, and by relating the average wage paid in 1926 to this basis. TABLE V. — RELATIVE NUMBER OF AVERAGE WAGES OF THE DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF MINE-WORKERS IN 1 9 2 6 (Average Wage in 1925 = 100) Category of workers All underground workers . . Average wages per day expressed in Average wages per year expressed in Belgian francs Gold francs Belgian francs Gold francs 116.9 117.2 115.1 117.0 82.9 83.1 81.6 82.9 117.6 118.6 115.7 118.0 83.4 84.1 82.0 83.7 The above figures show that the changes in wages have been practically equal for the different categories of workers. Average wages expressed in the national currency have increased by about 15 to 18 per cent ; owing to the depression of the Belgian franc in 1926 the average wages expressed in terms of gold francs have decreased by about 16 to 18 per cent. The purchasing power in the international market of wages paid by the Belgian coal industry thus decreased considerably in 1926. In order to know how these fluctuations have affected the standard of living of workers, it will be necessary to ascertain the changes in the internal purchasing power of the Belgian franc. A general idea of these changes will be obtained by means of the index numbers of food prices and cost of living which refer to retail prices in 59 Belgian towns. Taking the index number shown for the month of July 1925 as equal to 100, the index numbers for July 1926 are : Foodstuffs . . Cost of living 139.1 130.8 It may be inferred from these figures that the cost of living increased in Belgium during the year 1926 more than the average wages paid in the coal industry, and that consequently the internal purchasing power of mine-workers' wages ("real wages" of mine-workers) were less in 1926 than in the preceding year. 1 The rates of exchange used in the conversion of Belgian francs to gold francs are : In 1925 100 Belgian francs = 24.67 gold francs In 1926 100 „ „ = 17.49 — 193 — According to provisional information published for 1927 1 , average wages per day of the different categories of workers were as follows 2 : BeJgian francs Gold francs Hewers 50.13 7.23 All underground workers 44.98 6.49 Surface workers 31.31 4.52 All mine-workers 40.83 5.89 Compared with the wage level of 1925 = 100, the relative number of average wages expressed in gold francs was 90. The purchasing power of these wages in the international market in 1927 was thus 10 per cent, below the corresponding purchasing power in 1925. On the other hand, the purchasing power of the wages of the Belgian miners in the internal market (or "real wages") was approximately on the same level in 1925 and 1927. As a matter of fact, if the relative number of average wages expressed in Belgian francs in 1925 is taken as = 100, the wages paid in 1927 are represented by the figure 154. The index number of foodstuffs, compared with July 1925 = 100, was, in July 1927, 157.9 and that of cost of living in general, 153.4. The fact that real wages thus increased in 1927 to their previous level is due to the application of a "combined index" to the regulation of wages in the coal industry during the period from 1 November 1926 to 1 November 1927 3. § 4. Table VI shows the total output of coal and its distribution for different uses in 1925 and 1926. TABLE VI. — TOTAL O U T P U T O F COAL AND ITS DISTRIBUTION FOR DIFFERENT USES, 1925 AND 1926 (Metric Tons—000's Omitted) T o n n a g e of Coal distributed t o mine-workers 1925 . . . . 1926 2,491 521 20,085 2,501 507 22,252 23,097 25,260 The average daily and annual output of coal per hewer, per underground worker, and per underground and surface worker is shown in Table VII. 1 Cf. MINISTÈRE DE L'INDUSTRIE, DU TRAVAIL ET DE LA PRÉVOYANCE SOCIALE, ADMINISTRATION DES MINES : L'Industrie charbonnière pendant l'année 1927; statistique provisoire et vue d'ensemble sur l'exploitation. Brussels, 1928. 2 In order to convert the Belgian francs to gold francs, the value of the belga at par has been divided by 5 (100 Belgas = 74.14 gold francs ; 100 Belgian francs = 14.43 gold francs). 3 This "combined index" was established on the basis of fluctuations of the retail prices of food and market prices of coal. 13 — 194 — TABLE VII. — AVERAGE DAILY AND ANNUAL OUTPUT OF COAL PER WORKER, 1925 AND 1926 (Metric Tons) Category of worker Underground worker . . . . Mine-worker in general . . . Average output per day Average output per year 1925 1926 1925 1926 3.56 0.70 0.47 3.88 0.72 0.51 1,047 210 144 1,150 228 155 These figures show that the average output increased by about 10 per cent, in 1926 as compared with the preceding year. The average ' 'gross wage' ' cost per ton of coal may be calculated from figures given in Tables I and VI. The average wage cost is calculated both in terms of Belgian francs and in gold francs. TABLE VIII. — AVERAGE WAGE COST OF A TON OF COAL, 1925 AND 1926 Ton ot Commercially disposable coal Average cost in Belgian francs Average cost in gold francs 1925 1926 1925 1926 56.10 64.51 60.48 68.66 13.84 15.91 10.58 12.01 It is seen t h a t the wage cost expressed in gold francs decreased considerably (by about 24 per cent.) from 1925 to 1926. In 1927 the total quantity of saleable coal was about 27,548,000 metric tons ; the average daily output was as follows : Per hewer 3.91 tons Per underground worker 0.74 ,, Per mine-worker in general 0.51 „ These figures show that while the total production continued to increase in the course of 1927, the average output remained almost stationary. Finally, the average wage cost per ton of saleable coal raised in 1927 was 79.44 Belgian francs, or 11.46 gold francs. The wage cost, expressed in terms.of gold, increased slightly as compared with the preceding year, but still remained considerably below (by about 17 per cent.) the 1925 level. Czechoslovakia § 1. Wage and output statistics for the coal-mines of the Republic of Czechoslovakia, published by the Statistical Office, are available for the years 1925 and 1926. The figures in question are fairly complete and are largely based on the methods used for the 1925 enquiry into wages and set forth in P a r t Two of this report. — 195 § 2. The total earnings shown in Czechoslovak statistics cover the various elements included in "aggregate actual earnings", with the exception of employers' contributions to social insurance. It must, however, be pointed out t h a t the figures given in the official statistics do not quite agree with those given by the Czechoslovak Government in reply to the 1925 enquiry ; for example, the allowances in kind are shown according to their taxed value, which is less than their real value 1 . The result of this is that the earnings in question as shown in the official statistics are somewhat lower than the figures obtained for our enquiry. The composition of the aggregate actual earnings in the coal-mines of the Republic and their distribution between the various classes of miners are shown in Tables I and II. TABLE I. — COMPOSITION OF AGGREGATE ACTUAL EARNINGS IN THE GOAL-MINES OF CZECHOSLOVAKIA IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (In Thousands of Crowns) 1925 1926 606,299 32,587 638,886 630,553 28,595 659,148 Composition of earnings Total money earnings Total value of allowances in kind TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF . . . . AGGREGATE ACTUAL EARNINGS IN 1925 AND 1926 (In Thousands of Crowns) Category of workers Total underground and surface workers . | 1925 255,601 498,435 140,451 638,886 | . 1926 260,754 525,010 134,138 659,148 The total number of shifts worked, calculated on the basis of the normal shift, and including overtime and short shifts, is shown in Table III, which also gives the total number of shifts lost when the mines were working and when work was suspended in the mines. 1 A comparison of the "taxed value" of allowances in kind as shown in the mining statistics, and their real value as given at the time of enquiry, proves that in 1925 the latter was exactly double the former. — 196 — TABLE III. — TOTAL NUMBER OF MANSHIFTS WORKED AND LOST IN 1925 AND 1926 (000's Omitted) Manshifts worked Manshifts lost Category of workers 1925 1926 1925 1926 Hewers All underground workers . . 5,074 11,579 4,713 11,111 1,346 3,149 1,110 2,615 All surface workers Total underground and surface 4,052 3,459 655 513 15,631 14,570 3,804 3,128 Table IV shows the number of workers employed in Czechoslovak coal-mines in 1925 and 1926. As was explained in a description of the methods used in compiling mining statistics, this number does not represent the average number of workers but rather the number of full-time workers. The number of shifts lost during the course of these two years having been rather high, the number of full-time workers is much lower than the average number of workers actually employed. TABLE IV. NUMBER OF MINE-WORKERS IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 Category of workers Total underground and surface workers . 1925 21,092 48,050 14,403 62,453 1926 19,004 45,183 13,011 58,194 § 3. The average actual earnings are calculated per manshift on the one hand, and per worker per annum on the other. The relative figures are shown in Table V *. 1 The rates used for the conversion of the Czechoslovak crown into gold francs were as follows : 1925 100 Kc. = 15.39 gold francs 1926 100 Kc. = 15.35 „ — 197 — TABLE V. — AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS PER MANSHIFT AND PER ANNUM IN 1925 AND 1926 Average earnings in gold francs Average earnings in crowns Category of workers 1925 j 1925 1926 1926 (i) Per Manshift Hewers All underground workers. . . All underground and surface workers 50.40 43.05 34.66 54.06 46.07 35.98 7.75 6.62 5.33 8.30 7.07 5.52 40.87 43.58 6.28 6.69 (ii) Per Worker per Annum Hewers All underground workers. . . All surface workers All underground and surface workers 12,118 10,373 9,752 13,721 11,620 10,310 1,863 1,594 1,499 2,106 1,784 1,583 10,230 11,327 1,572 1,739 Table V shows that earnings expressed in Czechoslovak currency rose slightly during 1926. On account of the stability of the Czechoslovak crown during the two years in question, the gold value of actual earnings also increased in each case. The increase is more noticeable in the case of annual average earnings than in the case of earnings per shift. This is explained by the fact (brought out by the number of shifts lost as shown in Table III) that the mines were worked more regularly in 1926 than during the preceding year. The increase of annual average earnings for the workers taken as a whole was 10 per cent, between 1925 and 1926. On the other hand, the purchasing power of wages on the home market appears to have remained stable, or it did not increase, during 1926. The official cost-of-living index number for the town of Prague fell by about 3 per cent, between July 1925 and July 1926. It may therefore be assumed that the real wages of Czechoslovak working miners increased during 1926. TABLE VI. — TOTAL COAL OUTPUT, 1925 AND 1926 (Metric Tons—000's Omitted) Distribution of tonnage Total saleable coal . . . 1925 861 254 11,444 12,559 1926 842 236 13,099 14,177 — 198 — TABLE VII. — AVERAGE OUTPUT OF SALEABLE COAL, 1925 AND 1926 (In Metric Tons) A v e r a g e output per manshift Category of workers Underground workers Underground and surf ace workers Average output per worker per a n n u m 1925 1926 1925 1926 2.475 1.086 0.803 3.008 1.276 0.973 595 261 201 746 314 244 § 4. The statistics relating to the total and average output of coal are summarised in Tables VI and VII. As is shown in Table VII, the average coal output both per shift and per worker per annum increased to a considerable extent during 1926 as compared with 1925. The increase was as high as 21 to 22 per cent. Finally, the labour cost per ton of saleable coal raised and per ton of commercially disposable coal may be calculated on the basis of the data given in Tables I to VI. These figures were as follows in 1925 and 1926. TABLE VIH. — WAGE COST PER TON OF COAL IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 W a g e cost in crowns W a g e cost in gold francs Ton of Saleable coal Commercially disposable c o a l . 1925 1926 1925 1926 50.87 55.83 46.49 50.32 7.82 8.58 7.14 7.72 The wages in the production of coal are thus seen to have decreased by almost 10 per cent., this result being obtained in spite of the increase in the average earnings of the working miners and as a result of the rise in the individual worker's output. France § 1. French mining statistics published by the Ministry of Public Works contain detailed information relating to employment, wages, and output in coal-mines, up to the end of 1925. For the years 1926 and 1927 recourse has been had to provisional information collected, but not published, by the Ministry 1. 1 It should be observed, however, that the Bulletin du Ministère du Travail et de l'Hygiène publishes from time to time a quarterly summary of mining statistics, but the fact that this information is irregular has prevented direct use being made of it. — 199 — The figures are given separately for each department in which minerals are worked, but in the following notes only those concerning the whole country have been included. § 2. Table I shows the total amount of wages paid in francs, and includes bonuses of all kinds. Compared with the amount of "aggregate actual earnings" supplied by the French Government in connection with the enquiry of 1925, the total wages paid to workers during that year represent 88 per cent. TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES PAID IN THE COAL-MINES OF IN 1925, 1926 AND 1927 (In FRANCE Thousands of French Francs) Year 1925 1926 1927 Underground workers Surface workers All workers 1,562,023 1,896,924 2,115,219 492,626 531,609 592,796 2,054,649 2,428,533 2,708,015 The same statistics also give information on the number of manshifts worked and the average number of workers. The latter figures include the "registered staff", which is counted each month, and include not only the personnel employed in coal-mines, but also that of the lignite mines, the importance of which is, however, small in comparison with the coal-mines. TABLE II. — TOTAL NUMBER OF DAYS WORKED AND AVERAGE NUMBER OF STAFF REGISTERED IN COAL-MINES, FROM 1 9 2 5 TO 1 9 2 7 Number of manshifts (000's omitted) Registered staff ' Year III Underground 60,158 61,850 62,565 Surface 25,211 23,674 23,699 Underground Surface Total 85,369 214,831 85,524 238,637 86,264 226,235 83,287 91,832 91,883 298,118 330,469 318,118 Total • For 1925, average number ; for 1926 and 1927, number registered on 31 December. § 3. The official statistics include the figures concerning average daily wages earned per worker 1 (Table III). 1 The rates used for the conversion of French francs into gold francs were as follows : 1925 100 French francs = 24.71 gold francs 1926 100 „ „ = 16.83 1927 100 „ „ = 20.34 — 200 — TABLE III. — AVERAGE DAILY WAGE OF MINING WORKERS FROM 1925 TO 1927 Wages in French francs Year 1925 1926 1927 Underground Surface 25.94 30.66 34.33 19.55 22.50 25.02 Wages in gold francs UnderUnderground and UnderSurface ground and ground surface surface 24.07 28.40 31.39 6.41 5.16 6.98 4.83 3.79 5.09 5.95 4.78 6.38 In order to illustrate the changes in wage levels expressed in French and gold francs, the relative figures for average wages have been calculated by taking the 1925 figures as a basis ( = 100). Table IV shows the relative value of the wages earned by underground and surface workers. TABLE IV. — RELATIVE AVERAGE DAILY WAGES 1925 TO 1927 OF MINERS FROM (Average Wage in 1925 = 100) Wages in French francs Wages in gold francs Year 1925 1926 1927 Underground Surface Underground Surface 100 118.2 132.3 100 115.1 128.0 100 80.5 108.9 100 78,5 105.4 The relative figures given above show that nominal wages expressed in French francs have risen to a considerable extent since 1925. The same, however, cannot be said when wages are converted into gold francs. As a consequence of fluctuations in the rate of exchange, the gold value of miners' average wages decreased in 1926. In the following year the rise in the rate of exchange resulted, in increasing the reduced wages in gold francs beyond their value in In order to show the fluctuations in the purchasing power of wages on the home market, the following official index numbers of foodstuffs for 250 French towns of over 10,000 inhabitants are given, the index numbers of prices in August 1925 being taken as a basis : August 1925 = 100 August 1926 = 135 August 1927 = 123 The purchasing power of the French franc, calculated in terms of retail prices, is thus seen to have decreased in 1926 and to have risen in 1927, without however reaching the 1925 level. It may therefore be concluded that the purchasing power of miners' wages (real wages) decreased during 1926 in comparison with 1925, and that it rose during 1927 so as to exceed the level of 1925. — 201 — § 4. The monthly coal extraction figures are shown in the French statistics. The figures in Table V relate to the tonnage of saleable and commercially disposable coal. The average output has been obtained by dividing the total output by the number of working days as given in Table II. TABLE V. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT FROM 1925 TO 1927 (Metric Tons) Total output (000's omitted) Daily output of saleable coal per w o r k e r Year Saleable coal raised 1925 1926 1927 48,091 52,362 52,669 Commercially disposable coal Underground 0.799 0.846 0.840 4i,972 45,772 46,143 In g e n e r a l 0.563 0.612 0.606 Table VI shows the cost of labour per ton of coal. TABLE VI. AVERAGE LABOUR 1925 COST TO PER Cost in French francs Year 1925 1926 1927 TON OF COAL FROM 1927 Per saleable ton Per commercially disposable ton 42.73 46.38 51.42 48.95 53.06 58.69 Cost in gold francs Per Per i .¡alpahle saleable ton ton | dcommercially isposable ton 10.56 7.81 10.46 12.10 8.93 11.94 Two facts are obvious from the above figures : first, that the average output per worker, after having undergone a considerable decrease in 1926, continued in the following year to show a slight tendency to fall ; and, secondly, that the labour cost per ton expressed in French francs, after declining considerably in 1926 as compared with 1925, rose again in 1927 to very near the 1925 level. Germany j § 1. The German statistics relating to the employment and production in the coal-mines are available for the years 1925 and 1926, as well as for the first three quarters of 1927. Statistics are given separately for the different coal districts and no figures for the country as a whole are furnished ; in the following notes (as in Part Two of the present report) statistics are shown separately for the two principal districts, viz. the Ruhr and Upper Silesia, as well as for the Free State of Saxony. The figures available for the lastnamed district are incomplete in several respects. It is to be observed that ancillary establishments are included in the official statistics of mines. — 202 — § 2. The total wages bill given in the German statistics distinguishes between the amount of total money wages, including additional payments for overtime (Leistungslohn inklusive Zuschläge für Überarbeiten), the value of allowances in money (Hausstandsgeld und Kindergeld), the sum of which constitutes total money earnings (Barverdienst) ; further, the total value of allowances in kind (Wert der wirtschaftlichen Beihilfen), and that of payments for holidays (Urlaubsentschädigung und Urlaubsabgeltung). The sum of these items and of total money wages gives the amount of "calculated actual earnings" (errechnetes Gesamteinkommen). The last-named amount corresponds to the amount of total actual earnings, excluding employers' contributions to social insurance, as defined in the present report. TABLE I. — COMPOSITION OF TOTAL EARNINGS BY DISTRICTS, 1925 TO 1927 (In R.M. —000's Omitted) Year and quarter Total money wages Total value of allowances in money : 1925 \l926 R u h r . . 1927: 1st / 2nd i 3rd 11925 Upper ) 1926 Silesia . (1927: 1st j 2nd ' 3rd /1925 \1926. . . Saxony. < 1927 : 1 s t / • 2nd { 3rd I 782,259 781,069 33,659 30,606 — — — — — — District qr. qr. qr. 63,293 75,339 2,228 2,387 qr. qr. qr. — — — — —. .— — . . qr. qr. qr. —. — — — — — — — • Total Total Total money value of payments for earnings allowances holidays in kind 815,918 811,675 226,038 213,000 227,885 65,521 77,726 21,686 19,823 23.157 41,999 46,223 12,148 10,785 10,763 12,341 11,262 3,406 2,498 2,610 2,112 2,239 19,275 20,650 3,737 8,967 10,048 1,428 1,655 551 500 495 212 538 695 1,669 1,587 1,188 1,230 418 351 314 16 569 601 Total actual earnings 847,534 843,587 233,181 224,465 240,543 69,061 81,620 22,449 20,861 24,347 44,856 49,040 12,582 11,705 11,678 The money earnings thus form about 93.6 to 96.2 per cent., the value of allowances in kind 1.3 to 3.7 per cent., and the payments for holidays 1.7 to 2.7 per cent., of the total actual earnings. The parts of the total money earnings and total actual earnings a ccruing to hewers and loaders (taken as a group), other underground workers, and surface workers are given in Table II. Surface workers are divided into three groups, viz. adult males over sixteen years of age, male juveniles under sixteen, and females. It may be observed that the number of juveniles given for the district of Upper Silesia includes a small number of juveniles employed underground. These figures are only available for the Ruhr and Upper Silesia for the years 1925 and 1926. The number of manshifts worked as given in the German statistics refers to the total of normal manshifts, supplementary manshifts — 203 and.overtime manshifts. T h i s n u m b e r is given s e p a r a t e l y for t h e different groups of workers a s s h o w n in T a b l e I I I . Only t h e t o t a l s for u n d e r g r o u n d a n d surface w o r k e r s t a k e n t o g e t h e r a r e a v a i l a b l e in t h e case of S a x o n y a n d for t h e o t h e r d i s t r i c t s for 1927. TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF TOTAL MONEY EARNINGS AND TOTAL ACTUAL EARNINGS BY CATEGORIES OF WORKERS, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (In R.M.—000's Omitted) Underground workers District Year Hewers and loaders Others Surface workers Adult males All Male juveniles Females All (i) Total Money Earnings 1925 1926 441,353 449,984 197,179 192,217 638,532 642,201 174,050 166,606 3,069 2,607 267 261 177,386 169,474 Upper : 1925 Silesia' 1926 22,760 27,491 26,337 32,550 49,097 60,041 15,481 16,770 148 124 795 791 16,424 17,685 Ruhr. . (ii) Total Actual Earnings 1925 Ruhr.. 1926 — Upper Silesia 1925 1926 TABLE III. — 459,257 468,586 204,794 199,714 664,051 668,300 180,118 172,401 3,089 2,618 276 268 183,483 175,287 23,923 28,818 27,733 34,125 51,656 62,943 16,415 17,719 149 124 841 834 17,405 18,677 TOTAL NUMBER OF MANSHIFTS W O R K E D BY CATEGORIES OF WORKERS, 1925 TO 1927 (000's Omitted) Underground workers District Year and quarter 1925 1926 1927 : 1st quarter Ruhr. 2nd quarter 3rd quarter 1925 Upper ,1926 Silesia . 1927 : 1st quarter 2nd quarter 3rd quarter 1925 1926 Saxony.) 1927: 1st quarter 2nd quarter 3rd quarter Hewers and loaders OUiers Surface workers 111 Adult males (oner 16) Juvenile males (under IS) 55,158 33,141 88,299 28,084 1,555 52,070 29,507 81,577 24,607 1,246 3,550 4,175 5,436 8,986 6,246 10,421 3,236 3,267 125 95 Underground and Females 68 63 111 surface workers 29,707 118,006 25,916 107,493 29,062 26,669 339 3,700 27,923 313 3,675 12,686 14,096 4,744 3,384 3,835 7,079 7,238 1,831 1,583 1.540 — 204 — Information as to the number of manshifts lost is given in Table IV for the total of underground and surface workers. TABLE IV. — TOTAL NUMBER OF MANSHIFTS LOST, 1925 TO 1927 (000's Omitted) District 1925 1927 1926 1st quarter 2nd quarter 3rd quarter Ruhr Upper Silesia . . , 17,782 1,756 920 15,171 1,830 975 3,990 407 243 4,107 524 280 4,448 539 279 The average number of workers calculated by dividing the sum of normal manshifts worked and manshifts lost by the number of possible working days in each category of workers is shown in Table V. Here, too, only totals are available for Saxony and in respect of the three quarters of 1927 only totals for the other districts. TABLE V. — A V E R A G E N U M B E R O F WORKERS, 1 9 2 5 TO 1 9 2 7 Underground workers District Vear 1925. 1926. R u h r . .< 1927 : 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr. 1925 Upper- 1 1926 Silesia < 1927 : 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr. 1925 1926. Saxony < 1927: 1st qr. 2nd qr. 2rd qr» Hewers and loader: Others Surface workers Ml Adult males Juveniles Females Ml Underground and surface workers 244 100,773 433,567 240 86,470 384,255 415,241 409,424 402,283 13,356 19,443 32,799 11,189 (a) 471 1,251 12,911 45,710 15,380 21,813 37,193 11,132 (I) 343 1,142 12,617 49,810 52,309 51,807 63,062 25,114 25,585 25,907 23,923 22,087 208,191 124,603 332,794 94,877 190,221 107,564 297,785 81,786 (a) Of which 178 occupied underground. 5,652 4,444 (b) OS which 140 occupied underground. § 3. Two different average earnings are calculated in the German statistics, viz. first, the average money earnings per manshift worked, and secondly, average actual earnings per worker employed. The averages are given not only in Reichsmarks, but also in terms of gold francs x. 1 The rates of exchange used in the conversion of R.M. to gold francs were as follows : 1925. R.M. 100 = 123.33 gold francs 1926. R.M. 100 = 123.33 R.M. 100 = 122.86 1st qr.. 1927 2nd qr. R.M. 100 = 122.86 R.M. 100 = 123.21 3rd qr. — 205 — TABLE VI. — AVERAGE MONEY EARNINGS PER MANSHIFT, 1925 TO 1927 Underground v, orkers Year and quarter District Hewers and loaders Others All 0) 1925 1926 1927: 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr, /1925 Upper Í1926 Silesia .<1927: 1st qr. 2nd qr, 3rd qr. Jl925 11926 SaxonW1927: 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr, Í 5.95 6.61 6.66 6.89 7.06 4.84 5.21 5.47 5.55 5.70 6.88 6.36 6.60 6.85 7.02 8.00 8.64 8.92 9.12 9.36 6.41 6.58 6.86 6.96 7.18 6.49 6.87 7.15 7.37 7.56 Surface workers Adult males Juveniles Females Average Earnings in K.M. 7.23 7.87 8.10 8.32 8.54 5.46 5.76 6.03 6.10 6.26 6.19 6.62 6.89 7.12 7.31 6.20 6.77 6.95 7.24 7.28 4.78 5.13 5.37 5.46 5.65 5.44 5.94 6.11 6.26 6.41 1.97 2.09 2.20 2.22 2.24 1.18 1.30 1.39 1.41 1.51 1.92 2.04 2.31 2.69 2.70 3.91 4.14 4.18 4.31 4.37 2.34 2.53 2.71 2.72 2.83 3.13 3.40 3.46 3.51 3.58 (ii) A v e r a g e Earnings in Qold F r a n c s /l925 •n , \1926 Ruhr. J 1 9 g 7 . 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr. /1925 Upper U926 Silesia .¿1927 : 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr. Jl925 11926 Saxony )l927: 1st 2nd 3rd 9.87 10.66 10.96 11.20 11.63 7.91 8.12 8.43 8.65 8.85 8.00 8.47 8.78 9.05 9.31 1 7.34 8.03 8.18 8.47 8.70 6.97 6.43 6.72 6.82 7.02 7.25 7.84 8.11 8.42 8.65 8.92 9.71 9.95 10.22 10.52 6.73 7.10 7.41 7.49 7.71 7.63 8.16 8.47 8.75 9.01 7.65 8.35 8.54 8.90 8.97 5.90 6.33 6.60 6.71 6.96 6.70 7.33 7.51 7.69 7.90 2.43 2.58 2.70 2.73 2.76 1.46 1.60 1.71 1.73 1.86 2.37 2.52 2.84 3.30 3.33 4.82 5.11 5.14 5.30 5.38 2.89 3.12 3.33 3.34 3.49 3.86 4.19 4.25 4.31 4.41 — 206 TABLE VII. — AVERAGE ACTUAL EARNINGS PER WORKER PER YEAR, 1925 AND 1926, AND PER QUARTER, 1927 Underground workers District Year and quarter Hewers and loaders Others All Surface workers Adult males Underground and Juven- Females surface iles workers (i) Average Actual Earnings in R.M. .1925 Rohr.. 1926 )1927:lstqr. 2nd qr. , 3rd qr. Í1926 Upper 11926 Silesia. YL927:1st qr. f 2nd qr. 1 3rd qr. Í1925 11926 Saxony 1927:1st qr. } 2nd qr. 3rd qr. k 2,206 2,463 1,644 1,857 1,996 2,244 1,899 2,108 546 589 1,132 1,118 1,791 1,874 1,426 1,564 1,575 1,692 1,467 1,592 316 360 672 731 . . . 1,955 2,195 562 548 598 1,511 1,639 429 403 459 . . . 1,917 486 489 629 . . . (ii) Average Actual Earnings in Gold Francs 1925 Ruhr.. 11926 <1927:lstqr. ' 2nd qr. } 3rd qr. 1925 Upper 11926 Silesia. YL927:lstqr. J 2nd qr. V 3rd qr. [1925. . . . ^1926 (1927:1st qr. j 2nd qr. [ 3rd qr. r 2,721 3,038 2,028 2,290 2,462 2,768 2,342 2,600 673 726 1,396 1,379 2,209 2,311 •1,769 1,929 1,942 2,087 1,809 1,963 390 444 829 902 . . . . . . . . . . 2,411 2,707 690 673 737 1,864 2,021 627 495 666 2,364 597 601 652 I — 207 — Tables VI and VII show that the average earnings received by the different categories of mine-workers in the three districts covered have, as a rule, increased since 1925. The average earnings per manshift have increased in the district of the Ruhr slightly more than in other coal-fields. The increase from 1925 to the third quarter of 1927 was, for all workers taken together, about 18 per cent. In Upper Silesia the corresponding increase has been about 17 per cent. and in Saxony slightly less than 18 per cent. The difference existing in 1925 between the earnings received in the Ruhr and other districts has thus been accentuated in the course of 1926 and 1927. As regards the changes which have taken place in the average earnings of the different categories of workers, it may be noted that the average earnings of surface workers have increased slightly more than those of underground workers. As the gold parity of the Reichsmark diminished slightly during the first two quarters of 1927, the wages expressed in terms of gold francs then increased less than wages expressed in terms of the national currency. On the other hand, the internal purchasing power of the Reichsmark has remained practically stable during the period under review. The cost-of-living index number (established on the basis of prices in 72 German towns) was as follows : July, 1925 . . . . 100 March, 1927 . . . 101 July, 1926 . . . . 99 July, 1927 . . . . 103 It thus may be inferred that the purchasing power of mine-workers' earnings in Germany has increased in some degree during 1926 and 1927. § 4. The total output of coal and its distribution for different uses is given in Table VIII. It is to be noted that the figures for the district of the Ruhr as given in the table, have not been furnished directly by German statistics, which give figures for the Ruhr and district of Schafberg-Piesberg together 1. TABLE VIII. — TOTAL PRODUCTION (Metric District Year R u h r . . (1925 i 1926 Upper \ 1925 Silesia 11926 Saxony . 11925 \ 1926 1 OF COAL, 1925 AND 1926 Tons—000's Omitted) Total tonnage Coal conof saleable sumed by the coal raised mines 104,124 112,131 14,273 17,462 3,869 4,147 6,935 6,279 513 569 488 479 Coal distributed to employees 1,395 1,233 198 213 86 79 Commercially disposable coal 95,794 104,619 13,562 16,680 3,295 3,589 In order to arrive at the figures given in the table, the International Labour Office has calculated the percentage of coal consumed by the mine plus coal distributed to workers to the total output of coal in the Ruhr, including Schafberg-Piesberg. These percentages have been applied to the total saleable coal raised in the Ruhr alone, which is known. — 208 — The average output of coal is calculated in the German statistics as (i) per manshift, and (ii) per full-time worker per year 1 ; the average output is not given for the Free State of Saxony. TABLE IX. — AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL, BY CATEGORY OF WORKERS, IN 1925 AND 1926 (Metric Tons) Aierage output per manshift District Year (1925 11926 Í1925 Upper Silesia Í1926 Ruhr Average output per full-time worker per ¡fiar Hewer Underground Underground and surlaca workers Homer 2.10 2.38 7.16 7.66 1.18 1.38 1.68 1.67 0.95 1.11 1.15 1.27 650 769 2,224 2,389 Underground 366 438 501 538 Underground and surftet workers 296 356 367 408 As the foregoing table shows, the average output, both daily and annual, has been considerably increased during the year 1926. The average wage cost per ton of saleable coal and per ton of commercially disposable coal (Table X) has been calculated from the data given in Tables I and VIII. These averages have been based on the total of money earnings {Barverdienst), including wages paid in ancillary establishments ; since the ancillary establishments do not produce coal, an error is introduced in the calculation. The figures are shown in Table X. TABLE X. — AVERAGE WAGES COST PER TON OF COAL, 1 9 2 5 AND 1926 District Ruhr Upper Silesia. . . Saxony . . Average cost in R.M. Per ton of commercially disposable coal Year Per ton of saleable coal i 1925 11926 J1925 \1926 11925 11926 7.84 7.24 4.59 4.45 10.86 11.15 8.52 7.76 4.83 4.66' 12.75 12.88 Average cost in gold francs Per ton of Per ton of commercially saleable disposable coal coal 9.67. 8.90 5.66 5.47 13.39 13.70 10.51 9.53 5.96 5.73 15.72 15.82 It appears from the above table that the wage cost of coal has decreased to some extent during the year 1926 in the districts of the Ruhr and Upper Silesia, whereas it has slightly increased in the Free State of Saxony during the same year. 1 It is to be observed that juveniles employed underground have been included in the total number of workers employed underground, which has been used as divisor in the calculation. On the other hand, the number of workers employed in ancillary establishments has been excluded from the number of workers used in the calculation. — 209 — Great Britain § 1. The presentation of the British statistics of employment and production in the coal industry is influenced by the exceptional conditions prevailing in the years 1925 and 1926. As a matter of fact, both of these years are sharply divided into two distinct periods. Owing to the gradual depression in the coal industry which continued from the preceding year during the first part of 1925, the Government decided to give a subvention to the coal industry from August 1925 •onwards for nine months. The broad principle governing the payment of the subvention, was that while the percentage of basic rates actually paid to the workmen in each district should continue a t not less than the minimum figure provided under the agreement of 1924, the percentage which the colliery owners themselves should pay should be the figures which resulted from the application of their own proposals of July 1925 ; where wages paid Jjy the owners were below the minimum level, the difference between t h e two was met by the subvention. The effect of the subvention was tantamount to a general and progressive reduction of wages costs •during the latter part of the year. The subvention continued to be paid during the first four months of 1926, which constituted a period of recovery, but during the last eight months of the year the production at the coal-mines was almost at a standstill in consequence of the longest coal stoppage on record, or was being slowly restored as the movement of the men back to the pits spread. This •stoppage came to an end in the course of December 1926, since when the coal-mining industry has been working under more normal conditions. Owing to these circumstances, no statistics are given for the last •eight months of 1926. For other periods figures are available for «ach quarter until the fourth quarter (inclusive) of 1927. They •cover about 96 to 99 per cent, of all the coal-mines of Great Britain. TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES BILL, DISTINGUISHING SUBVENTION, IN BRITISH COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 5 , 1 9 2 6 , AND THREE QUARTERS OF 1 9 2 7 (Pounds Sterling) Year, quarter, and month 1925: 1st quarter. 2nd 3rd „ 4th , 1926 : 1st quarter. April month 1927: 1st quarter. 2nd „ 3rd „ 4th „ Wages, excluding subvention Amount of subvention Wages, including subvention £ 36,923,043 32,533,634 28,622,700 27,020,362 £ — — 3,360,744 8,667,117 £ 36,923,043 32,533,634 31,983,444 35,687,479 . . . . . . 28,765,639 9,340,648 8,464,972 2,515,016 37,230,611 11,855,664 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32,471,656 29,437,500 28,028,105 27,867,260 — — — — 32,471,656 29,437,500 28,028,105 27,867,260 . . . . . . . 14 — 210 — § 2. The total wages bill (Table I, previous page) as given in the British statistics includes money wages only which correspond to about 94 per cent, of workers' " t o t a l actual earnings", excluding employers' contributions, as defined in P a r t Two of the present report. It is t o be noted that allowances to low-paid day-wage workers under clauses 6 and 7 of the agreement dated 18 June 1924, are included in the wages ; moreover, the costs of raising ancillary minerals at coal-mines are included. The amount of subvention is shown separately in Table I. All averages which are given in the following tables are based on the amount of wages including the subvention. The number of manshifts given in the British statistics includes* apart from the number of manshifts worked on ordinary hours, also week-end and overtime manshifts which are calculated by adding up in each district the number of hours worked during week-ends and overtime, and dividing the same by the number of hours included in the normal manshift. The number of manshifts lost refers to manshifts which "could have been worked" during days when mines were open, but which were not actually so worked, including absences due to sickness or accidents. The average number of workers is calculated on the basis of numbers registered at each weekly pay-day in colliery books (Table II). TABLE II. — NUMBER OF MANSHIFTS WORKED AND LOST, AND NUMBER OF WORKPEOPLE EMPLOYED AT COAL-MINES DURING 1925,. 1926, AND 1927 Number of manshifts worked (OOO's omitted) Year, quarter, and month By underground workers Number of Number manshifts of lost (OOO's workpeople omitted) employed Hewers Others All By surface workers 1925: 1st quarter 2nd 3rd 4th 27,533 C 24,280 24,122 27,166 27,553 24,296 24,191 26,935 55,086 48,576 48,313 64,101 14,374 13,014 13,167 14,343 69,460 61,590 61,480 68,444 6,164 4,680 5,219 5,089 1,074,079 1,032,216 1,013,767 1,041,997 1926 : 1st quarter April month 28,565 9 029 28,172 8,895 56,737 17,924 14,864 4,775 71,601 22t63c 5,867 J.,OUO 1,074,395 1,071,184 1927: 1st quarter 2nd 3rd 4th 24,479 22,748 22,595 22,948 23,878 22,445 22,273 22,570 48,357 45,193 44,868 45,518 12,960 12,322 12,368 12,446 61,307 57,515 57,236 67,964 4,287 3,490 3,762 3,660 969,943 981,393 946,487 945,480 Total The total number of possible coal-winding days in 1925 was 299.59, and the number of days on which pits wound coal was 252.78. Corresponding figures are not given for 1926 and are not yet available for 1927. — 211 — § 3. The average wages (including subvention) are given for t h e whole of mine-workers only. They are expressed here also in terms of gold francs 1 . Two different averages are given, namely, average wages per manshift and average wages per quarter per worker 2. TABLE III. — AVERAGE WAGES PER MANSHIFT AND PER QUARTER OF COAL-MINING WORKERS DURING 1 9 2 5 , 1 9 2 6 , AND 1 9 2 7 Average Wages in £ s. d. Year, quarter, and month Per manshift Per quarter per worker £ s. d. Average wages in gold francs Per quarter Per manshift per worker Fr. Fr. S. d. 10 10 10 10 1\ 6f4f 5i 34 7 31 10 31 11 34 5 6 4 0 0 13.29 13.21 13.01 13.06 . . . . . . . . 10 4f 10 5 | 34 13 1 13.08 13.14 872 . . . . 10 10 9 9 33 9 7 29 19 11 29 12 3 29 9 6 13.32 12.86 12.31 12.09 842 754 745 741 1925 : 1st quarter 2nd „ 3rd „ 4th „ . . . . 1926: 1st quarter April month 1927: 1st quarter 2nd „ 3rd „ 4th „ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1\ 2f 91 7f ' 860 789 789 857 As the currency was practically stable throughout the period covered, the average wages expressed in sterling and in gold francs show similar tendencies. It will be seen that the average wages per manshift varied but little from the beginning of 1925 to the first quarter of 1927, but decreased during the last three quarters of 1927. The average wage per manshift during the fourth quarter of 1927 was about 9 per cent, below the level prevailing during t h e first quarter of 1925. The average quarterly wages increased, as the above table shows, during the subvention period (from the third quarter, 1925, to t h e first quarter, 1926), but diminished gradually after the dispute period : the fall from the first quarter, 1926, which shows t h e maximum for the period considered, to the fourth quarter, 1927, was 15 per cent. 1 The rates of exchange used for the conversion of sterling to gold francs are as follows : 1925 £1 = 25.02 gold francs 2 1926 1927 £1 = 25.17 £1 = 25.15 The quarterly averages have been calculated by the International Labour Office. — 212 — This decrease has been, perhaps, counterbalanced to some extent by an upward tendency of the internal purchasing power of wages. At any rate the official cost-of-living index number for 630 towns and localities shows a steady, though slight, decrease. If the price level prevailing in July 1925 is taken as equal to 100, that for July, 1927, "was 92. § 4. The total and average output of coal, expressed in metric tons, may be seen from Table IV. TABLE IV. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL IN BRITISH MINES DURING 1925, 1926 AND 1927 (Metric Tons) Average output oí saleable coal Total output (000's omitted) Year, quarter, and month 1925: 1st quarter . 2nd 3rd 4th 1926 : 1st quarter April month . 1927: 1st quarter . 2nd 3rd 4th Tonnage conof saleable Mine sumption coal raised Miners' coal Tonnage Per disposable Per man- quarter comshift and mercially worker 63,458 65,862 65,856 63,665 3,965 3,612 3,618 3,947 1,687 1,361 1,255 1,608 67,806 50,889 50,983 58,110 0.914 0.907 0.909 0.930 59.1 54.1 55.1 61.1 67,128 21,319 4,041 1,309 1,695 565 61,392 19,445 0.938 0.939 62.5 64,343 69,823 59.522 61,316 3,666 3,481 3,436 3,608 1,523 1,302 1,189 1,442 59,164 55,040 54.897 66,266 1,050 1,040 1.040 1,058 66.3 61.0 62.9 64.9 It may be added that the tonnage of coal raised and weighed at the pit head during the dispute period (May to December 1926) was 34,454,000 metric tons (based on 96 per cent, of all coal-mines in the country). It will be seen t h a t the average daily output rose considerably in 1927. This is due to the increase in hours of work which came in force on the termination of the stoppage of 1926. Finally, the average wage cost (including subvention) of a ton of coal may be calculated on the basis of figures, given in Tables I and IV. Table V shows separately the wage cost of a ton of saleable coal, and of a ton of commercially disposable coal, both in £ s. d. and in gold francs. — 213 — TABLE V. — AVERAGE WAGE COST OF A METRIC TON OF COAL DURING 1925,1926, AND 1927 Wage cost in gold francs •Wage cost in s. d. Year, quarter, and month 1925: 1st quarter . . 2nd „ . . 3rd 4th „ . . 1926: 1st q u a r t e r . . April month . 1927: 1st q u a r t e r . . 2nd 3rd „ . . 4th „ . . Per metric ton Per metric ton Per metric ton Per metric ton of of of of saleable coal commercially saleable coal commercially disposable coal disposable coal S. d. S. d. . 11 11 11 11 8 8 5 3 12 12 12 12 9 9 7 3 Fr. 14.60 14.60 14.30 14.10 Fr. 15.95 15.95 15.75 15.35 . . 11 11 1 1 12 12 2 2 13.95 13.95 15.30 15.30 . 10 9 9 9 1 10 5 1 11 10 10 9 0 8 3 11 12.70 12.35 11.85 11.42 13.80 13.40 12.90 12.46 . . . . This table shows clearly that the wage cost of a ton of coal has constantly diminished. The diminution from the first quarter of 1925 to the fourth quarter of 1927 is more than 20 per cent. Netherlands § 1. The wage and output statistics for coal-mines in the Netherlands, published by the Chief Engineer of Mines, cover the years 1925 and 1926. In addition to this information, monthly statistics of average wages were published during 1927 by the Central Statistical Office. § 2. The total wages bill shown in Table I includes wages in cash, workers' contributions to social insurance, as well as family and social allowances, but excludes expenditure incurred by the workers in connection with their work and payments made for overtime. The figures given may therefore be considered as "money earnings" corresponding to 97 per cent, of the "aggregate actual earnings" as defined in the wages report of 1925. TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES PAID IN THE COAL-MINES OF THE NETHERLANDS IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (In Thousands of Gulden) Category of workers Underground Surface Total 1925 32,879 9,384 42,263 1926 34,656 9,849 44,505 — 214 — Dutch statistics show the total number of manshifts worked underground and above ground, as well as the total number of workers employed exclusively in the coal-mines. The figures for 1925 and 1926 are as shown in Table II. TABLE I I . — TOTAL NUMBER OF MANSHIFTS WORKED AND AVERAGE NUMBER OF WORKERS EMPLOYED IN THE COAL-MINES IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 Number of manshifts Category o! workers 1925 | 1926 6,119,570 6,370,762 2,381,392 2,505,368 8,500,962 8,876,130 Total Average number of workers 1925 1926 22,176 8,230 30,406 23,203 8,463 31,666 § 3. The daily and annual average earnings of underground and surface workers are shown in Table III in gulden and gold francs 1 TABLE III. MINERS AVERAGE DAILY AND ANNUAL EARNINGS IN 1925 AND 1926 Earnings in gulden Earnings in gold francs Category of -workers 1925 | 1926 1925 [ 1926 (i) Daily Earnings Underground and surface 5.37 3.94 5.44 3.93 11.17 8.20 11.30 8.16 4.97 5.01 10.34 10.41 (ii) Yearly Earnings per Worker Underground Surface . . . . . . . 1,483 1,140 1,494 1,164 3,086 2,372 3,103 2,418 Underground a n d surface 1,389 1,405 2,890 2,918 1 The rates used for the conversion of the gulden into gold francs are as follows : 1925 1926 1927 January April July October Year 209.35 208.30 207.27 207.06 207.89 207.27 207.89 208.09 207.68 208.51 207.27 208.14 208.09 207.72 — — 215 — The information given in the preceding table may be completed by relative figures concerning the average earnings of hewers, underground workers, surface workers, and other classes of workers for different periods (January, April, July, October) of the years 1925, 1926 and 1927 (Table IV). TABLE IV. — AVERAGE DAILY EARNINGS OF THE DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF WORKERS EMPLOYED IN COAL-MINES FROM 1925 T01927 Aierage earnings in gold francs Average earnings in gulden Underground Year and month Surface Hewers All classes Ml workers (underground and surface) Hewers Ml workers Surface til workers (underground and surface) Underground 1925 : January April. . July . . October . . . . 6.40 6.10 6.09 6.13 6.60 5.28 6.29 5.36 4.04 3.89 3.90 3.90 5.09 4.89 4.91 4.95 13.40 12.63 12.66 12.78 11.54 10.93 11.00 11.18 8.46 8.05 8.11 8.13 10.66 10.13 10.21 10.32 1926 : January April. . July. . October . . . . 6.11 6.10 6.13 6.28 5.35 6.38 5.40 5.50 3.93 3.92 3.91 3.91 4.95 4.96 4.98 5.06 12.73 12.68 12.76 13.02 11.14 11.18 11.24 11.40 8.19 8.15 8.14 8.10 10.31 10.31 10.36 10.49 1927 : January April. . July . . October . . . . 6.46 6.21 6.24 6.21 5.68 5.45 5.49 5.52 4.13 3.95 3.96 4.08 5.25 5.03 6.06 5.11 13.39 12.87 12.96 12.93 11.77 11.30 11.40 11.49 8.56 8.19 8.22 8.49 10.88 10.43 10.61 10.64 Miners' wages in the Netherlands show a general tendency to remain stable ; the small fluctuations observed are of a seasonal character. The difference between wages in April and July of 1925, which are the lowest during the period considered, and those paid in January 1927, which represent the maximum, is not quite 7 per cent. In October 1927, the general level of salaries was 4 per cent. higher than in October 1925. The variations of wages expressed in gold francs correspond, as a rule, to those expressed in gulden in spite of a slight fluctuation of the gold value of the gulden during the period in question. The purchasing power of the gulden on the home market increased in a regular, if somewhat negligible, fashion during the years 1926 and 1927. The official cost-of-living index numbers for the town of Amsterdam, 1925 figures being taken as a basis, were as follows : June 1925 100 „ 1926 96 „ 1927 93 From the above it may be concluded that the real wages of Dutch miners increased slightly during 1926 and 1927 in comparison with real wages in 1925. — 216 — § 4. The total output of coal and the distribution of the tonnage produced is shown in Table V. The tonnage commercially disposable has been estimated by deducting from the total tonnage produced the quantity of coal consumed in the mines or distributed to the personnel. TABLE V. — TOTAL OUTPUT OF COAL IN 1925 AND 1926 (Metric Tons—000's Omitted) Distribution of tonnage Amount consumed in the mines (including deliveries t o ancillary undertakings) . . Distributed t o employees Tonnage commercially disposable . . . . T o t a l saleable coal raised. . . 1925 1926 1,439 58 5,352 6,849 1,857 61 6,690 8,608 The average output of saleable coal per manshift on the one hand, and per annum and per worker on the other, was as follows : TABLE VI. — AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL PER MANSHIFT AND PER ANNUM IN 1925 AND 1926 (In Metric Tons) Average output per manshift Categories of workers Underground Underground and surface Average annual output per worker 1925 1926 1925 1926 1.12 1.35 309 371 0.81 0.97 225 272 The cost of wages per ton is shown as follows : TABLE VII. — COST OF WAGES PER TON OF COAL IN 1 9 2 5 AND 192ft Ton of Commercially disposable coal Cost of wages in gulden Cost of wages in gold francs 1925 1926 1925 1926 6.17 7.90 5.17 6.65 12.84 16.44 10.74 13.81 The cost of wages per ton in the Netherlands decreased in 1926 by about 16 per cent, in comparison with the previous year. This decrease is explained by the fact that the production of coal increased more than the amount of wages paid, while average wages remained practically stable. — 217 — Poland § 1. The movement of wages earned by workers employed in Polish coal-mines is shown in a special enquiry carried out b y t h e Directorate of Mines and Metallurgy, a department attached to the Ministry of Industry and Commerce 1. This enquiry covers the first and fourth quarters of 1925 and 1926, and includes a certain amount of additional information for the month of March 1927. Coal output statistics published by the same department extend to the third quarter of 1927. § 2. Figures concerning the aggregate actual earnings, the total number of manshifts worked and lost, and the average number of workers are not included in the report. § 3. The average daily earnings established by Polish statistics represent the actual earnings of the miners and include the total wages received for work performed, allowances in cash and in kind, as well as holiday allowances. Table I shows the average earnings in zloty and their value in gold francs 2. TABLE I. — AVERAGE DAILY EARNINGS IN POLISH COAL-MINES IN 1925 AND 1926 Arerage earnings in zloty District Year and period Underground III workers (underground and surface) Average earnings in gold francs Alf workers (underground and All workers surface) Underpaid Miners All workers /1925:1st quarter Upper-Silesia ) 4th „ /l926:1st quarter 1 4th „ 7.96 8.13 8.23 10.45 5.80 6.17 6.30 7.86 5.47 5.81 5.94 7.46 7.91 5.87 5.50 6.06 6.77 4.45 4.21 4.55 5.44 4.19 3.97 4.33 11925:1st quarter Dombrowa.. ) 4th „ /1926:1st quarter \ 4th „ 7.41 7.85 8.61 10.31 5.30 5.52 5.97 7.14 4.78 4.93 5.28 6.36 7.37 6.67 5.75 5.98 5.27 3.99 3.99 4.14 4.75 4.66 3.63 3.68 11925:1st quarter 7.70 8.00 8.18 10.23 5.62 5.97 6.15 7.59 5.21 5.51 5.68 7.06 7.65 5.78 6.47 5.93 5.59 4.31 4.11 4.40 5.18 3.98 3.80 4.09 1 4til Wholecountry \ " /1926:1st quarter \ 4th „ 1 Miners OFFICE CENTRAL DE STATISTIQUE DE LA RÉPUBLIQUE POLONAISE : Statistique du Travail, No. 2, 1927. JEAN DERENGOWSKI : " Les salaires en Pologne à la période de l'an 1924 à mars 1927 ". 2 The rates used for the conversion of the zloty into gold francs were as follows : 1st quarter 1st half June-July 4th quarter 31 March 1925 1926 99.40 99.40 66.84 72.20 1927 50.10 59.00 59.07 — 218 — In order to give clear expression to the changes taking place, the absolute figures given above for the whole of Poland have been converted into relative figures shown in Table II. TABLE II. — RELATIVE FIGURES OF DAILY AVERAGE EARNINGS IN POLISH COAL-MINES IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (Earnings of First Quarter 1925 = 100) Earnings oxprosod in ilotj Period 1925 : 1 s t quarter . . 4th „ 1926 : 1 s t quarter . . 4th „ . . Underground Earnings expressed in gold francs Underground Miners til workers Ml workers (underground and surface) Minors All workers Ml workers (underground and surface) 100 103.9 106.2 132.9 100 106.2 109.4 135.1 100 105.8 109.0 135.5 100 75.6 81.5 77.5 100 77.1 73.5 78.7 100 76.8 73.4 79.0 It may be seen from the above figures that although nominal earnings increased by more than one-third between the beginning of 1925 and the end of 1926, their gold value decreased during the same period by nearly one-quarter of what it was a t the beginning of 1925. The changes in the various mining districts correspond almost exactly t o that shown by the national figures. Table I I I gives a summary of the fluctuation of wage rates in the basins of Upper Silesia and Dombrowa between 1925 and 1927. These rates represent the minimum wages established by collective agreements or regulated by the trade unions, on the basis of an eighthour day. They do not include any kind of allowance or supplementary payment. — 219 — TABLE III. — WAGE RATES OF THE VARIOUS CATEGORIES OF WORKERS IN UPPER SILESIA AND DOMBROWA, FROM THE FIRST HALF OF 1925 TO 31 MARCH 1927 District and category of workers 1st half of 1925 On 30 June 1926 On 31 March 1927 (i) Wage Rates in Zloty Upper Silesia Hewers working tranversally (contract rates). . Hewers in the galleries (contract rates). . . . Haulage men, wagon men Juvenile underground Surface workers . . . . Dombrowa Hewers (contract rates). . Assistant underground workers (over 24 years of age) Juvenile underground Assistant surface workers (over 24 years of age) . 6.52 7.91 9.22 5.86 1.70 — 4.06 7.11 2 . 4 3 — 4.92 8.29 2 . 8 3 — 5.73 1.12 1.12 — 3.68 1.43 1.76 — 4.64 1.66 2.08 — 5.44 5.20 6.24 7.28 3.00 — 3.20 3.60 — 3.84 4 . 2 0 — 4.48 1.80 — 2.00 2.16 — 2.40 2.52 — 2.80 2.60 — 3.00 3.12 — 3.60 3.64 — 4 . 2 0 (ii) W age Rates in Gold Francs Upper Silesia Hewers working transversally (contract rates) . Hewers in the galleries (contractrates). . . . Haulage men, wagon men Juvenile underground Dombrowa Hewers (contract rates) . Assistant underground workers (over 24 years of age) Juvenile underground Assistant surface workers (over 24 years of age) . 6.48 3.96 5.45 5.82 1.69 — 4.04 3.56 1.22 — 2.46 4.90 1.67 — 3.38 1.11 1.11 — 3.66 0.72 0.88 — 2.32 0.98 1.23 — 3.21 5.17 3.13 4.30 2 . 9 8 — 3.18 1.80 — 1.92 2.48 — 2 . 6 5 1.79 — 1.99 1.08 — 1.20 1.49 — 1.65 2.58 — 2.98 1.56 — 1.80 2.15 — 2.48 — 220 — Expressed in relative figures the fluctuations in wage rates were as follows : TABLE IV. — R E L A T I V E F I G U R E S OF W A G E RATES IN UPPER SILESIA A N D D O M B R O W A F R O M T H E F I R S T H A L F O F 1 9 2 5 TO 3 1 M A R C H (First District a n d category of workers Upper Silesia Hewers working transversally Hewers in the galleries Haulage men (average) Juvenile undergound workers . . . . Surface workers (average) Dombrowa Hewers Assistant underground workers (average) . Juvenile underground workers (average) . Assistant surface workers (average) Half of 1925 = 100) W a g e rates in gold francs (&) W a g e rates in zloty (a) 1st half 1925 1927 On On i 30 J u n e 31 March 1926 1927 1st half 1925 On 30 J u n e 1926 On 31 March 1927 100 100 100 121.3 121.3 127.8 141.4 141.5 148.6 100 100 100 61 61 64 84 84 100 100 127.7 133.3 148.2 156.7 100 100 65 67 91 100 120 140 100 60 83 100 120 140 100 60 83 100 120 140 100 60 83 100 120 140 100 60 83 (a) Figures given in the Polish enquiry. (6) Figures calculated on the basis of d a t a given in Table HI (ii). It is seen that the general movement of wage rates was similar to that of average earnings. Wage rates expressed in zloty continued to increase considerably until the first quarter of 1927. Their value in gold francs decreased in 1926, but rose again in 1927 without, however, reaching the level of 1925. As regards the fluctuations in wage rates of the different classes of workers, the same percentage increase was made in the wages of all workers in the Dombrowa Basin, while in Upper Silesia the rates for unskilled workers and surface workers were increased in a relatively greater proportion than those of miners properly so called. The Polish enquiry also furnishes information on the fluctuations in the cost of foodstuffs in two mining districts, viz. Kattowitz (Upper Silesia) and Sosnowiec (Dombrowa). Taking the prices of the first quarter of 1925 as a basis, the index numbers were as follows : Kattowitz Sosnowiec 1st quarter 1925 J u n e 1926 March 1927 100 100 124.4 124.4 145.1 141.2 These figures show that, generally speaking, nominal wages increased in proportion with the rise in the cost of foodstuffs. In so far as the price of foodstuffs reflect the cost of living in general, — 221 — it may be said that the purchasing power of wages earned by Polish miners remained unchanged during the period between the first quarter of 1925 and the first quarter of 1927. The regular wage statistics published by the Directorate of Mines show that wage rates continued to increase between March and December 1927. On the other hand the cost of living showed a similar tendency to increase during the same period. Therefore it may be concluded that the real wages earned by miners did not change to any considerable extent during the year 1927. § 4. — Polish statistics contain information on the number of workers occupied in the mines and in the production of coal classified according to the mining regions. The number of workers registered in the mines at the end of the years 1925 and 1926, and at the end of the first three quarters of 1927 is shown in Table V. TABLE V. — NUMBER OF WORKERS OCCUPIED IN COAL-MINES FROM 1925 TO 1927 Number of workers employed at the end of 1927 Mining region 1925 Kielce (Dombrowa). . . Whole country . . 74,960 26,911 7,860 109,731 1926 87,823 30,677 9,810 128,210 March June September 81,624 28,446 7,915 117,984 75,167 26,842 7,964 109,973 75,653 26,915 8,078 110,646 («) (a) Provisional figures. The total output of coal during the years 1925 and 1926 and the first three quarters of 1927 was as follows : TABLE VI. — TOTAL COAL OUTPUT FROM 1 9 2 5 TO 1 9 2 7 (In Thousands of Metric Tons) 1927 Mining region 1925 1926 1st qr. Kielce (Dombrowa). . . 21,660 5.729 1,692 26,165 7,226 2,366 — Whole country . . 29,081 35,747 10,109 2nd qr. 3rd qr. — — 8,103 9,520 — 222 — From the above figures it is possible to calculate the average output per worker per annum or per quarter. TABLE VII. — A V E R A G E O U T P U T OF COAL PER W O R K E R PER A N N U M IN 1925 AND 1926, AND PER QUARTER IN 1927 (Metric Tons) 1927 Mining region 1925 289 213 215 298 236 240 — Kielce (Dombrowa). . . Cracow Whole country . . 265 279 86 1926 1st qr. 2nd qr. 3rd qr. — — 74 86 It has not been possible to estimate the labour cost per ton of coal. Saar Territory § 1. In reply to the enquiry of the International Labour Office, the Directorate of State Mines of the Territory of the Saar supplied comparable information for the years 1925 and 1926. This information may be completed by quarterly figures published by the Christian Miners' Trade Union for the year 1927. § 2. The total amount of "aggregate actual earnings" of the •workers and the elements included in them are shown in Table I. TABLE I. — COMPOSITION OF THE AGGREGATE ACTUAL EARNINGS OF MINERS IN THE SAAR TERRITORY IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 {In Thousands of French Francs) Component parts of actual earnings N e t money wages Workers' contributions to social insurance. Allowances in money Allowances in kind : P a y m e n t s for holidays 1925 1926 427,754 40,148 54^733 570,592 57,020 55,248 22,210 490 10,065 32,054 697 13,223 555,400 728,834 The distribution of the aggregate actual earnings between the different classes of workers (hewers, other underground workers, surface workers) is shown in Table II. — 223 — TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF AGGREGATE ACTUAL EARNINGS A C C O R D I N G TO V A R I O U S C L A S S E S O F W O R K E R S I N 1 9 2 5 A N D 1 9 2 6 (In Thousands of French Francs) Category of workers 1925 1926 Underground workers Surface workers T o t a l underground and surface workers. . 222,267 194,351 416,618 138,782 555,400 285,208 262,035 547,243 181,591 728,834 Table III summarises the statistical information relating to the Saar Territory as regards the total number of manshifts worked and the average number of workers. The former number covers working days of unspecified duration ; the second is calculated on the basis of the number of workers registered in the mines on p a y days. T A B L E I I I . — TOTAL N U M B E R O F M A N S H I F T S W O R K E D A N D A V E R A G E N U M B E R O F M I N E R S A C C O R D I N G TO CLASSES O F W O R K E R S , I N 1 9 2 5 AND 1926 Total number of manshifts A v e r a g e number of workers Category of worker Other 1925 1926 1925 6,689,000 6,821,000 25,450 25,282 7,279,000 13,368,000 5,436,000 7,607,000 14,428,000 6,602,000 27,130 52,580 17,890 26,880 52,162 17,738 19,303,000 20,030,000 70,470 69,900 1926 underground Underground workers. Surface workers . . . Total underground and surface workers. . . The total number of manshifts lost in 1925 was 1,497,000, in 1926 1,029,000. The time lost was due mainly to involuntary absence on the part of the miners during days when coal was wound. § 3. The average earnings per manshift and per annum for t h e various classes of workers have been calculated on the basis of t h e information given in the above tables. These averages are expressed in French francs and have been converted into gold francs x. 1 The rates used for the conversion of French francs into gold francs were as follows : 1st quarter 2nd quarter 3rd quarter 4th quarter Annual average 1925 1926 1927 — — — 20.85 24.71 19.04 16.32 14.02 17.55 16.83 20.37 20.30 20.30 20.37 — — 224 — TABLE IV. — AVERAGE DAILY EARNINGS ACCORDING TO CATEGORIES OF WORKERS IN 1925 AND 1926 Category oí workers Hewers Other underground workers . Underground workers . . . . Average earnings in French francs Average earnings in gold francs 1925 1926 1925 1926 33.73 26.70 30.04 25.53 41.81 34.45 37.93 32.42 8.33 6.60 7.42 6.31 7.03 5.80 6.38 5.46 28.77 36.39 7.11 6.12 T o t a l underground a n d surface TABLE V. — AVERAGE ANNUAL EARNINGS ACCORDING TO CATEGORY OF WORKERS IN 1925 AND 1926 Category of workers Average earnings in French francs 1925 Other u n d e r g r o u n d workers . Underground workers . . . . | Average earnings in gold francs 1926 1925 1926 8,733 7,164 7,924 7,758 11,281 9,748 10,491 10,237 2,158 1,770 1,958 1,917 1,899 1,641 1,766 1,723 7,881 10,427 1,947 1,755 T o t a l underground a n d surface Generally speaking, average earnings in 1926 were higher than those of the preceding year. For t h e workers taken as a whole, the increase in daily earnings was 26 per cent., that of annual earnings lieing 32 per cent. Expressed in gold currency these earnings •decreased respectively 14 and 10 per cent. In order t o study the changes in wages in 1927 it is necessary to have recourse to the statistics published by the above-mentioned trade union 1. These statistics are, however, established on a •different basis from those summarised above, and cover money wages including t h e workers' contributions to social insurance, and the various allowances in money (Table VI). 1 GEWERKVEREIN CHRISTL. BERGARBEITER DEUTSCHLANDS FÜR DAS SAARGEBIET : Der Saar-Bergknappe, 1927, Nos. 14 and 38, and 1928, Ko. 15. — 225 — TABLE VI. — AVERAGE MONEY WAGES PER MANSHIFT IN 1925, 1926 AND 1927 Wages in French francs AU Underground underground All and Hewers workers surface workers Period 1925: 4th quarter 1926: 1st quarter 2nd „ 3rd „ 4th „ 1927: 1st quarter 2nd , 3rd 4th , Wages in gold francs AU underground All and Hewers workers surface workers Underground . . . . 33.33 29.68 28.39 6.95 6.19 5.92 . . . . . . . . 34.82 36.76 41.55 45.22 30.97 32.96 37.23 40.57 29.60 31.68 35.74 39.06 6.63 6.00 5.83 7.94 5.90 5.38 5.22 7.12 6.64 5.17 6.01 6.86 . . . . . 45.38 42.40 42.47 44.10 40.72 38.36 38.53 40.28 39.21 37.02 36.97 38.74 9.24 8.61 8.62 8.98 8.29 7.79 7.82 8.21 7.99 7.52 7.50 7.89 The fluctuations in daily wages stand out more clearly in the figures given in the following table : TABLE VII. RELATIVE FIGURES OF AVERAGE PER MANSHIFT FROM 1 9 2 5 TO 1 9 2 7 MONEY WAGES (Base: Average Wages during Fourth Quarter, 1925 = 100) Period Wages in French francs All Underground underground All and Hewers workers surface workers Wages in gold francs All Underground underground All and Hewers workers surface workers 1926: 1926: 1st quarter 2nd 3rd 4th „ 100 100 100 100 100 100 104.5 110.3 124.7 135.7 104.3 104.3 111.6 125.9 137.6 95.4 86.3 83.9 114.2 95.3 86.9 84.3 115.0 95.3 87.3 84.6 115.9 138.1 130.4 130.2 Ï36.5 132.9 123.9 124.0 129.2 133.9 125.8 126.3 132.6 135.0 127.0 126.7 133.3 111.1 125.4 136.7 1927: 2nd „ 4th „ 136.2 127.2 127.4 132.3 137.2 129.2 129.8 135.7 A study of the fluctuations of wages expressed in French francs, .as indicated in the previous tables, shows a progressive and regular increase during the year 1926, This increase continued during the 15 — 226 — first quarter of 1927, but was then followed by a fall during t h e two following quarters of the same year. At the end of 1927 wages were slightly lower than during the last quarter of t h e previous year. Expressed in gold francs, wages at first underwent an inverse movement, t h a t is to say, they fell continually until the end of the third quarter of 1926, rising again during the fourth quarter of the same year and during the first quarter of 1927. During t h e past year they have undergone the same variations as wages in French francs, as the rate of exchange of the latter has remained stable. On comparing the tendencies shown by the Saar statisticswith those already noted in France, it is seen that wages in French. francs increased in the Saar to the same extent as in France, whereas their gold value was less affected in the Saar by the variations of the exchanges rates, although these were the same in both cases.. In order to give an idea of the purchasing power of wages on thehome market, we quote the following cost-of-living index numbers* calculated by the Statistical Department of the Saar Government. Taking the prices in December 1925 as a basis, the index numbers. during 1926 and 1927 were as follows : December 1925 . . December 1926 . . . March 1927 . . . . 100 137 129 June 1927 . . . . September 1927. . . December 1927 . . 129 124 124 It is thus seen that real wages (the purchasing power of wages on the home market) remained at practically the same level as in 1925,. with the exception, however, of the first, third, and fourth quartersof 1927, when they were slightly above that level. § 4. The total output of coal in 1925 and 1926 was as follows : Saleable coal in 1925 12,597,000 Saleable coal in 1926 13,319,000 Commercially disposable coal in 1925 . . . 11,321,000 Commercially disposable coal in 1926 . . . 11,943,000 The average output of saleable coal raised per manshift and per annum was as follows : TABLE VIII. — AVERAGE OUTPUT OF SALEABLE GOAL ACCORDING- TO CLASSES OF WORKERS IN 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (Metric Category of workers underground workers . . . Underground and surface Tons) Average output per manshift Average annual output per worker 1925 1926 1925 1926 1.91 0.91 1.95 495 240 527 255 179 191 0.65 0.92 0.67 It is seen t h a t the average output per manshift remained practically stable, while the average annual output increased considerably in 1926. — 227 — The cost of wages per ton of saleable coal raised and of commercially disposable coal, expressed in French francs and gold francs, is shown in the following table : TABLE IX. — WAGE COST PER Ton of TON OF GOAL IN 1 9 2 5 AND W a g e cost in French francs 1925 Commercially disposable coal. 44.09 49.06 ! 1926 W a g e cost in gold francs 1926 1925 1926 54.72 61.03 10.89 12.12 9.21 10.17 These figures demonstrate that the gold value of wage costs per ton of coal decreased to a considerable extent during the year 1926. APPENDIX V HOURS OF LABOUR AND WAGES IN T H E COAL INDUSTRY OF NON-EUROPEAN COUNTRIES PRELIMINARY N O T E The scope of the comparative study of hours of labour and wages in the coal-mining industry presented in P a r t Two, has been confined to European countries only. The reason for this limitation lies in the fact that the material received from other countries is comparable neither with the data supplied for Europe, nor among these nonEuropean countries. Since, however, the coal industry outside Europe is, from an international point of view, as important as the European coal trade, it is necessary to make an attempt to complete the enquiry by statistics relating to those countries overseas for which any useful information is available. At the outset, it will be convenient to indicate which are the principal coal-producing countries outside Europe. This will bé seen from the following table, where the total output of coal is taken as the criterion of importance 1 . PRODUCTION OF COAL IN THE PRINCIPAL NON-EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, 1909-1913 AND 1925 (Metric Tons—000's Omitted) Absolute figures Countries Union of South Africa Total outside Europe World 1 Percentage to total world production 1925 Average 1909-1913 1925 . . . . 6,692 10,698 11,621 12,869 464,587 15,126 17,885 6,613 11,793 13,847 8,627 20,500 530,776 21,102 31,495 10,975 1.0 1.2 0.7 1.7 44.7 1.8 2.6 0.9 . . . 546,091 551,543 649,115 538,688 54.6 45.4 1,097,634 1,187,803 100.0 Figures are taken from : LEAGUE OF NATIONS, INTERNATIONAL : Documentation, Memorandum on Coal, Vol. I, Annex IV, p. 4 3 ; Geneva, 1927. ECONOMIC CONFERENCE — 229 — The above figures show that, in 1925, the United States alone produced almost as large a quantity of coal as the whole of Europe. Compared with America, all other non-European countries are of less importance from the point of view of production ; on the other hand, Japan, India, and China are as large coal producers as, for instance, Poland and Belgium. Information and statistics relating to hours of labour and wages have not been obtained for all of the above countries. Only the Union of South Africa, India, and Japan have forwarded to the International Labour Office certain data in reply to the questionnaires sent with a view to the present enquiry. Further, official statistics published for Canada and the United States have been secured and utilised for the enquiry. These five countries represented, in 1925, about 61 per cent, of the world production of coal, and 93 per cent, of the total production outside Europe. It is regretted that no statistics have been ascertained in respect of Australia and China. It follows from the above remarks that the chapters dealing with the hours and wages in non-European countries will have a rather heterogeneous character. The method of presentation cannot, of course, be the same as that adopted in the comparative study of European countries. As the scope of the statistics, the methods employed therein, and their completeness and accuracy are widely different, each country is dealt with in a separate note. It is to be observed that the information available for the five countries does not refer to the same period. Statistics for South Africa and India refer to the year 1925, those for Japan to the year 1924, those for Canada to the years 1925 and 1926 (in certain cases also 1927), and those for the United States to the years 1924 and 1926. Owing to the incomparability of the data, the average earnings are in each case expressed in terms of the national currency only. Per contra, with regard to the total and average production, statistical comparisons are not impossible, and therefore the quantities of coal are in each case converted to metric tons. Furthermore, an estimate of the average wage cost per ton of coal may be attempted in certain cases, and the average cost has then been expressed in terms of gold francs. The following discussion is divided into two parts, dealing with (A) hours of labour and (B) wages. A. HOURS OF LABOUR Canada The production of coal in Canada is restricted to the four following provinces : Alberta, British Columbia, New Brunswick, and Nova Scotia. As the coal-mining industry of New Brunswick is of very little importance 1 , it is not taken into account. 1 The number of workmen employed in the mines of these provinces in 1925 was : Nova Scotia, 12,100 ; Alberta, 3,370 ; British Columbia, 5,095 ; New Brunswick, 544 ; Total, 21,109. The miners of the first three provinces represent more than 96 per cent, of the total. (Figures taken from the Coal Statistics for Canada for the Calendar Year 1926, of the D O M I N I O N B U R E A U OF STATISTICS.) — 230 — The regulation of hours of work is within the competence of the provinces. Each of the three provinces under consideration possesses legislation limiting the hours of work in the mines. In the province of Alberta the Mines Act of 1922 \ whose scope extends to coal-mines, lays down in section 8, subsection (1), that " n o workman shall be below ground in a mine for the purpose of his work or for going to or from his work, or be allowed to be below ground for that purpose, for more than 8 hours during any consecutive 24 hours". Subsection (2) of the same section stipulates that there is no infraction of the provisions of subsection (1) if " t h e period between the times at which the first workman in a shift leaves the surface and the first workman in the shift returns to the surface, and the period between the times at which the last workman in the shift leaves the surface and the last workman in the shift returns to the surface, do not exceed the time fixed by this section", that is totsay, 8 hours. With a view to ensuring the execution of these provisions, " t h e owner, agent or manager of every mine shall fix for each shift of workmen in the mine the times at which the lowering of workmen to the mine is to commence and to be completed, and the times at which the raising of workmen from the mine is to commence and to be completed, and the same shall be fixed in such manner t h a t every workman shall have an opportunity of returning to the surface without contravention of the foregoing provisions of this section, and such owner, agent or manager shall post at the pithead a conspicuous notice of the times so fixed, and shall make all arrangements necessary for the observance of these times in lowering and raising the workmen." (Section 8, subsection 3.) "The interval between the times fixed for the commencement and for the completion of the lowering and raising of each shift of workmen to and from the mine shall not exceed the time reasonably required for the purpose, and the same shall be approved b y the Chief Inspector." (Section 8, subsection 4.) "The owner, agent or manager of every mine shall appoint a person or persons to direct at the pithead the lowering and raising of workmen to and from the mine, and shall cause a book to be kept in which shall be entered the times at which workmen are lowered into and raised from the mine, and the cases in which any workman is below ground for more than the time fixed by this Act, and the cause thereof." (Section 9.) Section 10 provides that the workmen in a mine may, at their own cost, institute a system of supervision of the times of lowering and raising. It follows from this legislation that the winding times are included in the legal duration of the shift. In British Columbia, section 19 of the Coal Mines Act of 1911, modified by the Act of 1918 2, stipulates that no person employed in or about a mine shall remain underground, for the purpose of employment, for a longer period than 8 hours in any one calendar day of 24 hours, counted from midnight to midnight. This period 1 2 Revised Statutes of Alberta, 1922, Chap. 190. Revised Statutes of British Columbia, 1924, Chap. 171. — 231 — îs comprised between the moment at which the workman enters the mine and the moment when he leaves it (from bank to bank). Where more than two shifts are worked in a mine the stay of some categories of workers (onsetters, cagers, pumpmen, certain •engineers, etc.) in the mine may be increased to 8% hours (from bank to bank). The descent and ascent are included in the legal duration of the shift. The Act of 23 April 1918 has added a subsection concerning surface workers to section 19 of the Act of 1911. The latter, with t h e exception of persons employed in the office, boarding house or bunkhouse, may not be employed at or about a mine for a longer period than 8 hours in any one calendar day of 24 hours, counted from midnight to midnight. In Nova Scotia the Act of 9 May 1924 *, modifying the Coal Mines Regulations Act, declares in section 39 (a), subsection (1), that " a workman shall not be employed at his working place below ground in a mine for the purpose of his work for more than 8 hours during any consecutive 24 hours". It appears from the tenor of this section that the descent and ascent are not included in the duration of the shift as fixed by legislation. The Eleventh Report on Wages and Hours of Labour in Canada, published by the Department of Labour as a supplement to the Labour Gazette of January 1928, contains statistics of wages and hours of work in the coal-mines of Nova Scotia, Alberta, and Vancouver Island (British Columbia) from 1920 to 1927. These statistics show that in 1927 the length of the shift worked by the miners as a whole, on the basis of which wages were compiled, was 8 hours, «xcept as regards surface labourers and machinists of Nova Scotia, who worked 8% hours. This regime has not varied since 1920, except in the case of carpenters and blacksmiths in Nova Scotia who worked 8% hours up till 1926. In the tnree provinces some engineers, pumpmen, firemen, etc., "worked 7 days a week. India The hours of work are regulated by the Mines Act of 23 February 1923 2 . The legal provisions, however, are not applicable to ' 'persons who may by rules be defined to be persons holding positions of supervision or management or employed in a confidential capacity". Hours of work are fixed by section 23, which stipulates : "No person shall be employed in a mine — (a) on more than six days in any one week, (b) if he works above ground, for more than 60 hours in any one week, (c) if he works below ground, for more than 54 hours in any one week." The reply of the Government of India to the questionnaire states : "Section 23 of the Indian Mines Act, 1923, imposes a weekly limit of 60 hours for surface workers and 54 hours for 1 2 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE Ibid., 1923, Ind. 3. : Legislative Series, 1924, Can. 5. — 232 — underground workers. These limits are considerably in excess of the average hours worked. The daily hours in the case of both surface and underground workers are probably in the neighbourhood of 8, and with the majority of miners days of absence are numerous. It is probable (although here again no reliable figures are available) that the average miner doesnot attain to an average of five days' work weekly throughout the year. There is at present no such statutory limit to the length of a shift or to the number of hours which a miner may work on any one day." On 25 March 1927 a draft amendment to the Act of 1923 was submitted to the Indian Legislative Assembly. The purpose of this draft is to define the daily hours of work. It provides for the prohibition of employment of workers in the mines for more than 12 hours in the course of 24 consecutive hours and for the introduction of shifts in all mines worked more than 12 hours in 24, and the periodic alternation of shifts. Weekly maxima are maintained. If the Bill is voted the mine-owners will have the choice either (a) of limiting the hours of work in the entire mining undertaking to 12 hours a day, or (Z>) of introducing a shift system with a 12-hour maximum organised so that the hours of work of the two shifts do not overlap for t h e same category of workers. Japan In Japan there is no limitation by law or by collective agreements for adult workers. The hours of work of underground workers are only regulated as regards women and young persons of less than 15 years of age 1. The maximum period of presence in the mine of women and children under the Act of 1916 is 12 hours inclusive of a compulsory rest of one hour (sections 6 and 9). As for adult workers, the length of this period is left to the decision of the employer. However, there is a certain indirect restriction in that mining enterprises are compelled to obtain the.consent of the authorities before issuing any regulation that it may be considered necessary to prescribe with regard to working hours of adult workers. This obligation contributes towards a shortening of the working day for women and children a . According to an enquiry carried out on 17 July 1923 on working hours in the most important coal-mines, the actual working period is understood to count from the time when the worker descends into the shaft to the time when he ascends from it. It is, therefore, calculated individually, includes the two winding times, and corresponds to the international manshift standard 3. 1 The modifications effected in this legal regime since 1925 are indicated on p. 235. 2 Note of the Japanese Government accompanying the tables on the hours of work. 3 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Industrial and Labour Information, Vol. XI. No. 3. Rodo Jiho, 27 July 1924 (monthly publication of the JAPANESE BUREAU OF SOCIAL AFFAIRS). HOURS OF WORK OF UNDERGROUND WORKERS IN THE TABLE I. Regulations Week Day or shift Regions Ctllutiri Ctllictin Legis- agreimBnts Legis- agraomants lation or arbitral lation or arbitral dissions 2 1 3 .... 4 5 11 11 Sendai Tokyo Osaka — Average time und Day or shift Week Going 6 7 8 9 2 3 6 4 decisions l Fukuoka Standard manshift actually worked Average time for descent or ascent — 40' 10.34' 63.24' 32' 20' 8.46' 52.36' 22' ) ) Whole country 11 11 — 30' 10.2' 60.6' 19' 36' 10.21' 62.6' 30' 1 The figures in this column refer to the duration of the working day as prescribed by the 1916 A children. Only limits fixed by laws and regulations are given. * The figures of the average duration of the descenti and ascent are those obtained from obser possible3 to utilise statistical data. The figures in this column represent the average hours of work of all workers in various m The hours of male workers are approximately the same as those of women and children. * The average duration of walking time (going to and returning from the working face for und working conditions in mines. The figures refer to given numbers of workers selected in each of the min * The average rest time, properly so called, is in practice one hour ; this is in agreement with the 8 The figures in this column are obtained by multiplying the average hours of work by six, — 234 — For women and young persons under 15 years of age the 1916 Act prescribes a break of half an hour if the hours of work are over six, and of one hour if they are over ten (section 9). In practice the average break for other classes of workers is also one hour 1. The average period of presence at the coal-face, after deducting rests, includes long waits for trucks and material : this loss of time is estimated a t 1 hour 50 minutes for the Fukuoka field, 33 minutes for the Sapporo field, 1 hour 37 minutes for the Sendai, Tokyo and Osaka fields, and 1 hour 42 minutes for the country as a whole. Iii this way t h e coal industry of Japan is placed at a disadvantage. Advantage is not taken of the long hours of work of the underground employées to the extent that it should be, owing to the dearth of material. In the case of surface workers also, legislation fixes a maximum ^working period only in the case of women and young persons under 15 years of age. This working period is 12 hours, including one hour of compulsory rest. In certain cases it includes other interruptions which diminish the duration of the actual working period correspondingly. In the case of adult workers, the decision as to working hours is left to the employer. In the following tables, drawn up in the same way as the corresponding tables for European countries, the figures furnished by the Japanese Government in its reply to the questionnaire are given. TABLE I I . — HOURS OF WORK OF SURFACE WORKERS IN THE JAPANESE MINES IN 1 9 2 5 Hours of work fixed by regulations Regions 1 Actual duration of work Week Day Collective Collective Legislation agreements Legislation agreements or arbitral or arbitral decisions 2 3 4 1 decisions 5 Day Week 6 7 3 1 Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . Sendai . ) Tokyo . [ Osaka . ) Whole country 11 11 11 11 — — — ' 10 9 60 54 10 60 9.52' 1 59.12' For women and children only. * These figures relate to all workers. * The figures in this column are obtained by multiplying the daily hours of work by six. 1 Communication from the Japanese Government, Aug. 1927. — 235 — Since 1925 modifications have been effected in the legal regime of hours of work. The Decree of 23 June 1926 \ which came into force on 1 July 1926, amended the Mines Act of 1916 in order to bring it into agreement with the regulations contained in the Factories Act of 1923 s . Under the new section 6 the maximum number of hours of attendance in the mine of women and young persons of under 16 years of age 3 is eleven i. These two groups of workers continue to benefit by the rest period prescribed in 1916 (30 minutes if the hours of work are over 6, and 1 hour if they are over 10). These provisions also apply t o surface workers in these groups. Union of South Africa The Mines Act of 15 April 1911 5 regulates hours of work in mines, but does not apply " t o work in coal-mines" (section 9, subsection (c)). Neither is there, as far as is known, any regulation of hours of work in coal-mines by collective agreement or by decisions of arbitration courts. The Government of the Union of South Africa in its reply t o the questionnaire says : "No returns are available, but the usual shift is about 9 hours long, and is from bank to bank. "In European countries the breaking or mining of coal is carried out by a white miner, while in South Africa work of a similar nature is done by coloured labourers. The so-called miner of South Africa is in reality a supervisor of labour and practically takes the place of an official in the British Isles, such as a deputy, and he only conducts blasting operations and, in isolated cases, erects and withdraws timber." United States For the purpose of an exposé on the hours of work in the coal-fields of the United States, information has been extracted from Hours of Labour in Industry: United States, published in its "Studies and Tieports" by the International Labour Office in 1925 e, and from the following publications of the Bureau of Labour Statistics of the United States Department of Labour : Hours and Earnings in 1 Legislative Series, 1926, Jap. 2. Ibid., 1923, Jap. 1. 3 Formerly 15 years. 4 Formerly 12 hours. 5 Bulletin of the International Labour Office (Basle), Vol. VI, 1911, p. 63. 2 6 INTERNATIONAL LABOUR OFFICE : Hours of Labour in United States. Industry: Studies and Reports, Series D, No. 14. Geneva, 1925. — 236 — Anthracite and Bituminous Coal-Mining, 1922 and 1924, and Hours and Earnings in Bituminous Coal-Mining, 1922, 1924, and 1926 *. In the first place, an outline is given of the regulations governing hours of work in virtue of legislation or collective agreements in the mining industry, and, secondly, statistics furnished in the course of the enquiries referred to above. Sixteen of the 48 States of the Union have limited by legal prescriptions the length of the shift of underground workers and machinists in the mining industry 2. The maximum duration of the shift is fixed at 8 hours, except for Maryland, where it is 10 hours 8 . Generally speaking, the hours of work are fixed by collective agreements. As regards anthracite mining, the most important collective agreement is t h a t of 1916 applying to Pennsylvania-, where nearly all the anthracite mines are to be found. This agreement provides for 8 hours' actual work at the usual place of work ; the time spent in coming and going not being taken into account. The prescription relating to hours of work is as follows : "An 8-hour day means eight (8) hours of actual work for all classes of labour at the usual working place, exclusive of noon time, for six (6) days per week,' if the operator desires to work his mines to that extent, excluding legal holidays. The time required in going and coming from place of employment in and about the mine shall not include any part of the day's labour." For the bituminous coal-mines, an agreement concluded by the mine operators of the Central Region (Illinois, Indiana, Ohio, Pennsylvania, that is to say, the principal centre of bituminous coal production in the United States) and the United Mine Workers of America 4 , is taken as the basis of negotiation by all organised workers. This agreement, which was renewed for a period of three years from April 1924, provides, in respect of nearly all categories of workers a basic shift of 8 hours' work at the coal-face, the time spent in coming and going not being taken into account. As regards the statistics of hours of work during the half-month under consideration the data were established in the following manner : The calculation of the hours of work of men on piece rates (tonnage men) being b u t rarely undertaken, it was necessary to make special arrangements with officials of the mines to determine exactly the 1 The results of these enquiries were published in the Monthly Labour Review, July 1925 and July 1927. 2 These States are the following : Arizona, California, Colorado, Idaho, Kansas, Maryland, Missouri, Montana, Nevada, North Dakota, Oklahoma, Oregon, Pennsylvania, Utah, Washington, Wyoming. The texts of the laws relating to hours of work of miners are incorporated in Labour Laws of the United States published by the UNITED STATES BUREAU OF LABOUR STATISTICS. 3 In Alaska the maximum legal duration of the shift is also 8 hours. The United Mine Workers of America comprised, in 1923, 400,000 of the 660,000 workers employed in the mines of the Union at that time. 4 — 237 — number of hours of work. For this purpose the Bureau of Labour Statistics came to an agreement with the companies selected to keep a day-by-day record of the hours of each tonnage worker for a basic half-monthly pay period. The method of noting hours of work is, however, not uniform. In certain cases the persons entrusted with this task have entered the total time spent in the mine, including or not, as the case may be, underground travel time and time taken for meals, while others have entered the total hours of presence at the coal-face with or without time taken for meals. Supplementary information was obtained by the agents of the Bureau of Statistics with regard to the average travelling time underground. The average time spent each day in going from the shaft to the coal-face and in returning from the coal-face to the shaft has been partly calculated and partly estimated. Most of the miners do not have a regular interval for meals ; they eat at the coal-face while waiting for empty trucks or while they are idle for other reasons ; hence, in general, averages of the times taken for meals have not been obtainable. The hours of work of wage-earners have been revised with a view to establishing a common basis for the calculation of average wages. Two units of time have been determined for the hewers (miners) and loaders on piece rates (tonnage men) and hewers on time rates, in anthracite mines ; these are : (a) Total hours of presence in the mine, that is to say, the number of hours actually spent in the mine from the moment (expressed in hours and minutes) of entering the shaft or other means* of access to the mine, in the morning, to the moment (expressed in hours and minutes) of leaving the shaft or any other means of access to the mine, in the afternoon, after the termination of the shift ; this includes the hours of work proper, the average travelling time, underground, and the time taken for meals. (b) Hours of presence at the coal-face, including meal-times, which represent the hours of actual work at the coal-face, from the moment (expressed in hours and minutes) of arrival at the coal-face, in the morning, to the moment (expressed in hours and minutes) of leaving the face after the termination of the shift. With regard to the miners on time rates (daily or hourly rates), the hours actually worked are entered on the pay-rolls of the company. The average hours used in the statistics refer to the time spent at the face to the exclusion of time taken for meals, that is to say, the number of hours actually spent in working. (a) Anthracite Mines The first of the above-mentioned publications of the Bureau of Labour Statistics J contains a survey summarising the results of a special enquiry on wages and hours of work in 1924 in the anthracite mines of Pennsylvania where the agreement of 1916 already referred t o is in force. The agreement fixes the duration of work at t h e coalface at 8 hours a day, exclusive of time spent in underground travel. 1 Hours and Earnings in Anthracite and Bituminous Coal1922 and 1924. — 238 — The shift of workers on time rates is generally fixed at. 8 hours, excluding meal-times. The hours of work of men on piece rates and their helpers seem to be the same as those of men on time rates, but in practice, these hours are more or less irregular. For the latter category of workers the average time required for underground travel from the shaft to the face and vice versa varies from 20 minutes a day in the mines where the journey is shortest to 1 y2 hours a day in the mines with the longest galleries. The most frequent time is 30 minutes a day, that is, 15 minutes going and 15 minutes returning. The time taken for meals is about 30 minutes a day. The following tables, incorporated in the publication referred to, give for 1924 (October and November) the average number of hours of work done during the half-monthly period under consideration in respect of each working day (start) 1 for the principal categories of wage-earners. As regards the underground workers, separate figures are given for the total hours of presence in the mine (including meal-times and underground travel time) and for the hours of presence at the coalface (including meal-times and excluding meal-times). TABLE I. — HOURS OF WORK OF UNDERGROUND WORKERS IN THE ANTHRACITE MINES, OCTOBER-NOVEMBER 1 9 2 4 Number of Average hours Average number in half-month based on per start based on OÎ Occupation starts mines employees (days) in halfmonth time at face time in mine including lunch excluding lunch time at face time in mine inclu- excluding ding lunch lunch Hewers x (miners) : Consideration .... Labourers : Company m i n e r s ' . . Consideration miners'.. Contract miners' . 47 22 55 1,735 961 11,778 10.3 10.9 10.8 96.7 96.3 81.4 89.8 90.1 73.9 84.5 84.7 68.5 9.3 8.9 7.5 8.7 8.3 6.8 8.2 7.8 6.3 47 1,699 10.2 96.5 89.4 84.1 9.4 8.7 8.2 22 53 748 6,794 10.6 10.1 97.7 79.1 91.4 72.4 86.1 67.3 9.2 7.8 8.6 7.2 8.1 6.7 In the anthracite mines the miners also act as loaders. ^ o r the definition of "start" which does not correspond exactly to "shift", see p. 266. — 239 — TABLE II. — HOURS OF WORK OF SURFACE WORKERS IN THE ANTHRACITE MINES, OCTOBER-NOVEMBER 1 9 2 4 Average number of starts (days) in halfmines employees month Number of Occupation Blacksmiths Cagers Carpenters Engineers Labourers Other employees . . , 55 52 56 41 52 51 55 54 51 45 53 56 142 234 607 231 441 413 2,612 381 244 366 1,103 2,334 12.5 12.1 12.3 10.9 14.2 14.7 12.0 11.7 13.2 11.1 11.6 12.7 Average hours worked in halfmonth per start (day) 113.4 112.4 109.0 97.2 122.7 123.6 109.3 104.4 122.5 96.1 96.2 113.6 9.1 9.3 8.9 8.9 8.6 8.4 9.1 8.9 9.3 8.6 8.3 8.9 As the notion of the working day (start) does not correspond exactly to that of shift, it is rather difficult to interpret the figures. in these tables. However, it appears from the examination of t h e m that, generally speaking, the 8-hour day was exceeded in 1924, (b) Bituminous Coal-Mines The second publication of the Bureau of Labour Statistics referred to 1 reproduces the results of an official enquiry undertaken in October 1926 in the coal-fields with a view to comparing hours of work and wages in 1926 with those of 1922 and 1924. The data for the enquiry were collected in 556 mines in Alabama, Colorado, Illinois, Indiana,. Kansas, Kentucky, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, Virginia, and West "Viginia. These statistics apply to 148,155 wage-earners (132,949 underground workers and 15,206 surface workers), t h a t is to say, 25 per cent, of the 588,498 workers who constitute the entire personnel of the bituminous mining industry of the United States. The following tables indicate hours of work during the half-monthly period under consideration and per working day (start) of the principal categories of wage-earners underground and at the surface. The figures relating to underground workers are in respect of hewers (miners) and loaders, who correspond to the category of average workers forming the subject of the enquiry in European countries. The figures show the average number of hours spent in the mine (including underground travel time and meal-times) and at the face (including meal-times). By "face" is meant not only the perpendicular face, but also the place of work of the miner in the mine. The time taken for meals is estimated at 30 minutes ; the underground travel time, going and returning, varies from 10 minutes to 2 hours, on an average it is 46 minutes—23 minutes going and 23 minutes returning. 1 Hours and Earnings in Bituminous Coal-Mining, 1922, 1924 audi 1926. — 240 — TABLE I I I . — HOURS OF WORK OF HEWERS (MINERS) AND LOADERS IN THE BITUMINOUS COM-"MINES IN 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 Number of Year Occupation mines wageearners Average number of starts (days) in halfmonth Average hours in half-month based on per start based on time time time time in mine at face in mine at face 1924 1926 24 61 170 694 9.5 10.1 84.3 92.4 79.9 85.3 8.9 9.1 8.4 8.4 1924 1926 514 488 61,936 66,414 8.1 9.4 68.6 80.3 63.3 73.7 8.5 8.6 7.8 7.8 1924 1926 10 23 102 306 9.4 9.9 90.4 93.7 84.3 87.3 9.6 9.5 . 9.0 8.8 Miners, gang 1924 1926 40 32 1,036 1,065 8.1 9.5 71.1 86.0 65.6 78.7 8.8 9.0 8.1 8.2 Miners, h a n d or pick . 1924 1926 291 254 21,424 20,594 8.5 9.8 71.2 84.3 65.6 77.0 8.4 8.6 7.7 7.9 1924 1926 485 464 6,499 6,055 8.8 10.3 78.6 93.3 72.9 86.0 8.9 9.0 8.3 8.3 1926 151 882 8.8 84.5 79.0 9.6 9.0 Loaders, c o n t r a c t . . . . Miners, machine Miners, machine (cutters') helpers . . . TABLE IV. — HOURS OF WORK OF SURFACE WORKERS IN THE BITUMINOUS COAL-MINES IN 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 Number of Occupation Years mines . wageearners hours Average Average worked number of starts (days) in half- in half- per start month month (day) 1924 1926 581 540 969 909 in 7 1Ï.9 92.0 104Í8 8.6 8.8 1924 1926 474 484 1,354 1,545 10.4 11.4 89.6 98.3 8.6 8.6 1924 1926 333 320 732 674 12.9 13.3 114.4 119.6 8.9 9.0 Labourers 1924 1926 591 550 7,514 7,877 9.5 10.7 81.2 92.6 8.6 8.7 Other employees . . . 1924 1926 578 540 4,823 4,201 11.1 12.1 99.1 108.1 8.9 8.9 Carpenters and car 241 In addition, it has been thought useful to give the following table, which shows for each of the various bituminous coal-producing States of the Union, hours of work of hewers (miners) and loaders taken en bloc, and labourers employed underground and at the surface. The first group represents the greater part of the underground skilled workers, the other two groups represent the greater part of the unskilled workers, both underground and at the surface. The number of workers in the three groups together is about 90 per cent, of the aggregate of workers employed in bituminous coalmines. TABLE V. — HOURS OF WORK OF HEWERS (MINERS) AND LOADERS, AND LABOURERS EMPLOYED UNDERGROUND OR AT THE SURFACE I N 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 IN VARIOUS STATES OF THE UNION Hewers and loaders ' Undarground labourers Average hour; berags (aar Slate nimbar of starb {Up) in halfmonth in half-month basad on tima at fa« including lunch ins in mine *! of starts (dais) in halfmonth 8.5 8.5 7.50 8.9 12.5 8.6 9.9 7.5 9.2 71.1 100.5 85.4 71.4 8.1 8.0 8.0 8.1 71.5 70.5 8.5 8.5 tima at lace inclu- in half- per start 8.8 8.7 8.0 8.1 8.0 8.1 9.0 85.1 77.2 9.5 8.6 1924 1926 10.2 87.8 79.8 8.6 7.9 1924 1926 9.5 84.8 77.1 8.9 8.1 Indiana 1924 1926 9.7 75.4 70.2 7.8 7.2 Kansas 1924 1926 9.4 71.7 67.4 7.7 7.2 9.1 76.5 71.8 8.4 7.9 10.7 8.9 8.4 8.3 9.4 79.1 72.9 8.5 7.8 8.9 8.2 73.3 63.2 . . . . 1924 1926 1924 1926 74.3 69.0 79.7 60.5 73.7 Pennsylvania. . . 1924 1926 9.9 88.1 80.4 8.9 8.2 9.8 10.7 81.5 89.1 Tennessee 1924 1926 8.5 72.5 67.2 8.5 7.9 7.8 7.6 62.8 59.5 9.2 78.9 73.6 8.6 8.0 7.6 8.4 61.6 70.4 9.6 75.3 69.1 7.9 7.2 8.8 9.8 73.5 83.1 8.3 7.7 8.3 8.4 8.1 7.9 8.1 8.4 8.4 8.5 9.5 82.2 75.4 8.6 7.9 8.9 9.4 74.2 78.7 8.3 8.4 Ohio . . . . W e s t Virginia . . 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1 iierage tumbar of ¡tarts (dan) in ballmonth in halfmonth per start 9.5 71.9 83.5 8.9 12.0 77.6 108.6 8.9 8.8 8.8 9.1 9.2 11.0 75.7 94.1 8.2 8.5 7.1 10.7 10.1 11.2 9.1 10.4 9.1 10.0 67.2 88.0 8.0 8.2 8.8 8.2 8.6 8.6 lunch 1924 1926 Kentucky Arirage baurs lirerag« him par start basad Aierage number on ting in mm Surface labourers 8.1 88.8 91.8 78.3 90.3 73.6 80.2 10.2 11.0 89.8 97.9 8.1 8.0 8.8 8.9 8.8 8.8 70.2 69.7 8.0 8.0 8.4 9.6 68.9 84.4 8.2 8.8 9.9 10.9 84.8 95.2 9.5 10.7 81.2 92.6 8.6 8.8 8.6 8.7 There are no statistics tor 1924 for these two categories of workers taken together. For the bituminous coal-mines, as for the anthracite mines — subject to the same reservation respecting the unit of measurement —the hours of work exceeded 8 per day in 1926. 15 — 242 — ' B. STATISTICS OF WAGES Canada § 1. Regular statistics of employment and production in the coalmines of Canada are published by the Dominion Bureau of Statistics in the annual report ; moreover, the Department of Labour publishes information as to wage rates prevailing in the September month of each year in three provinces *. The' latest years for which complete information is published are 1925 and 1926, and these years only are taken into consideration in the following notes. It should be observed that the year 1925 was exceptional in that the employment and production, owing largely to labour troubles in somes mines, were less than in several preceding years. In 1926 both employment and production showed an improvement without, however, attaining the maximum level reached. previously. The statistics cover both bituminous, sub-bituminous, and lignite mines. In accordance with the general plan of the enquiry, only bituminous mines will be taken into account. Such existed in five provinces, namely, Nova Scotia, New Brunswick, Alberta, British Columbia, and Yukon a . Similarly, salaried employees are excluded from the following notes as in the case of other countries. It may be noted t h a t little or no information as to the methods employed in the Canadian statistics are to be found in the publications referred to, except the statements that the figures published are based on returns received from each mine, and that uniform methods are followed throughout the country. TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES PAID IN THE COAL-MINES OF DIFFERENT PROVINCES, 1925 AND 1926 (In Dollars) Province New Brunswick 1925 1926 $ 10,707,656 536,871 4,164,568 7,199,205 3,022 22,611,322 $ 14,041,702 432,006 4,677,717 6,544,188 600 25,696,213 1 CANADA, DEPARTMENT OF TRADE AND COMMERCE, DOMINION BUREAU OF STATISTICS : Coal Statistics for Canada for the Calendar Years 1925 and 1926 ; Ottawa, 1926 and 1927. DEPARTMENT OFLAROUR, CANADA I Wages and Hours of Labour in Canada, 1920 to 1927 (Wages and Hours of Labour Report No. 11, issued as a Supplement to the Labour Gazette, Jan. 1928) ; Ottawa, 1928. 2 Sub-bituminous mines lie all in the province of Alberta, and lignite mines in the provinces of Saskatchewan and Alberta. — 243 — § 2. The total of wages paid to wage earners in bituminous mining is shown in Table I for each province. The figures refer apparently to money wages only ; no information is available in respect of allowances in kind, payment for holidays, or employers' contributions to social insurance 1. Furthermore, statistics do not show separately the total of wages paid to underground and surface workers. It will be seen from this table t h a t the employment of labour is important in the provinces of Nova Scotia, Alberta and British Columbia. The total wages bill in New Brunswick is less than onetenth of that paid in Alberta, while Yukon is quite negligible. § 3. The Canadian statistics give the total number of days' work (man-days) done, as well as the average number of wage earners employed underground and on the surface. The number of days* work is based on records kept in the mines which are communicated monthly to the central authority. The number for each province is shown in Table II. TABLE II. — NUMBER OF DAYS' WORK DONE IN THE COAL-MINES, B Y PROVINCES, 1925 AND 1926 Province Days' work underground 1925 1926 Days' work on surface 1925 | 1926 Total of days' work 1925 1926 Nova Scotia . . 1,448,327 2,375,145 421,640 613,136 1,869,967 2,988,281 New Brunswick. 167,069 135,590 103,098 40,501 126,568 32,492 654,558 Alberta . . . . 840,269 601,627 203,302 451,256 238,642 British Columbia 1,332,768 857,889 479,062 964,275 474,879 1,443,337 431 112 56 108 323 56 Canada . . 2,990,749 3,937,815 1,144,613 1,359,205 4,135,362 6,297,020 The number of wage earners refers to workers registered on colliery pay-rolls, and the average is calculated from the monthly figures secured from each province. The average number of workers classified by places of work and provinces is seen from Table III (on next page). Tables II and III show that the number of days worked and the average number of wage earners in Nova Scotia, Alberta, and British Columbia form about 97 per cent, of the respective totals for the whole Dominion. On account of the very small figures given for Yukon, it will not be worth while to calculate below any averages for this province. The underground workers form in the country as a whole about three-fourths of the total labour force employed. 1 Compulsory industrial accident insurance is in force in the provinces of Nova Scotia, New Brunswick, Alberta, and British Columbia, and workmen's compensation in the province of Yukon. The employers are responsible for the whole cost of these schemes. — 244 — The wage earners are classified further by individual occupation, The statistics show nineteen different occupations for white employees classified in three principal groups : (i) crafts employed mainly underground, (ii) crafts employed mainly on surface, (iii) miscellaneous. TABLE I I I . — AVERAGE NUMBER OF WAGE EARNERS EMPLOYED, BY PROVINCES, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 Average number underground Province New Brunswick. . . . British Columbia . . . Yukon Canada TABLE IV. 1925 1926 6,689 468 2,412 3,713 3 13,285 9,878 415 2,546 3,435 1 16,275 — AVERAGE NUMBER Average number on surface 1925 1926 1,644 146 851 1,623 1 2,222 129 824 1,660 1 4,265 4,836 Average number all w a g e earners 1925 1926 8,333 614 3,263 5,336 4 17,550 12,100 644 3,370 6.096 2 21,111 OF WAGE EARNERS EMPLOYED, BY OCCUPATIONS, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 Underground On surface Total Occupations 1925 I. Officials underground Hand cutters and Machine cutters . . . Machine loaders and Horse 1926 1925 1926 875 10 7 784 882 6,139 1,231 6,077 1,925 6 5 6,146 1,231 6,082 1,925 2,396 2,805 1 2,397 2,805 1,504 1,795 34 26 1,538 1,821 1,651 371 452 859 191 27 14 2 14 61 5 4 17 11 214 455 1,160 424 323 326 238 302 1,811 260 74 4 8 15 7 205 476 1,386 449 338 363 283 306 1,969 1,612 376 466 876 202 6 1 102 1,431 246 2,026 464 549 1,113 197 24 12 6 14 1 7 2 162 1,960 233 240 506 2,100 468 557 1,128 204 229 488 1,392 463 339 370 285 468 3,929 473 17,311 20,247 6,662 6,161 22,973 26,408 haulage Ventilation employees II. Administration . . . Foremen and clerks . Screenmen and loaders III. Bnginemen . . . . Firemen . . . . . . . Carpenters and masons Other mechanics. . . All other white. . . . IV. Coloured Total 1926 774 haulage em- Mechanical 1925 241 469 1,162 438 323 332 239 404 3,242 — 245 — Coloured employees—a very insignificant group—are only employed in the province of British Columbia and are chiefly Chinese, though several Japanese and a few Indians are also employed. Table IV gives the average number of wage earners classified by occupation for the Dominion as a whole. It is, however, to be noted that the figures include all mine-workers in Alberta, since the wage earners employed on bituminous mines are not shown separately in this classification ; as a consequence the totals are higher than in Table III*. Finally, from the figures given in Tables II and III, the Canadian statistics calculate the average number of day's work per man per year in the different provinces. This number, which indicates the regularity of the employment, is shown in Table V. TABLE V. — AVERAGE NUMBER OF DAYS WORKED PER MAN PER YEAR IN THE DIFFERENT PROVINCES, 1 9 2 5 AND Underground On surface 1926 Underground and on surface Provinces i Nova Scotia . . . New Brunswick British Columbia Canada . . . . 1925 1926 1925 1926 1925 217 270 187 260 240 248 236 249 256 277 239 295 276 252 280 286 224 272 201 271 247 249 249 261 225 242 268 281 236 252 j 1926 It will be seen that in neither year the full number of possible working days has been worked in any province. The employment was generally more regular in 1926 than in 1925 ; but this does not apply to all provinces ; in New Brunswick and British Columbia the average number of day's work was somewhat Jess in 1926. Further, the number of days worked by underground men is, as may be expected, considerably below the corresponding average for surface workers in both years and in all provinces. Finally, it is seen that a minimum average number of days worked was recorded in 1925 in Alberta, while in 1926 the average was sensibly equal in the different provinces. The employment has in general been most regular in British Columbia. § 4. From the data given in Tables I, II and III, thefaverage wage earned per day and per year can be calculated for each province and for all wage earners taken together. The average earnings are computed simply by dividing the total wages bill (a) by the number of day's work, and (b) by the number of workers employed (Table VI). 1 The average number of wage earners in sub-bituminous mines in Alberta was 654 in 1925 and 611 in 1926. That of wage earners employed in lignite mines was 5,150 in 1925 and 5,042 in 1926. — 246 — T'ABLE VI. — AVERAGE WAGE EARNED PER DAY WORKED AND PER YEAR, ALL WAGE EARNERS IN COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 5 AND 1926 (In Dollars) Average earnings per clay's work Average earnings per man per year 1925 1926 1925 1926 $ 5.73 3.21 6.36 4.99 $ 4.69 3,18 5.57 4.91 5.47 4.85 $ 1,285 873 1,276 1,349 1,288 $ 1,160 794 1,430 1,284 1,223 Province Nova Scotia New Brunswick . . . . • British Columbia . . . These figures show that average day earnings were highest in 1925 in the provinces of Alberta and Nova Scotia ; in 1926 there was a considerable decrease in the earnings received in Nova Scotia and the highest earnings were received in Alberta and British Columbia. The average yearly earnings are, owing to the larger number of days worked, highest in British Columbia in 1925 and in Alberta in 1926. In all cases New Brunswick shows a very much lower level of earnings than other provinces. The above results may be completed by information drawn from another source, namely, from statistics showing the day wages in the month of September of each year. These data are based, according to information given, on agreements between the coal-mining operators and the employees, in some cases represented by unions and in others b y committees of employees. They thus give wage rates. As regards workers employed on the piece-work basis, the minimum rate per day paid when miners are not working on contract, per ton, per yard, etc., is shown. However, in the case of "contract miners", the wages are given as showing "average earnings per day on contract, per ton, etc.," and these cannot have been taken from collective agreements. In some of the mines in each district the wages of unorganised employees are stated to be somewhat lower than those in agreements. These figures (Table VII) are available for the month of September in 1925, 1926, and 1927 for eleven occupations in three principal districts, namely, Nova, Scotia, Alberta, and Vancouver Island (including three mines in South-Eastern British Columbia). Chinese workers employed in Vancouver are not included. Among the three districts covered, Alberta shows the highest level of daily earnings for contract miners and highest time rates for other mine workers ; the lowest level is in all cases shown for Nova Scotia. — 247 — TABLE VII. — DAILY WAGE RATES IN COAL-MINES IN NOVA SCOTIA, ALBERTA, AND VANCOUVER ISLAND, SEPTEMBER 1 9 2 5 , 1 9 2 6 AND 1 9 2 7 Nova Scotia Sept. 1925 Sept. 1926 Contract miners (a). . . S 6.08 $ 6.25 Machine miners (6) . . . — — Hand miners (b) . . . . 4.30 4.15 Hoisting engineers . . . 4.35 4.15 3.60 3.60 3.75 3.65 Pumpmen 4.00 3.90 Labourers, underground 3.35 3.35 Labourers, surface . . . 3.25 3.25 Machinists 4.35 4.15 Carpenters 4.00 3.85 Blacksmiths 4.10 4.00 Vancouver Island Alberta Sept. 1925 Sept. 1926 Sept. 1927 Sept. 1925 Sept. 1926 Sept. 1927 S 7.92 ( 5.65 7.00 4.16 I 5.00 5.40 5.50 4.15 6.00 4.70 3.60 4.90 5.20 3.65 5.40 4.26 3.90 4.75 4.25 3.35 • 4.45 4.00 3.25 ; 4.20 4.15 | 4.70 5.50 5.30 3.85 | 5.50 5.30 4.00 | 5.50 7.10 5.65 7.00 5.00 5.57 5.60 6.00 4.70 5.25 5.20 5.57 4.26 4.75 4.25 4.67 4.00 4.20 4.70 5.71 5.30 5.77 5.30 5.77 7.74 5.65 7.00 5.00 5.57 5.50 | 6.00 J 4.70 | 5.25 j 5.20 ) 5.57 4.25 1 4.75 . 4.25 1 4.67 ; 4.00 i 4.20 / 4.70 1 5.71 1 5.30 I 5.77 J 5.30 1 5.77 J S $ 6.78 $ 6.99 6.76 4.81 4.81 4.81 4.52 4.52 4.52 5.39 5.39 5.39 4.13 4.13 4.13 4.35 4.36 4.35 3.96 3.96 3.96 3.97 3.97 3.97 3.76 3.76 3.76 5.40 5.40 5.40 4.83 4.83 4.83 5.11 5.11 5.11_ Sept. 1927 $ 6.62 1 1 (a) Average earnings per day on contract, per ton, etc. (ft) Minimum rate per day when not working on contracts per ton, yard, etc. TABLE VIII. — TOTAL PRODUCTION OF BITUMINOUS COAL AND ITS DISTRIBUTION FOR DIFFERENT USES, 1 9 2 5 AND 1 9 2 6 (Metric Tons, 000's Omitted) Distribution of tonnage Supplied to employees P u t in waste heap 1925 123 603 126 (0.7) 431 170 7,120 8,574 466 8,108 1926 147 704 145 9 452 181 9,983 11,621 380 11,241 248 § 5. The output of bituminous coal and its distribution for different uses in Canadian mines (converted to metric tons) is seen from Table VIII. The tonnage of coal shipped formed about 88 per cent, of the total output in 1925, and 89 per cent, in 1926. The total output of bituminous coal as well as the average output per man per day and per man per year in each province is given in Table IX. TABLE IX. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT OF BITUMINOUS COAL, BY PROVINCES, 1925 AND 1926 (In Metric Tons) Total Output (000's omitted) Province 1925 New Brunswick. . . . Alberta British Columbia . . . Yukon Canada . . . . 3,486 189 1,946 2,487 (0.7) 8,108 1926 6,120 167 2,593 2,371 (0.3) 11,241 Average output • Per m a n per d a y Per m a n per year 1925 | 1926 1925 | 1926 1.86 1.13 2.97 1.72 2.05 1.16 3.09 1.78 418 308 596 466 606 289 769 465 1.96 2.12 462 532 These figures show that the provinces of Nova Scotia, Alberta, and British Columbia yielded about 97 per cent, of the total quantity of coal produced in Canada. The figures relating to the average output show very considerable variations as between different provinces. The average output, both daily and yearly, is by far the highest in the province of Alberta ; and it is only in this province t h a t it is above the general averages found for the whole Dominion. The average output in Nova Scotia and British Columbia is sensibly equal, while New Brunswick shows t h e minimum in each case. If the average daily output in Canadian mines is compared with the corresponding average found for other countries, it will be seen that Canadian output is about twice as high as the output in any European country, but only half of the corresponding average shown for the United States (bituminous mines). As regards the annual output, Canada shows an average which is much higher than the average in the most productive European coal-field (German Upper Silesia), approximately equal to the average in South Africa, but less than three-fourths of the corresponding average in the United States (bituminous mines). In short, the productivity of Canadian mines is second highest in the world. § 6. On the basis of data given in Tables I and IX the average wage cost of a metric ton of coal may be calculated. The average cost is shown both in terms of dollars and in terms of gold francs. The results of these calculations are shown in Table X. — 249 — TABLE X . — A V E R A G E W A G E COST P E R M E T R I C TON O F COAL, 1925 AND 1926 W a g e cost in dollars W a g e cost in gold francs Province Nova Scotia New Brunswick . . . . Alberta British Columbia . . . Canada 1925 1926 1925 1928 $ 3.07 2.87 2.14 2.89 S 2.29 2.75 1.80 2.76 Francs 15.91 14.87 11.09 14.97 Francs 11.87 14.25 9.33 14.30 2.79 2.29 14.46 11.87 As will be seen, the wage cost was in 1926 considerably less than in the preceding year in all provinces. Of the different provinces, Alberta shows the lowest wage cost in each year ; the maximum was reached in 1925 in Nova Scotia, and in 1926 in New Brunswick and British Columbia where the wage cost of coal was practically equal. Compared with other countries the wage cost of coal in Canada appears as very high. It is higher than the corresponding cost in any European or non-European country, except Great Britain and Belgium. India § 1. The statistics available for India are very scanty. The information received from the Department of Industries and Labour (Government of India), and the India Office (London) is summarised below. The number of workers employed is given for the year 1925£as follows 1 : Hewers 49,538 Other underground workers 61,063 AH underground workers 110,601 Surface workers 61,329 Total 171,930 The classification by sex of these workers was as follows : Males 113,399 Females 58,531 Total 171,930 It will be seen that the employment of female labour is a particular characteristic of Indian coal-mining ; the proportion of women to the total number of workers—34.5 per cent.—is much in excess 1 Statistics are available for each year from 1919tol925. Account is taken of the last-named year only which shows slightly lower figures than the preceding years. — 250 — of the corresponding proportion found in other countries. On the other hand, child labour has not been extensive in Indian mines, and since 1 July 1924 the employment of persons under thirteen years of age has been prohibited 1. § 2 Accurate information is not available as to average earnings. It is, however, estimated by the Department of Industries and Labour that the average weekly earnings were during the year 1925 as follows : Rs. Hewers 4 Other underground workers 3.11 Workers above ground 3.1 Mineowners provide as a rule free housing, sanitation, water supply, lighting and domestic fuel. They also pay contributions under the Workmen's Compensation Act and provide in some cases medical attendance. § 3. Statistics are further given as to the total and average output of coal. The total output of coal was as follows : Metric tons Saleable coal Coal consumed by the mine Coal distributed to employees 2 Commercially disposable coal The average annual output per worker was 20,289,000 1,981,000 532,000 17,776,000 as follows : Metric tons Per worker underground 183 Per worker under and above ground 118 It may be observed that the average output per worker under and above ground in Indian mines appears to be lower than in any other country covered by the present enquiry. Japan § 1. The statistics of wages prepared by the Bureau of Social Affairs of J a p a n refer to the year 1924. These statistics are not considered by the Bureau of Social Affairs as comprehensive, and to quote the report, "there may be cases of presuming the whole from the partial data so long as a certain amount of accuracy can be maintained by this method". However, the available statistics are fairly comprehensive as compared with the information available for other non-European countries, and they have been completed by the Japanese authorities by a special enquiry into labour conditions in mines which covered nearly all the leading mines throughout Japan, and another enquiry into family budgets of 400 households of coal-miners, covering a period of three months. The statistics are given separately for three administrative districts, namely, Fukuoka, which is by far the most important mining district, Sapporo, and the district of Sendai-Tokyo-Osaka. 1 A certain number of children, however, are reported to have been employed in 1925 in contravention of the Act. 2 Estimated at 3 per cent, of saleable coal. — 251 — § 2. Table I shows the total wages bill for each district. In general, the method outlined by the International Labour Office for the present enquiry has been followed ; some remarks, however, should be made. The money wages (column 2) are calculated "from the average working-day wages of a mirier, the percentage of his working days, and the number of miners" as shown by the special enquiry mentioned above ; they include amounts corresponding to the occupational charges. As regards workmen's contributions (column 3), it should be observed that social insurance contributions properly so called were not yet collected in 1924 ; the figures refer in fact to mutual-aid associations against accidents, sickness, occasions for congratulations and condolences, etc., which have been organised in almost every mine, and which are generally financed by both the employers and the workers, the average contribution per worker (ascertained from special enquiries) being about 30 sen. The figures shown in the table have been obtained by multiplying this average contribution by the total number of mining workers. The figures concerning free coal (column 4) are taken solely from the leading coal-mines in the district of Sapporo, because in the other districts the value of the free coal is negligible. The amounts shown under "allowances in kind other than free coal" (column 5) include payments for "the supply of housing accommodation, the sale at reduced prices of articles of daily necessity, education and recreation, the redemption of loans, etc." ; they are calculated from the allowance of an average individual worker, and are based on special enquiries. The figures relative to employers' contributions to social insurance (column 6) refer to allowances for occupational diseases as prescribed by the laws and regulations, contributions or subsidies by employers to mutual-aid associations, and hospital expenses for the benefit of sick or injured workers, as well as all other necessary expenditure for the sanitary equipment 1 . The figures for the allowances for occupational diseases are calculated on the basis of a report on the laws and TABLE I. — TOTAL WAGES BILL OF COAL-MINING WORKERS, 1924 (In Yen) District 1 Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka. . . Total . . Money wages 2 WorkAllowances in kind men's contributions to social Free coal Other insurance 3 4 5 Employers' Deductions Total actual contribu- for occupaearnings tions (columns 2-6, tional to social charges less insurance column 7) 6 7 8 68,351,414 725,339 (a) 11,131,936 6,143,297 2,538,686 83,813,300 12,160,759 92,844 258,957 1,977,450 1,385,244 315,670 15,559,684 9,669,174 85,666 (a) 1,203,364 804,348 702,458 11,060,094 90,181,347 903,849 258,957 14,312,750 8,332,889 3,556,814 110,432,978 (a) Amount negligible. 1 It appears that the term "employers' contributions to social insurance" has been interpreted in Japan in a wider sense than in European statistics. — 252 — regulations, and those for the cost of sanitary equipment on the basis of a special enquiry ; as regards the employers' contributions to the expenses of mutual-aid associations, the amount contributed is presumed to be the same as that paid by the workers, which is a practice generally adopted. No figures are given in respect of allowances in cash and payments for holidays. On the other hand, occupational charges, which form in Japan an important item in the total wages bill, are shown in a separate column. The figures relating to these charges (column 7) are calculated from the expenditure of an average individual worker, and are based on the enquiry into family budgets mentioned above. It will be seen from Table I that the money wages (including occupational charges) constitute about 82 per cent, of the total wages bill (excluding occupational charges). Of the other items the most important are the allowances in kind other than free coal, which represent 13 per cent, of the total wages bill, and employers' contributions, corresponding to 7.5 per cent, of the total. Workmen's contributions t o social insurance represent only 0.8 per cent, and free coal distributed to the employees not more than 0.2 per cent. Deductions for occupational charges form not less than 3 per cent, of the total wages bill, including occupational charges. The distribution of the total wages bill among the different categories of workers has been calculated on the basis of the number of days worked and the number of workers in the different categories, as shown by the special enquiry. TABLE II. — DISTRIBUTION OF THE TOTAL WAGES BILL AMONG DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF WORKERS, 1924 (In Yen) Underground workers District Fukuoka . . . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka . . . . Total Surface workers Hewers Other All 25,729,269 7,807,967 42,399,527 3,896,701 68,128,796 11,704,668 15,684,504 3,854,916 4,503,207 4,025,358 8,528,565 2,531,529 38,040,443 50,321,586 88,362,029 22,070,949 Table II shows that the part of the total wages bill accruing to hewers forms 34 per cent, of the total, that accruing to other underground workers 46 per cent, and the part to all underground workers 80 per cent. The wages paid in respect of surface workers thus forms 20 per cent, of the total wages bill. § 3. The total number of days worked is shown in the following table ; the number of days worked by the different categories of workers is calculated on the basis of the percentage of working days and the number of mining workers, as shown by the special enquiry. — 253 — TABLE III. — TOTAL NUMBER OF DAYS WORKED, 1 9 2 4 Country and district Fuknoka . . Sapporo . . . Sendai-Tokyo. Osaka . . . Total. . Undergound By hewers On surface By other workers Total Underground and on surface 10,446,104 19,976,388 30,422,492 11,327,538 41,750,030 2,355,936 1,790,087 4,146,023 2,076,477 6,222,500 1,393,600 1,964,675 3,358,275 1,378,629 4,736,904 14,195,640 23,731,150 37,926,790 14,782,644 52,709,434 As regards the number of days lost, information is only available in respect of underground workers. The number lost by this group is shown in Table IV. TABLE IV. — TOTAL NUMBER OF DAYS LOST, UNDERGROUND MINES, 1924 Days lost when the mine was working owing to District Fukuoka voluntary absence . . . . Sendai-Tokyo Osaka Total involuntary absence Days lost when the mine was not working Total 7,835,940 545,561 6,537,413 452,918 790,648 83,337 15,164,001 1,081,816 843,505 657,149 78,758 1,579,412 9,225,006 7,647,480 952,743 17,825,229 The percentage of the total of days worked and lost underground (55,752,019), represented by the days lost, was, in 1924, 32. The corresponding percentage of days lost when the mine was operating and on account of workers' voluntary absence, was 16.5 per cent. and owing to workers' involuntary absence 13.8 ; the percentage of days lost on account of mines not being in operation was not more than 1.7. TABLE V. — NUMBER OF COAL-MINING WORKERS RECORDED AT THE END OF J U N E 1 9 2 4 Country and District Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka . . . Total . . . Underground workers Hewers Other | Total Surface workers All workers 51,739 10,120 97,517 7,036 149,256 17,156 52,227 8,634 201,483 25,790 6,923 9,424 16,347 7,449 23,796 68,782 113,977 182,759 68,310 251,069 — 254 — § 4. The number of coal-mining workers given in Table V refers to the number employed at the end of June 1924, the date at which the working conditions in Japanese mines are most normal throughout the year. It will be seen from Table V that hewers form 27 per cent, of the total number of workers ; other underground workers 46 per cent., and all underground workers taken together, 73 per cent. ; the percentage of surface workers thus is 27. The Japanese statistics give also the number of workers classified by sex and age. The term "juvenile workers" means workers under sixteen years of age. The figures for Japan as a whole are as follows : Adults Juveniles Total Males 178,127 4,490 182,617 Females 65,174 3,278 68,452 Total . . . . 243,301 7,768 251,069 § 5. From the data given in Tables I, II, III, and V, the average earnings per day and per year can be calculated. The average earnings per hour of attendance and of effective work may be computed on the basis of the enquiry into the working hours in mines 1. The average daily earnings are given in Table VI, the average hourly earnings in Table VII and average annual earnings in Table VIII. TABLE VI. — AVERAGE ACTUAL EARNINGS PER DAY 1 9 2 4 (In Yen) Underground workers District Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka . . . Whole country Surface workers Underground and surface workers Hewers Others All workers 2.46 3.31 2.12 2.18 2.24 2.83 1.39 1.86 2.01 2.50 3.23 2.05 2.54 1.84 2.34 2.68 2.12 2.33 1.49 2.10 TABLE VII. — AVERAGE ACTUAL EARNINGS PER HOUR, 1 9 2 4 (In Yen) Average earnings per hour of effective work Average earnings per hour of attendance underground District Hewers Other All workers workers Undergound Hewers All J ^ e r s workers Above ground Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka . . . 0.23 0.36 0.20 0.26 0.21 0.32 0.34 0.47 0.33 0.35 0.34 0.44 0.14 0.21 0.31 0.21 0.25 0.42 0.33 0.37 0.18 Whole country 0.25 0.21 0.23 0.34 0.33 0.35 0.15 1 See Appendix V, (A), note on Japan. — 255 — TABLE VIII. — AVERAGE (In ANNUAL EARNINGS, 1924 Yen) Underground workers Hewers Other All workers Surface workers Underground and surface workers District Fukuoka . . Sapporo . . . Sendai-TokyoOsaka . . . 497 772 436 554 456 682 300 446 316 603 650 429 521 340 465 Whole country 553 442 483 323 440 The Japanese statistics give further the average annual earnings separately for males and females, adults and juveniles. It will be of interest to give these figures for J a p a n as a whole. Adults Yen Juveniles Yen Males 484 259 Females 341 271 All workers 445 264 No calculations have been made in respect of real wages in the different districts of Japan. § 6. The total average output of coal is shown in Table IX on the same lines as in the enquiry into the European coal mines. It is to be observed that the tonnage of saleable coal raised is based on a special enquiry conducted by the Department of Commerce and Industry ; the tonnage of coal consumed by the mines is obtained by a calculation based on the amount of coal consumed by different mines and the capacity in horse-power of the boilers employed in both coal and other mines, since figures for coal consumed by the coal-mines alone are not available. The tonnage of coal distributed to employees refers solely to the district of Sapporo, where the figures of the leading coal-mines are taken as the basis for the total TABLE IX. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL, 1924 (In Metric Tons) Total output District Saleable coat raised Coal consumad by the nine Coal nïitritatetl to employees Aierage output Per day worked Commercially disposable coal by a newer (a) 19,728,458 2.09 Fukuoka . . . 21,828,259 2,099,801 5,192,792 160,988 70,947 4,960,867 2.20 Sapporo . . . Sendai-Tokyo490,777 (a) 2,698,998 2.22 Osaka . . . 3,089,775 Whole country 30,110,826 2,751,566 70,947 27,288,313 2.12 (a) Amount negligible. under and above. ground Per year per worker underground under and atom ground 0.72 0.61 1.25 0.84 421 146 531 303 108 201 0.93 0.60 0.79 0.55 446 189 438 165 130 120 underground newer — 256 — amount of coal distributed to employees in all the coal-mines in that district ; • the tonnage distributed to employees in other districts is negligible. Finally, the figures representing the average output are computed by dividing the total amount of saleable coal by the number of manual workers and that of days worked. The foregoing table shows that the province of Fukuoka produces about 72 per cent, of the total tonnage of coal raised in Japan. The average output per manshift of a hewer is sensibly equal in the different districts ; but owing to the variations in the number of other workers, the average output per manshift of underground workers and mine workers in general is, in the district of Sapporo, considerably higher than in the other coal-fields and in the country as a whole. The same remarks apply when the average annual output is taken into consideration. In all cases the average output appears to be lower in the principal district —that of Fukuoka —than in the country as a whole. Compared with the corresponding averages calculated for the European countries, it will be seen that the average output per manshift in Japan is somewhat higher than in Belgium, but lower than in other countries. The average annual ouput in Japan is lower than in any European country. § 7. The average labour cost of a ton of coal is shown in Table X. Following the method adopted in respect of European countries, two different conceptions of total wages bill have been taken into account, viz. (a) wages excluding employers' contributions, and (b) wages including the same. On the other hand, averages are computed as per ton of saleable coal and as per ton of commercially disposable coal. TABLE X. — AVERAGE WAGES COST PER TON OF COAL, 1 9 2 4 {In Yen) District Wages excluding employers' contributions Wages including employers' contributions Per ton of Per ton o! commersaleable cially disposable coal coal Per ton oi saleable coal Per ton of commercially disposable coal o Sendai-Tokyo-Osaka 3.56 2.73 3.32 3.94 2.86 3.95 3.84 2.94 3.58 4.25 3.14 4.26 Whole country 3.39 3.74 3.67 4.05 . . . . It will be seen that the inclusion of employers' contributions, as well as the exclusion of coal consumed by the mine and the miners, both increase the wage« cost per ton by 8 to 10 per cent. The wages cost is considerably lower in the district of Sapporo (where the productivity was shown to be the highest) than in the two other districts which, again, show practically the same level of wages cost. — 257 — Since the total wages bill and the total production of coal in Japan have been established on approximately the same lines as the corresponding data for Europe, it may not be inappropriate to attempt to make a rough statistical comparison of this point. Converting the yen into terms of gold francs, the average wages cost, excluding •employers' contributions, is as follows : Gold francs Per ton of saleable coal 7.24 Per ton of commercially disposable coal 7.99 If these amounts are compared with the corresponding figures for European countries \ it may be noted t h a t the average wages cost of a ton of coal in Japan is relatively low. However, it is somewhat Jiigher than the wages cost in Poland and German Upper Silesia and less than the cost in other countries. It is thus seen that both the productivity (as shown by the average output per manshift) and the labour cost (i.e. average wages paid per ton of coal) in Japan are lower than the corresponding averages in most European countries. In Europe, it will be remembered, relatively low productivity usually corresponds to relatively high labour cost. By what natural, racial, and industrial conditions the Japanese situation may be explained, is outside the scope of the present notes. Union of South Africa § 1. The statistics furnished by the Government of the Union of South Africa are considerably different from those furnished by other countries, owing to the special peculiarities of coal-mining. In this country, the breaking or mining of coal is carried out by coloured labourers, while the so-called "miner" is in reality a supervisor of labour and takes the place of an official or supervisor in European countries : he only conducts blasting operations and, in isolated cases, erects and withdraws timber. The South African mining statistics, published by the Government Mining Engineer, give separate information for the three provinces of Transvaal, Natal, and the Orange Free State. There are a few small collieries in the Cape Province, but the number of employees and the production in this district are negligible and are omitted from the present summary. The following statistics refer to the year 1925 2 . § 2. Table I shows the amount of the total wages bill in South African mines in 1925. It is to be observed that the figures refer to money wages only. No information is available as to the value of {a) allowances in kind, which are likely to be very important since ^11 native workers are fed and housed by the employers ; (6) free coal, which is allowed to white workers but is not valued. On the other hand, there are no insurance contributions, either from workers or employers, nor any holidays with pay. The total money wages paid to white, Asiatic, and native employees, are shown separately. 1 2 Cf. Part II, Chapter II, § 28 and Table XIV. Statistics are available for the period 1911 to 1913 and for each year from 1919 to 1925. As in the case of other countries, the following notes are confined to the year 1925, which is a fairly representative year lor South Africa. 17 258 TABLE I. — TOTAL MONEY WAGES, 1 9 2 5 {In Pounds Sterling) White employees Province Coloured employees Asiatics Native and other Total £ £ £ £ 262 431,138 431,400 60,218 417,603 477,821 66,726 66,726 60,480 915,467 975,947 331,745 313,189 47,663 692.597 Transvaal . . . . Natal Orange Free State. Total § 3. The statistics relating to the workers employed distinguish between labour " i n service" and labour " a t work", but no information is given as to the method by which the different figures are obtained. The average number of labour " a t work" is given in Table I I l . The principal distinction is between white employees and coloured workers. Coloured workers are further subdivided into those employed underground and those on the surface. On the other hand,. separate figures are not given for Asiatics and natives. TABLE II. — AVERAGE NUMBER OF LABOUR " A T W O R K " , 1 9 2 5 Coloured employees White employees Province Natal Total TABLE III. Days worked by white employees . . . . Orange Free S t a t e Total On surface Total 797 742 128 9,536 10,149 1,532 4,229 5.165 '546 13,765 15,314 2,078 1,667 21,217 9,940 31,157 — TOTAL NUMBER OF DAYS WORKED, Province Transvaal Underground 1925 Days worked by coloured employees Underground On surface 248,664 231,504 39,936 1,319,448 ' 2,975,232 3,166,488 . 1,611,480 170,352 477,984 520,104 6,619,704 3,101,280 Total 4,294,680 4,777,968 648,336 9,720,984 1 The number of workers "in service" exceeds in general the number of workers "at work" by about 10 per cent. — 259 — It will be seen that of the total labour employed in South African mines, 97 per cent, are coloured workers. Direct returns of manshifts worked and lost are not available. However, an approximate number of days worked during the year may be calculated by multiplying the number of workers given above by 312, which is given as the number of working days in a year. The result obtained by this calculation will be seen from Table III. § 4. The average daily and annual wages may now be computed from the above data for the total of white and of coloured workers. These calculations have been effected by the International Labour Office. TABLE IV. — AVERAGE MONEY WAGES PER DAY AND PER ANNUM, 1 9 2 5 Average wages per day worked Province White Average for Union Coloured Wliite 1 Coloured d. S. d. £ S. 26 8 27 1 23 10 2 2 2 0 0 1 416 422 372 5 2 7 £ s. 31 7 31 4 32 2 26 2 0 415 9 31 S. Transvaal . . . . Natal Orange Free S t a t e . Average wages per year and worker 8 6 The striking difference between the average wages of white employees and the coloured workers shown in the above table requires no comment. As regards native workers, the annual statistics published by the Government Mining Engineer, give the average monthly wage per person working on the mines, classified into Asiatics and natives. They also contain separate information as to the average monthly wages of female workers ; but it is to be observed that the number of female workers covered by these statistics is very small 1 . TABLE V. — AVERAGE MONEY WAGES PER COLOURED EMPLOYEES, 1 9 2 5 MONTH, Native and others Asiatics Province £ Natal Average for Union Female workers Male workers . . . . S. d. 3 12 3 2 9 4 3 5 2 £ 2 2 2 2 2 s. d. 12 3 10 10 13 6 5 6 11 8 £ S. d. 2 14 1 9 7 5 14 10 1 8 4 1 The total wages earned during the year 1925 by female native workers in all provinces, including Cape Province, was not more than £255. — 260 — The above data may be completed by averages for whites given in the annual report of the Government Mining Engineer. These figures show the average pay including allowances, but excluding overtime, "rated per shift" (third Wednesday in June 1925), or "rated per m o n t h " (June 1925). The average for a few principal occupations is given in the following table ; it is, however, to be noted that the number of employees covered is very small, except in the case of coal-miners. TABLE VI. — AVERAGE PAY RATED PER SHIFT OR PER MONTH CERTAIN CLASSES OF WHITE EMPLOYEES, 1 9 2 5 Average rated per shift Province Transvaal Natal Orange Free State . . Number of workers covered Coalminers Screeners s. 23 20 23 d. 2 2 5 s. 18 15 20 d. 2 9 7 52 362 Average rated per month Fitters s. 22 20 22 FOR Mine overseers d. 5 2 0 £ 53 48 65 111 s. 9 1 5 d. 4 6 0 45 Shift bosses £ 41 38 46 s. 6 16 0 d. 6 4 0 51 § 5. Information has been further supplied as to the total output of coal produced, and the average output of coal per year per person " a t work". As regards the total output, the statistics distinguish between coal mined, "waste coal", and coal sold. It should be observed that coal consumed by the mine is partly included in "waste coal", and partly accounted for by the difference in coal mined and the sum of waste and coal sold. The total and average output of coal, expressed in terms of metric tons, in South African mines in 1925 is shown in Table VII. TABLE VII. — TOTAL AND AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL, 1925 (In Metric Tons) Total coal produced (000's omitted) Province Mined Transvaal . . . . Natal Orange Free S t a t e . Waste Sold Coal mined per year (tons) Per under- Per worker ground under and worker above ground 9,024 6,188 1,155 1,206 1,256 111 7,515 4,696 990 923 594 734 620 385 523 16,368 2,573 13,202 750 499 It will be seen from the figures relating to the average annual output per worker that these are very much higher in the Transvaal than in the other provinces and in the Union as a whole ; the contrary is true of the province of Natal. Compared with the European — 261 — countries, South African coal-fields appear to be very productive : the average output in the Transvaal was nearly twice as high as that shown for German Upper Silesia in 1925 (the most productive district in Europe), and the average output in the Union as a whole at least 50 per cent, larger than that in any European country. § 6. On the basis of data given in Tables I and VII, the average money wage paid per ton of coal mined may be calculated. The total wages paid to white and coloured labour has been taken as the divisor. TABLE VIII. — AVERAGE MONEY WAGE PER METRIC TON OF COAL, 1 9 2 5 Province Average per ton of coal mined S. d. 1 Natal Average 8i 2 6f 1 If 2 OJ Average per ton of coal sold S. d . 2 3 2 2 0£ 4\ 3f 6i The above figures indicate that the wage cost is the highest in the province of Natal. Both of the other provinces show a wage cost which is below the average for the whole Union ; the lowest point is reached in the Orange Free State in the case of coal mined, but in the Transvaal as regards the cost of coal sold. In considering these figures, it is of course to be remembered that a considerable part of the real cost of labour is excluded from them. No comparison is therefore possible with the corresponding figures given for other countries. United States of America § 1. The statistics of wages of coal-mining workers in the United States, published by the United States Bureau of Labour Statistics, are not regular, but have rather the character of special enquiries 1. These enquiries have, however, been renewed in recent years at several intervals, and are based on a uniform method. They refer to certain periods in 1919, 1922, 1924, and 1926. For the last-named year, however, the scope of the statistics is limited in that it only covers bituminous coal-mines. Since enquiries relating to the years 1919 and 1922 are limited in scope, and their results are now out of date, it will be convenient to summarise the statistics for the two years 1924 and 1926. 1 U.S. DEPARTMENT OP LABOUR ; BUREAU OF LABOUR STATISTICS : Hours and Earnings in Anthracite and Bituminous Coal-Mining, 1922 and 1924 (Bulletin No. 416), Washington, Sept. 1926 ; and Hours and Earnings in Bituminous Coal-Mining, 1922, 1924, and 1926 (Bulletin No. 454), Washington, Nov. 1927. A further special enquiry into labour conditions in the coal industry was made by the United States Coal Commission for the year 1921, with complementary information for 1922. The wage data given are, however, out of date and have not been utilised for the present note. — 262 — A particular characteristic of the statistics of wages in the American coal-mines is its division into two distinct parts, viz. that referring to the anthracite or hard coal industry, and that covering bituminous or soft coal.. Both the natural, industrial, and labour conditions are, in fact, different in the anthracite and bituminous coal-fields. Practically all of the anthracite mines lie within a small area in North-Eastern Pennsylvania, and this geographical situation has favoured concentration of ownership and the integration of the producing part of the industry;, the mine-workers are organised into strong unions. The methods of payments of wages are nevertheless very varied, the miners being paid a widely differing rate in different mines for the same kind of work. The bituminous coal-mines are scattered over thirty-one States and Alaska, employ four times as many men as the anthracite industry, produce about five to seven times as much coal, and present a great variety of industrial and labour conditions, from the most primitive to the most highly organised. In view of the importance of the industrial organisation, the bituminous coal-fields are usually classified into "union fields," i.e. mining districts where workers are organised, and "non-union fields". In the "union fields" wage rates are fairly uniform, the same rate being paid throughout a district and sometimes throughout the State, and wage adjustments occur only at stated intervals. Taking the industry as a whole, however, the standardisation is by no means complete and the variations in the rates within and between different coal-mines are still very marked. Generally speaking, the wage level of the union fields is determined by wage negotiations of the "central competitive field" (Illinois, Indiana, Ohio, and West Pennsylvania). In other organised areas (South-Western inter-State field consisting of Kansas, Missouri, Oklahoma, and Arkansas, as well as Iowa, Michigan, Kentucky, Montana, West Virginia, Wyoming, etc.) rates are agreed upon in separate joint conferences. In the non-union fields the wage rates are fixed by individual bargaining and consequently show greater differences than those prevailing in the union fields. These circumstances, peculiar to the United States, should be borne in mind when considering the methods and results of the wage statistics of the American coal industry. § 2. The statistics of the Bureau of Labour Statistics cover neither the whole of the coal industry nor the entire year to which they refer. They are based on the representative method both as regards mines covered and periods investigated. (i) The data are secured from the records of a certain number of representative mines in 11 principal States, viz : Alabama, Colorado, Illinois, Indiana, Kansas, Kentucky, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, Virginia, West Virginia. The degree in which these States, and the mines for which data are presented, represent the coal-mining industry in general is seen from Table I. As regards the bituminous coal industry, it will be seen from this table that it is largely concentrated in the eleven States covered ; about 92 per cent, of the total American production and about 90 per cent, of the total number of coal-mining employees in 1924 and 1926 were in these States. The scope of the statistics is, however, further limited by the choice of representative mines, the — 263 — TABLE I. — SCOPE OF THE AMERICAN WAGE STATISTICS, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 Total output of coal—metric tons-000's omitted Number of mines Number of wage earners 1924 1924 160,009 44,500 79,750 56 1924 1926 All mines in the 11 States 1924 covered by the statistics . 1926 Mines covered in the 11 States 1924 1926 7,586 7,144 6,439 6,018 Ö99 556 619,604 588,493 559,956 534,315 140,719 148,155 438,704 471,688 405,240 438,661 Mines and States Year Anthracite: Pennsylvania : All mines . . „ Mines covered Bituminous: All mines in all States . . . — number of which was in 1924 7.9 per cent, of the total number of mines and in 1926 7.8 per cent. The number of wage earners employed in these representative mines was in the anthracite mines (in 1924) 28 per cent, of the total number of employees ; in bituminous coalmines (in 1924) 23 per cent, and (in 1926) 25 per cent, of the total. (ii) The sample pay-roll period to which the data refer is in all cases half a month. Since the anthracite coal-field is limited to one State, the data have been secured from all companies for the same payroll periods, viz. half-months ending 31 October or 15 November 1924. The same method was not practicable in respect to bituminous €oal-mines, as the field of enquiry has been extended over mines in a great number of States. The pay-roll periods considered vary within a period of three months (October to December) in 1924, and November and December in 1926, being extended in several cases to January, February, and March 1927. All data are taken directly from the mines records by agents of the Bureau of Labour Statistics ; only a few companies have themselves made a copy of the wage data from their records according to instructions of the Bureau. Since the half-month covered by the statistics has not been identical for all mining companies, the number of working days in the different half-months has been 11, 12, 13, or 14. When some employees are shown as having made more days, this is because they worked on Sundays as well as weekdays. § 3. The basis of calculating the average earnings is formed by the aggregate earnings of each occupational group in the half-month period covered. The composition of the earnings in both anthracite and bituminous collieries may be briefly stated as follows. The "gross earnings" include, first, wages received on the basis of rates for coal cut or for hour or day work. They include also in most cases a number of items of cost which are called occupational charges, such as the cost of powder, dynamite, electric exploders, fuses and caps used by miners and loaders in blasting coal from the seams, carbide, lamp oil, machine oil, blacksmithing and tool sharpening, as well as payment for the wages of a checkweighman, — 264 — etc., items necessary for the purpose of work and for which the employee pays. They include also lodging free of charge or at reduced rent, household coal free of charge or at reduced prices, and severat store supplies. The net earnings" mean earnings after deductions from gross earnings of the occupational costs or charges. The reports indicate that there are very few companies which do not charge employees. for explosives or for tool sharpening. The statistics take into account "net earnings". However, t h e aggregate amount of net earnings is not shown in the statistics as. published. § 4. A very complete classification by occupations of the coalmining employees is given in the American statistics. It will be convenient at the outset to define several specific terms used in theclassification : By tonnage men are meant miners and loaders who are employed on the piece-wage rate basis 1 . Anthracite miners paid exclusively on piece-rates are called "contract miners",which is the basic occupation. in anthracite coal-mining. Most of them have one or more helpersgenerally known as "contract miners' labourers" whose wages are paid principally from the gross earnings of the contract miners, only a small part being paid by the company. In bituminous coal-mines,. pick or hand miners, machine-miners, as well as hand and machine loaders (underground) are all usually paid tonnage rates. Among these,. two special occupations are further to be distinguished, viz. "gang miners" who work in groups dividing their earnings equally regardless of the kind of work performed ; and "contract hand loaders" whoemploy one or more helpers whom they pay out of their earnings.. Their importance is small, however. By company men are understood all workers paid on the time-rate basis. In anthracite collieries some of the regular contract miners who, in consequence of obstructions in their working chambers or rooms, or bad working conditions, are unable to earn on a tonnage basis an amount equal to a specified rate per day, are paid this rate until they are able to earn more.on a tonnage basis ; these "consideration miners" thus form an intermediate class between tonnage and company men. In the anthracite mines, further, some miners who seldom mine coal but operate machines, drill holes, and load cars, are entirely working on the time basis and are called "company miners".. Corresponding crafts do not exist in bituminous coal-mines. All. other company men fill auxiliary occupations, other than mining.. The two principal groups of these company men are "inside men"„ i.e. underground workers other than miners and loaders, and "outside men" i.e. surface employees. The occupational classification given in the American statistics includes nearly sixty different crafts. The classes for which data are: presented are given below : Anthracite Mines Miners and their Labourers. (a) Tonnage men : Contract miners ; Contract miners' labourers. (b) Company men : Company miners ; Company miners' labourers ;: Consideration miners ; Consideration miners' labourers. 1. 1 The term "miner" as used in the American statistics refers to hewer,. and not to mine-worker generally. — 265 — 2. Employees other than Miners. (a) Company men, inside : Blacksmiths ; Cagers ; Car runners p Door tenders (boys) ; Drivers ; Engineers ; Labourers ; Machinists ; Masons ; Motormen ; Motor-brakemen ; Pumpmen ; Timbermen ; Trackmen ; Other employees. (b) Company men, outside : Ashmen ; Blacksmiths ; Cagers ; Carpenters ; Car-runners ; Dumpers ; Engineers ; Firemen ; Jigrunners ; Labourers ; Loaders ; Machinists ; Oilers ; Platemen ; Repair men ; Slaters (boys) ; Timber cutters ; Trackmen ; Other employees. Bituminous Coal-Mines 1. Miners and Loaders (Tonnage Men). Gang miners : Hand or pick miners ; Machine miners (cutters); Machine miners' helpers ; Contract loaders ; Hand loaders ; Machine loaders. 2. Employees other than Miners and Loaders (Company Men). (a) Inside workmen : Brakemen ; Bratticemen and timbermen ; Cagers ; Drivers ; Labourers ; Motormen ; Pumpmen ; Trackmen ; Trappers (boys) ; Other employees. (b) Outside workmen: Blacksmiths ; Carpenters and car repair men ; Engineers ; Firemen ; Labourers ; Other employees. Table II (page 266) gives the number of coal-mining employees covered by the statistics, cJassified by occupation. The number of workers is as recorded in the colliery books at the time of the enquiry. Owing to the importance of the group of miners and loaders, each occupation is shown separately ; but as regards employees other than miners and loaders, i.e. company men inside and outside the mine, only the principal occupations are shown separately. It will be seen from Table II that in the anthracite collieries miners. and their labourers form 53 per cent, of the total number of employees covered ; other inside men form 24 per cent, and all inside men 77 per cent, of the total ; outside men or surface workers represent 23 per cent, of the total number of workers. The percentages are rather different in the bituminous coal mines. Miners and loaders constituted both in 1924 and 1926, 65 per cent, of the total number of employees covered ; other inside men 24 per cent, (in 1924) and 25 per cent. (in 1926) and all inside men taken together, 89 per cent. (1924) and 90 per cent. (1926) ; the number of surface workers was not more than 11 per cent. (1924), and 10 per cent. (1926) of the total number of employees. The statistics published by the United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of Mines, which refer to the total number of coal-mining employees in the country, show that these proportions are approximately representative for American coal-mining. Table III (page 267) shows the number of mines and employees in bituminous coal-mining, classified by States. Separate figures are only given for the three largest and most representative groups of coal-mining employees, viz. miners and loaders taken together, labourers inside and labourers outside the mine. § 5. The American wage statistics give three different averages, namely, average net earnings per start, per hour of worker, and for the half-month period covered. — 266 — TABLE II. — NUMBER OF MINES AND COAL-MINING EMPLOYEES COVERED BY THE WAGE STATISTICS, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY OCCUPATION N u m b e r of mines reporting Occupation Anthracite 1924 1926 47 — — 47 22 — — 22 55 53 Consideration miners . Consideration miners' laContraot miners . . . . Contract miners' la- Number of employees covered Anthracite 1924 Miners and loaders : Company miners . . . Company miners' la- Contract workers . . . Bituminous 1924 1926 1,735 — — — — 1,699 961 — — — — — — — — 748 • 11,778 — — — — — — 6,794 — — — — — —' — — — 170 1,036 61,936 21,424 102 6,499 — 61 32 488 254 23 464 151 56 599 556 23,715 91,167 96,010 — 62 55 50 55 56 547 377 602 548 587 599 518 320 500 520 554 556 1,054 2,388 733 406 5,840 4,259 4,603 7,228 3,751 4,026 9,657 4,368 4,530 8,823 4,239 4,246 10,733 56 599 556 10,421 33,524 36,939 55 53 56 591 550 7,877 599 — 556 2,612 1,103 6,649 7,514 — Total 56 599 556 10,364 16,028 15,206 Grand total. . . . 56 599 556 44,500 140,719 148,155 — — • Hand or pick miners.. . Machine loaders . . . . Machine miners . . . . Machine miners' helpers. Total Other inside men : Other employees inside . Total Ontsido men : Other employees outside — — —. — — 24 40 514 291 10 485 1924 Bituminous —. — — 8,514 694 1,065 66,414 20,594 306 6,055 882 — 7,329 (i) The start means a day on which aminer had coal hoisted. This measure may or may not be the equivalent of a full-time working day. The relevant figures are therefore subject to some error. On the one hand, one or more cars of coal may be dumped in the morning from a previous day and the employee credited with a start despite the fact that he was not in attendance ; on the other hand, a whole day could be spent clearing falls of rock and doing other work preparatory to mining, when no coal was hoisted and no credit for attendance given. Counting the days when a miner works without having coal hoisted tends to offset, in the aggregate, the error of considering men at work when coal is dumped and credited to them when they are not in the mine. — 267 — TABLE III. — NUMBER OF MINES AND EMPLOYEES IN BITUMINOUS COAL-MINING, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES State Year Alabama. . . . Colorado . . . Illinois . . . • Indiana . . . . Kansas . . . . Kentucky . . . Ohio Pennsylvania . Tennessee . . . Virginia . . . West Virginia All States . . Number of employees covered Number of mines Miners and Labourers Labourers All mining reporting loaders inside mine outside employees mine 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 39 36 17 17 46 39 23 17 9 11 79 86 57 45 155 151 20 . 14 12 22 142 118 4,968 5,230 2,448 2,318 15,769 16,945 3,627 3,052 1,474 1,749 8,802 11,762 7,637 7,600 29,190 29,821 1,873 1,271 1,121 2,227 14,258 14,036 736 965 69 61 1,097 1,122 167 151 21 21 1,017 1,661 213 505 2,012 2,081 126 111 98 345 1,672 1,800 580 620 210 234 765 778 192 162 37 53 999 1,190 441 474 2,017 2,098 157 146 136 292 1,980 1,830 8,495 9,078 3,797 3,616 22,749 23,555 5,177 4,469 1,874 2,173 15,003 20,024 10,645 10,817 42,796 43,693 2,902 2,092 1,908 4,034 25,473 24,604 1924 1926 599 556 91,167 96,010 7,228 8,823 7,514 7,877 140,719 148,155 (ii) The method of recording the total number of hours worked in the half-month period covered has been already explained x. It will be seen that two time units have been determined in respect of miners and loaders, namely, (a) the total time in the mine, including the hours worked, the average travel time inside the mine, and such time as may be taken for lunch ; (b) the time at the face, excluding the average travel time, but including time for lunch, i.e. actual hours at the face or place of work in the mine. As regards the other employees, i.e. company men (excluding company miners and day labourers in anthracite mines) the actual hours worked, including time for lunch, are given. The average number of hours per start is obtained by dividing the average number of hours per half-month by the average number of starts. (iii) For the calculation of the average earnings for half-month, the number of workers in each occupation and in each State is necessary. 1 See Appendix V, section A. — 268 — The average number of starts and the average hours worked in the half-month period and per start, have been given above in connection with the discussion on hours of labour in the United States 1 . It appears from these tables that both the number of starts and the hours worked during the sample period have been larger in anthracite mines t h a n in bituminous mines. In the former, tonnage miners work less starts and much shorter hours than other miners and all company men. The maximum hours are worked, on the average, by motormen underground, and by outside labourers. As regards bituminous mines, the figures for 1926 are regularly higher than those for 1924. This is due to a general depression in bituminous mining in 1924, resulting in less work in many mines in several States covered. It appears further that hand miners and hand loaders work shorter hours than machine workers and loaders ; even when time for lunch and travel in the mine are included, these crafts work fewer hours in the half-month than employees in any other occupation. The hours of company men inside and outside do not show considerable differences. The number of starts and the hours in the different States covered in the statistics, show considerable variation. The number of employees has been given above in Tables II and III. § 6. On the basis of the record of the aggregate earnings of the employees in the half-month pay period, the recorded time of work and the number of workers, the average earnings are calculated as follows : (i) Average earnings per start are obtained by dividing the total of the actual earnings of all employees in the occupation by the total number of the starts worked in the half-month payroll period considered. (ii) Average earnings per hour are obtained by dividing the total of the actual earnings of all the employees in the occupation by the total of (a) the "hours in mine" or (b) the "hours at face" worked in the half-month pay-roll period. (iii) Average earnings in half-month are obtained by dividing the total of the actual earnings of all the employees in the occupation by the total number of these employees. These averages are summarised in respect of the principal occupations in Tables IV and V. It appears from these tables that the average earnings of "contract miners" in the anthracite mines are considerably higher than those of other groups ; their average earnings per hour and in the half-month are the highest in the United States. The average earnings of company miners' labourers (which group receives the lowest wages) are less than 60 per cent, of those of contract miners. In the bituminous mines the group of "gang" and "machine miners" form a conspicuous exception as earning much higher wages than all other categories of workers in these mines. Their average earnings per start show the maximum for the whole American coal industry, and their earnings per hour and in the half-month are next to those received by contract miners. The earnings of the two largest groups, viz. "hand miners" and "hand loaders" do not differ considerably from one another ; owing to the relatively high wages of the 1 See Appendix V, section A. — 269 — TABLE IV. — AVERAGE EARNINGS OF MINERS AND LOADERS, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY OCCUPATION Average earnings per start Kind of mine and occupation Time n mine 1924 Anthracite Company miners . . Do. labourers. . . Consideration miners Do. labourers. . . Contract miners . . Do. labourers. . . All miners and their labourers . . . . 6.49 5.72 7.26 6.21 9.07 6.47 — — — 7.77 Bituminous Contract loaders . . Gang miners . . . . Hand l o a d e r s . . . . Hand miners . . . . Machine loaders. . . Machine miners . . Do. helpers 7.82 9.66 6.32 6.26 6.20 9.65 All miners and loaders 6.60 — 1926 $ $ $ 0.747 0.655 0.876 0.722 1.327 0.903 —. — — — — — 67.15 58.57 78.99 65.98 98.07 65.39 — — — — — — — 1.064(a) — 81.59(a) 0.784 1.260 0.715 0.715 0.735 1.101 0.637 0.929 1.187 0.811 0.808 0.690 1.163 74.26 77.79 51.29 53.02 58.20 84.79 — 0.849 1.377 0.779 0.783 0.788 1.195 0.681 — 72.43 108.33 57.48 60.31 68.80 102.68 53.77 0.749 0.843 0.817 64.44 61.61 $ $ 0.694 0.607 0.820 0.676 1.204 0.826 — — — —. — — — • — 7.16 • 0.881 11.36 1.094 6.12 0.748 6.18 0.744 6.96 0.644 9.93 1.079 6.14 — 6.46 1924 1926 $ 0.777 T i m e a t face including lunch 1926 1924 1926 $ A v e r a g e earnings A v e r a g e earnings per hour 1924 $ — (a) These averages are not given in the official report and are calculated on the basis of the average earnings per start, the average number of starts, and the average number of hours per start for all miners (cf. Bulletin No. 416, p. 26). TABLE V. — AVERAGE EARNINGS OF COAL "MINING EMPLOYEES, OTHER THAN MINERS AND LOADERS, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY OCCUPATIONS Average earnings per start Occupation Anthra- Bituminous Anthracite cite 1924 1 1924 Inside men : Brakemen . Drivers . . . Labourers. . Motormen. . Trackmen. . Outside men : Labourers. . Slaters (boys) All inside and outside men. A v e r a g e earnings per hour 1926 1924 Bituminous 1924 | 1926 Average earnings in half-month Anthra cite Bituminous 1924 j 1924 1926 S ? $ $ $ $ $ $ $ 5.46 5.68 6.60 6.47 5.96 6.12 5.47 6.46 6.14 5.82 5.88 5.18 6.27 5.92 0.632 0.664 0.703 0.741 0.710 0.748 0.657 0.752 0.737 0.687 0.708 0.620 0.718 0.705 61.83 63.05 75.32 77.39 53.25 54.08 48.74 62.89 59.83 57.61 59.80 48.82 67.97 64.15 5.24 3.08 4.93 4.74 0.577 0.575 0.546 63.10 46.73 50.63 35.68 0.371 — 5.92 5.70 — 0.696 0.664 — 57.81 60.87 — 270 — machine miners, as well as of the small groups of "gang miners" and "contract loaders", the average for all miners and loaders is somewhat above the average for hand miners and loaders. In general, the earnings in the half-month of miners and loaders in bituminous mines are below those received in anthracite mines, but on account of the smaller number of starts and of the shorter hours worked in the half-month by the bituminous coal-workers, the differences are smaller in the case of daily and hourly averages. Comparing wages earned in 1924 and 1926 in bituminous mines, it will be seen that averages per start and per hour were less in 1926 than in 1924 (except for a few occupations), while the aggregate earnings in the half-month, owing to a high average of starts and hours worked, were higher in 1926. Table VI shows the average earnings for all miners and loaders taken together and Table VII t h a t for labourers inside and outside mines, classified by States. The American statistics do not give averages per hour and per half-month in respect of miners and loaders for 1924. TABLE VI. — AVERAGE EARNINGS OF MINERS AND LOADERS IN BITUMINOUS Year State Alabama . . . Colorado . . . Illinois . . . . Indiana. . . . Kansas . . . . Kentucky. . . Ohio Pennsylvania . Tennessee. . . Virginia COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES . . . "West Virginia All S t a t e s . . Average earnings per Average Average hour earnings in earnings per half-month Time in mine Time at face start 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 $ 4.57 4.57 7.23 6.31 8.55 8.90 8.56 8.20 5.92 5.83 5.63 5.18 7.17 6.71 6.40 6.18 4.08 3.49 4.65 5.04 6.10 5.85 1924 1926 6.60 6.46 •a 0.481 0.530 40.92 ' 0.730 0.804 64.12 0.999 1.100 84.76 1.055 1.134 79.61 0.761 0.809 54.53 0.616 0.656 47.09 0.793 0.861 62.77 0.693 0.759 61.03 0.409 0.441 29.63 0.587 0.629 46.30 0.743 0.811 56.00 0.749 0.817 61.61 — 271 — TABLE VII, — AVERAGE EARNINGS OF LABOURERS INSIDE AND OUTSIDE MINE IN BITUMINOUS COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES Average earnings of labourers inside mine Year 1924 1926 1924 Colorado. . 1926 1924 Illinois . . • 1926 1924 Indiana . . 1926 1924 Kansas . . 1926 1924 Kentucky . 1926 1924 Ohio . . . 1926 .1924 Pennsylvania 1926 1924 Tennessee . • 1926 1924 Virginia . . 1926 1924 West Virginia 1926 1924 All States 1926 Alabama. . Average earnings of labourers outside mine Per start Per hour In halfmouth Per start Per hour In halfmonth $ 3.38 3.46 7.36 5.36 7.32 7.36 7.59 7.47 •7.53 6.91 4.54 4.32 7.17 6.58 6.16 5.65 . 3.20 2.93 3.12 3.58 4.54 4.54 5.47 5.18 $ 0.383 0.398 0.921 0.664 0.915 0.911 0.940 0.934 0.941 0.857 0.532 0.507 0.866 0.859 0.744 0.676 0.396 0.372 0.388 0.426 0.543 0.536 0.657 0.620 28.73 29.55 65.46 66.73 63.08 72.64 56.89 68.76 80.37 61.22 38.02 35.77 63.48 54.27 60.58 60.18 24.90 22.16 23.84 29.97 39.89 44.51 48.74 48.82 ? $ 2.53 2.54 6.27 4.71 7.07 7.31 6.81 6.82 7.62 6.82 4.00 3.77 6.92 6.77 5.51 4.99 3.03 2.70 3.02 3.16 4.08 4.23 4.93 4.74 $ 0.284 0.288 0.716 0.519 0.863 0.858 0.850 0.829 0.865 0.831 0.467 0.437 0.859 0.847 0.626 0.563 0.379 0.339 0.367 0.361 0.477 0.482 0.575 0.546 20.39 24.09 55.53 56.41 65.36 80.77 48.64 72.90 76.77 76.29 36.55 39.44 63.24 67.97 56.20 65.11 26.64 23.64 25.33 30.49 40.44 45.93 46.73 50.53 ? It appears from these tables that average earnings are rather different in the various States, and that these differences have remained constant for the period 1924-1926. Comparing the average earnings of all workers, it will be seen that the highest earnings were received in the States of Illinois, Indiana and Ohio, i.e. in the principal p a r t of the "central competitive field". Pennsylvania, which also belongs to this field, shows a level of earnings which is very near the average for all States. Apart from these States, also Colorado (in most. cases) and Kansas (in some cases) exceed the average level of earnings for the whole country. In all other States, earnings are usually below the general average and are least in the States of Tennessee and Alabama. § 7. On the basis of average earnings in the half-month, the American statistics make further an estimate of the amount t h a t would have been earned in twelve months, had all the employees worked every day of operation during the twelve months a t the average earnings they received during the half-month covered by t h e study. — 272 — For this calculation the average number of days of operation during the year concerned is required. This number has been calculated in two ways in respect of the year 1924. On the one hand, the Bureau of Labour Statistics has recorded the number of days of operation for the twelve months ending 31 October 1924 in all mines covered by the enquiry (except 50 bituminous coal-mines for which no data were available). On the other hand, the United States Geological Survey has ascertained the average days of operation in the calendar year 1924 for all mines in each State ; this number is weighed by the total number of employees in all occupations of each mine ; and the average number of days of operation in all States covered is obtained Jay weighing the days of operation for each State by the number of miners and loaders employed, as shown in Table III. For the year 1926, the average number of days of operation for mines reporting TABLE VIII. — AVERAGE NUMBER OF DAYS OF OPERATION IN YEAR, AND ESTIMATED POSSIBLE AVERAGE YEARLY EARNINGS OF MINERS AND LOADERS, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES Kind ot mine, and State Anthracite Pennsylvania . Bituminous Alabama . . . Colorado . . . Illinois . . . Indiana. . . . Kansas . . . . Kentucky. Ohio . . . . . . . Pennsylvania . Tennessee. . . Virginia . . . West Virginia Total, bituminous . . . possible average Average days of operation Estimated yearly earnings Year In mines reporting In all mines in State In mines reporting S In all mines in State $ 1924 286.7 274 2,228 2,129 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 231.2 1,057 200.3 220 266 178, 202 148 172 136 173 151 158 174 230 143 159 180 224 159 234 226 263 182 247 1,005 1,216 1,287 1,275 1.265 1,531 1,164 1,419 894 921 980 1,191 1,025 1,067 1,152 1,384 649 817 1,051 1,326 1,110 1,445 1924 1926 198.2 187.0 173.5 147.7 192.9 177.7 215.2 185.6 242.5 204.4 172 214 1,352 1,483 1,264 1,142 1,128 1,274 1,377 757 1,128 1,247 1,300 1,128 1,382 — 273 — has not been computed by the Bureau of Labour Statistics, and only the average number for all mines in each State, calculated by the United States Bureau of Mines, is available. The annual earnings are computed on the basis of the number of days of operation, by multiplying this number by the average earnings per start. The average days of operation and the estimated possible average yearly earnings in 1924 and in 1926 are seen in Table VIII. The difference between the anthracite and bituminous coal-mines is striking. Anthracite mining is limited in area and in number and capacity of collieries. The annual production of an anthracite coalmine seldom exceeds the demand, and consequently the collieries have been operated nearly the full number of working days in each year. Hence the estimated possible yearly earnings are very high, as compared with those paid in bituminous coal-mining. Bituminous mining is very extensive in area, and the number and capacity of mines are large. Production would be much in excess of demand should all the mines in the industry be operated nearly full time, or approximately 300 days per year. Many mines, however, have been in operation much less than 300 days per year, due primarily to lack of a market or of orders. As a consequence the estimated possible yearly earnings are on an average only 60 per cent, of those of anthracite mines. Another noteworthy difference is between the number of days of operation and the estimated annua] earnings in bituminous mines, as calculated for the mines reporting and for all mines. The number of days of operation and consequently average yearly earnings are superior for the former group of mines. This is due to the fact that mines seldom, if ever, record hours per start, and that therefore mines in operation in the latter part of 1924, to which period the statistics refer, were selected for the study, and many of the other mines may have been in operation in the early part of 1924, although they were closed in the latter part *. Finally, it is seen that the average number of days of operation, and the average number of earnings differ widely from State to State and from the year 1924 to 1926. The general average of days of operation of the States included increased from 172 in 1924 (which year was particularly irregular) to 214 in 1926. Further, the average number of days of operation in all mines ranged (in 1924) from 136 for Indiana to 226 for Virginia, and (in 1926) from 158 in Kansas to 266 for Alabama. The estimated average earnings were the highest in 1924 in the States of Colorado and Illinois, and in 1926 in the States of Illinois, West Virginia, and Indiana. The lowest earnings were received in both years in the States of Tennessee and Kansas. § 8. Information as to the production of coal is calculated by the United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of Mines. Table IX shows the total tonnage of coal raised and its distribution for different uses for the country as a whole. The figures relate to calendar years 1924, 1925, and 1926 ; the distribution of the total tonnage raised between different uses is distinct from that given in 1 This condition, however, does not materially affect the representative character of the average hours or earnings in the half-month period covered since the mines kept a special day-by-day record of hours for each of the workers considered. 18 — 274 — respect of European countries : the American statistics distinguish between tonnage used at mines for steam and heat, tonnage made into coke at mines, tonnage sold to local trade and used by employees, and, finally, tonnage loaded at mine for shipment. TABLE IX. — TOTAL PRODUCTION OF COAL-MINES, 1924 TO 1926 (Metric Tons — 000's Omitted) Tonnage Tonnage Tonnage sold to used at made into local trade mines for coke at and used steam and mines by heat employees Year Total tonnage raised 1 ¡ 1924 Anthracite . . . 1925 ; 1926 79,750 56,068 76,584 6,925 4,684 5,833 Kind of mines Tonnage loaded at mines for shipment 2,761 2,617 2,437 70,064 48,767 68,314 i Bituminous coal 1924 1925 1926 438,704 471,688 520,044 6,002 5,239 5,195 13,054 14,288 16,101 19,148 19,365 21,407 400,500 432,796 477,341 All coal . . . 1924 1925 1926 518,454 527,756 596,629 12,927 9,923 11,028 13,054 14,288 16,101 21,909 21,982 23,844 470,564 481,563 545,655 The above figures show t h a t of the total tonnage of coal raised, 11 to 13 per cent, in the anthracite collieries and 8 to 9 per cent, in the bituminous mines were used at mines and by the mining employees, and sold to local trade. A difference between anthracite. and bituminous mines is that the tonnage used at mines for steam and heat is about 8 per cent, in the former mines, but not more than 3 per cent, in the latter. In order to calculate the average output for the eleven principal States covered by the wage statistics, it is necessary to know the tonnage raised, the number of employees and the average number of days worked in each State. The last-named number has been given in Table V I I I above. The other elements are shown in Table X. The most important States from the point of view of production are Pennsylvania, West Virginia, Illinois, and Kentucky ; the least important among the eleven States separately shown are Tennessee and Kansas. The "central competitive field" (States of Illinois, Indiana, Ohio, and Pennsylvania) produced, in 1926, about 48 per cent, of the total production of bituminous coal in the United States. — 275 — TABLE X. — TOTAL PRODUCTION AND NUMBER OF WORKERS IN ANTHRACITE AND BITUMINOUS COAL-MINES, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES Kind ot mine, and State Anthracite Pennsylvania Year Total number of workers Total tonnage raised during Under and the year in Underground above ground metric tons (000's omitted) 1924 1926 79,750 76,584 119,363 126,231 160,009 165,386 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 17,351 19,048 9,473 9,648 61,969 62,916 19,482 21,030 3,853 4,005 40,948 57,072 27,639 25,280 118,485 138,809 4,133 5,251 9,699 12,819 92,208 438,703 130,163 520,044 23,108 23,024 11,001 10,854 80,757 68,288 23,927 20,041 7,432 6,831 46,567 51,664 38,447 33,852 147,085 135,959 7,962 6,750 10,386 11,567 85,547 531,904 99,952 510,824 27,956 27,345 12,954 12,815 89,363 75,870 27,558 23,404 8,561 8,172 55,766 60,578 44,229 38,547 169,322 155,999 9,365 7,948 12,679 13,764 102,203 619,604 118,726 593,647 All anthracite and bit- 1924 uminous mines . . . 1926 518,454 596,628 651,267 637,055 779,613 759,033 Bituminous Colorado Indiana Ohio Pennsylvania Tennessee West Virginia All bituminous mines. The average output of coal raised in the years 1924 and 1926 will be seen from Table XL The average "per man per d a y " is calculated by twice dividing the total tonnage raised, viz. first b y the total number of employers, and then by the average number of days of operation (as shown in Table IX). This average can be computed only in respect of all mine employees, since the average days of operation are not given separately for underground workers. The average "per man per year" is the result of the total tonnage of coal raised, divided by the number of underground workers, or t h a t of all employees. — 276 — TABLE XI. — AVERAGE OUTPUT OF COAL IN ANTHRACITE AND BITUMINOUS MINES, 1 9 2 4 AND 1 9 2 6 , BY STATES (Metric Tons) Average outpw Kind of mine, and State Year Per man per day Per man jer year Under and above ground Underground Anthracite Pennsylvania . . . . Under and above ground 1924 1926 1.81 1.90 668 607 498 463 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 1924 1926 2.82 2.62 4.10 3.73 4.68 4.82 5.22 5.19 2.98 3.10 4.24 4.10 4.37 4.13 3.87 3.97 2.77 2.82 3.38 3.54 4.97 4.44 751 827 861 889 767 921 814 1,049 518 586 879 . 1,105 719 747 806 1,021 519 778 934 1,108 1,078 1,302 621 697 731 753 693 829 707 899 450 490 734 942 625 656 700 890 441 661 765 931 902 1,096 All bituminous mines 1924 1926 4.14 4.07 825 1,018 708 876 All anthracite and bituminous mines . 3.46 3.56 796 937 665 786 Bituminous Colorado Indiana Kentucky Ohio p. West Virginia 1924 1926 Marked differences may be observed between the different coalfields in respect of the average output. The first point to be noticed is t h a t in the anthracite coal-fields the average output is considerably lower than in the bituminous coal-fields 1 ; in the State of Pennsylvania, the average daily output of anthracite is less than half of that of bituminous coal. Owing to the larger number of days of operation in the anthracite industry, the average annual output in anthracite mines falls short of that in bituminous mines much less than does the average daily output. 1 A few bituminous coal districts (not shown in the table) have a still lower average output per day, but the production in the States concerned is negligible. — 277 — As regards particularly bituminous mines, the highest average daily output in both years considered is shown for Indiana, Illinois and West Virginia ; there are, however, other States, not shown in Table XI, where the average output attains a level considerably above the maxima given in the table 1 . Of the other States, Kentucky and Ohio show an average output above the average for the whole of the United States ; all other States are below it, and the average output in Alabama and Tennessee is among the lowest averages in the whole country. Owing to the varying number of days of operation, the average yearly output shows results somewhat different from the daily average output. There is a noteworthy difference between the two years considered: the average yearly output in 1924 was much below that shown for 1926 in all States. The highest average is shown in all cases for West Virginia, while the States of Virginia and Kentucky come in the second and third place. The lowest average is shown for Kansas, Tennessee and Alabama, and (in 1926) Ohio. These yearly averages, it should be noted, are a result of the daily output and the regularity of operation, and thus do not indicate as well as the daily averages the productivity of coal-mining. It may be stated that in the United States the high-wage States are, as a rule, at the same time districts where the productivity is relatively large, and vice versa, a low level of earnings usually corresponds to relatively low productivity. When the average output in the United States is compared with the corresponding figures calculated for other countries, it will be easily ascertained that the "productivity", as shown by the average daily output per worker, is in the United States by far the highest in the whole world. It is about twice as high as in South Africa, more than thrice as high as in the most productive European coal district (German Upper Silesia), more than four times as high as in Great Britain, and eight times as high as in India or Japan. § 9. In conclusion, a few remarks may be made on the subject of the "wage cost" of production of coal in the United States. Official statistics contain no information on this point, and as a matter of fact, the data available do hardly permit of any accurate calculations. However, a rough approximation may be attempted on the basis of the statistics of earnings of representative mines. It should be observed that these earnings, as defined in the American statistics 2, correspond fairly well to the concept of "actual earnings" (excluding employers' contributions to social insurance) outlined in the present enquiry. 1 These States are Montana, Utah, North Dakota, and Wyoming. With regard to Utah, however, the daily average is probably too high because of the practice of men going into mines to shoot coal and load mine cars on days when mines as a whole are not in operation. The maximum daily output in 1926 was 6.5 metric tons (Montana) and the annual output 1,124 tons (Utah). 2 Cf. above, S 3. — 278 — In the absence of data relative to the total wages bill, the method of the estimate should be to divide the amount of average earnings per man per day by the tonnage of average output per man per day. Now, the average earnings of all mine-workers taken together are not given in the American wage statistics. In order to obtain this average, it is therefore necessary to use the same method as is employed in the American statistics themselves, in the calculation of the average earnings for all States. Given the average earnings of all miners and loaders, as well as the average earnings of all other (inside and outside) employees, a general average for all employees may be obtained by weighing each of the former averages by the number of employees in each group. This calculation can be effected in respect of bituminous mines only, the result being as follows : Average for miners and loaders . . . Average for other employees . . . . Weighted average for all employees 1924 1926 6.60 5.92 6.36 6.46 5.70 6.19 These averages refer to the representative mines covered by the wage statistics. It should now be remembered that the ratio of miners and loaders to other employees is about the same in the mines covered and in all mines of the United States ; consequently the weights used are applicable to the country as a whole. If then the average earnings per start (day) given in the American statistics are really representative, as there is sufficient reason to assume, then also the above averages for all employees may be applied to the United States as a whole. Dividing the above amounts by the average tonnage produced per day, and converting them into terms of gold francs, the average wage cost of a ton of bituminous coal* raised will be : In 1924 In 1926 ? 1.55 = 8.04 gold francs. ? 1.52 = 7.86 gold francs. ft should be emphasised that these results are only rough estimates because the average earnings only refer to a half-month period in some mines (representing little more than a quarter of all mining employees in the country), while the average output is for the whole year, and for all mines in the country, and is itself calculated on the basis of an approximate number of employees. But, strictly speaking, the corresponding figures calculated for other countries are also more or less approximate. At any rate, it does not seem inappropriate to compare the general tendency of the average wage cost in the United States, as shown above, with the corresponding cost in other countries. It will then be seen that the wage cost in American bituminous mines is relatively low ; it is not lower than in the 1 As the tables given above show, the earnings received in the anthracite mines are,; in general, somewhat higher than in bituminous mining, while the average output is less. Consequently, the average wage cost per ton must be in the anthracite mines considerably higher than in the bituminous mines. — 279 — European districts which show the smallest wage per ton, viz. Poland and Gez-man Upper Silesia, but it is about at the same level as the cost in Czechoslovakia and also Japan, and sensibly below the wage cost of a ton of coal in Great Britain, Belgium, and the Netherlands. This of course does not necessarily mean that the total cost of a ton of coal in the United States is lower than in the other countries mentioned, since the natural, geographical and industrial conditions in America are very different from those existing in other parts of the world. To sum up, the general characteristics of the American coal industry may be stated to be high money earnings of mining employees, very high productivity of coal-mines, and relatively low wage cost of production. IMPRIMERIE DU JOURNAL DE 5-7, rue Général-Dufour, GENÈVE 5-7